CT8
CT8
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your
answer booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
3. You have 15 minutes of planning and reading time before the start of this examination.
You may make separate notes or write on the exam paper but not in your answer
booklet. Calculators are not to be used during the reading time. You will then have
three hours to complete the paper.
5. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
2 An investor has taken out a $100,000 loan at a 10% per annum rate of interest,
annually compounded. The investor uses the loan to buy a portfolio of stocks whose
value follows a lognormal distribution, with parameters μ = 12% per annum and
σ2 = 25% per annum.
The investor plans to sell the stocks and repay the loan after five years.
(i) Calculate the mean and the variance of the lognormal distribution. [1]
(ii) Calculate the probability that the investor will have enough money to repay the
loan plus interest. [2]
After five years the stocks are only worth $120,000 so the investor cannot afford to
repay the loan plus interest.
(iii) Calculate the one-year 95% value at risk of the investor’s stock portfolio from
time t = 5 to time t = 6. [2]
The annual standard deviation of the investor’s stock portfolio at time t = 5 is $81,708.
The bank agrees to continue the loan for another five years, as long as the investor can
prove that the annual standard deviation of his portfolio is no higher than $40,000 at
time t = 5.
(iv) Calculate the proportion of the investor’s stock portfolio he would have to sell
in order to bring the value at risk down to a level acceptable to the bank. [1]
The bank also offers a cash deposit account returning a 6% per annum rate of interest,
annually compounded.
The investor sells the proportion of the stock portfolio in part (iv) and invests the
funds in the cash deposit account. The bank therefore continues the loan for another
five years.
(v) Calculate the probability that the investor’s stocks and cash deposit combined
are sufficient to repay the loan plus interest at time 10. [3]
CT8 S2018–2
3 In a market in which the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) model holds, the expected
return is given by:
Assume the risk-free rate rf = 0.04. Consider two well diversified portfolios Pi with
the following features in a two factor model:
P1 P2
E Ri 15.50% 11.95%
bi,1 (a) (b)
bi,2 1.5 0.7
(ii) Determine the values (a) and (b) for l1 = 0.05 and l2 = 0.06. [3]
[Total 5]
4 An investor has £100 and is considering investing in two different stocks. The prices
of both stocks are assumed to follow the lognormal model with the parameters below.
(iii) Calculate the expected value of the investor’s portfolio at time 3. [1]
(iv) Calculate the standard deviation of the value of the investor’s portfolio at
time 3. [3]
(v) Comment on the expected return and standard deviation of the portfolio
compared to investing the whole £100 in one stock. [4]
[Total 14]
6 Consider a call option ct and a put option pt written on a non-dividend paying stock St.
(i) Prove the put-call parity relationship by constructing two portfolios that
produce the same value at maturity. [4]
A stock market includes four options set out below. All the options are for a term of
10 years and relate to a single non-dividend paying stock, currently priced at $5. The
continuously compounded risk-free rate is 3% per annum.
(iii) Determine lower and upper bounds for the price of option C. [2]
(iv) Determine lower and upper bounds for the price of option D. [2]
[Total 10]
CT8 S2018–4
7 A company is currently financed entirely by equity with 100,000 shares in issue and
no debt. The current share price is $1. The company has total assets of $100,000 with
volatility of 15% per annum.
The company is considering raising $250,000 by issuing zero-coupon debt with a five-
year maturity date. The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 3% per
annum.
The company intends to set the redemption value of the debt such that the share price
will remain unchanged under the Merton model.
(i) Give the value of the company’s assets immediately after issuing the debt. [1]
(ii) Calculate the redemption value of the debt using the Merton model. [5]
One year later, the company is struggling. The share price has fallen to $0.50 and the
current value of the debt has fallen to $50 per $100 of redemption value.
(v) Suggest why the value of the equity has fallen by proportionately more than
the fall in the value of the debt. [3]
[Total 13]
8 Consider a binomial tree model for the non-dividend paying stock with price St .
Assume this price either rises by 30% or falls by 20% each quarter (3 months) for the
next three quarters. Assume also that the risk-free rate is 2% per annum continuously
compounded. Let S0 = £60.
(i) Calculate the price of a vanilla European call option with maturity in nine
months’ time and a strike price of £55. [3]
(ii) Calculate the price of a vanilla European put option with the same maturity
and strike price as the contract in part (i). [1]
Assume the investor has a portfolio formed by a short position in the call option given
in part (i) and a long position in the put option given in part (ii).
(iii) Determine how the value of the portfolio would differ if the possible change in
the stock price was a fall of 30% instead of 20%. [3]
[Total 7]
where Wt is a Brownian motion under the real-world probability measure P. Let V(t)
be the value at t of a self-financing portfolio, consisting of Ft stocks and Yt cash
bond.
(ii) Determine the conditions under which the discounted value e–rtV (t) is a
martingale.[3]
[Total 6]
10 (i) State the main assumptions underpinning the Black-Scholes model. [3]
Consider a put option on a non-dividend paying stock when the stock price is £8, the
exercise price is £9, the continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 2% per
annum, the volatility is 20% per annum. and the time to maturity is three months.
(ii) Calculate the price of the option using the Black-Scholes model. [4]
(iii) Discuss how the price of the contract in part (ii) would change if the rate of
interest increases. (There is no need to carry out further calculations.) [2]
[Total 9]
CT8 S2018–6
11 Consider a market in which the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) holds.
(i) Write down the equation of the Security Market Line, defining all the notation
you use. [2]
In this market, the risk-free rate of interest is 9.44% per annum. There are only two
risky assets in the market with the following attributes.
(ii) Determine the weight of each asset in the market portfolio to be consistent
with β1 = 0.46, β 2 = 1.36. [3]
END OF PAPER
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2018
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
Mike Hammer
Chair of the Board of Examiners
December 2018
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to
construct asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are
also required to communicate with other financial professionals and to critically
evaluate modern financial theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to
those shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate.
Marks for the methodology are also awarded.
1. In general, the real differentiators in those who scored well were attention to detail
in their algebraic steps, and the breadth of knowledge in being able to score the
knowledge marks and even attempt most questions. A number of candidates did not
gather relevant information from the text of the question, and translate it in the
appropriate equivalent statistical concepts. For example, candidates struggled with
formulating the probability that an event occurs in appropriate mathematical terms,
and determining from the information in the question the direct way to recover
required variances and covariances.
C. Pass Mark
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Solutions
Q1
Anchoring and adjustment Anchoring is a term used to explain how people will produce estimates.
They then adjust away from this initial anchor to arrive at their final judgement. [1]
Prospect theory A theory of how people make decisions when faced with risk and uncertainty. It
replaces the conventional risk averse / risk seeking decreasing marginal utility theory. [1]
Framing (and question wording) The way a choice is presented (“framed”) and, particularly, the
wording of a question in terms of gains and losses, can have an enormous impact on the answer given
or the decision made. [1]
Myopic loss aversion This is similar to prospect theory, but considers repeated choices rather than a
single “gamble”. [1]
Estimating probabilities Issues (other than anchoring) which might affect probability estimates
include: [0.5]
• Dislike of “negative” events – the “valence” of an outcome (the degree to which it is considered as
negative or positive) has an enormous influence on the probability estimates of its likely occurrence.
[0.5]
• Representative Heuristics – people find more probable that which they find easier to imagine. As the
amount of detail increases, its apparent likelihood may increase (although the true probability can
only decrease steadily). [0.5]
• Availability – people are influenced by the ease with which something can be brought to mind. This
can lead to biased judgements when examples of one event are inherently more difficult to imagine
than examples of another. [0.5]
Overconfidence People tend to overestimate their own abilities, knowledge and skills. This may be a
result of: [0.5]
• Hindsight bias – events that happen will be thought of as having been predictable prior to the event,
events that do not happen will be thought of as having been unlikely prior to the event. [0.5]
• Confirmation bias – people will tend to look for evidence that confirms their point of view (and will
tend to dismiss evidence that does not justify it). [0.5]
Mental accounting People show a tendency to separate related events and decisions and find it
difficult to aggregate events. [1]
Effect of options Other issues include:
• Primary effect – people are more likely to choose the first option presented, but [0.5]
• Recency effect – in some instances, the final option that is discussed may be preferred! (The gap in
time between the presentation of the options and the decision may influence this dichotomy.) [0.5]
• Other research suggests that people are more likely to choose an intermediate option than one at
either end! [0.5]
• A greater range of options tends to discourage decision-making. On the other hand, a higher
probability is attributed to options explicitly stated than when included in a broader category. [0.5]
• Status Quo bias – people have a marked preference for keeping things as they are. [0.5]
• Regret aversion – by retaining the existing arrangements, people minimise the possibility of regret
(the pain associated with feeling responsible for a loss). [0.5]
• Ambiguity aversion – people are prepared to pay a premium for rules. [0.5]
[Max 10]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q2
i) Mean = exp(µ+0.5*σ2) = exp(0.12+0.5*0.25) = 1.2776 [0.5]
Variance = exp(2µ+σ )*(exp(σ )-1) = exp(2*0.12+0.25)*(exp(0.25)-1) = 0.4636
2 2
[0.5]
iii) P(S(6)/S(5) < t) = 0.05 => P(Z < (ln(t)-0.12) / 0.25^0.5) = 0.05 [0.5]
=> (ln(t)-0.12) / 0.25^0.5 = -1.645 [0.5]
=> t = exp( -1.645 * 0.25^0.5 + 0.12) = 0.4954 [0.5]
=> VaR = £120,000 * 0.4954 = $59,446 [0.5]
[Or for £120,000 * (1 – 0.4954) = £60,552 lose one mark]
iv) The investor can retain 40,000 / 81,708 = 48.95% of his stocks, so he would need
to sell $61,254 of stocks. [1]
vi) There is a slightly less than 50:50 chance that the investor would be able to repay
the loan at time t=5. [1]
The cash account pays a lower rate of interest than the loan charges, so the
investor would be better off repaying $61,254 of the loan at time 5 if this is
possible. [1]
The investor could also seek other assets that deliver a higher potential return. [1]
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Or the investor could try to find other funds to cut his losses and repay the loan at
time 5. [1]
[Max 2]
Q3
i. 𝐸𝐸[𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 ] is the expected return of security i; [0.5]
𝑏𝑏𝑖𝑖,𝑘𝑘 is the responses of the rates of return on security i to factor k (alternatively the
sensitivity of security i to index k). [1]
𝜆𝜆𝑘𝑘 is the risk premium corresponding to factors k. [0.5]
ii. The risk free portfolio has zero exposure to any risk factor, i.e. 𝑏𝑏𝑖𝑖,𝑘𝑘 = 0 for all 𝑘𝑘, which
implies 𝜆𝜆0 = 𝑟𝑟𝑓𝑓 . [1]
The majority of students scored either full marks or nearly full marks on
this knowledge question.
