Jurisprudence Telekom
Jurisprudence Telekom
Jurisprudence Telekom
Abstract
Electronic
Electroniccopy
copyavailable
availableat:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=1851315
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1851315
1. Introduction.
1
Judgment of the Court (First Chamber), 17 February 2011, Case C-52/09, Konkurrensverket v.
TeliaSonera Sverige AB.
Electronic
Electroniccopy
copyavailable
availableat:
at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=1851315
http://ssrn.com/abstract=1851315
customers at a low price, such that the downstream competitors are
effectively “squeezed” out of the downstream market.
2
Oscar Bronner GmbH & Co. c. Mediaprint Zeitungs und Zeitschriftenverlag GmbH & Co. KG,
Judgment of EJC, 26 November 1998, Case C-7/97, E.C.R. I-7791; (1999) 4 C.M.L.R. 112.
3
Presentation by MIGUEL DE LA MANO, at the ABA Antitrust Section Spring Meeting 2009, Thoughts
on Margin Squeeze (and Refusal to Supply) held in Washington, 25 March 2009.
4
See, for a comprehensive review of the issues at stake, CRISTOPHE HUMPE and CYRIL RITTER,
“Refusal to supply”, Global Competition Law Centre (College of Europe), Research Paper, June 2005.
5
LANG, T., “Defining Legitimate Competition: Companies’ Duties to Supply Competitors, and Access
to Essential Facilities”, 1994 Fordham Corporate Law Institute 245, B. Hawk ed. (1995), p. 245.
6
Decision of 16 July 2003, relating to proceeding under Article 82 EC (Case COMP/38.233 – Wanadoo
Interactive).
7
CROCIONI, P. and VELJANOVSKI, C., “Price squeezes, Foreclosure and Competition Law –
Principles and guidelines”, Journal of Network Industries, Vol. 4, 2003, pp. 28-60.
The NCA alleges that TeliaSonera abused its dominant position on the
wholesale market by applying a margin between the wholesale price
for input ADSL products and the retail price for ADSL services it offers
to consumers which would not have been sufficient to cover
TeliaSonera’s incremental costs on the retail market, in the period
from April 2000 to January 2001.
For the sake of time and room saving, we cannot address all of them
in this paper, so we will focus solely in Question 1 –conditions
establishing an abusive margin squeeze-, Question 3 –lack of a
regulatory obligation to supply- and Question 7 –indispensability of
the product- given their relevance to the ECJ’s judgment in this case.
For the sake of discussion and clarity in our analysis, prior to deal
with Question 1 of the referring court –and AG conclusion about
them- we consider more appropriate beginning with the other two
issues, the regulatory obligation to supply and the indispensability
test.
There are many –and all of them quite significant- issues discussed in
the ECJ’s ruling in the TeliaSonera case; however, we are only going
to focus here on the ones we consider more relevant to the topic
we’re analysing, margin squeeze, and more broadly, abuse of
dominant position under EC Competition Law.
It may be said that, arguably, the ECJ's approach goes beyond the
Commission’s 2008 Guidance on its enforcement priorities; this
assertion is founded in the significant fact that in those priorities
refusal to supply and margin squeeze are placed in the same section8.
Thankfully, the ECJ went further still by clarifying (paragraph 66) that
in the absence of any effect on the competitive situation of
competitors, a margin squeeze cannot be classified as an
exclusionary practice and consequently there will be no infringement
if such pricing policy does not make penetration by the competitors in
the market any more difficult.
8
Communication from the Commission – Guidance on the Commission’s enforcement priorities in
applying Article [102 TFEU] to abusive exclusionary conduct by dominant undertakings (2009/C 45/02),
OJ 2009 C 45.
9
Case T-271/03 Deutsche Telekom v Commission [2008] ECR II-477
So, although the ECJ has adopted a broader test for margin squeeze
than the AG proposed, there are still signs of the ECJ adopting a more
rigorously economic analysis, and therefore not fully departing from
the Commission’s views as expressed in its Guidance paper on Art.
102 TFUE.
The ECJ also appears to have put paid to any thinking that the level
of market power (so called "super-dominance") can affect whether an
abuse has been committed. It clarified that the degree of a
company’s market power can speak to the extent of effects, as
opposed to whether or not the abuse exists. It notes (paragraph 81):
However, the ECJ did consider (paragraph 45) that the costs and
prices of competitors can sometimes be appropriate comparators,
including where the particular market conditions of competition
dictate it (for example, because the level of the dominant company’s
costs is specifically attributable to the "competitively advantageous
situation" in which its dominant position places it).
