2012-KER Crime LeeShin
2012-KER Crime LeeShin
2012-KER Crime LeeShin
8
I. Introduction
II. Model
When a person decides whether to supply his labor in the legal or illegal labor
market, the person considers his relative position in the distribution of expected
lifetime income rather than in the current distribution. The latter is related to
conventional static inequality measures such as the Gini coefficient, while the
former is determined by the entire lifetime income stream of the person, which in
turn depends on, among others, the mobility of the person to the income group
other than the one to which he belongs. Given this perspective, even a current low-
income earner would not have high crime incentive if he had better prospects in the
54 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
future. If one has higher expectation of upward mobility, then expected lifetime
income is high and so is the marginal cost of the current crime action; therefore, one
has lower crime incentive.
More precisely, we consider a utility maximization problem to explain individual
crime incentive. We assume that the individual has utility function
u( yi ,η i ) = V ( yi ) + η i , where yi is the income (or wealth) level of person i,
V ( yi ) > 0 , ∂V ( y) / ∂y > 0 , ∂ 2V ( y) / ∂y2 < 0 , and ηi is the psychological crime
disincentive factor of person i. In the literature, the psychological crime disincentive
factor ηi is normally specified as the individual level of honesty, which is
independent of income level. We emphasize, however, that the expected lifetime
income or expectation of future income mobility is another important determinant
for the psychological crime disincentive. To model such idea, we assume that
society is divided into two income groups, Gr (rich) and Gp (poor), whose
average income and population sizes are denoted as μ r , μ p , and nr , np ,
respectively. We then define
Consequently, the rich generally have a greater extent of crime disincentive than
the poor do.
The crime pays x with probability (1 − q) and − F (i.e., fine once the crime
is detected) with q . Similar to the standard crime model (e.g., Bourguignon, 1999),
individual i (assuming he is the only person to commit a crime; i.e., ceteris paribus)
opts for criminal activity if
____________________
3
For the rich class, even dishonest people usually do not involve themselves in criminal activity
because of the feeling of economic safety. Equation (2) may not be satisfied even when ηi = IMir .
56 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
group income gap is greater or when the within-group income distribution is less
dispersed. When income levels of individuals are more clustered around a local
mean, each individual feels a greater extent of group identity to members of their
own group, which enhances income class separation and lessens the subjective
probability of switching to the other group. To the extreme, if all individuals in the
lower income group had the same income level as μ p and all income levels of
individuals in the higher group were identical to μ r such that no bridge income
level exists in the society, the crime incentive of the poor would be high even for a
relatively small between-group income gap. Given these conditions, the average
feeling of immobility of the poor group is specified as follows.
Equation (5) describes how the expectation of future mobility of the poor group
affects the overall crime rate. To repeat, first, other things being equal, the between-
group income distance raises the subjective immobility of the poor group, which
____________________
4
In the empirical execution, we also attempt to use the ratio of within-group standard deviation to
overall standard deviation as an alternative measure of υ p and find little difference in the results.
Yoonseok Lee · Donggyun Shin: Mobility-Based Explanation of Crime Incentives 57
increases the crime incentive of the poor. Second, as income levels of individuals are
more clustered around μ p , the poor feel a greater extent of income class separation
(or group identity), which enhances the crime incentive of the poor (called the
“clustering effect”). In addition, equation (5) emphasizes the group size as an
additional crime determinant. Given the clustering effect, the poor feel a greater
extent of group identity as the group size increases, which is positively associated
with the crime incentive (called the “scale effect”). The poor tend to view the
income class separation more as a structural problem when the population
proportion of their income group increases; otherwise, income class separation is
viewed as a personal problem.
Finally, by substituting (5) into (3), the crime rate is determined by the following
equation.
____________________
5
Although not explicit in the current model, inclusion of the net gain from the current crime action
partly reflects imperfection of the labor market.
58 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
Finally, by obtaining comparable expressions for equation (4) and (5), the crime
rate in a society is determined by the following equation.
In the present setup, the hypothesis is that β p > 0 and β r < 0 ; a unit increase
in the group-specific measured immobility increases the crime rate among the poor
and decreases it among the rich. Whether the overall crime rate will increase or
decrease following a change in the current income distribution also depends on how
the change affects within-group dispersions as well as group sizes. Specifically,
given the hypothesis that β p > 0 and β r < 0 , if the change in the income
distribution enhances the size-adjusted group identity of the poor, υ p−1π p , and
weakens that of the rich, υ r−1π r , then the overall crime rate increases, other things
being equal. If the distribution change enhances the identification feelings of both
groups, the overall crime rate increases if and only if β p Δ(υ p−1π p ) > β r Δ(υ r−1π r ) .