For part (i), common mistakes were confusing the different parameters
such as describing lambas as sensitivities and vice versa.
For part (ii), common mistakes were not including the risk-free rate in the
equations or minor calculation errors.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q4
i)
a. E[A 3 ] = A 0 exp(µt+0.5σ2t) = 100exp(0.05*3+0.5*0.22*3) = £123.37 [1]
b. E[B 3 ] = B 0 exp(µt+0.5σ2t) = 100exp(0.08*3+0.5*0.32*3) = £145.50 [1]
ii)
a. SD[A 3 ] = √(A 0 2exp(2µt+σ2t)(exp(σ2t)-1)) [0.5]
= √(1002exp(2*0.05*3+0.22*3)(exp(0.22*3)-1)) [1]
= £44.05 [0.5]
b. SD[B 3 ] = √(B 0 2exp(2µt+σ2t)(exp(σ2t)-1)) [0.5]
= √(1002exp(2*0.08*3+0.32*3)(exp(0.32*3)-1)) [1]
= £81.01 [0.5]
v) The expected return of the portfolio falls halfway between the expected return on
each of the one-stock investment strategies. [1]
But the standard deviation is well below halfway between the two one-stock
strategies.
[1]
The price of risk for stock A is 23.37/44.05 = 0.53 [1]
The price of risk for stock B is 45.5/81.01 = 0.56 [1]
But the price of risk for the portfolio is 34.44/51.59 = 0.67 [1]
So the portfolio delivers a better expected return per unit of risk [1]
This is because the assets are not fully correlated… [1]
Which shows the benefit of diversification. [1]
[Max 4]
For part (iv), some students did not calculate a standard deviation
for the portfolio that was consistent with their answers in part (ii).
Their portfolio standard deviation was either much higher or much
lower.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q5
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
But 𝑑𝑑𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 = −𝛾𝛾𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝐵𝐵𝑡𝑡 so 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑(𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 , 𝑡𝑡) = 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝐵𝐵𝑡𝑡 [1]
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
𝑡𝑡 𝑡𝑡
Integrating between 0 and t gives ∫0 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑(𝑋𝑋𝑠𝑠 , 𝑠𝑠) = 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑑𝑑𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑓𝑓(𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 , 𝑡𝑡) − 𝑓𝑓(𝑋𝑋0 , 0) = 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑑𝑑𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 − 𝑋𝑋0 = 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑑𝑑𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 = 𝑋𝑋0 𝑒𝑒 −𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 + 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾(𝑠𝑠−𝑡𝑡) 𝑑𝑑𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 ] [1]
𝑡𝑡 𝑑𝑑 𝑡𝑡
Then ∫0 (𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑑𝑑𝑋𝑋𝑠𝑠 ) = ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 − 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾0 𝑋𝑋0 = 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 = 𝑋𝑋0 + 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 [1]
𝑡𝑡
So 𝑋𝑋𝑡𝑡 = 𝑋𝑋0 𝑒𝑒 −𝛾𝛾𝛾𝛾 + 𝜎𝜎 ∫0 𝑒𝑒 𝛾𝛾(𝑠𝑠−𝑡𝑡) 𝑑𝑑𝐵𝐵𝑠𝑠 ] [1]
6 Q6
i) Portfolio A = one call plus cash of Kexp(-r(T-t)) [1]
Portfolio B = one put plus one share [1]
Both portfolios have value max{K,S T } at expiry, hence by the principle of no
arbitrage they must have the same value at all earlier times. [1]
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Alternatively, option C is the same as B but with a strike price $2 higher. It can never be in
the money by more than $2 more than B, so it can never be worth more than $2 more than B.
[1]
Hence it can’t be worth more than $3.25. [1]
[Max 2]
[Or the American option is worth at least as much as the European option for 0.5 marks.]
In parts (iii) and (iv) most students identified the correct bounds but
some struggled with the American option.
Q7
ii) Under the Merton model, we consider that the shareholders have a call option on the
company’s assets, with a strike price equal to the nominal value of the debt. [1]
We want the share price to remain unchanged, so the value of the ‘call option’ after
the debt has been issued must be $1 per share = $100,000 in total. [1]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
We need to find the nominal value of the debt at maturity, which will be the strike
price of this option. [1]
[Max 2 so far]
Trying a strike price of $250,000 gives a call value of $137,811 [1]
Trying a strike price of $350,000 gives a call value of $71,960 [1]
Interpolating gives a strike price (i.e. nominal debt value at maturity) of $307,419
(actual value is $302,582) [1]
iii) The required yield on the debt is i where 250,000e5i = 302,582 => i = 3.82% [1]
=> credit spread = 3.82% - 3% = 0.82% [1]
Most students struggled with this question with most failing to score
more than a few marks.
In general, students did not understand they had been given the
value of equity and debt and had to solve for the redemption value
that was consistent with the values given.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
present value of debt that was higher than the redemption value,
leading to a negative credit spread.
Q8
i.
Stock tree
time 0 3 month 6 month 9 month
60.00 78.00 101.40 131.82
48.00 62.40 81.12
38.40 49.92
30.72
The price C 0 of the option is computed via Risk Neutral Valuation; let 𝑝𝑝̂ denote the risk neutral
probability of an up movement, then
𝑒𝑒 0.02∗0.25 −0.80
𝑝𝑝̂ = = 0.41 [1]
1.30−0.80
and
3
𝐶𝐶0 = 𝑒𝑒 −𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 � �𝑘𝑘3 �𝑝𝑝̂ 𝑘𝑘 (1 − 𝑝𝑝̂ )3−𝑘𝑘 𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚𝑚�0, 𝑆𝑆0 𝑢𝑢𝑘𝑘 𝑑𝑑3−𝑘𝑘 − 𝐾𝐾� [1]
𝑘𝑘=0
= 𝑒𝑒 −0.02∗0.75 (76.82 × 𝑝𝑝̂ 3 + 26.12 × 3𝑝𝑝̂ 2 (1 − 𝑝𝑝̂ ) ) = 12.87 [1]
The detailed workings are provided below – in case attempts to answer this
question go through the whole tree.
CALL
time 0 3 month 6 month 9 month
12.87 25.30 46.67 76.82
4.35 10.66 26.12
0.00 0.00
0.00
ii. Either from the put-call parity or by repeating calculation: 𝑃𝑃0 = 7.05 [1]
iii. The value of the position is 𝐶𝐶0 − 𝑃𝑃0 = 𝑆𝑆0 − 𝐾𝐾𝐾𝐾 −𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 [1].
This value would not change as it is independent of the expected movements of the
stock (i.e. its volatility) [2]
[Or students can recalculate the value for full marks.]
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
For part (ii), some students calculated the put price from first
principles rather than simply using the put-call parity relationship.
This was a valid approach but took up more time in the exam.
Q9
ii. Using the result from the previous part, the martingale property for the discounted
value of the portfolio is the same as for the discounted stock price. [1]
(𝜇𝜇 − 𝑟𝑟)�
This requires a change of measure to adjust for the market price of risk 𝜆𝜆 = 𝜎𝜎
[2]
[Or we can apply Taylor’s theorem to d(S t e-rT) and check that the drift is zero.]
[Or we could use Ito’s Lemma.]
[Or just 𝜆𝜆 = 𝑟𝑟 as a possible solution for one mark.]
Q10
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
3. The risk-free rate of interest is constant, the same for all maturities and the same
for borrowing or lending. [1/2]
4. Unlimited short selling (that is, negative holdings) is allowed. [1/2]
5. There are no taxes or transaction costs. [1/2]
6. The underlying asset can be traded continuously and in infinitesimally small
numbers of units. [1/2]
ii.
Data: 𝑆𝑆 = 8; 𝐾𝐾 = 9; 𝑟𝑟 = 2%; 𝜎𝜎 = 20%; 𝑇𝑇 = 0.25
By the Black-Scholes formula:
−𝑑𝑑1 = 1.0778 [0.5]
−𝑑𝑑2 = 1.1778 [0.5]
𝑁𝑁(−𝑑𝑑1 ) = 0.8594 [0.5]
𝑁𝑁(−𝑑𝑑2 ) = 0.8806 [0.5]
Therefore 𝑃𝑃0 = 9𝑒𝑒 −0.02×0.25 × 0.8806 −8 × 0.8594 [1]
= 1.01 [1]
iii. As interest rates increase in the market, the expected return required by investors in stock
tends to increase [0.5]
However, the present value of any future cash flow generated by option contracts decreases
[0.5]
The combined impact of these two effects is to decrease the value of the put option [1]
Rho is negative for a put option [0.5]
put options become less valuable in times of increasing interest rates because they
effectively defer the selling of a share and so delay access to the cash required to obtain the
risk-free rate
[0.5]
[Or students could explain how the terms in the formula change.]
