Regulating Digital Piracy Consumption
Regulating Digital Piracy Consumption
Regulating Digital Piracy Consumption
∗ † ‡
Jieteng Chen Yuetao Gao T. Tony Ke
December 25, 2023
Abstract
Regulators across the globe have imposed penalties on consumers for digital piracy
consumption. Contrary to expectations, however, digital piracy consumption has con-
tinued to grow. We develop a simple model of competition between a copyright holder
and a pirate firm to offer a plausible account for this observation as well as actionable
guidelines for optimal regulation design. The core of our idea is to endogenize the pi-
rate firm’s strategic investment in anti-tracking technologies that help consumers evade
a regulator’s penalty. We find that as the penalty rises, piracy consumption can sur-
prisingly increase after decreasing first; relatedly, the copyright holder and the society
may suffer from tighter regulation. Depending on the cost of anti-tracking technologies
of the pirate firm, the regulator optimally sets the penalty to operate in two different
regimes. When the technology is available at a low cost, the regulator can achieve the
goals of maximizing social welfare and minimizing piracy consumption simultaneously
by setting a moderate penalty that maximizes consumers’ expected penalty and toler-
ates some level of piracy consumption. In contrast, when the technology is costly, the
regulator should set a relatively high penalty to completely impede piracy supply. Ad-
ditionally, we show that supply-side regulation does not substitute away demand-side
regulation, and educating consumers about copyright protection may unintentionally
lead to an increase in piracy consumption. Lastly, we identify complex non-monotonic
long-run effects of piracy consumption regulation on the copyright holder’s incentives
for content creation and copyright protection.
Keywords:
digital piracy, regulation, copyright protection
∗
Department of Marketing, Business School, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, Hong Kong,
China. Email: jieteng.chen@link.cuhk.edu.hk
†
Department of Marketing, School of Management, Xiamen University, Xiamen, Fujian, China. Email:
ytgao@xmu.edu.cn
‡
Department of Marketing, Business School, The Chinese University of Hong Kong, Shatin, Hong Kong,
China. Email: tonyke@cuhk.edu.hk
Digital piracy refers to the act of illegally downloading and distributing copyrighted
digital material over the Internet. Digital piracy is a serious problem that has witnessed an
unprecedented rise over the years (Brown and Holt 2021). According to Blackburn, Eisenach,
and Harrison Jr (2019), digital piracy annually eroded $29.2–71 billion revenue and drained
230,000–560,000 jobs of the U.S. economy. A report by an anti-piracy solution provider
(MUSO 2022) estimates that piracy websites attracted 182 billion visits globally in 2021—a
15.2% increase from 2020.
Pirated digital content is commonly downloaded by piracy users for no monetary cost
through peer-to-peer networks (such as torrent) using notorious piracy websites. Pirate
Bay is one such example, consistently topping the list of the most visited piracy websites
among torrenting users in recent years. In response to digital piracy consumption, regulators
across the globe have enacted or strengthened regulations by penalizing users who download
pirated digital content, with the aim of curbing these activities. For instance, in 2008, the
U.S. issued the PRO-IP Act, which boosted civil penalties for copyright infringement from
$500–100,000 to $1,000–200,000. Likewise, in 2021, France replaced the 13-year-old anti-
piracy agency HADOPI (High Authority for the Distribution of Works and the Protection of
Rights on the Internet) with a new regulatory body named ARCOM (Regulatory Authority
for Audiovisual and Digital Communication), aimed at producing tighter regulation and
stronger protection of access to digital content. These demand-side regulations are unique
to digital content, as digital consumption can be traced by regulators much more easily than
physical transactions.
Given the high penalty invoked by the above regulations, one might naturally intuit that
piracy users would be reluctant to visit Pirate Bay. Contrary to the intuition, however, user
visits to Pirate Bay, as measured by Google Trends, have actually risen since the inception of
these regulations, as shown in Figure 1.1 Similar trends have also been observed with respect
1
There is no intention to infer any causal relationship from these time series; rather, they show that these digital
100
The PRO-IP Act in the U.S.
80
60
40
Apr 13, 2008 Jul 13, 2008 Oct 13, 2008 Jan 13, 2009 Apr 13, 2009
(Effective Date)
100
The HADOPI Law in France
80
60
40
Apr 30, 2009 Jul 30, 2009 Oct 30, 2009 Jan 30, 2010 Apr 30, 2010
(Effective Date)
100
The ARCOM Law in France
80
60
40
Apr 27, 2021 Jul 27, 2021 Oct 27, 2021 Jan 27, 2022 Apr 27, 2022
(Effective Date)
Figure 1: Pirate Bay’s Google Trends Before and After Enforcement of New Anti-Piracy
Laws
Most piracy websites, including Pirate Bay, make money from advertising revenue, which
is positively associated with the traffic volume of piracy users. Pirate Bay thus suffers when
its users avoid surfing its website out of concerns about high regulatory penalties. To counter
this user reluctance, Pirate Bay constantly invests in new technologies or exerts efforts that
help piracy users evade regulators’ attempts to track their footage on its website. Table 1
piracy regulations are not effective (or not effective enough) to suppress the ongoing growth of piracy consumption.
Google Trends, which measures the popularity of search queries on Google, has been used as a proxy for piracy
consumption in the literature (e.g., Lu, Rajavi, and Dinner 2021).
2
This study was originally written in French, and its main findings were summarized in English in a news report
https://tinyurl.com/4nbzut8w (france24.com) [retrieved from waybackmachine; accessed April 7, 2023].
Time Actions
2008 Supported SSL encryption in response to Sweden’s new wiretap-
ping law
2008 Inserted “random IP addresses” automatically to pollute the evi-
dence gathering of anti-piracy outfits
2010 Offered the IPREDator VPN service that keeps piracy users
anonymous and safe from being tracked by law enforcement
2012 Switched from torrents to untraceable magnet links, which makes
it more difficult to determine who has downloaded a file using the
website
2013 Released a free web browser, PirateBrowser, to circumvent inter-
net censorship
2020 Used the IP address operated by an anonymous VPN service
provider, OPVN, which does not store any logs
regulator’s penalty for piracy consumption. Consumers differ in their preference regarding
product quality and choose between copyrighted and pirated products subject to a potential
penalty.
Our equilibrium analysis shows that when the pirate firm can develop anti-tracking tech-
nologies at a relatively low cost, piracy supply cannot be completely eliminated from the
market no matter how high the penalty imposed on piracy users is, because the pirate firm
will always participate in the market by investing in these technologies to help consumers
evade the penalty. More importantly, we find that piracy consumption exhibits a U-shape
with the penalty, where an increase in the penalty can surprisingly promote piracy consump-
tion when the penalty is relatively high. The rise in piracy consumption is again driven by the
MODEL SETUP
Consider a consumer market of size one served by two firms. A legal firm holds the
copyright for a digital product with quality v > 0, and a pirate firm offers a pirated version
of the product with quality βv, where β ∈ (0, 1) can be seen as the copyright holder’s
copyright protection level, as copyrighted products are generally superior to their pirated
counterparts (Jain 2008; Guo and Meng 2015).5 Marginal production costs of the firms are
set as zero due to the nature of digital products. The copyright holder charges price pc for its
copyrighted products. Consistent with common practice and the literature (Dey, Kim, and
Lahiri 2019), we assume that the pirate firm offers its products for free to consumers and
earns revenue kDp from advertising, where k > 0 is the expected ad revenue per consumer
and Dp is consumer demand for pirated products.6
5
We will endogenize the copyright holder’s product quality as well as the quality differential between copyrighted
and pirated products in two extensions respectively.
6
This model specification captures the commonly observed practice that copyright holders and pirate firms
typically adopt different revenue models. Piracy websites, such as Pirate Bay, are essentially online platforms that
uc = θv − pc ,
up = θβv − xt,
where θ measures consumers’ preference for product quality and is assumed to follow a
uniform distribution in [0, 1] across consumers. Consumers also have an outside option of
monetize visitor traffic through sponsored ads; copyright holders, like software developers, in general profit from
selling their own products directly to consumers and do not accommodate ads from other firms. Nevertheless, we
allow the pirate firm to adopt pricing-based revenue model in an extension.
7
We focus on demand-side regulation in this paper. While the regulator can also rely on supply-side regulation
to fight piracy, it involves other complexities. For example, piracy websites, such as Pirate Bay, could locate their
servers anywhere globally and actively modify their domain names to evade detection. As such, it is difficult to shut
down piracy websites via supply-side regulation. Nevertheless, we will incorporate supply-side regulation formally in
Section of Policy Implications. Additionally, as in Becker (1968) and Wu and Geylani (2020), a higher t could result
from a higher punishment level and/or a higher enforcement level. In Section of Policy Implications, we consider
Internet service provider (ISP) as an intermediary between the regulator and consumers, who can influence the
enforcement level.
8
In an extension, we allow anti-tracking actions to be initiated by consumers instead of the pirate firm.
Assumption 1.
1−β
γ< .