This would be called weak asymmetry in the mobility-generated crime incentive
between the rich and the poor. Even given an equal increase in the extent of the
group-specific identification feeling, the crime rate increases if and only if
β p > β r , which is called strong asymmetry in the crime incentive. The main goal
of the next section is to verify that with all else being controlled for, our immobility
variable increases the crime rate among the poor in equation (6), and enhanced
immobility increases the crime incentive of the poor but reduces that of the rich in
equation (8) (or in the following equation (9)). Our sample also was tested for the
existence of asymmetry.
Yoonseok Lee · Donggyun Shin: Mobility-Based Explanation of Crime Incentives 59
The most challenging aspect of this empirical study is to compute our immobility
variable using micro data on individual households, which requires a large sample
size for each unit of analysis. In particular, for each unit of analysis in which crime
is examined, our immobility variable requires dividing the sample into the poor and
the rich and computing the Gini coefficient as well as various group-level statistics
for each group. Thus, a unit smaller than the country is difficult to consider in the
analysis.6 On the contrary, differences in the definition of household income often
make the comparison of various inequality and income mobility measures across
different countries difficult. Thus, we adopt country data from the Luxembourg
Income Study (LIS) database, which includes micro income data obtained from
many countries at different times. The LIS uses the same definition and
components of household income across countries, which renders more significance
to a cross-country comparison of income-related statistics. We use household
disposable income adjusted by the “OECD equivalency scale” (e.g., Atkinson,
Rainwater, and Smeeding, 1995) and household sample weights.
One more advantage of using country data is that when the unit of analysis is
very small, the local crime rate does not necessarily reflect the economic conditions
of the region. Criminals travel to neighborhoods in search of higher returns (e.g.,
Demombynes and Özler, 2005), or those who are frustrated in one region transfer to
another region where they have better prospects and thus decide to supply labor to
the legal labor market. This increased geographical interdependence makes the
analysis extremely complicated. By contrast, the crime market is closed at the
country level. The original LIS includes a large number of countries in its data set,
while our final regression sample has 100 country-year observations for 24 countries,
where the sampling frequency is approximately five years on average.7 The LIS
serves as our main data set, although we also supplement the results with another
country-level data set, the Cross-National Equivalent File (CNEF). The CNEF
uses sources of income data different from the LIS. Unlike the LIS, the CNEF
contains only longitudinal micro data sets for all member countries, enabling
longitudinal cross-country research on topics like employment and earnings
____________________
6
This may explain why none of the studies that investigate the relationship between crime and
inequality using the unit of observation smaller than the level of country include inequality measures
in their regression models (e.g., Cornwell and Trumbell, 1994; Glaeser, Sacerdote, and Scheinkman,
1996; Wilson and Daly, 1997; Kelly, 2000).
7
They are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland,
France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Mexico, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Slovenia,
Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
60 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
where log CRit represents the logarithm of the crime rate of country i in year t ,
immobility _ poor = μ −1(μr − μ p )υ p−1π p , immobility _ rich = μ −1(μr − μ p )υr−1π r ,
and netgain = (1 − μ μ p ) . log( police) is the logarithm of the police size. Xit
−1
2. Findings
Based on the LIS data, Figure 1 displays the sample correlation between the total
crime rate and our measure of immobility of the poor group, while Figure 2 shows
the result for the rich group. We normalize the total crime rate and the immobility
variable by the country-specific mean of each variable, exploiting within-variation of
each variable. Apparently, crime is positively correlated with the feeling of
immobility of the poor group and negatively correlated with the immobility of the
rich group. Although not reported for brevity, the CNEF also reveals similar
patterns.10 Technically speaking, these observed correlations would be obtained by
applying fixed-effect estimation of the crime rate with only the immobility variable
included in the right hand-side variable. In the following exercises, we test if these
observed patterns survive controlling for other variables.
____________________
9
A similar instrumental variable is suggested by Cornwell and Trumbull (1994). Information on
the numbers of violent and property crimes is obtained from the CTS.
10
The negative association of the crime rate and the immobility of the rich group is even more
apparent in the CNEF.