[Max 2]
For part (ii), simple calculation errors were the most common
mistake.
Q11
i. SML: 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 = 𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 + 𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 (𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 − 𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 ) [1]
for
• 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 : expected return on Asset i. [1/4]
• 𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 : risk-free rate. [1/4]
• 𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 : beta factor of security i defined as 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 , 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 )/𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ). [1/4]
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2018 – Examiners’ Report
ii. Note that 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 = 𝑥𝑥1 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅1 + 𝑥𝑥2 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅2 [1/4], and 𝑥𝑥1 + 𝑥𝑥2 = 1 [1/4]
Substitute into the SML and solve for 𝑥𝑥1 , so that
𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 −𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅2 −𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 (1−𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 )
𝑥𝑥1 = (𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅1 −𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅2 )𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖
. [1]
From the data: 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅1 = 16.30% [1/4]
𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅2 = 29.70% [1/4]
Substituting either for Asset 1 or Asset 2, 𝑥𝑥1 = 0.4 [1/2]
and therefore 𝑥𝑥2 = 0.6 [1/2]
[Alternatively, the beta of the market portfolio is 1, so x_1*0.46 + x_2*1.36 = x_1*0.46
+ (1-x_1)*1.36 = 1 => x_1=0.4]
[Round up to nearest half mark.]
iii. 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) = 0.42 ∗ 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅1 ) + 0.62 ∗ 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅2 ) + 2 ∗ 0.4 ∗ 0.6 ∗ 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅1 , 𝑅𝑅2 ) = 0.00617.
[1]
Consequently �𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 − 𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 �/𝜎𝜎𝑀𝑀 = 1.897. [1]
For part (i), some students confused the Security Market Line and
the Capital Market Line despite these being given in the Actuarial
Tables.
Page 14
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your
answer booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
3. You have 15 minutes of planning and reading time before the start of this examination.
You may make separate notes or write on the exam paper but not in your answer
booklet. Calculators are not to be used during the reading time. You will then have
three hours to complete the paper.
5. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
(ii) Prove that the horse racing fan exhibits constant relative risk aversion. [2]
The horse racing fan is attending a race and she intends to place bets on two horses.
The table below shows the pay-out per £1 bet on each of these horses if it wins the
race, and the investor’s estimated probabilities of each horse winning the race. The
pay-out is the total paid and is not in addition to the bet being returned.
The horse racing fan has total wealth of £1,000 and she will bet all of her wealth on
this race. Negative bets are not allowed.
(iii) Calculate the amount she should bet on each horse to maximise her expected
utility of wealth. [7]
(iv) Calculate the expected wealth resulting from the bets in part (iii). [1]
(v) Explain how and why this differs from the utility of the horse racing fan’s
initial wealth. [2]
[Total 14]
2 Describe the difficulties in estimating parameters for asset pricing models. [5]
3 The value of an investment asset follows the equation A(t) = exp(Bt ), where Bt follows
standard Brownian motion.
(i) State the five defining properties that apply to Bt as a standard Brownian
motion.[5]
(ii) Calculate the expected value of this investment at time 5. [2]
(iii) Calculate the probability that the value of the student’s investment is less than
$10,000 at time 5. [2]
[Total 9]
CT8 A2018–2
4 Mr and Mrs Jones both wish to buy stocks in Widgets Inc. They don’t have enough
money right now, so they are considering buying either forwards or options on the
stocks, both with a term of 4 years.
The stock price at time 0 is £10 with standard deviation of 12% per annum. The stock
does not pay any dividend. The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is
5% per annum.
(ii) Calculate the price at time 0 of a 4 year call option on one stock with a strike
price of £12.21. [3]
Mrs Jones enters into one forward contract, while Mr Jones buys one call option. At
time 4 the stock is worth £12.
(iii) Calculate the accumulated profit or loss at time 4 for Mrs Jones. [1]
(iv) Calculate the accumulated profit or loss at time 4 for Mr Jones. [2]
(v) Explain why Mr Jones makes a loss despite having an option that does not
force him to buy the stock. [2]
(vi) Calculate the range of stock prices at time 4 which would leave Mr Jones
better off than Mrs Jones. [3]
[Total 12]
5 Consider a zero-coupon bond Bt with three years to maturity. The bond pays $100
at maturity if it has not defaulted, or $30 if it has defaulted. The continuously
compounded risk-free rate is r. In a two-state model the default intensity is l under
the probability measure P, and the bond price is:
A derivative pays $35 at time 3 if the bond has defaulted and $0 otherwise.
(ii) (a) Determine a constant portfolio containing the bond and cash which
replicates this derivative.
(b) Derive an expression for the arbitrage-free price for the derivative at
time 0 in terms of r and l.[5]
(iii) Explain how your answers to parts (i) and (ii) are related through the value of
the portfolio in part (ii) also being a martingale. [3]
[Total 12]
(i) State the conditions under which this market is arbitrage free. [1]
Let S0 = £95 and assume this price either rises or falls by 20% each year for the
next three years. Assume also that the risk-free rate is 5% per annum continuously
compounded.
(ii) Calculate the price of a vanilla European put option with maturity in three
years and strike price 110. [4]
Assume a change in market conditions such that the same share price now either rises
or falls by 5% each year for the next three years.
(iii) Determine how this change would impact on the option price. [2]
[Total 7]
The price process of a traded security satisfies the following stochastic differential
equation
where Wt is a Brownian motion under the real-world probability measure P. Let r > 0
be the continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest, with r ≠ μ.
(ii) Show that the discounted stock price e–rtSt is not a martingale under the real-
world probability measure P.[3]
(iii) Demonstrate how the discounted asset price e–rtSt can be a martingale under
an equivalent martingale measure Q. [3]
[Total 7]
CT8 A2018–4
8 The current price of a non-dividend paying stock is £65 and its volatility is 25% per
annum. The continuously compounded risk-free interest rate is 2% per annum.
Consider a European call option on this share with strike price £55 and expiry date in
six months’ time. Assume that the Black-Scholes model applies.
(iii) Calculate the value of the delta of the call option. [2]
(iv) Calculate the value of the delta of a European put option written on the same
underlying, with the same strike and maturity as above. [2]
[Total 9]
(i) Calculate the values of (a), (b), (c), (d), (e) in the table above. [5]
(ii) Write down the stochastic differential equations of two standard models for the
short rate of interest. [2]
[Total 7]
(i) Calculate the price of the option using the Black-Scholes model. [4]
(ii) Determine the (risk neutral) probability of the option expiring in the money.
[1]
1 if ST > K
0 otherwise
CT8 A2018–6
11 Consider a market in which the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) holds.
(i) List the assumptions, additional to those used in modern portfolio theory, of
the CAPM. [2]
(ii) Prove that the market portfolio has unit beta. [2]
In the same market as above, there are two assets with the following attributes.
(iv) Determine the value of the risk-free rate of interest which is consistent with
the results obtained in part (iii), under the assumption that the CAPM holds.[2]
[Total 9]
END OF PAPER
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2018
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
Luke Hatter
Chair of the Board of Examiners
June 2018
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to
construct asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are
also required to communicate with other financial professionals and to critically
evaluate modern financial theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to
those shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate.
Marks for the methodology are also awarded.
2. In general, the real differentiators in those who scored well were attention to detail
in their algebraic steps, and the breadth of knowledge in being able to score the
bookwork marks and even attempt most questions. The majority of candidates
seemed unable to gather from the text of the question the relevant information, and
translate it in the appropriate equivalent statistical concepts. For example,
candidates struggled with formulating the probability that an event occurs in
appropriate mathematical terms, and determining from the information in the
question the direct way to recover required variances and covariances. This showed
a lack of sufficient confidence with the fundamental statistical concepts which
Financial Economics so heavily relies on.
C. Pass Mark
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Solutions
Q1
i)
a. U’(w) = w-0.5 > 0 for w > 0 [1]
b. U’’(w) = -0.5w-1.5 < 0 for w > 0 [1]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Part i) and ii) were very well answered with most students scoring full
marks.
Many students found iii) challenging with only a few able to formulate
the expected utility correctly allowing for the possibility of neither horse
winning. Some students understood the method required of setting the
first derivative to zero and so were able to score method marks even if
they were unable to obtain the correct formula for the expected utility.
Very few candidates checked for conditions on the second order
derivative.
Quite a few candidates were able to derive the expected wealth correctly
for iv) based on their answer in iii) and so were able to score this mark.
Some candidates were able to score a mark for calculating the utility of
the initial wealth although few were able to make sensible comments to
score additional marks.
Q2
The estimation of parameters is one of the most time-consuming aspects of [½]
stochastic asset modelling.
The simplest case is the purely statistical model, where parameters are [½]
calibrated entirely to past time series. Provided the data is available, and
reasonably accurate, the calibration [½]
can be a straightforward and mechanical process.
Of course, there may not always be as much data as we would like, and [½]
the statistical error in estimating parameters may be substantial.
For example, what should be done when fitting a Gaussian model in the [½]
presence of large outliers in the data?
The model standard deviation may be subjectively nudged upwards after [½]
the fitting process, in order to give some recognition to the outliers which
have been excluded.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
It has often been the practice in actuarial modelling to use the same data [½]
set to specify the model structure, to fit the parameters, and to validate the
model choice.
A large number of possible model structures are tested, and testing stops [½]
when a model which is found which passes a suitable array of tests.
Many of these tests (for example, tests of stationarity) have notoriously [½]
low power, and therefore may not reject incorrect models.
Indeed, even if the “true” model was not in the class of models being [½]
fitted, we would still end up with an apparently acceptable fit, because
the rules say we keep generalising until we find one.
This theory may impose constraints, for example on the relative [½]
volatilities of bonds and currencies. Observed data may not fit these
constraints perfectly.