β
The assumption ensures that the fraction of ethical consumers is not too large; otherwise,
the copyright holder may only serve ethical consumers, unethical consumers may only adopt
pirated products, and consequently, there is no direct competition between the two firms.10
Notice that γ is allowed to take the value of zero under the assumption. Put differently, our
results do not rely on the existence of ethical consumers in the market.
EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS
We solve the game by backward induction. Given that the pirate firm’s products are of
lower quality and entail a potential penalty for piracy consumption, it may be unprofitable
for the pirate firm to participate in the market when facing competition with the copyright
holder. This implies that there are two subgames to study.
In subgame I, both firms operate in the market. Let us first analyze the demand of
unethical consumers, who choose between the two products and the outside option based
9
In an extension, we study two alternative timings of the game where the copyright holder moves either before
or after the pirate firm, and we find the equilibrium outcome does not change qualitatively.
10
The analysis for sufficient large γ is provided in Section of Policy Implications.
pc − xt pc
uc ≥ up ⇔ θ ≥ , and uc ≥ 0 ⇔ θ ≥ ,
(1 − β)v v
where the first constraint reflects the copyright holder’s demand loss from unethical con-
sumers due to the existence of pirated products. That is, the demand loss can be measured
by the segment of unethical consumers with θ ∈ [pc /v, (pc − xt)/[(1 − β)v]) as they would
purchase copyrighted products in the absence of pirated products.
Analogously, an unethical consumer adopts a pirated product if and only if
pc − xt xt
up ≥ uc ⇔ θ ≤ , and up ≥ 0 ⇔ θ ≥ .
(1 − β)v βv
Since
pc − xt pc pc − xt xt xt
> ⇔ > ⇔ pc > ,
(1 − β)v v (1 − β)v βv β
there are two cases to consider depending on the comparison between pc and xt/β, as shown
in Figure 3. Note that when pc ≤ xt/β, pirated products generate no demand even when
offered. The left panel in Figure 3 demonstrates the consumer market segmentation where
patrons of piracy tend to have intermediate θ. To map this result to real-world observations,
notice that θ can be reinterpreted as a measure of consumer income.11 Demand for piracy
emerges due to copyright streaming services owning content that is typically unavailable in
other portals. Therefore, the left panel in Figure 3 implies that consumers with intermediate
income are most interested in accessing content across platforms via piracy, because their
income is not very low so that they are still willing to bear the risk of a potential piracy
penalty but not very high so that they are subject to budget constraints.
11
On page 97, Tirole (1988) defines u(I) as a consumer’s utility over her income I and shows that θ = u′ (I)−1 ,
which increases with I due to concavity of u(·).
10
Furthermore, notice that ethical consumers’ demand is always given by Case (b). Conse-
quently, we can write down consumer demand for copyrighted products and pirated products
respectively as:
h i
pc pc −xt xt
γ 1 −
+ (1 − γ) 1 − if pc > ,
v (1−β)v β
DcI (pc , x) =
1 −
pc
v
otherwise;
h i
(1 − γ) pc −xt − xt xt
(1−β)v βv
if pc > β
,
DpI (pc , x) =
0 otherwise,
s xt
ΠIp (pc , x) = kDpI (pc , x) − (1 − x)2 for pc > .
2 β
11
∗ (1 − γ)kt
x = max 1 − ,0 . (1)
β(1 − β)sv
Interestingly, the pirate firm’s best response function, x∗ , does not depend on pc .12 Cor-
respondingly, the pirate firm’s maximum profit under x∗ is,
h i
(1−γ)k pc −
t (1−γ)kt2
(1−β)v β
+ 2β 2 (1−β)sv
if 0 ≤ t < T,
ΠIp (pc , x∗ ) =
(1−γ)kpc −
s
otherwise;
(1−β)v 2
β(1−β)sv
where T ≡ (1−γ)k
. The pirate firm will participate in the market if and only if
t −
(1−γ)kt2
β 2β 2 (1−β)sv
if 0 ≤ t < T,
ΠIp (pc , x∗ ) > 0 ⇔ pc > pec ≡
(1−β)sv
otherwise;
2(1−γ)k
To summarize subgame I and subgame II along with the pirate firm’s participation con-
straint, we have consumer demand for two types of products as follows:
h i n o
pc pc −xt xt
γ 1 −
+ (1 − γ) 1 − if pc > max , pec ,
v (1−β)v β
Dc (pc , x) =
1 −
pc
v
otherwise;
h i n o
(1 − γ) pc −xt − xt xt
(1−β)v βv
if pc > max β
, pec ,
Dp (pc , x) =
0 otherwise.
12
The key driving forces behind the independence of x∗ and pc are that (1) the pirate firm’s demand is linear in
x, which results from the uniform distribution of the consumer quality preference, and (2) the pirate firm’s profit
margin does not depend on pc nor x. Consequently, the marginal return from a lower x is a constant that does not
depend on pc . In other words, by investing in a better anti-tracking technology, the pirate firm gains some marginal
consumers who would have chosen the copyrighted product in the absence of the investment, and the number as well
as profitability of these marginal consumers do not depend on the current market share of the pirate firm and thus
do not depend on the competing copyright holder’s price, pc .
12
Proposition 1 solves the equilibrium price and tracking probability by a set of equations
as follows:
p∗ = arg max Πc (pc , x∗ ),
c pc
where given p∗c and x∗ , we can define the equilibrium demand Dj∗ ≡ Dj (p∗c , x∗ ) and the
equilibrium profit Π∗j ≡ Πj (p∗c , x∗ ) for j ∈ {c, p}. We will provide necessary derivations or
elaborations that lead to each proposition in the main text but relegate complete proofs to
Web Appendix.
(i) if 0 < s < s or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t, the pirate firm’s equilibrium anti-tracking
technology choice is
∗ (1 − γ)kt
x = max 1 − ,0 ,
β(1 − β)sv
(1 − β)v + (1 − γ)x∗ t
p∗c = ;
2(1 − γβ)
(ii) otherwise, if s ≥ s and t ≥ t, the pirate firm does not participate in the market, and
the copyright holder’s equilibrium price is
n vo
p∗c = min pec , .
2
Proposition 1 implies that when the technology cost is relatively low with 0 < s < s or
13
EFFECTS OF REGULATION
In this section, we examine the effects of piracy consumption regulation on the equilibrium
outcome in a series of propositions. To begin with, we are interested in how penalty t
influences the pirate firm’s anti-tracking technology choice and consumers’ expected penalty.
Proposition 2 states the results. By Proposition 1, when s ≥ s, we restrict ourselves to
0 ≤ t < t, because otherwise, x∗ is not well defined.
(i) (a) If 0 < s < s, x∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < T and stays at zero for t ≥ T ;
(ii) There exists a threshold s that does not depend on t such that
(a) if 0 < s < s, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < T ,
and stays at zero for t ≥ T ;
(b) if s ≤ s < s, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t and decreases with t for t ≤ t < t;
The relationship between x∗ and t has a clear intuition—as penalty t increases, the
pirate firm reduces x∗ to keep its products still attractive for unethical consumers, whose
consumption utility of pirated products, up , depends on the whole term of x∗ t, the expected
14
d(x∗ t) dx∗
∗ (1 − γ)kt (1 − γ)k
= x + ×t =1− + − ×t . (2)
dt |{z} dt{z } β(1 − β)sv β(1 − β)sv
direct effect | | {z } | {z }
strategic effect direct effect strategic effect
Here, we focus on the situation where x∗ > 0; otherwise, the expected penalty will never
change even if the regulator further increases the penalty. The first part in Equation (2) is
the positive direct effect. The second part is the negative strategic effect and comes from the
pirate firm’s strategic investment in improving its anti-tracking technology in response to
tighter regulation. It is somewhat surprising that the strategic effect can dominate the direct
effect when s is relatively low and t is relatively high. In fact, one may interpret penalty t
as a form of tax on piracy consumption, and further intuit that while the pirate firm has an
incentive to compensate consumers by reducing x∗ to mitigate the adverse effect of piracy
tax, the compensation is a second-order effect that will never override the first-order effect
of taxation per se. However, it turns out that this intuition is incorrect, as shown in Figure
4. This is because the pirate firm’s compensation for consumers is not a simple monetary
transfer; instead, the effective tax on consumers is the expected penalty, x∗ t, which is jointly
determined by the regulator and the pirate firm, who bears a technology development cost
of s(1 − x∗ )2 /2. Since the pirate firm’s marginal benefit of reducing x∗ , (1 − γ)kt/[β(1 − β)v],
increases with t, the pirate firm has strong incentives to lower x when the penalty is high.
As a result, the strategic effect can override the direct effect under a high penalty.
15
0.026
Expected Penalty
0.042
Expected Penalty
0.018 0.028
0.009 0.014
0.000 0.000
t T t t
Penalty Penalty
16
(i) If 0 < s < s, Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, increases with t for t ≤ t < T , and is
invariant in t for t ≥ T .
(ii) If s ≤ s < s, Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, increases with t for t ≤ t < t, and stays
at zero for t ≥ t.
(iii) Otherwise, if s ≥ s, Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t and stays at zero for t ≥ t.