Following what has been said above, the door has been left open for
an "adjusted equally efficient operator" test in some circumstances,
such as where former state-owned monopolies have gained
unmatchable advantages from their historic position.
10
DÍEZ ESTELLA, F., Telecoms Regulation, Antitrust and Margin Squeeze: Widening the Already Wide
Gap between US and EU Competition Policy? (2011). Available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1828723
11
Verizon Communications Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis v. Trinko, LLP , 540 U.S. 398 (2004)
Again, this approach is the exact opposite to the one taken by the
ECJ in TeliaSonera, and to the views expressed by the ECJ itself in its
France Telekom ruling, where, in a similar case of providing access to
its ADSL network to a competing operator in the retail market, the
French incumbent was found guilty of an abusive conduct consisting
in pricing below cost, that is, predatory pricing14.
12
Pacific Bell Telephone Co., d/b/a AT&T California v. LinkLine Communications, Inc., Slip Opinion,
October Term 2008 (555 U.S. ____ ), available at: http://www.supremecourtus.gov/opinions/08pdf/07-
512.pdf
13
Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993).
14
Judgment of European Court of Justice (First Chamber), 2 April 2009, Case C-202/07 P, France
Télécom v. Commission.
First, with respect to the wholesale level, the Court points out the
District Court had held AT&T had no “antitrust duty to deal,” the
Court of Appeals had “assumed that any duty to deal arose only from
FCC regulations,” and the question on which the Court granted
certiorari “made the same assumption.” Thus, given the absence of
any antitrust duty to deal at the wholesale level, there can be no
violation based on unilateral pricing decisions at wholesale, for:
15
linkLine, slip Op., at 7, citing United States v. Colgate & Co., 250 U.S. 300, 307 (1919).
16
Id. at 8, citing Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 US 585, 608-611 (1985).
17
Id. at 9.
18
Id. at 9.
19
Id. at 11.
20
Id. at 12.
21
Guidance Paper, supra note 8, at § 80.
22
European Commission Decision of 4 July 2007, regarding a proceeding under Article 82 EC Treaty
(Case COMP/38.784 – Wanadoo España v. Telefonica).
23
Vid., for a detailed analysis, FERNÁNDEZ ÁLVAREZ-LABRADOR, M., “Margin Squeeze in the
Telecommunications Sector: An Economic Overview”, World Competition, 29 (2), 2006.
24
We have already discussed them in Section 2, above.
So, to sum up, the Commission’s view now is that price squeeze is a
“stand alone” abuse and, therefore, the standard of proof is more
focused on the insufficient margin left to competitors to “survive”.
25
See Telefónica Decision, paragraph 302.
26
GERADIN, D., “Refusal to supply and margin squeeze: A Discussion of why the ‘Telefonica
exceptions’ are wrong” (January 28, 2011), Available at http://ssrn.com/abstract=1762687.
In addition, AG Mazák noted that it had been argued that it was not
clear why a public source of funding for property should lead to a
stricter legal standard. The reason is that Article 102 TFEU does not
allow a distinction to be made between public and private funding.
First of all, over the years the number of Article 102 TFEU
investigations has increased significantly at the EU Commission level,
and so the amount of fines imposed for abusive conduct. As regards
27
Guidance Paper, supra note 8, at § 81.
28
Of course, Telefonica does dispute this assertion, arguing that: (i) there were real and/or potential
alternatives to the regional and national wholesale access services of Telefónica, (ii) the regional and
national wholesale access services of Telefónica could be replicated and (iii) the alleged conduct was not
likely to eliminate all competition on the downstream market. Telefónica concluded that given the fact it
was not obliged under Article 102 TFEU to grant access to its own network, it was illogical, and legally
unjustified, to maintain that its pricing policy concerning its national and regional wholesale products was
nonetheless subject to 102 TFEU on the mere ground that these wholesale products had been offered to
competitors as a result of a regulatory obligation (Wanadoo España vs. Telefónica, supra note 22, at §
301). Whether this approach prevails or not, remains to be seen, and the ECJ will say in its forthcoming
judgment dealing with Telefonica’s appeal to the Commission decision.
29
GERADIN, D. and O’DONOGHUE, R., “The Concurrent Application of Competition Law and
Regulation: The Case of Margin Squeeze Abuses in the Telecommunications Sector”, [2005] Journal of
Competition Law and Economics 1(2), 355-425.
30
G. FAELLA and R. PARDOLESI, “Squeezing Price Squeeze under EC Antitrust Law”, September
2009, available at http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1478937