[Note to markers: please award ½ mark for any valid idea presented by the
candidates. We only need the concept to earn a half mark, not all the detail
above.]
[Max 5]
This was generally poorly answered with most candidates picking up one
or two marks at most. Many candidates focused on why the CAPM and
APT models were unrealistic rather than focusing specifically on the
challenges of estimating parameters and hence were unable to score
well.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q3
i) EITHER Bt has independent increments, OR Bt - Bs is independent of {Br , r <=
s} whenever s < t, OR BOTH
EITHER Bt has stationary increments, OR the distribution of Bt - Bs depends
only on t – s, OR BOTH
EITHER Bt has Gaussian increments, OR the distribution of Bt - Bs is N(0, t - s),
OR BOTH
Bt has continuous sample paths t -> Bt.
B0 = 0.
[1 Mark each]
[Total of 5]
ii) A(0) = exp(0) = 1, so the students buys 1,000 units of the asset. [½]
E[A(5)] = exp(0.5*12*5) = 12.182 [1]
So the expected value of the investment is $12,182. [½]
Part i) was bookwork and was well answered with the majority of
candidates scoring full or close to full marks.
Parts ii) and iii) proved challenging for many candidates although the
techniques required were quite standard. Students in general struggled
with identifying the correct parameters and which expectation and
probability to calculate.
Q4
i) F(4) = 10exp(4*0.05) = £12.21 [1]
ii) We can obtain d1 and d2 from the Black Scholes formula as:
d1 = 0.1214 [1]
d2 = -0.1186 [1]
Call price = £0.96 [1]
iii) Paid £12.21 for a stock worth £12 = loss of £0.21 [1]
iv) Paid £0.96 for call option = 0.96*exp(4*0.05) = £1.17 at time 4 [1]
Call expires worthless, hence loss of £1.17 [1]
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
[Note to marker: please award ½ mark for using £0.96 as the loss on the position]
vi) If the stock is worth more than £12.21 at time 4 then Mrs Jones will make [½]
a profit
and this profit will always be larger than Mr Jones’ profit because he had [1]
to buy the option.
If the stock is worth less than £12.21 at time 4 then Mrs Jones will make [½]
a loss
of £12.21 minus stock price [1]
ALTERNATIVE ANSWER: Profit from Call > Profit from forward [1]
Max{S(T) – 12.21, 0} – 1.17 > S(T) – 12.21 [½]
=> Max{– 12.21, – ST} > – 11.04 [½]
=> S(T) < 11.04 [1]
[Note to Markers: please accept valid answers carrying forward an erroneuos £0.96
as loss]
In general, parts i), ii) and iii) were well answered although there were
some calculation errors. Some candidates though did not reflect on the
magnitude of their answer to determine if it was realistic.
For iv) many candidates did not accumulate the premium paid to expiry
as required by the question and so were not able to score full marks.
In part v) most candidates did not explain properly why a premium is
required to enter the option and hence lost a mark.
Part vi) was quite poorly answered and quite a few candidates struggled
as they were unable to consider all the different possible outcomes.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q5
If the bond has already defaulted by time s then e-rsB s = e-rs30e-r(3-s) = e-rtB t [1]
We also need the value at time 3 to be zero if the bond has not defaulted, [1]
so xe3r +100y = 0
(b) The price at time zero must be the cost of buying this portfolio [½]
= 35e-3r(1-e-3λ) [½]
This fits with the fact that being able to hedge a derivative price without [1]
arbitrage means we can price it under the Equivalent Martingale Measure.
[Max 3]
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
This was a difficult question that was very poorly answered with
candidates either not attempting or only superficially attempting this
question. Overall the lowest scoring question from the paper.
For i), the majority of candidates appeared unfamiliar with the term
“equivalent martingale measure”, and did not realise they needed to
focus on the discounted price process.
There were more attempts for ii) although the majority were unable to
formulate the required equations for the replicating portfolio.
Part iii) was very poorly attempted and any reasonable comment was
given credit.
Q6
i) EITHER: The market is arbitrage free if and only if there exists a probability
measure under which discounted asset prices are martingales. [1]
OR
The probability exists if 1 − 𝑑𝑑 < 𝑒𝑒 𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 < 1 + 𝑢𝑢. [1]
OR BOTH [max 1]
[Note to markers: please accept solutions with 𝑑𝑑 < 𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒(𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟) < 𝑢𝑢, and 𝛿𝛿𝛿𝛿 = 1.]
𝑒𝑒 0.05 − 0.80
𝑝𝑝̂ = = 0.6282
1.20 − 0.80
[1]
and
3
3
𝑃𝑃0 = 𝑒𝑒 −𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 � � � 𝑝𝑝̂ 𝑘𝑘 (1 − 𝑝𝑝̂ )3−𝑘𝑘 (𝐾𝐾 − 𝑆𝑆0 𝑢𝑢𝑘𝑘 𝑑𝑑3−𝑘𝑘 )+
𝑘𝑘
𝑘𝑘=0
[2]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
iii) The given market conditions imply that 1 − 𝑑𝑑 = 0.95, 1 + 𝑢𝑢 = 1.05; [1]
however the discount factor is 𝑒𝑒 0.05 = 1.0513
[Alternatively, candidates can recalculate the risk neutral probability 𝑝𝑝̂ , which in this
case would give 1.0127, hence there is arbitrage in the market
Alternatively, candidates can obtain a negative option price ].
Parts i) and ii) were well answered although there were a few
calculation errors in ii). Lost marks were mostly for getting an incorrect
probability value, forgetting the combination factor in the final
calculation or slipping up with the numbers. A few students also got
confused and tried to price a call option.
There were quite a few good answers to iii) although about half did not
spot that the no arbitrage condition would not hold under the new
scenario.
Q7
i) The market is complete if for any contingent claim X there is a [1]
replicating strategy (Φ𝑡𝑡 , Ψ𝑡𝑡 )
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
[Alternative solutions based on solving the SDE and checking the martingale condition
are equally acceptable. This is equivalent to check that the identity E[𝑆𝑆̃𝑇𝑇 |𝐹𝐹𝑡𝑡 ]= 𝑆𝑆̃𝑡𝑡 for
𝑆𝑆̃𝑡𝑡 = 𝑆𝑆0 exp((𝜇𝜇 − 𝑟𝑟 − 0.5𝜎𝜎 2 )𝑡𝑡 + 𝜎𝜎𝑊𝑊𝑡𝑡 ) does not hold.]
iii) We need to change the Brownian motion by means of the Girsanov [1]
�𝑡𝑡 = 𝑊𝑊𝑡𝑡 + 𝜆𝜆𝜆𝜆 be a Brownian motion under a new probability
Theorem. Let 𝑊𝑊
measure 𝑄𝑄
then the above SDE becomes: [1]
For the martingale property to hold set the drift to zero, which implies
(𝜇𝜇 − 𝑟𝑟)�
𝜆𝜆 = 𝜎𝜎 . [1]
[Alternative solution carrying equal marks: change the Brownian motion as above
and take the conditional expectation under the new measure; this returns 𝐸𝐸 𝑄𝑄 �𝑆𝑆̃𝑇𝑇 �𝐹𝐹𝑡𝑡 � =
(𝜇𝜇 − 𝑟𝑟)�
𝑆𝑆̃𝑡𝑡 𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒𝑒(𝜇𝜇 − 𝑟𝑟 − 𝜆𝜆𝜆𝜆)(𝑇𝑇 − 𝑡𝑡). The martingale condition requires 𝜆𝜆 = 𝜎𝜎 .]
Q8
i) Data: 𝑆𝑆0 = 65, 𝐾𝐾 = 55, 𝜎𝜎 = 25% 𝑝𝑝. 𝑎𝑎. , 𝑇𝑇 = 0.5 𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦, 𝑟𝑟 = 2%
Let Ct be the price of the European call.
The Black-Scholes formula returns [½ Mark each]
𝑑𝑑1 = 1.09
𝑑𝑑2 = 0.9132
𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑1 ) = 0.8621
𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑2 ) = 0.8194
Therefore 𝐶𝐶0 = 65 × 0.8621 − 55𝑒𝑒 −0.02×0.5 × 0.8194 [1]
= 11.42 [1]
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕
ii) 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 = 𝜕𝜕𝜕𝜕
[1]
[Note to markers: please award ½ mark for stating 𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑1 ) ]
iii) In the Black-Scholes model 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 = 𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑1 ) [1]
Using the results from above 𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 = 0.8621 [1]
This question was generally well answered with quite a few scoring full
marks or close to full marks. Many got (iv) correct, but a significant
number of candidates got the sign wrong.
Q9
i) Using continuous compounding.
[Note to markers: please accept any correct attempt using different compounding
convention]
1 97.5
a. − 0.25 𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙 100 = 10.13% [1]
1 94.9
b. − 0.5 𝑙𝑙𝑙𝑙 100 = 10.47% [1]
c. 0.04 × (94.9 + 90) + 104 × 𝑒𝑒 −0.1068×1.5 = 96 [1]
(0.1054×1−0.1047×0.5)
d. 1−0.5
= 10.60% [1]
(0.1068×1.5−0.1054×1)
e. 1.5−1
= 10.97% [1]
ii) Two standard models for the short rate of interest are the Vasicek model
and the CIR model.
The corresponding SDEs are respectively
𝑑𝑑𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 = 𝑘𝑘(𝜃𝜃 − 𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 )𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + 𝜎𝜎𝜎𝜎𝑊𝑊𝑡𝑡
𝑑𝑑𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 = 𝑘𝑘(𝜃𝜃 − 𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 )𝑑𝑑𝑑𝑑 + 𝜎𝜎�𝑟𝑟𝑡𝑡 𝑑𝑑𝑊𝑊𝑡𝑡
[1 mark each]
Alternatively: another standard model is the Hull and White model which extends
the Vasicek model to allow for time-inhomogeneity, therefore the parameters in
the SDE are time dependent.