0.471 0.471
Piracy Consumption
Piracy Consumption
0.448 0.353
0.425 0.236
0.402 0.118
0.378 0.000
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
Furthermore, we study how regulation affects the copyright holder’s price and profit,
which are summarized in Proposition 4. When 0 < s < s, the copyright holder’s equilibrium
price and profit exhibit an inverse U-shape with t for 0 ≤ t < T and are invariant in t for
t ≥ T , which can also be explained by the inverse U-shape between x∗ t and t for 0 ≤ t < T
and invariance between x∗ t and t for t ≥ T as shown in Proposition 2. The similar inverse
U-shape exhibits for 0 ≤ t < t when s ≤ s < s. When s ≥ s, it is interesting to see that
the copyright holder drops its price discretely at t = t so as to edge the pirate firm out
of the market. As t further increases, the maximum price the copyright holder can charge
17
(i) If 0 < s < s, p∗c increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < T , and is
invariant in t for t ≥ T .
(ii) If s ≤ s < s, p∗c increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < t, drops
discretely at t = t, increases with t for t ≤ t < T , and is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
(iii) Otherwise, if s ≥ s, p∗c increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, drops discretely at t = t, increases
with t for t ≤ t < T , and is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
The relationship between Π∗c and t is the same as between p∗c and t except that Π∗c is continuous
in t with no drop at t = t if s ≥ s.
0.257 0.267
0.253 0.245
Price
Price
0.249 0.222
0.245 0.200
0.241 0.177
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
18
Pro-t
0.129 0.142
0.125 0.131
0.120 0.120
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
Lastly, we analyze the effect of regulation on consumer surplus and social welfare in
Propositions 5 and 6. We consider two measures in calculating consumer surplus and social
welfare. First, in calculating consumer surplus (CS) and social welfare (SW ), we exclude
consumer surplus from pirated products as well as penalty fees. This reflects the idea that
the regulator should not design policies aiming to maximize consumer surplus gains from
consuming illegal products. Second, we also calculate total consumer surplus (T CS) and
total social welfare (T SW ), which further include consumer surplus from consuming pirated
products and penalty fees.
(i) (a) If 0 < s < s, CS exhibits a non-monotonic relationship with t in general for
0 ≤ t < T and is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
(ii) (a) If 0 < s < s, T CS decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, increases with t for t ≤ t < T ,
and is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
19
0.251 0.338
0.251 0.316
Consumer Surplus
Consumer Surplus
0.251 0.294
0.250 0.272
0.250 0.250
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
0.319 0.338
Total Consumer Surplus
0.313 0.325
0.308 0.311
0.302 0.297
0.296 0.283
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
Consumer surplus (CS) is calculated by integrating over all consumers who buy copy-
righted products, where the surplus for each consumer equals her valuation of a copyrighted
product minus price p∗c . A higher expected penalty has two opposing effects on CS: (1) it
makes pirated products less attractive and thus increases consumer demand for copyrighted
products, and (2) it induces the copyright holder to charge a higher price. These two op-
posing effects result in a non-monotonic relationship between CS and x∗ t. Furthermore, as
20
(i) (a) If 0 < s < s, SW increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < T ,
and is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
(b) If s ≤ s < s, SW increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < t,
jumps discretely at t = t, decreases with t for t ≤ t < T , and is invariant in t for
t ≥ T.
21
0.389 0.484
0.384 0.456
Social Welfare
Social Welfare
0.380 0.427
0.375 0.399
0.370 0.370
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
0.447 0.484
Total Social Welfare
0.445 0.473
0.443 0.462
0.442 0.451
0.440 0.440
t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
Social welfare (SW ) comprises CS and the copyright holder’s profit. When 0 < s < s,
as the expected penalty rises, more consumers buy copyrighted products and the copyright
holder’s profit grows, which in turn improves SW . This implies that the pattern of SW
follows that of the expected penalty, peaking at t = t. When s ≥ s, analogously, the
relationship between SW and t follows that between x∗ t and t for 0 ≤ t < t. However, the
22
POLICY IMPLICATIONS
After solving the equilibrium and identifying the effects of regulation, we analyze a series
of policy tools that could help the regulator combat piracy. We start by solving the welfare-
maximizing regulation.
Optimal Regulation
23
Proposition 7 follows directly from Proposition 6. Let’s start with the scenario where
the regulator wants to maximize social welfare (SW ). When the pirate firm can develop
anti-tracking technologies at a relatively low cost with 0 < s < s, SW is maximized at the
moderate penalty t = t, where the expected penalty hits the maximum (Proposition 2) and
piracy consumption touches the minimum but cannot be completely eliminated (Proposition
3). The reason is that a penalty higher than t will encourage more consumer adoption
of pirated products and thus hurt the copyright holder due to the pirate firm’s strategic
investment in anti-tracking technologies. Therefore, a moderate penalty that maximizes the
expected penalty can simultaneously maximize SW and minimize piracy consumption. This
suggests the following actionable guideline for policymaking in this scenario: To achieve the
social optimum, the regulator should simply resort to maximizing the expected penalty when
setting the penalty. On the other hand, we also find that when s ≥ s, SW is peaked at the
high penalty t = t that edges the pirate firm out of the market.
Next, we consider the scenario where the regulator tries to maximize total social welfare
(T SW ) that includes the consumer surplus from pirated products and penalty fees. The
optimal penalty that maximizes T SW is the same as that maximizing SW , except for the
case when s ≥ s+ . As shown in Figure 10, when s > s+ , T SW increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t+ ,
then decreases with t for t+ ≤ t < t, and reaches the maximum at t = t+ . In comparison,
SW increases monotonically with t for 0 ≤ t < t. The difference comes from the consumer
surplus from pirated products and penalty fees, which decrease with the expected penalty
and thus decrease with t given s > s+ . Consequently, the global maximizer of T SW could
be either t = t+ or t = t as shown in Figure 10. At t = t, the copyright holder will set a low
price to force the pirate firm out of the market, and this task is easier to achieve when the
anti-tracking technology is costly. As a result, copyrighted products’ price at t = t increases
with s, and hence, T SW at this point becomes lower under a higher s. Therefore, when
24
0.432
0.411
0.391
0.370
t+ t
Penalty
Figure 10: Effect of Penalty on Social Welfare and Total Social Welfare for s ≥ s+
(v = 1, β = 0.55, γ = 0.12, k = 1, s = 260)
Supply-Side Regulation
In practice, regulators can also explore supply-side regulations to combat piracy. Will
supply-side regulations completely replace the role of demand-side regulations? As we have
argued earlier, this is unlikely, as it may prove challenging to rely on supply-side regulations
solely to completely shut down piracy websites, who have the ability to host their servers
globally and constantly alter their domain names to avoid detection. We formally examine
the role of supply-side regulation and its relationship with demand-side regulation next.
Specifically, we extend the main model by allowing the regulator to exert an effort of
d·y 2 /2 to raid and take down the pirate firm with probability y ∈ [0, 1], where d > 0 is a cost
parameter. As a result, given the regulator’s supply-side investment, with probability y, we
end up with the copyright holder as the monopoly in the market, and with the complementary
probability of 1 − y, the market remains the same as in the main model.
If social welfare (SW ) is the regulator’s target, it will choose t and y to maximize ySW M +
(1−y)SW −d·y 2 /2, where SW M is social welfare when the copyright holder monopolizes the
market. On the other hand, if the regulator seeks to maximize total social welfare (T SW ),
its objective becomes yT SW M + (1 − y)T SW − d · y 2 /2, where by definition, T SW M =
SW M . Solving the regulator’s joint maximization problem, we obtain the optimal supply-
25
Proposition 8.
(ii) When the regulator aims to maximize T SW , y ∗ = 0 and the optimal demand-side
regulation t∗ is the same as in Proposition 7.
Proposition 8 implies that even if the regulator has access to supply-side regulation, it
does not use it unless s is low. The intuition is that using supply-side regulation to shut down
the pirate firm softens market competition and thus hurts social welfare. When SW M < SW
(T SW M < T SW ), the regulator will optimally choose y ∗ = 0 to maximize (total) social
welfare. An active supply-side regulation is implemented only when s is sufficiently low such
that 0 < s < min{ŝ, s}, under which case, so much piracy is supplied in the market such
that too many consumers switch from the copyright holder to the pirate firm, which reduces
SW . In a nutshell, Proposition 8 suggests that supply-side regulation may be useful when
the anti-tracking technology is available at a sufficiently low cost, but it does not substitute
the role of demand-side regulation even when it is being actively used.
26
The condition of 0 < t < t̂ in Proposition 9 ensures that the penalty is not prohibitively
high so that the pirate firm remains active in the market. The proposition shows that a
higher γ could increase piracy consumption. This is also illustrated in Figure 11 below. The
intuition is that as the fraction of ethical consumers in the market increases, the copyright
holder may find it more profitable to give up all unethical consumers and serve only ethi-
cal consumers by setting the monopoly price. As a result, this would lead to an increase in
piracy consumption from unethical consumers, because all of them now turn to pirated prod-
ucts. Moreover, it can be verified that this result does not depend on whether the tracking
probability x is exogenous or endogenous. In summary, it seems educating consumers about
ethical and legal usage of copyrighted products could inadvertently increase piracy consump-
tion, and thus cannot replace the role of punitive regulation on piracy consumption.