62 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
LIS CNEF
Variables
Specification 1 Specification 2 Specification 3 Specification 3
0.630*** 0.562** 1.607**
Immobility_Poor -
(0.238) (0.236) (0.643)
1.044 0.907 7.302**
Net gain of crime -
(0.812) (0.774) (3.058)
0.906 0.855 0.784 0.443**
Log(police)
(0.782) (0.787) (0.710) (0.195)
0.060*** 0.050*** 0.051*** 0.076
Urban population
(0.011) (0.010) (0.010) (0.082)
1.110 0.815 1.114 -15.760*
Young men
(0.902) (0.809) (0.952) (8.748)
0.020 0.034*** 0.023* -0.035
Unemployment rate
(0.016) (0.012) (0.014) (0.033)
0.052 -0.012 0.023 -1.136***
Education
(0.042) (0.035) (0.043) (0.434)
0.009*** 0.013*** 0.010*** 0.115***
Population density
(0.003) (0.003) (0.002) (0.042)
F-test of excluded instrument:
0.220 0.260 0.238 0.096
Prob>F
Hansen J-test 0.244 0.589 0.541 0.139
N: country-year 100 30
[country] [24] [5]
The dependent variable is the logarithm of the number of total crimes per 100,000. Our
immobility variable is measured based on household income data from the LIS and the CNEF.
Fixed-effect GMM estimation with HAC standard error estimates. The police size is
instrumented by the TAX-GDP-RATIO and CRIME COMPOSITION. *, **, *** =
significance at 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively.
the net gain is controlled for. Evidence from the CNEF also suggests that although
the crime rate increases in the net gain, the income immobility also increases the
crime rate significantly even after the net gain is controlled for. The effects of other
control variables are generally consistent with those in existing studies. Overall,
other things held constant, the crime rate increases in the population share of those
living in urban areas, the population density, and the unemployment rate.
[Table 2] Asymmetry between the Rich and the Poor in the Immobility Effect
Table 2 shows estimation results of equation (9). Consistent with our hypothesis
that enhanced immobility increases crime incentive of the poor but decreases that of
the rich, both data sets show that estimated β p is positive and estimated β r is
negative. As a minor difference between the two data sets, while the LIS reveals that
the estimated coefficient of the immobility of the rich group is negative but
insignificant, the corresponding estimate obtained from the CNEF data is negative
both statistically and substantially. Also consistent with the conventional belief, the
crime rate increases when criminals expect higher returns net of their opportunity
costs. Estimated coefficients of other control variables remain similar to those in
Yoonseok Lee · Donggyun Shin: Mobility-Based Explanation of Crime Incentives 65
Table 1.
Our model addresses how the poor and the rich groups behave differently in
response to a change in the income distribution. Note that the extent of the feeling
of immobility of each group ( immobility _ poor or immobility _ rich in equation
(9)) is measured by the product of the between-group income distance and the
extent of size-adjusted within-group clustering. Estimates presented in Table 2
indicate the marginal effect of a unit-increase in the feeling of immobility of each
group. Evidence obtained from the LIS data supports the strong asymmetry
hypothesis; given an equal increase in the extent of the feeling of immobility for
both groups, the rise in the crime incentive of the poor is greater than the reduction
in the crime incentive of the rich. Evaluation of whether the crime rate increases
following a change in the income distribution requires information on how the
distribution change affects the expectation of future immobility of each group. Our
LIS sample shows that the average change between two adjacent years (on average,
five years apart) in the measured immobility feeling is 0.015 and -0.001 for the poor
and the rich group, respectively. Therefore, the feeling of immobility of the rich
group has actually weakened albeit by a small extent, which resulted in an increase
in the crime rate even among the rich. Finally, the estimated overall immobility
effect generated by a distribution change is approximately 0.008 for the poor, while
the comparable figure for the rich is 0.0001. Evidence obtained from the CNEF
shows similar results. As previously stated, estimates obtained from the CNEF
sample do not support the strong asymmetry hypothesis, as the estimated coefficient
of the immobility variable is larger in an absolute value for the rich than the poor.
However, even the CNEF sample observes a reduction in our measure of the
feeling of immobility among the rich; the average change between two adjacent
years (on average, two years apart) in the measured feeling of immobility is 0.007
and -0.0015 for the poor and the rich group, respectively. Consequently, the
estimated overall immobility effect of the poor is approximately 0.007, while the
comparable figure for the rich is 0.003.
In sum, estimates show that the feeling of income class separation or between-
group immobility is an important determinant of the decision of individuals to
engage in crime, and enhanced immobility increases the crime incentive of the poor
but decreases the crime incentive of the rich. Evidence obtained from the LIS data
also supports the hypothesis of strong asymmetry between the poor and the rich in
the crime incentive/disincentive generated by enhanced feeling of immobility.
IV. Conclusion
Both our theoretical reasoning and empirical execution suggest that the decision
66 The Korean Economic Review Volume 28, Number 1, Summer 2012
References