Parts i) a) and b) were very well answered and d) was also well answered
by many. Parts c) and e) proved difficult with only a few getting the
marks here.
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Q10
i) Data:
𝑆𝑆0 = 15, 𝐾𝐾 = 12, 𝜎𝜎 = 20% 𝑝𝑝. 𝑎𝑎. , 𝑇𝑇 = 0.25 𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦𝑦, 𝑟𝑟 = 2%.
Let Ct be the price of the European call.
𝑑𝑑1 = 2.3314
𝑑𝑑2 = 2.2314
𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑1 ) = 0.9901
𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑2 ) = 0.9872
ii) Probability of expiring in the money: 𝑃𝑃(𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 > 𝐾𝐾) = 𝑁𝑁(𝑑𝑑2 ) [½]
hence from above 𝑃𝑃(𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 > 𝐾𝐾) = 0.9872. [½]
iii) Risk neutral valuation applied to the given digital option returns
𝐸𝐸�𝑒𝑒 −𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 1𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇>𝐾𝐾 � = 𝑒𝑒 −𝑟𝑟𝑟𝑟 𝑃𝑃(𝑆𝑆𝑇𝑇 > 𝐾𝐾) [1]
From above it follows that the price is 𝑒𝑒 −0.02×0.25 × 0.9872 = 0.98225 [1]
a. Share prices can jump. This invalidates assumption that the stock price evolves
as geometric Brownian motion, as this process has continuous sample paths.
However, hedging strategies can still be constructed which substantially reduce
the level of risk.
b. The risk-free rate of interest does vary and in an unpredictable way. However,
over the short term of a typical derivative, the assumption of a constant risk-free
rate of interest is not far from reality. (More specifically the model can be
adapted in a simple way to allow for a stochastic risk-free rate, provided this is a
predictable process.)
c. Unlimited short selling may not be allowed, except perhaps at penal rates of
interest. These problems can be mitigated by holding mixtures of derivatives
which reduce the need for short selling. This is part of a suitable risk
management strategy.
d. Shares can normally only be dealt in integer multiples of one unit, not
continuously, and dealings attract transaction costs. Again we are still able to
construct suitable hedging strategies which substantially reduce risk.
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
e. Distributions of share returns tend to have fatter tails than suggested by the
lognormal model.
[Note to Markers: please award ½ mark for any valid idea/comment. Just the concept
is enough for a half mark, no need for all the detail above.]
[Max 2]
Part i) was well answered although there were some calculation errors.
Parts ii) and iii) proved challenging for some although quite a few
candidates were able to score full marks.
Part iv) was generally well answered although quite a number of
candidates struggled to generate enough points to score full marks for a
standard bookwork question.
Q11
i) CAPM assumptions [½ mark each]
ii) By definition the beta of each security is 𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 = 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 , 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 )/𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) [½]
where 𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 is the rate of return on security 𝑖𝑖, 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 , 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) are respectively
the rate of return on the market portfolio and its variance [½]
Hence
𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 , 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 )
𝛽𝛽𝑀𝑀 = =1
𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 )
as required [1]
(Note to markers: the same conclusion can be reached from the Security Market
Line, and is equally acceptable)
iii) As the market portfolio is the weighted portfolio of the risky securities
in the market, and the given weights are 0.4 and 0.6, then
𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 , 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) = 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 , 0.4𝑅𝑅1 + 0.6𝑅𝑅2 )
[1]
from which it follows that [½ mark each]
Page 14
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2018 – Examiners’ Report
Also:
𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) = 0.42 ∗ 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅1 ) + 0.62 ∗ 𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅2 ) + 2 ∗ 0.4 ∗ 0.6 ∗ 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅1 , 𝑅𝑅2 ) =
0.00125
Consequently 𝛽𝛽1 = 0.70915, 𝛽𝛽2 = 1.1939 [½ each]
[Note to Markers: please accept any correct attempt with rounded figures. For
𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅1 , 𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 ) = 0.4𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉𝑉(𝑅𝑅1 ) + 0.6𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶(𝑅𝑅1 , 𝑅𝑅2 ) = 0.0009
we obtain 𝛽𝛽1 = 0.72, 𝛽𝛽2 = 1.2]
iv) From the Security Market Line it follows that 𝑅𝑅𝑓𝑓 = (𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 − 𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 )⁄(1 − 𝛽𝛽𝑖𝑖 )
From the data 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅1 = 6.40%, 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅2 = 9.90% . [½ marks each]
Consequently
𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑀𝑀 = ∑2𝑖𝑖=1 𝑤𝑤𝑖𝑖 𝐸𝐸𝑅𝑅𝑖𝑖 = 8.5% [½]
Page 15
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
3. You have 15 minutes of planning and reading time before the start of this examination.
You may make separate notes or write on the exam paper but not in your answer
booklet. Calculators are not to be used during the reading time. You will then have
three hours to complete the paper.
5. Attempt all nine questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
Consider four assets which will deliver a one-year return ri on asset i with
probabilities as set out below:
P(ri = –5%) P(ri = –3%) P(ri = 0%) P(ri = +3%) P(ri = +5%)
(ii) State the two assumptions about investor behaviour that are needed for the
existence of efficient portfolios. [1]
An investment universe includes two assets, A and B, with expected return on asset i
of ri and variance vi as set out below:
A rA = 0.05 vA = 0.16
B rB = 0.07 vB = 0.25
CT8 S2017–2
Let R be the expected return on the portfolio.
(v) Determine the two portfolios on the efficient frontier that also lie on the
investor’s indifference curve. [4]
(vi) Comment on the implications for part (v) if short selling is not allowed in the
market. [2]
[Total 15]
(i) State whether each of the following changes in underlying factors would
increase or reduce the price of this option:
[You should assume that each change occurs on a standalone basis, i.e. all
other factors are unchanged.] [2]
Consider a European put option with price pt written on the same underlying security,
with the same strike price K and the same maturity T as the call option described
above.
(iii) Write down a formula that relates the values of ct and pt. [1]
The call option has value £0.50 at time t = 0, and the put option has value £1.00. Both
options are written on a security with current value S0 = £5, and both options have
strike price £6.00 and maturity T = 3 years.
(v) Suggest, with justification, how the formula in part (iii) can be rewritten as an
inequality if both options are American options. [3]
[Total 12]
Let S0 = $100 and assume that in three months’ time the stock price is either $125 or
$105. No dividends are payable on this stock.
Assume also that the continuously compounded risk-free rate is 5% per annum.
(i) Verify that this market is not arbitrage-free by considering the relationship
between the risk-free rate and the stock price movements. [2]
Now assume that the continuously compounded risk-free rate is 20% per annum.
Consider a European put option on this stock, expiring in three months’ time and with
strike price K = $120.
(ii) State an important property of the discounted value of a security price process
under the risk-neutral measure. [1]
The price process St of a traded security satisfies the following stochastic differential
equation:
(iii) Show, using parts (i) and (ii), that Wt + λt is a Brownian motion under the
risk-neutral probability measure, if λ = (μ − r ) . [3]
σ
(iv) Calculate the value of λ in the case in which μ = 0.04 + r and σ = 0.4. [1]
Another traded asset has a price process satisfying the stochastic differential equation
(v) Determine the value of the volatility coefficient γ, using your result from
part (iv). [2]
[Total 10]
CT8 S2017–4
6 (i) Write down an expression for the price of a derivative in a Black-Scholes
market in terms of an expectation under the risk-neutral measure, defining any
additional notation that you use. [3]
Consider an option on a non-dividend-paying stock when the stock price is £50, the
exercise price is £49, the continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 5% per
annum, the volatility is 25% per annum, and the time to maturity is six months.
(ii) Calculate the price of the option using the Black-Scholes formula, if the option
is a European call. [4]
(v) Determine how the prices of the contracts in parts (ii) to (iv) would change in
the case of a dividend-paying underlying stock. [Note that you do not have to
perform any further calculations.] [3]
[Total 13]
7 (i) State the main potential drawback of the Vasicek model. [1]
(ii) Discuss the extent to which this drawback may be a problem. [3]
(iii) Explain how the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model avoids this drawback. [3]
The Vasicek term structure model is described by the following stochastic differential
equation:
and a, b, σ > 0.
Under this model, the short rate rt follows a Normal distribution with mean
E (rt ) = r0e− at + b (1 − e− at )
σ2
and variance Var (rt ) = (1 − e −2 at ).
2a
(iv) Assess, using the information provided above, whether the model generates
interest rates that are mean reverting and, if so, the value to which they revert.
[2]
(v) Assess, using the information provided above, the relevance of the
parameter a to any mean reversion. [2]
[Total 11]
Assume that rf = 0.075. Consider a two-factor model (i.e. n = 2) and two well-
diversified portfolios (P1 and P2) with the following features:
P1 P2
Suppose that in the market there is another portfolio with the following features:
(iv) Comment on the feasibility of such a portfolio under the APT model
assumptions. [3]
[Total 10]
Assume that a firm has issued a zero-coupon bond maturing in five years’ time with
maturity value €100m, and that the current value of the firm’s assets is €110m.
Further assume that the estimated volatility of the firm’s assets is 25% per annum and
the risk-free rate of interest is 2% per annum continuously compounded.
(i) Show that the current value of the debt of the firm is €76.88m. [5]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2017–6
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2017
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
Luke Hatter
Chair of the Board of Examiners
December 2017
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to
construct asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are
also required to communicate with other financial professionals and to critically
evaluate modern financial theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to
those shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate.
Marks for the methodology are also awarded.