0.535
Piracy Consumption
0.401
0.268
0.134
0.000
1!-
-
e
. 1
.
27
This extension considers two alternative timings of the game. First, when the copyright
holder sets pc before the pirate firm sets x, we find that the equilibrium outcome is exactly
the same as in the main model. This is because the pirate firm’s optimal choice x∗ does
not depend on the copyright holder’s price pc , as shown by Equation (1). Second, when the
pirate firm sets x before the copyright holder sets pc , Proposition 10 states that our main
findings are robust.
Proposition 10. There exist thresholds sat and sat such that
(i) if 0 < s < sat , x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < tat , decreases with t for tat ≤ t < T at ,
and is invariant in t for t ≥ T at , while Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < tat , increases
with t for tat ≤ t < T at , and is invariant in t for t ≥ T at ;15
at
(ii) if sat ≤ s < sat , x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < tat and decreases with t for tat ≤ t < t ,
at
while Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < tat and increases with t for tat ≤ t < t ;
at
(iii) otherwise, if s ≥ sat , x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t , while Dp∗ decreases with t for
at
0≤t<t .
In this extension, we consider the copyright holder to be the digital content creator
and explore the impact of regulation on its incentives to invest in quality improvement for
its products (content creativity). Specifically, we add a pre-stage to the game where the
copyright holder decides on quality v of its products, which entails a cost of mv 2 /2. The
copyright holder’s profit is Φc (v) = Π∗c (v)−mv 2 /2, where m > 0 is assumed to be sufficiently
15
The superscript ”at” stands for ”alternative timing”, and it signifies thresholds in this extension. For conve-
nience, we omit the superscript for all equilibrium variables in Extensions.
28
dv ∗ ∂Φ′ (v)/∂t
= − c ′′ ,
dt Φc (v) v=v ∗
which is in the same sign as ∂Φ′c (v)/∂t, as Φ′′c (v) < 0 by concavity of Φc (v). It is more
convenient to explicitly signify the dependence of Φc (v) on t by introducing ϕc (v, t) =
Φc (v); furthermore, we can isolate the impact of t on ϕc (v, t) through x∗ by introducing
ϕec (v, t, x∗ (v, t)) = ϕc (v, t) = Φc (v). Then, we have
!
dv ∗ ∂Φ′c (v) ∂ 2 ϕc ∂ 2 ϕec ∂ 2 ϕec ∂x∗ ∂ 2 ϕec ∂ 2 ϕec ∂x∗ ∂x∗ ∂ ϕec ∂ 2 x∗
∝ = = + + + + ∗ . (3)
dt ∂t ∂v∂t ∂v∂t ∂v∂x∗ ∂t ∂x∗ ∂t ∂x∗2 ∂t ∂v ∂x ∂v∂t
The first term on the right-hand side in Equation (3) is a direct effect under exogenous
x, which can be shown to be negative (see details in Web Appendix). That is, raising the
penalty induces lower product quality because the copyright holder faces weaker competition
from the pirate firm and thus has fewer incentives to differentiate its products from pirated
products. The remaining terms consist of an indirect effect due to endogenous x, which can
be shown to be positive for 0 ≤ t < T when 0 < s < s, and for 0 ≤ t < t when s ≥ s.
Intuitively, the pirate firm’s investment in anti-tracking technologies intensifies competition
and thus prompts the copyright holder to invest more in quality improvement.
29
1.044 0.971
0.952 0.875
0.860 0.780
T t T
Penalty Penalty
In Figure 12, we show that the indirect effect can dominate the direct effect such that
v ∗ increases with penalty t. Moreover, the left panel in Figure 12 illustrates that when t is
sufficiently high, v ∗ is determined as if there is no regulation in the market because the pirate
firm always sets x∗ = 0, given that the copyright holder’s equilibrium profit is the function
of x∗ t. Lastly, the right panel in Figure 12 also reveals that v ∗ first drops discretely at t = t
and then increases with t. The drop is explained by the copyright holder’s strategic use of
a low price to force the pirate firm out of the market, whereas the subsequent increasing
relationship is due to stronger protection of monopoly profit with a higher penalty. Note
that Π∗c (v) is invariant in t for t ≥ T , so v ∗ stays the same for t ≥ T .
In this extension, we add a pre-stage to the game where the copyright holder engages in
copyright protection by influencing the quality of pirated products. In other words, we allow
the copyright holder to control β. The lower the β, the stronger the copyright protection.
To this end, we specify the copyright holder’s profit as Φc (β) = Π∗c (β) − h(1 − β)2 /2, where
h > 0 is assumed to be sufficiently high so that Φc (β) is concave in β. The optimal copyright
protection β ∗ is determined by the first-order optimality condition, Φ′c (β)|β=β ∗ = 0. By
30
dβ ∗ ∂Φ′ (β)/∂t
= − c ′′ ,
dt Φc (β) β=β ∗
which has the same sign with ∂Φ′c (β)/∂t because Φ′′c (β) < 0 by concavity of Φc (β). To
separate the impact of t on Φc (β) through x∗ , we introduce ϕec (β, t, x∗ (β, t)) = ϕc (β, t) =
Φc (β). Then, we have
where the first term on the right-hand side in Equation (4) is a direct positive effect under
exogenous x. That is, tighter regulation results in weaker copyright protection since the
copyright holder faces weak competition from the pirate firm. The remaining three terms
consist of an indirect effect under endogenous x, with the first term being negative. Intu-
itively, when penalty t is high, the pirate firm has an incentive to reduce x∗ to compete with
the copyright holder. To avoid intense competition, the copyright holder may reduce β to
enlarge vertical differentiation between the two firms to mitigate this incentive.
The direct effect or the indirect effect can dominate, so β ∗ can increase or decrease with
t, as shown in Figure 13 (a) and (b). The two panels also demonstrate that β ∗ is identical
when t = 0 and when t is sufficiently high since x∗ t = 0 for both cases. Moreover, Figure 13
(c) and (d) illustrate that β ∗ can jump (drop) discretely at t = t and then decrease (increase)
with t for the case of high s. That is, to drive the pirate firm out of the market, the copyright
holder can choose a combination of a higher pec and a lower β or a combination of a lower pec
and a higher β, depending on which one is more cost-effective. Furthermore, β ∗ is constant
for t ≥ T because Π∗c (β) is invariant in t for t ≥ T .
31
0.565 0.409
0.555 0.392
0.546 0.375
T T
Penalty Penalty
0.641 0.444
Optimal Copyright Protection
0.597 0.398
0.575 0.375
0.554 0.352
t T t T
Penalty Penalty
Figure 14 below illustrates that piracy consumption can increase with the penalty when
the copyright holder endogenously determines β. On the one hand, as in the main model,
an increase in t directly induces the pirate firm to reduce x to help piracy users evade the
penalty. On the other hand, an increase in t also affects β ∗ , which can indirectly mitigate
the pirate firm’s incentives to reduce x. It turns out that the direct effect can dominate
the indirect effect. Consequently, our main results can qualitatively remain to hold in this
extension.
32
Piracy Consumption
Piracy Consumption
0.478 0.475
0.455 0.450
0.433 0.425
0.411 0.400
t T t T
Penalty Penalty
0.500 0.500
Piracy Consumption
Piracy Consumption
0.375 0.375
0.250 0.250
0.125 0.125
0.000 0.000
t t T t t T
Penalty Penalty
In practice, regulators may not have direct access to piracy consumption records, and
they may have to rely on an Internet service provider (ISP) to garner the relevant information
and carry out punishment. In this case, the ISP can be viewed as an intermediary between
the regulator and consumers. How will the existence of such an intermediary impact piracy
demand regulation? We aim to look into this question here.
If a complete contract between the regulator and the ISP is available such that they
are able to share all the relevant information about piracy users’ activities and cooperate
to jointly devise penalties based on the information, the two parties can be treated as an
integrated agent. Our main model applies to this case directly without the need of any
33
r
ΠI = Π0I − l(1 − z) − z 2 ,
2
where Π0I is the ISP’s baseline profit. The maximization problem yields z ∗ = min {l/r, 1}.
The following proposition shows that our main result is robust for any l > 0.
Proposition 11.
(i) If 0 < l < r, the effects of t on the x∗ t and Dp∗ follow qualitatively the same relationship
as in the main model, except that the thresholds on t depend on l and r.
It is not surprising to find that for a sufficiently high punishment l, the ISP will choose
z ∗ = 1 so that we end up with the main model. Furthermore, Proposition 11 shows that
34
(i) if 0 < s < sca , Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < s and is invariant in t for t ≥ s;16
ca ca
(ii) otherwise, if s ≥ sca , Dp∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t and stays at zero for t ≥ t .
To understand this, note that total piracy cost for piracy consumption is the sum of the
expected penalty x∗ t and the cost of taking anti-tracking actions s(1 − x∗ )2 /2. Although
consumers can reduce x∗ when penalty t increases, total piracy cost is nondecreasing in t.
Consequently, raising the penalty (weakly) diminishes piracy consumption.
This extension considers a pricing-based revenue model for the pirate firm. Formally,
the pirate firm sells pirated products at price pp . Then the pirate firm’s profit is Πp =
pp Dp − s(1 − x)2 /2. We characterize the equilibrium in Web Appendix and present the
impact of t on the equilibrium outcome by the following proposition.
35
pb
(ii) otherwise, if s ≥ spb , x∗ t and x∗ t + p∗p increase with t for 0 ≤ t < t , while p∗p and Dp∗
pb
decrease with t for 0 ≤ t < t .
p$p + x$ t p$p x$ t
0.106
0.080
Piracy Costs
0.053
0.027
0.000
tpb t
pb
Penalty
Figure 15: Effect of Penalty on Cost of Piracy Consumption (for 0 < s < spb )
(v = 1, β = 0.55, γ = 0.12, s = 0.04).
Proposition 13 shows that the results of this extension are similar to those of the main
model. To understand this, note that total expected cost for piracy consumption is the sum
of price p∗p and the expected penalty x∗ t. The pirate firm’s equilibrium price, p∗p , exhibits
a U-shape with t, just the opposite of the expected penalty. Intuitively, when the expected
penalty is high (low), the pirate firm should set a low (high) price to compensate consumers.
However, because the dependence of p∗p on t is a strategic effect derived from the relationship
between x∗ t and t, the total effect is still governed by this relationship, as shown in Figure
15.
In particular, we would like to highlight that Proposition 13 can shed light on regulations
of other criminal activities, such as drug sales, prostitution, and tax evasion. This is because
illegal firms engaging in these activities make money from pricing and selling their products
17
The superscript ”pb” stands for ”pricing-based revenue”, and it signifies thresholds in this extension.
36
CONCLUSIONS
37
38
Becker, Gary S (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political
Economy, 76 (2), 169–217.
Blackburn, David, Jeffrey A Eisenach, and David Harrison Jr (2019), “Impacts of Digital Video
Piracy on the US Economy,” theglobalipcenter.com https://tinyurl.com/2s4hjjyy, (re-
trieved from waybackmachine; accessed March 20, 2023).
Brown, Steven Caldwell and Thomas J Holt (2021), Digital Piracy: A Global, Multidisciplinary
Account Taylor & Francis Limited.
Chen, Yeh-ning and Ivan Png (2003), “Information Goods Pricing and Copyright Enforcement:
Welfare Analysis,” Information Systems Research, 14 (1), 107–123.
Dai, Tinglong and Shubhranshu Singh (2020), “Conspicuous by its Absence: Diagnostic Expert
Testing under Uncertainty,” Marketing Science, 39 (3), 540–563.
Dejean, Sylvain, Thierry Pénard, and Raphaël Suire (2010), “Une première évaluation des effets de
la loi Hadopi sur les pratiques des Internautes français,” marsouin.org https://tinyurl.com/
3ab2r7ea, (retrieved from waybackmachine; accessed April 7, 2023).
Dey, Debabrata, Antino Kim, and Atanu Lahiri (2019), “Online Piracy and the “Longer Arm” of
Enforcement,” Management Science, 65 (3), 1173–1190.
Durbin, Erik and Ganesh Iyer (2009), “Corruptible Advice,” American Economic Journal: Mi-
croeconomics, 1 (2), 220–42.
Gao, Yuetao (2018), “On the Use of Overt Anti-counterfeiting Technologies,” Marketing Science,
37 (3), 403–424.
Gao, Yuetao and Yue Wu (2023), “Regulating Probabilistic Selling of Counterfeits,” Management
Science, 69 (8), 4498–4517.
Guo, Liang and Xiangyi Meng (2015), “Digital Content Provision and Optimal Copyright Protec-
tion,” Management Science, 61 (5), 1183–1196.
Iyer, Ganesh and Shubhranshu Singh (2018), “Voluntary Product Safety Certification,” Manage-
ment Science, 64 (2), 695–714.
Iyer, Ganesh and J Miguel Villas-Boas (2003), “A bargaining theory of distribution channels,”
Journal of Marketing Research, 40 (1), 80–100.
Jain, Sanjay (2008), “Digital Piracy: A Competitive Analysis,” Marketing Science, 27 (4), 610–626.
Lahiri, Atanu and Debabrata Dey (2013), “Effects of Piracy on Quality of Information Goods,”
Management Science, 59 (1), 245–264.
Lu, Shijie, Koushyar Rajavi, and Isaac Dinner (2021), “The Effect of Over-the-top Media Services
on Piracy Search: Evidence from a Natural Experiment,” Marketing Science, 40 (3), 548–568.
Mortimer, Julie Holland, Chris Nosko, and Alan Sorensen (2012), “Supply Responses to Digital
Distribution: Recorded Music and Live Performances,” Information Economics and Policy,
24 (1), 3–14.
MUSO (2022), “2021 MUSO Discovering Piracy by Industry Data Review,” muso.com https:
//tinyurl.com/4w6272j9, (retrieved from waybackmachine; accessed April 7, 2023).
Singh, Shubhranshu (2017), “Competition in Corruptible Markets,” Marketing Science, 36 (3),
361–381.
Tirole, Jean (1988), The Theory of Industrial Organization MIT press.
39
40
Proof of Proposition 1
Proof. In any equilibrium, the copyright holder chooses to either charge a high price such that
the pirate firm exists in the market (subgame I), or charge a low price such that the pirate firm
cannot survive in the market and consumers only buy copyrighted products (subgame II),
which is sustainable since the pirate firm cannot make profits taking the copyright holder’s
n o
x∗ t (1−γ)kt2 (1−β)sv
price as given (Tirole 1988). Since pec − β = min 2β 2 (1−β)sv , 2(1−γ)k ≥ 0, we have
p c 1 − p c
v
if 0 ≤ pc ≤ pec ,
Πc (pc ) =
n h io
pc −x∗ t
p γ 1 − pc + (1 − γ) 1 −
otherwise,
c v (1−β)v
n o
∗ (1−γ)kt
where x = max 1 − β(1−β)sv
,0 . Notice Πc (pc ) is a piecewise quadratic function. As pc
increases, Πc (pc ) drops discretely at pc = pec . For pc > pec , its unconstrained maximizer is
(1−β)v+(1−γ)x∗ t
denoted as pIc = 2(1−γβ)
.
(i) If pIc > pec , which is equivalent to 0 < s < (1−γ)k
1−γβ
and t ≥ 0, or s ≥ (1−γ)k
1−γβ
and 0 ≤
√ 2 2 2
(2−γβ−β)βsv− β sv [(2−γβ−β) s−4(1−γ)(1−β)k]
t < t′ ≡ 2(1−γ)k
, we have pec < v2 , which implies that pIc
and pec are two local maximizers of Πc . Denote ∆Πc (t) = Πc (pIc ) − Πc (pec ). If ∆Πc (t) > 0,
the equilibrium is subgame I in which p∗c = pIc and x∗ is given by Equation (1); otherwise,
∆Πc (t) ≤ 0, the equilibrium is subgame II and p∗c = pec .
d∆Πc (t) (1−γ)k
First, we show dt
≤ 0. For t ≥ T , ∆Πc is constant. When 0 < s < 1−γβ
and
(1−γ)k
0 ≤ t < T , or when s ≥ 1−γβ
and 0 ≤ t < t′ we have
d∆Πc (t) 2(1 − γ)kt 1 2 (1 − γ)kt
= M (t) 1 − − 1 − pec (t) 1 − ,
dt β(1 − β)sv β v β(1 − β)sv
n h o i
(1−γ) (1−γ) (1−γ)kt
where M (t) = 2(1−γβ) (1−β)v
1− t + 1 > 0. For 0 ≤ t < min{t, t′ }, where t =
β(1−β)sv
β(1−β)sv
, it suffices to show M (t)− β1 1 − v2 pec (t) < 0, which increases with t. Let us consider
2(1−γ)k
4(1−γ)k (1−γ)
two cases. When t ≤ t′ ⇔ s ≤ 3−2γβ−β , we have M (t) − β1 1 − v2 pec (t) < − 2(3−2γβ−β)
< 0;
41
Combining (i) and (ii), we conclude that when 0 < s < s, or when s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t,
the equilibrium is subgame I; when s ≥ s and t ≥ t, the equilibrium is subgame II.
Proof of Proposition 2
dx∗ (1−γ)k
Proof. (i) We have dt
= − β(1−β)sv < 0 for 0 ≤ t < T and x∗ = 0 for t ≥ T .
d(x∗ t) 2(1−γ)kt β(1−β)sv
(ii) When 0 < s < s, we have dt
=1− β(1−β)sv
>0⇔0<t<t≡ 2(1−γ)k
. We also have
x∗ = 0 and x∗ t = 0 for t ≥ T . When s ≥ s, if t < t, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t and
then decreases with t for t ≤ t < t; otherwise, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t. As shown in
4(1−γ)k 4(1−γ)k
proof of Proposition 1, when s > 3−2γβ−β
, t < t′ < t always holds. When s ≤ s ≤ 3−2γβ−β
,
we can show that t < t if and only if s < s. Formally, we have
p
4(1 − γ)[(3 − 2γβ − β) − 3β(1 − γ)(1 − γβ)]
t < t ⇔ ∆Πc (t) > 0 ⇔ s < s ≡ k.