C. Pass Mark
Solutions
Q1 (i) (a) Absolute dominance exists when one investment portfolio [1]
provides a higher return than another in all possible circumstances.
(b) The first order stochastic dominance theorem states that, [½]
assuming an investor prefers more to less, A will dominate B
(i.e. the investor will prefer portfolio A to portfolio B) if:
(c) The second order stochastic dominance theorem applies when the [½]
investor is risk averse, as well as preferring more to less.
x x
a FA ( y)dy a FB ( y)dy, for all x, [½]
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
and where a is the lowest return that the portfolios can possibly [½]
provide.
[Max 4]
(ii)
PDF –5% –3% 0% 3% 5%
1 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2
2 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.2 0.2
3 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.3 0.1
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Q2 (i) (a) A portfolio is inefficient if the investor can find another [½]
portfolio with the same expected return and lower variance,
(b) A portfolio is efficient if the investor cannot find a better one [½]
in the sense that it has both the same or higher expected return
(a) Investors are never satiated. [At a given level of risk, they [½]
will always prefer a portfolio with a higher expected return to
one with a lower return.]
(b) Investors dislike risk. [For a given level of return, they will [½]
always prefer a portfolio with lower expected variance to one
with higher variance.]
(vi) The second solution implies a proportion of –0.2889 invested in asset B [1]
so would not be allowed, hence only the first solution would remain. [1]
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) (a) This is because there is a lower intrinsic value (or, where the [1]
intrinsic value is currently zero, a smaller chance that the option
is in-the-money at maturity).
(c) This is because there is again a lower intrinsic value, or a smaller [1]
chance that the option is in-the-money at maturity.
(d) This is because the higher the volatility of the underlying share, [1]
the greater the chance that the share price can move significantly
in favour of the holder of the option before expiry.
(e) This is because the money saved by purchasing the option rather [1]
than the underlying share has to be invested at this lower rate of
interest, thus decreasing the value of the option.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Q4 (i) The market is arbitrage free if and only if there exists a probability [1]
measure under which discounted asset prices are martingales
Alternatively, it can be seen that investment in the stock will gain [1]
more than the risk-free rate…
(ii) (a) The investor could buy the stock at 100 by borrowing money [1]
at the risk-free rate of interest.
In three months, the investor then could sell the stock and [1]
repay the loan + interest
(b) This would result in a profit of either 23.74 – in the case in [1]
which the stock is worth 125
(iii) The price C0 of the option is computed via risk-neutral valuation; let 𝑝̂ denote
the risk-neutral probability of an up movement, then
e0.20.25 1.05
pˆ 0.0064 [1]
1.25 1.05
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
t
and where Zt Zt 0 s ds is a standard Brownian motion under Q. [1]
[Max 3]
(ii) Under the risk-neutral probability measure, the discounted value of asset
prices are martingales. [1]
( r )
If then the drift term is zero, as required (for a martingale). [1]
0.04 r r
(iv) 0.1 [1]
0.4
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(v) The risk driver is the same, therefore the market price of risk is identical. [1]
0.06 0.06
Hence 0.6 . [1]
0.1
and the expectation is taken under the risk-neutral martingale measure. [½]
[Max 3]
d1 = 0.3441 [½]
d2 = 0.1673 [½]
(iii) Same as European call (as the stock is non-dividend-paying), i.e. 4.66 [1]
pt = ct + Ke-r(T-t) - St [1]
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(v) If the stock is dividend-paying, the payment of the dividends would cause the
value of the underlying asset to fall – which follows from the no arbitrage
principle [1]
Alternatively: in valuing the option we must take account of the fact that
dividends are payable on the underlying asset which do not feed through to the
holder of the option. [1]
… since by buying the option instead of the underlying share the investor
forgoes the income [½]
The American call would now be more expensive than the European call due
to potential early exercise opportunity [1]
[Max 3]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) The extent of the problem depends on the probability of negative interest
rates… [½]
… within the timescale of the problem in hand (or, for example, less of an
issue if the time horizon is short)… [1]
It also depends on the economy being modelled, as negative interest rates have
been seen in some countries. [1]
[Max 3]
(iii) The CIR model does not allow interest rates to go negative. [1]
This is because the volatility under the CIR increases in line with the square
root of r(t). [1]
… provided σ2 ≤ 2αµ
[Max 3]
Hence interest rates under the model are mean reverting [½]
This implies that the convergence of the rate to the long run mean b is faster
the bigger a [1]
[Max 2]
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Most students here knew that the Vasicek model allows negative
interest rates, and were able to explain why the Cox-Ingersoll-
Ross model does not. Part (ii) required students to think about
why negative interest rates might (or might not) be a problem in
the real world –many students just repeated bookwork about the
Vasicek model and scored no marks. Parts (iv) and (v) were
answered fairly well, though not all students worked through
the algebra correctly.
(ii) The risk-free portfolio has zero exposure to all risk factors [1]
as the given expected return does not satisfy the given APT equation [1]
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Q9 The Merton model for credit risk is based on the Black-Scholes formula. Hence.
(i) The current value of the debt, say D0 , of the firm is the value of a risk-free
zero coupon bond with the same face value and maturity of the firm debt
corrected by the cost of default. That is, where F0 is the value of the firm’s
assets (=110) and L is the face value of the debt (=100):
d1 0.6289
d2 0.0699
[½ for each]
N(d1) 0.7353
N(d2) 0.5279
N(-d1) 0.2647
N(-d2) 0.4721
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Note to markers: give full marks for correct answer, even if no working
shown.
Page 13
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
3. You have 15 minutes of planning and reading time before the start of this examination.
You may make separate notes or write on the exam paper but not in your answer
booklet. Calculators are not to be used during the reading time. You will then have
three hours to complete the paper.
5. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
U(w) = w + dw2.
(iii) Explain why the investor can only use this utility function to make decisions
over a limited range of wealth, w. Your answer should include a statement of
this range. [2]
The investor states that the upper limit of wealth where she can use this utility
function is w = $1,000.
The investor wins a prize of $250 in a gameshow. She is then offered the opportunity
to exchange this prize for a larger prize of $600 if she can answer one more question
correctly. However, she will receive no prize at all if she gets the question wrong.
She estimates her chances of answering the question correctly to be 50%.
(v) Determine whether the investor should take this opportunity to exchange. [3]
[Total 10]
2 Describe the empirical evidence relating to the continuous-time lognormal model for
security prices. [8]
CT8 A2017–2
3 Consider a non-dividend-paying security with price St at time t. The security price
follows the stochastic differential equation:
where:
An investor has taken out a house loan, with a repayment of £100,000 due in six
years’ time.
(ii) Determine the amount that the investor would need to invest in the security to
give a 75% probability of having an investment value of at least £100,000 in
six years’ time. [4]
The investor only has £50,000 available, which he invests in this security at time
t = 0.
(iii) Calculate the following risk measures applied to the difference between the
value of the security and £100,000 at time t = 6:
(iv) Comment on the implications for the investor of your answers to part (iii). [2]
(v) Suggest two changes that the investor might therefore make to his portfolio.
[2]
[Total 17]
(a) delta
(b) vega
(c) theta
(d) gamma
[4]
Consider a call option with price ct at time t (in years) written on an underlying non-
dividend-paying asset with price St at time t and volatility σ.
Using Taylor’s expansion, it can be shown that the change in value of the option is
approximately given by:
At time t = 0, the underlying asset price is €23 and the volatility is 20% per annum.
The option is priced at €6.17 and has the following properties:
• delta = 0.822
• vega = 0.104
• theta = –0.855
• gamma = 0.033
At time t = 1, the security price has fallen to €20 and its volatility is now 15% per
annum.
The delta of a call option is always positive, whilst the delta of a put option is always
negative.
CT8 A2017–4
5 Consider a three-period binomial tree model for a stock price process St , under which
the stock price either rises by 18% or falls by 15% each month. No dividends are
payable.
Let S0 = $85.
Consider a European put option on this stock, with maturity in three months (i.e. at
time t = 3) and strike price $90.
(ii) Calculate the risk-neutral probability that the put option expires out-of-the-
money. [2]
(iii) Assess whether the probability calculated in part (ii) would be higher or lower
under the real-world probability measure. [No further calculation is required.]
[3]
[Total 9]
6 The market price St of a traded security satisfies the following stochastic differential
equation:
(i) Determine the value of λ such that the discounted asset price process
St = e− rt St is a martingale under the given probability measure. [3]
A European call option on this share has a strike price of £6.50 and term to maturity
of one year.
(i) Calculate the price of this call option, assuming that the Black-Scholes model
applies. [4]
(ii) Show that the volatility of the share implied by the true market price of the
option is 60% per annum, to the nearest 1% per annum. [6]
[Total 10]
Let B (t , T ) be the price at time t > 0 of a zero-coupon bond which pays a value of 1
when it matures at time T.
Let F (t , S , T ) be the forward rate at time t for a deposit starting at time S > t and
expiring at time T > S.
A At time t:
B At time t:
At time S:
Invest the redemption amount from the bond at the forward rate F (t , S , T ) and
continue to hold this deposit to time T.
CT8 A2017–6
9 Let Ri denote the return on security i in a two-factor model.
(i) Write down the return equation for this two-factor model, defining all
additional notation that you use. [2]
10 In a market in which the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) holds, there are two
securities with the following attributes (expressed per annum):
security A B
E(ri) 0.196 0.164
Cov(ri, rj) A 0.05 0.01
B 0.01 0.03
(i) Determine the composition of the market portfolio with expected return 18%
per annum. [2]
(ii) Calculate the beta of each security, under the assumption that the risk-free rate
of interest is 10% per annum. [2]
11 (i) Describe the three main approaches to modelling credit risk. [5]
Consider the Merton model for credit risk. Let F(t) be the total value at time t of a
corporate entity which has issued zero-coupon debt with promised repayment amount
L due at time T.