β 2 (1 − γ)2 + 9(1 − β)(1 − γβ)
42
Proof of Proposition 4
Proof. First, we analyze the effect of t on p∗c . If 0 < s < s, or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t,
(1−β)v+(1−γ)x∗ t dp∗c d(x∗ t)
p∗c = 2(1−γβ)
, which implies dt
∝ dt
. If s ≥ s, p∗c drops discontinuously from
pIc to pec at t = t since pIc > pec for 0 ≤ t ≤ t, as shown in Proof of Proposition 1. For
t ≤ t < T , p∗c = min{e pc , v/2} is weakly increasing in t since pec increases with t. For t ≥ T ,
n o
(1−β)sv v
p∗c = min 2(1−γ)k , 2 is invariant in t.
Second, we analyze the effect of t on Π∗c . If 0 < s < s, or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t,
(1−γ)
Dc∗ = 1
2
+ 2(1−β)v
(x∗ t). Since both p∗c and Dc∗ are positively linear in x∗ t, Π∗c = p∗c Dc∗ has the
same relationship with t as that between x∗ t and t. If s ≥ s and t ≤ t < T , p∗c = min{pec , v/2}
is increasing in t but does not surpass v2 . Hence, Π∗c is increasing in t. If s ≥ s and t ≥ T ,
Π∗c is also invariant in t.
Proof of Proposition 5
Proof. (i) First, we consider CS. If 0 < s < s, or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t, we have
dCS d(x∗ t)
R1 R1
CS = γ p∗c (θv − p∗c )dθ + (1 − γ) p∗c −x∗ t (θv − p∗c )dθ. Then we have dCS
dt
= d(x ∗ t) dt
and
v (1−β)v
where the first term is the positive effect of a higher x∗ t, which induces more consumers to
buy copyrighted products, and the second term is the negative effect of a higher pc on CS.
Notice that if 0 < s < s and t ≥ T , CSc is invariant in t since x∗ t = 0.
R1
If s ≥ s and t ≥ t, we have CS = p∗c (θv − p∗c )dθ. Notice that p∗c discretely drops from pIc
v
pIc −x∗ t
to pec at t = t. We observe that pec < pIc < (1−β)
, which implies that both the integrand and
integration range of CS discretely jump at t = t. Hence, CS discretely jumps at t = t. For
∗
p∗c dpc
t ≤ t < T , dCS
dt
= − 1 − v dt
≤ 0. For t ≥ T , CS is invariant in t as p∗c .
43
∗
which implies dT CS
dt
∝ − d(xdt t) .
If s ≥ s and t ≥ t, T CS = CS decreases with t for t ≤ t < T and is invariant in t for
t ≥ T . At t = t, because T SW , which is the sum of T CS, Π∗c and penalty fees, discretely
jumps and penalty fees drop to zero as shown in the proof of Proposition 6, T CS must
discretely jump too.
Proof of Proposition 6
Proof. (i) First, we consider SW . If 0 < s < s, or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t, we have
R1 R1
SW = γ p∗c (θv)dθ + (1 − γ) p∗c −x∗ t (θv)dθ, and
v (1−β)v
dSW (1 − γ) d ∗ d
(1 − β 2 γ)p∗c − (1 + γ − 2γβ)x∗ t (x t) ∝ (x∗ t),
= 2
dt 2(1 − γβ)(1 − β) v dt dt
because [(1 − β 2 γ)p∗c − (1 + γ − 2γβ)x∗ t] > (1 − γβ)(βp∗c − x∗ t) > 0, which is positive since
x∗ t
p∗c > pec > , as shown in the proof of Proposition 1.
β
R1
If s ≥ s and t ≥ t, we have SW = p∗c (θv)dθ. At t = t, p∗c discretely drops from pIc to
v
pIc −x∗ t
pec and pec < pIc < (1−β)
, which implies that the integration range of SW ∗ discretely jumps .
∗ ∗
Hence, SW ∗ discretely jumps at t = t. For t ≤ t < T , dSW
dt
= − pvc dpdtc ≤ 0. For t ≥ T , SW
is invariant in t.
(ii) Second, we consider T SW . If 0 < s < s, or if s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t, we have T SW =
∗ −x∗ t
R p(1−β)v
c
R1 R1
γ p∗c (θv)dθ + (1 − γ) p∗c −x∗ t (θv)dθ + x∗ t (θβv)dθ . We have
v (1−β)v βv
44
∗ 2 ( ∗ 2 ∗ 2 )
p c − x∗ t
v pc v xt
lim T SW = lim γ 1 − + (1 − γ) 1 − (1 − β) −β
t↗t t↗t 2 v 2 (1 − β)v βv
I 2 2
v pc |t=t v pec |t=t
< 1− < 1− = T SW t=t ,
2 v 2 v
where the second inequality is due to pIc > pec at t = t. So T SW discretely jumps at t = t.
Proof of Proposition 7
Proof. (i) First, we consider social welfare. If 0 ≤ s < s, or if s ≥ s, Proposition 6 applies
immediately. If s ≤ s < s, SW has two local maximizers t and t. Since pec t=t
< pIc t=t
<
pIc −x∗ t
pIc t=t
< (1−β) t=t
, we have
Z 1 Z 1 Z 1
SW |t=t = γ (θv)dθ + (1 − γ) (θv)dθ < (θv)dθ = SW |t=t .
pIc pIc −x∗ t p
ec
v t=t (1−β)v t=t v t=t
(1−β)v (1−β)v
We prove pec t=t
< p∗c t=0
by contradiction. Suppose pec t=t ≥ 2(1−γβ)
= 2(1−γβ)
, we
√
(1−γ)k (1−γβ)s− (1−γβ)s[(1−γβ)s−(1−γ)k]
must have 1−γβ
< s < s and t ≥ (1−γ)(1−γβ)k
β(1 − β)v > t. We have
(1−β)v(4k+βs)2 (1−β)v(4k+βs)2 (1−β)(1+β−2γβ)v
Πc (pIc ) t=t
< Πc (pIc ) t=t
= 64(1−γβ)k2
≤ 64(1−γβ)k2
< 4(1−γβ)2
≤ Πc (pec ) t=t
, which
contradicts with ∆Πc (t) = Πc (pIc ) t=t
− Πc (pec ) t=t
= 0.
45
p
β(1 − β)sv −β(1 − β)sv[β(1 − β)sv − 4(1 − γ)ke]
t(e) =
2(1 − γ)k
p
β(1 − β)sv − β(1 − β)sv[β(1 − β)sv − 4(1 − γ)ke] + 2(1 − γ)ke
pec (e) = .
4β(1 − γ)k
46
p
β 2 (1 − β)sv[(1 − β)sv − 2(1 − γ)k pec )]
β(1 − β)sv −
t(pec ) =
(1 − γ)k
p
β(1 − β)sv − β 2 (1 − β)sv[(1 − β)sv − 2(1 − γ)k pec ]
e(pec ) = − + 2β pec .
(1 − γ)k
increases with s.
Lastly, we conclude that T SW t=t+
> T SW |t=t if s > s+ ≡ max{s+ +
1 , s2 }.
Proof of Proposition 8
Proof. (i). Let us consider social welfare. If 0 < s < s, when the maximum social wel-
fare is lower than SW M , which is equivalent to SW |t=t < SW M = 38 v ⇔ s < ŝ =
√
4(1−γ)k[1−β 2 γ−(1−γβ) 1+2βγ−3β 2 γ]
n M o
∗ SW −SW |t=t
(3γ+1)γβ 3 −2γ(3+γ)β 2 +(1+3γ)β
, the regulator should choose y = min d
, 1 and
t∗ = t; otherwise, when ŝ ≤ s < s, the optimal demand-side regulation is still t and
SW |t=t ≥ SW M , which yields y ∗ = 0. If s ≥ s, the maximum social welfare is always higher
R1
than SW M since SW |t=t = pec |t=t θvdθ > SW M , which also implies that y ∗ = 0 and the
v
47
since pec |t=t < v2 . Then, maximizing W (y) yields y ∗ = 0 and the optimal t∗ is the same as in
Proposition 7.
Proof of Proposition 9
n o
1
β(1−β)sv
Proof. The analysis is performed under 0 < t < t̂ ≡ min β− 2
v, β(1 − β)v, k
.
We use backward induction to solve this game. Given pc , the pirate firm’s profit is
h i
xt pc −(1−β)v
− − − 2s (1 − x)2 if 0 < x ≤
k(1 γ) 1 βv t
,
h i
Πp (pc , x) = k(1 − γ) pc −xt − xt − s (1 − x)2 if pc −(1−β)v
<x≤ βpc
,
(1−β)v βv 2 t t
− s (1 − x)2 βpc
2
if x > t
.
Then, we have the pirate firm’s optimal choice as follows: when 0 < pc ≤ pec , the pirate
firm does not participate in the market; when pc > pec , the pirate firm joins the market and
the optimal choice is
h i
k(1−γ)t k(1−γ)t
1− if pc > (1 − β)v + 1 − βsv t
βsv
x∗ =
h i h i
pc −(1−β)v k(1−γ)t k(1−γ)t
t
if (1 − β)v + 1 − β(1−β)sv t < pc < (1 − β)v + 1 − βsv
t
h i
1 − k(1−γ)t k(1−γ)t
β(1−β)sv
if pec < pc < (1 − β)v + 1 − β(1−β)sv t.
Given the pirate firm’s participation decision and optimal choice, we have
pc
p 1 − if 0 ≤ pc ≤ pec ,
c
v
k(1−γ)t
pc −[1− β(1−β)sv ]t
h i
Πc (pc ) = γpc 1 − c + (1 − γ)pc 1 −
p
k(1−γ)t
v (1−β)v
if pec < pc ≤ (1 − β)v + 1 − β(1−β)sv
t,
h i
k(1−γ)t
γpc 1 − pc
if (1 − β)v + 1 − t < pc ≤ v.
v β(1−β)sv
h i
k(1−γ)t
Notice that when pc > (1 − β)v + 1 − β(1−β)sv
t, only ethical consumers buy copyrighted
48
First, we have
H(γ)
∆ΠIc (γ) = where H(γ) = b1 γ 4 + b2 γ 3 + b3 γ 2 + b4 γ + b5 ,
4β 3 (1 − γβ)(1 − β)3 s2 v 3
b1 = k 2 t4 ,
b4 = −4k 2 t4 + 2β(1 − β)kst2 v[2(1 − β)v + 3t] − β 2 (1 − β)2 s2 v 2 [(1 − β)v 2 + 2(1 − β)tv + 2t2 ],
We have H ′′ (γ) = 12b1 γ 2 + 6b2 γ + 2b3 > 0 since its discriminant 12(3b22 − 8b1 b3 ) < −48β 2 (1 −
4 2 2 2 4 4 ′ 1−β
β) (2 − β )k s t v < 0. Since H β
< 0, H(γ) should either decrease with γ or first
1−β ′ 1−β
decrease and then increase with γ for β < γ < γ . Given H β > 0, and H(γ ′ ) < 0,
1−β
there exists an unique threshold γ
e1 such that for β
e1 , ∆ΠIc (γ) > 0 and for
< γ < γ
e1 ≤ γ < γ ′ , ∆ΠIc (γ) ≤ 0.
γ
d∆ΠII
c (γ) 2pec kt2
Second, we have ∆ΠII
c (γ) decreases with γ because dγ
= 1− − v4 <
v 2β 2 (1−β)sv
kt2
2β 2 (1−β)sv
− v
4
< − (2β−1)v
4
II ′ II 1−β
< 0. We also have ∆Πc (γ ) < 0. Therefore, if ∆Πc β
> 0,
49
maximized at pc = v2 .
1−β
Combing (i) and (ii), we find that for β
<γ<γ
e, copyright holder charges either pec or
pIc to serve both ethical consumers and unethical consumers; for γ
e ≤ γ < 1, copyright holder
charges v
2
e, p∗c jumps from pec or pIc
to serve only ethical consumers. Consequently, at γ = γ
(1−γ)[(1−γ)kt2 −βsvt+β 2 sv 2 ]
to v2 , so Dp∗ jumps either. For γ
e ≤ γ < 1, Dp∗ = β 2 sv 2
decreases with γ.
Proof of Proposition 10
Proof. First, we state the equilibrium in Lemma A1.
at
Lemma A1 (Equilibrium Characterization). There exist thresholds sat and t such that
at
(i) if 0 < s < sat , or if s ≥ sat and 0 ≤ t < t , the pirate firm’s equilibrium anti-tracking
n o
technology choice is x∗ = max 1 − (2−γβ−β)(1−γ)kt
2β(1−β)(1−γβ)sv
, 0 , and the copyright holder’s equi-
(1−β)v+(1−γ)xat∗
librium price is p∗c = 2(1−γβ
;
at
(ii) otherwise, if s ≥ sat and t ≥ t , the pirate firm does not participate in the market, and
the copyright holder’s equilibrium price is p∗c = v2 .
Proof. We use backward induction to solve the game. If the pirate firm participates in the
market, at the second stage, the copyright holder’s problem is maxpc Πc = pc DI (pc , x), where
50
(1−β)v+(1−γ)xt β(1−β)v
2(1−γβ)
if 0 ≤ xt < 2−γβ−β
,
p∗c (xt) =
n o
min xt , v
otherwise.
β 2
At the first stage, taking p∗c (xt) into consideration, the pirate firm’s profit is
h i
(1−γ)k 1 − 2−γβ−β
− 2s (1 − x)2 β(1−β)v
2(1−γβ) β(1−β)v
xt if 0 ≤ xt < 2−γβ−β
;
Πp (x) =
− s (1 − x)2
otherwise.
2
n o
∗ (2−γβ−β)(1−γ)kt
Maximizing Πp (x) yields x = max 1 − 2β(1−β)(1−γβ)sv
,0 . The pirate firm participates
(1−γ)k
in the market if and only if Πp (x∗ ) > 0, which is equivalent to 0 < s < sat ≡ (1−γβ) , or
n √ o
at 2β(1−β)v (1−γβ)s− (1−γβ)s[(1−γβ)s−(1−γ)k]
s ≥ sat and 0 ≤ t < t ≡ (1−γ)(2−γβ−β)k
; otherwise, if s ≥ sat and
at
t ≥ t , the copyright holder monopolizes the market by charging v/2.
Next, we analyze the effect of regulation in Proposition 10. If 0 < s < sat , we have
d(x∗ t) β(1−β)(1−γβ)sv 2β(1−β)(1−γβ)sv
dt
> 0 ⇔ 0 ≤ t < tat ≡ (1−γ)(2−γβ−β)k
, and x∗ = 0 for t ≥ T at ≡ (1−γ)(2−γβ−β)k
. If s ≥ sat ,
similar to the proof of Proposition 2, we have
h i
(1−γ)k at (1−γ) 2−γβ−β ∗
Lastly, if 0 < s < sat ≡ (1−γβ)
, or s ≥ sat and 0 ≤ t < t , we have Dp∗ = 2(1−γβ)
1− β(1−β)
xt
dDp∗ ∗
and dt
∝ − d(xdt t) .
Proof of Proposition 11
Proof. The equilibrium derivation directly follows the proof Proposition 1, except that we
need to replace t with z ∗ t. We only state the equilibrium in Lemma A2 and omit the proof.
Lemma A2.
51
(ii) Otherwise, if s ≥ s and t ≥ t/z ∗ , the pirate firm does not participate in the market,
and the copyright holder’s equilibrium price is p∗c = min pec , v2 , where
z∗ t − (1−γ)k(z ∗ t)2
if 0 ≤ t < T /z ∗ ,
β 2β 2 (1−β)sv
pec ≡
(1−β)sv
otherwise;
2(1−γ)k
Lemma A3.
(i) If 0 < s < s, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t/z ∗ , decreases with t for t/z ∗ ≤ t < T /z ∗ ,
and stays at zero for t ≥ T /z ∗ .
(ii) If s ≤ s < s, x∗ t increases with t for 0 ≤ t < t/z ∗ and decreases with t for t/z ∗ ≤ t <
t/z ∗ .
The proof of comparative statics largely follows that of Proposition 2 and thus is omitted.
Notice that when 0 < l < r, 0 < z ∗ < 1 and the effect of t on x∗ t is the same as the main
model, except that thresholds on t are different. When l ≥ r, we have z ∗ = 1, and thus the
equilibrium and comparative statics degenerate to the main model.
Proof of Proposition 12
Proof. Maximizing up with respect to x yields unethical consumers’ optimal technology
choice x∗ = max{1 − st , 0}, which implies total piracy cost tca = x∗ t + 2s (1 − x∗ )2 =
52
h i
pc pc −tca tca
γ 1 −
+ (1 − γ) 1 − if pc > ,
ca v (1−β)v β
Dc (pc , t ) =
1 −
pc
v
otherwise.
Then, maximizing pc Dc (pc , tca ) yields the copyright holder’s equilibrium price as:
ca
(1−β)v+(1−γ)t if 0 ≤ tca < β(1−β)v
2(1−γβ) 2−γβ−β
,
p∗c =
n o
min tca , v
otherwise.
β 2
Then we have
h i
(1−γ) 2−γβ−β ca β(1−β)v
if 0 ≤ tca <
2(1−γβ)
1− β(1−β)v
t 2−γβ−β
,
Dpca∗ =
0 otherwise.