(ii) State the condition under which the corporate entity is assumed to default in
this model. [1]
(iii) State the type of process that F(t) can be assumed to follow. [1]
(iv) Give an expression for the risk-neutral probability of default of the corporate
entity at time 0, defining any additional notation used. [2]
[Total 9]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2017–7
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2017
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping candidates, both
those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers as a revision aid and
also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The Examiners have
access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and will generally base
questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core Reading specifically or
exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in this
report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions, particularly the
open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points than the Examiners
will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances may
have changed if using these reports for revision.
Luke Hatter
Chair of the Board of Examiners
July 2017
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to construct
asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are also required to
communicate with other financial professionals and to critically evaluate modern financial
theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to those
shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate. Marks for the
methodology are also awarded.
1. Students performed relatively well on bookwork questions, although many missed the
opportunity to be awarded full marks due to relatively superficial knowledge.
2. The majority of the students seemed to struggle on the application parts of the questions,
because they were not able to use and combine the information given to them in the
question. In a few instances, students did not know how to go from the lognormal
distribution to the Normal and then to the standard Normal. Further, there is often a lack
of knowledge of how to use the distribution tables to compute probabilities (in the specific
case of this exam paper, the normal distribution), and relative inaccuracy in getting the
details right.
C. Pass Mark
Solutions
Q1 (i) The expected utility theorem states that a function, U(w), can be constructed
representing an investor’s utility of wealth, w, at some future date. [1]
Decisions are made on the basis of maximising the expected value of utility
under the investor’s particular beliefs about the probability of different
outcomes. [1]
Because the investor is risk averse, we must have U’’(w) < 0 (alternatively to
satisfy the condition of diminishing marginal utility of wealth (risk aversion))
[½]
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
So the quadratic utility function can only satisfy the condition of non-satiation
over a limited range of w:
… because the expected utility of the exchange opportunity is lower than that
of the prize. [½]
[Total 10]
Generally well answered. In part (i) many students covered the axioms on
which the theory is based rather than the theorem, as asked. In part (ii) some
candidates confused non satiation with risk aversion. A significant number of
candidates did not know how to reply to part (iv). In part (v) students
appeared to have difficulties distinguishing between utility of expected wealth
and expected utility of wealth.
Q2 Share prices are always positive, which is consistent with this model. [½]
The increments of share prices are proportional to the share price itself. [½]
However, estimates of σ vary widely according to what time period is considered. [1]
One way of modelling this behaviour is to take volatility as a process in its own right.
This can explain why we have periods of high volatility and periods of low volatility.
[1]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
One class of models with this feature is known as ARCH: autoregressive conditional
heteroscedasticity. [½]
A more contentious area relates to whether the drift parameter μ is constant over time.
[½]
There are good theoretical reasons to suppose that μ should vary over time. [½]
For example, if interest rates are high, we might expect the equity drift, μ, to be high
as well. [½]
One unsettled empirical question is whether markets are mean reverting, or not. [½]
… but the evidence rests heavily on the aftermath of a small number of dramatic
crashes. [½]
A further strand of empirical research questions the use of the normality assumptions
in market returns. [½]
Actual returns tend to have many more extreme events, both on the upside and
downside, than is consistent with such a model. [1]
While the random walk produces continuous price paths, jumps or discontinuities
seem to be an important feature of real markets. [1]
Furthermore, days with no change, or very small change, also happen more often than
the normal distribution suggests. [1]
Market jumps are consistent with the arrival of information in packets rather than
continuously. [½]
After a crash, many investors may have lost a significant proportion of their total
wealth; it is not irrational for them to be more averse to the risk of losing what
remains. [½]
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Many orthodox statistical tests are based around assumptions of normal distributions.
If we reject normality, we will also have to re-test various hypotheses. In particular,
the evidence for time-varying mean and volatility is greatly weakened. [1]
[Max 8]
Standard bookwork question. Overall most of the candidates described some key
points worth some marks, but not everyone covered all the necessary points to get
full marks. Most students focussed on the appropriateness of the normality
assumptions. A few students instead discussed Brownian motion rather than the
lognormal model.
As Zt is normal, [1]
with parameters
(ii) To find the initial investment we need the 25th percentile of logSt over 6 years,
i.e. with parameters 0.12875 × 6 = 0.7725 [½]
P( (log S6– 0.7725) / √(0.375) < X) = 0.25 under a normal distribution [1]
X = –0.6745 [½]
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
So:
X = –1.2816 [½]
(iv) The investor has an expected surplus, and therefore expects to repay the
loan… [1]
[Note to markers: please award marks for any reasonable point which is
consistent with answers in 3(ii) and 3(iii) – even if those results were wrong.]
(v) The investor might move his investments to an asset with a lower expected
return but also lower variance. [1]
The investor might decide to diversify his portfolio between a large number of
different securities. [1]
The investor might decide to pay off some of the loan early. [1]
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
The investor might decide to buy an insurance product rather than using
securities. [1]
[Max 2]
[Total 17]
Q4 (i) Let f be the value of the derivative, S the price of the underlying, σ its
volatility, T maturity of the derivative and t current time.
f f
(a) (t St ) [1]
s s
(b) f [1]
f
(c) Either or [1]
t
2 f
(d) [1]
s 2
(iii) The delta for a call option is always positive because an increase in the share
price makes an option to buy the share for a set price more valuable. So as the
share price increases, the call option price also increases, hence the relative
change (the delta) is positive. [1]
Similarly, the delta for a put option is always negative because an increase in
the share price makes the option to sell the share for a set price less valuable.
So as the share price increases, the put option price reduces, hence the relative
change (the delta) is negative. [1]
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) The more volatile an asset is, the more valuable the choice offered by an
option. [1]
[Total 9]
Q5 (i)
Stock tree
time 0 1 2 3
85.00 100.30 118.35 139.66
72.25 85.26 100.60
61.41 72.47
52.20
The price C0 of the option is computed via risk-neutral valuation; let ̂ denote
the risk-neutral probability of an up movement, then:
e0.0025 0.85
pˆ 0.4621 [1]
1.18 0.85
And
3
3
3 k
C0 e rT pˆ k 1 pˆ K S0u k d 3k [2]
k
k 0
e 0.0075 17.53 3 pˆ 1 pˆ 37.80 1 pˆ
2 3
12.82 [1]
[Max 4]
The detailed working are provided below – in case attempts to answer this
question go through the whole tree [and it carries same marks as above].
PUT
time 0 1 2 3
12.82 5.05 0.00 0.00
19.55 9.41 0.00
28.36 17.53
37.80
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(iii) Under the risk-neutral probability the expected rate of return on the stock is
the risk-free rate of return, i.e. 0.25% per month. [1]
Under the real-world probability measure instead, the stock is expected to earn
a much higher rate of return… [1]
… in order to justify the higher risk it carries compared to the risk-free bond
[1]
Consequently we would expect the probability of the put option to expire out-
of-the-money to be higher than 0.4433. [1]
[Max 3]
[Total 9]
For the martingale property to hold, set the drift to zero [1]
which implies
r . [1]
In other words the expected rate of return on the stock is given by the risk-free
rate of interest [1]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
d1 = 0.5103 [½]
d2 = 0.1103 [½]
= 1.50 [1]
(ii) 60% returns a call price of 1.995, following the same calculations as in part (i)
d1= 0.5068, [½]
d2 = -0.0932, [½]
N(d1) = 0.6939, [1]
N(d2) = 0.4629 [1]
We need to check that the volatility is closer to 60% than 61%, so we calculate
the call price with a volatility of 60.5%. We need this price to be larger than 2.
[1]
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Therefore, since the 60% result is smaller than 2 and the 60.5% result is larger
than 2, the implied volatility is 60% to the nearest 1%. [1]
[Max 6]
[Total 10]
… if they have the same value at time T then they must have the same value at
time t [1]
Hence B(t,T) = B(t,S) [1]
log B t ,T log B t , S
F t, S ,T . [1]
T S
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Solving the last equality with respect to the ZCB price, we obtain:
T
f t , s ds
B t ,T e t [½]
[Total 10]
Large variety of answers and only well prepared candidates scored well. In
part (i) many candidates failed to list all the key points; in part (ii) a number of
candidates failed to use the given portfolio to obtain the required result and,
instead, used the result they had to show as given. In part (iii) candidates
struggled to recognise that they needed to define the instantaneous forward
rate.
where ai and ci are the constant and random parts respectively of the
component of the return unique to security i [½]
These use observable economic time series as the factors, such as the annual
rates of inflation and economic growth, short term interest rates, the yields on
long term government bonds, and the yield margin on corporate bonds over
government bonds. [1]
These use company specific variables as the factors, e.g. the level of gearing,
the price earnings ratio, the level of research and development spending, the
industry group to which the company belongs. [1]
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
Q10 (i) The market portfolio is the weighted portfolio of the risky securities in the
market, consequently
Eri r f
i
ErM r f
(iii) Empirical studies do not provide strong support for the model. [½]
Investors may not have the same estimates of expected returns, standard
deviations and covariances of securities. There are basic problems in testing
the model since, in theory, account has to be taken of the entire investment
universe open to investors, not just capital markets. [½]
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
It does not account for inflation. [Or: some investors may measure in real
terms and some in money terms.] [½]
It does not account for situations in which there is no riskless asset. [½]
The basic model does not allow for currency risk. [Or: investors may not
measure in the same currency.] [½]
It does not consider multiple time periods. [Or: investors do not all have the
same one-period time horizon.] [½]
Well answered by most candidates. However, in part (ii) there was some
evidence of students not being able to calculate the market portfolio correctly
instead calculating the minimum-variance portfolio under Mean-Variance
Portfolio Theory.