Notice that tca increases with t for 0 ≤ t < s and stays at s/2 for t ≥ s. If 0 < s <
2β(1−β)v s β(1−β)v
sca ≡ 2−γβ−β
, we have tca ≤ 2
< 2−γβ−β
, and thus Dpca∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < s
ca
and is invariant in t for t ≥ s. Otherwise, if s ≥ sca , there exists a threshold t such that
q
ca ca ca
t < 2−γβ−β for 0 ≤ t < t and t ≥ 2−γβ−β for t ≥ t , where t = s − s2 − 2β(1−β)sv
ca β(1−β)v ca β(1−β)v
2−γβ−β
.
ca ca
So Dpca∗ decreases with t for 0 ≤ t < t and stays at zero for t ≥ t .
Proof of Proposition 13
Proof. We solve the game and present the equilibrium outcome in the following lemma.
pb
Lemma A4 (Equilibrium Characterization). There exists a threshold t such that
pb
(i) if 0 ≤ t ≤ t , the pirate firm’s equilibrium price and anti-tracking technology choice
53
pb
(ii) otherwise, if t > t , the pirate firm does not participate in the market, and the copyright
holder’s equilibrium price is
t v
p∗c = min , .
β 2
Proof. Similar to main model, consumer demands for copyrighted and pirated products are
h i
γ 1 − pc
pc −pp −xt pp +xt
v
+ (1 − γ) 1 − (1−β)v
if pc > β
,
DcI (pc , pp , x) =
1 −
pc
v
otherwise;
h i
(1 − γ) pc −pp −xt − pp +xt pp +xt
(1−β)v βv
if pc > β
,
DpI (pc , pp , x) =
0 otherwise.
Similar to the main model, we consider two subgames. The copyright holder chooses
to either charge a high price and the pirate firm participates in the market (subgame I) or
charge a low price such that the pirate firm cannot earn a positive profit and consumers only
buy copyrighted products (subgame II). When the pirate firm participates in the market
with positive demand, its profit is
pc − pp − xt pp + xt s pp + xt
Πp (pc , pp , x) = (1 − γ)pp − − (1 − x)2 for pc > .
(1 − β)v βv 2 β
54
dΠp =
(1−γ) p∗p (pc ) =
β(1−β)(βpc −t)sv
dpp β(1−β)v
(βpc − 2pp − xt) = 0,
2β(1−β)sv−(1−γ)t2
,
⇒ (5)
dΠp = − (1−γ)tpp + s(1 − x) = 0;
x∗ (p ) = 1 −
(1−γ)(βpc −t)t
dx β(1−β)v c 2β(1−β)sv−(1−γ)t2
,
which depend on pc . Correspondingly, consumer demand for pirated products is Dp∗ (pc ) =
(1−γ)s(βpc −t) (1−γ)s(βpc −t)2
2β(1−β)sv−(1−γ)t2
and the pirate firm’s maximum profit is Π∗p (pc , p∗p (pc ), x∗ (pc )) = 2[2β(1−β)sv−(1−γ)t2 ]
.
Therefore, the pirate firm will participate in the market if and only if Π∗p (pc ) > 0 and
Dp∗ (pc ) > 0, which is equivalent to pc > βt . Consequently, in subgame II, the optimal price is
n o
t v pII
pII
c = min ,
β 2
, and the copyright holder’s profit is Π II
c = p II
c 1 − c
v
.
In subgame I, the copyright holder’s profit is Πc = pc DcI , and we have
dΠIc
2pc 2pc − pp − xtc
=γ 1− + (1 − γ) 1 − . (6)
dpc v (1 − β)v
q
t (1−γ)β(1−β)v 2β(1−β)sv
(i) If pIc > β
, which is equivalent to (a) 0 < s ≤ 2(2−γβ−β)2
and 0 ≤ t < 1−γ
or (b)
(1−γ)β(1−β)v β(1−β)v t
s> 2(2−γβ−β)2
and 0 ≤ t < 2−γβ−β
, we have β
< v2 . We denote ∆Πc (t) = ΠIc − ΠII
c , the
55
56
where ϕ(t) = (1 − γ)(2 − γβ − β)t2 − 2β(1 − β)(1 − γ)vt + β(1 − β)(4 − 3γβ − β)sv.
β(1−β)(1−γ)v
(i). When s ≥ (4−3γβ−β)(2−γβ−β)
, the discriminant of ϕ(t) is always smaller than or equal to
pb
zero. This implies that ϕ(t) ≥ 0 for all 0 ≤ t < t .
β(1−β)(1−γ)v
(ii). When s < (4−3γβ−β)(2−γβ−β)
, ϕ(t) < 0 if t > tpb ,where
p
pb β(1 − β)(1 − γ)v − β(1 − β)(1 − γ)v[β(1 − β)(1 − γ)v − (2 − γβ − β)(4 − 3γβ − β)s]
t (s) = .
(1 − γ)(2 − β − γβ)
pb
Similar to the proof of Proposition 2, if tpb ≥ t , then ϕ(t) is always positive for all
pb pb pb
t ∈ (0, t ); if tpb < t , ϕ(t) ≥ 0 for 0 ≤ t ≤ tpb and ϕ(t) < 0 for tpb < t ≤ t . Moreover,
q
pb
if 8β(1−β)(1−γ)v
(8−5γβ−3β)2
≤ s ≤ β(1−β)(1−γ)v
(4−3γβ−β)(2−γβ−β)
, we have tpb
≥ 2β(1−β)sv
(1−γ)
> t , which means that
8β(1−β)(1−γ)v
we only need to focus on the case where 0 < s < (8−5γβ−3β)2
and prove that there exists a
pb pb
threshold spb ∈ (0, 8β(1−β)(1−γ)v
(8−5γβ−3β)2
) such that for 0 < s < spb , tpb < t and for s ≥ spb , tpb ≥ t .
Equivalently, we prove that ∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) is positive if and only if s < spb .
57
d∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) ∂∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) ∂∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) dtpb (s)
= +
ds ∂s ∂t ds
pb pb
∂∆Πc (s, t (s)) (1 − γ) dt
< − ,
∂s 4 − 3γβ − β ds
(1−β) ϕ(t) 1
where the first ” < ” is due to pIc < 2−γβ−β
and [(4−3γβ−β)β(1−β)sv−(2−γβ−β)(1−γ)t2 ]2
< β(1−β)(4−3γβ−β)sv
.
dtpb ∂∆Πc (s,tpb (s))
Then we have ds
and ∂s
as follow:
β(1−β)(1−γ)v
which implies that ∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) decreases with s for 0 < s < (4−3γβ−β)(2−γβ−β)
.
4(1−β)(1−γβ)v 8β(1−β)(1−γ)v
When s = 0, ∆Πc (s, tpb (s)) s=0
= ∆Πc (0, 0) = (4−3γβ−β)2
> 0. When s = (8−5γβ−3β)2
,
58
where L(t) = −5(1 − γ)2 kt2 + 4β(1 − β)(1 − γ)sv ∗ t + 2β(1 − β)2 s(v ∗ )2 , which is an open-down
4β(1−β)sv ∗
quadratic function of t and thus L(t) > 0 for 0 ≤ t ≤ 5(1−γ)k
.
∗
If 0 < s < s and 0 ≤ t < T , we should have t < β(1−β)sv
(1−γ)k
; otherwise, x∗ will be zero in
∗
2 ∗ 2
the following stage. We have L(t) > L β(1−β)sv
(1−γ)k
= β(1−β) s(vk ) (2k−βs) > 0 since s < s < 2k
β
.
β(1−β)sv ∗
If s ≥ s and 0 ≤ t < t, we should have t < t(v ∗ ) ≤ (1−γ)k
, where t(·) is defined as
the main model given v ∗ ; otherwise, x∗ will not be well defined in the following stage. If
β(1−β)sv ∗ 4(1−γ)k
2k
s ≤ s < β , then L(t) > L (1−γ)k > 0. If s ≥ 2k
β
> 3−2γβ−β , then t(v ∗ ) < t′ (v ∗ ) <
4β(1−β)sv ∗
t(v ∗ ) < 5(1−γ)k
and L(t) > 0, where t′ (·) and t(·) are defined as the main model given v ∗ .
59
where W (t) = −3(1−γ)2 kt2 +2β ∗ (1−β ∗ )(1−γ)svt+β ∗ (1−β ∗ )2 sv 2 > 0. Let us focus on the
∗ ∗
cases when the pirate firm joins the market and x∗ > 0. If s ≤ βk∗ , we have 0 < t < β (1−γ)k (1−β )sv
∗
(1−β ∗ )sv ∗ ∗ 2 2 ∗
and thus W (t) > W β (1−γ)k = β (1−β ) ksv (k−β s) ≥ 0. Otherwise, if s > βk∗ , we have
√
∗ ′ ∗ (1−β ∗ )v[β ∗ s+ β ∗ s(β ∗ s+3k)]
0 < t < t(β ) < t (β ) < , which implies W (t) > 0 since W (0) > 0
√ 3(1−γ)k
(1−β ∗ )v[β ∗ s+ β ∗ s(β ∗ s+3k)]
and W 3(1−γ)k
= 0, where t′ (·) and t(·) are defined in the main model
∂x∗ ∂ 2 x∗
given β ∗ . Notice that if β ∗ > 12 , ∂β
and ∂β∂t
are negative and thus the three terms of indirect
effect are all negative.
60