Structural models aim to link default events explicitly to the fortunes of the
issuing corporate entity. [1]
Reduced form models use observed market statistics rather than specific data
relating to the issuing corporate entity. [1]
The market statistics most commonly used are the credit ratings… [½]
… issued by credit rating agencies such as Standard and Poor’s and Moody’s.
[½]
Page 14
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2017 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) Default occurs if the value of the assets is not enough to cover the face value
of the debt at maturity
(iii) F(t) follows a geometric Brownian motion (or continuous time lognormal
model). [1]
F 0 2
ln r q T
L 2
P F T L 1 N
T
where P(.) is the probability under the risk-neutral measure, F (0) is the
current value of the firm, σ is its volatility, r is the risk-free rate and q
denotes any potential payout cashflow. [2]
[Total 9]
Candidates familiar with the study material scored well. Part (i) was often
answered correctly although some candidates failed to describe properly the
main approaches and some mixed the names of the approaches. In part (iii)
many candidates missed the “q”.
Page 15
1
2 INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
3
4
5
6
7 EXAMINATION
8
9
6 October 2016 (pm)
10
11
Subject CT8 – Financial Economics
12
Core Technical
13
14 Time allowed: Three hours
15
INSTRUCTIONS TO THE CANDIDATE
16
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
17 booklet.
18
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
19 supervisor.
20
3. You have
Mark 15 minutes
allocations are of planning
shown and reading time before the start of this examination.
in brackets.
21 You may make separate notes or write on the exam paper but not in your answer
4. booklet. all
Attempt Calculators are beginning
10 questions, not to be used
yourduring
answerthetoreading time. You
each question on will
a newthen have
page.
22 three hours to complete the paper.
23 5. Candidates should show calculations where this is appropriate.
4. Mark allocations are shown in brackets.
24
5. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning
Graph paper your
is NOT answerfor
required to each question on a new page.
this paper.
25
26 6. Candidates should show calculations where this is appropriate.
AT THE END OF THE EXAMINATION
27 Graph paper is NOT required for this paper.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
28 question paper.
29 AT THE END OF THE EXAMINATION
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
30 Hand in BOTHand your answer
Tables and booklet,
your ownwith any additional
electronic calculatorsheets firmly
from the attached,
approved list. and this
question paper.
31
32 In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
33
34
CT8 S2016 Institute and Faculty of Actuaries
35
1 Consider an asset whose return follows the probability density function f(x).
(i) Write down a formula for the Value at Risk for the asset, at confidence level p.
[1]
(ii) Write down a formula for the downside semi-variance of the return on the
asset, defining any additional notation you use. [1]
(iii) State the arguments for and against using semi-variance as a risk measure. [2]
A farmer has a small apple tree which produces one harvest of apples per year. The
number of apples the tree produces follows a Poisson distribution with a mean and
variance of 8.
(iv) Determine the 10% Value at Risk level for the number of apples produced. [3]
Consider a mean-variance portfolio model with two securities, with respective returns
SA and SB, where the expected return E[SB] = 0.25E[SA] and the variance of return
V[SB] = 0.25V[SA].
(ii) Determine, in terms of E[SA], the expected return on the minimum variance
portfolio if:
(a) ρ=0
(b) ρ=1
[4]
(iii) (a) Calculate the variance of the return on the minimum variance portfolio
for part (ii)(b).
CT8 S2016–2
3 In a market where the assumptions of the Capital Asset Pricing Model hold, there are
two risky assets with the following attributes:
Security A B
Expected return (p.a.) 20% 16%
(i) Determine the composition of the market portfolio with expected return 18%
per annum. [2]
(ii) Calculate the beta of each security under the assumption that the risk-free rate
of interest is 10% per annum. [2]
[Total 4]
4 Let Ri denote the return on security i given by the following multifactor model:
Ri ai bi ,1 I1 bi ,2 I 2 bi , L I L ci
where ai and ci are the constant and random parts respectively of the component of
the return unique to security i, I1 , , I L are the changes in a set of the L indices and
bi ,k is the sensitivity (factor beta) of security i to factor k.
(a) index 1 is a price index, index 2 is the yield on government bonds and
index 3 is the annual rate of economic growth.
Consider the following two-factor model for the returns on three assets A, B and C:
Asset A B C
ai 0.03 0.05 0.1
bi,1 1 3 1.5
bi,2 4 2 1.5
(ii) Determine the equation for the expected return on a portfolio which:
(iii) Construct a portfolio of securities A, B, C that has a factor beta of 2 on the first
factor and 1 on the second factor, i.e. the expected return on the portfolio is:
RP aP 2 I1 I 2 cP . [3]
[Total 9]
6 Let pt denote the value at time t (measured in years) of a European put option on a
non-dividend-paying stock with price St . The option matures at time T and has a
strike price K. The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is r.
S1 10% £10
S2 20% £10
(ii) Identify, with reasons, five discrepancies in these option prices. [5]
[Total 9]
CT8 S2016–4
7 Consider a binomial tree model for the stock price St. Let S0 = 50 and let the price
rise by 10% or fall by 5% each month for the next three months. Assume also that the
risk-free rate is 5% per annum continuously compounded.
(i) State the conditions under which the market is arbitrage free. [2]
(ii) Calculate the price at time t = 0 of a European call option on this stock, which
expires in three months and is struck at-the-money (i.e. strike price K = 50).
[4]
A special option, called a knock-out barrier option, goes out of existence (i.e. expires
without any payoff or value) if the underlying asset reaches a pre-specified barrier
b > 0 either from above (down-and-out) or from below (up-and-out).
max( ST K , 0) if min St b,
0t T
0 otherwise.
Assume this special option is written on the given stock, has the same strike price and
maturity as the European call option described in part (ii) and the barrier b is fixed
at 48.
(iii) Calculate the price of this contract using the binomial tree model and risk-
neutral valuation. [3]
(iv) Determine the price of the down-and-out contract when b = 40, without
performing any further calculations. [2]
[Total 11]
(i) Write down the formula for the delta of this option under this model. [1]
Suppose that the stock price at time 0 is S0 = $40 and the continuously compounded
risk-free rate is 2% per annum. The call option has strike price $45.91, term to
maturity 5 years and a delta of Δ = 0.6179.
(ii) Determine the implied volatility of the stock to the nearest 1%. [4]
A second stock with price Rt is currently priced at R0 = $30 and has volatility
σR = 15% per annum.
An exotic option pays an amount c at time T if S1/S0 < kS and R1/R0 < kR.
(iii) Give a formula for the value of the option at time 0 if the two stocks are
independent, defining any additional notation used. [2]
(iv) Explain how the structure of the option could be simplified if the assets were
perfectly correlated. [3]
Assume now that the stock prices are independent. The option has term T = 1 year,
payoff c = $50 and strike prices kS = 0.8 and kR = 0.6.
CT8 S2016–6
9 (i) Write down the properties of the following two models for interest rates:
[You are not required to give any formulae for the models.] [4]
The Vasicek term structure model is described by the following stochastic differential
equation:
t
rt r0e at b 1 e at e dWs .
a t s
[4]
0
(iii) Determine the expectation, the variance and the distribution of the short
rate rt . [3]
[Total 11]
(i) Derive an expression for the value of the debt at time 0 using the Merton
model, in terms of the total value of the company and the value of a call
option. [4]
The current total value of the company is £200m. The continuously compounded
risk-free interest rate is 1% per annum.
The current arbitrage-free prices of options on the company’s shares, with maturity in
five years’ time and a strike price of £100, are as follows:
(ii) Calculate, using put-call parity, the value of the zero-coupon bonds per £100
nominal. [3]
The volatility of the total value of the company is 17% per annum.
(iii) Determine the approximate change in the share price and the bond price that
would arise from a £1m increase in the total value of the company.
[Hint: consider the delta of an appropriate option.] [4]
(iv) Comment on the relative change in the share and bond prices in part (iii). [2]
(v) Comment, without carrying out any calculations, on how the relative change
in part (iii) would differ if the total value of the company was lower. [1]
[Total 14]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2016–8
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2016
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping candidates, both
those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers as a revision aid and
also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The Examiners have
access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and will generally base
questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core Reading specifically or
exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in this
report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions, particularly the
open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points than the Examiners
will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances may
have changed if using these reports for revision.
Luke Hatter
Chair of the Board of Examiners
December 2016
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to construct
asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are also required to
communicate with other financial professionals and to critically evaluate modern financial
theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to those
shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate. Marks for the
methodology are also awarded.
1. Students performed relatively well on bookwork questions, although many missed the
opportunity to be awarded full marks due to relatively superficial knowledge.
2. The majority of the students seemed to struggle on the applications part of the questions,
because they were not able to use and combine the information given to them in the
question. In a few instances this resulted in students re-calculating given data from basic
principles and therefore running out of time. Further, there is often a lack of knowledge of
how to use the distribution tables to compute probabilities (in the specific case of this
exam paper, the normal distribution), and relative inaccuracy in getting the details right.
C. Pass Mark
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Solutions
μ
−∞ (μ − x)
2
(ii) f ( x)dx where μ is the mean return at the end of the chosen
period.
μ
−∞ ( x − μ)
2
[Or equivalently f ( x)dx ] [1]
(iii) For:
Most investors do not dislike uncertainty of returns as such; rather they dislike
the possibility of low returns. One measure that seeks to quantify this view is
downside semi-variance. [1]
Against:
Alternatively, directly from the Formulae & Tables: P(X ≤ 4) = 0.09963 [1]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
A common mistake was to calculate the VaR and Expected Shortfall using the
distribution function rather than the probability mass functions, i.e. P(X ≤ x)
rather than P(X = x).
Q2 (i) Investors select their portfolios on the basis of the expected return and the
variance of that return over a single time horizon. [1]
The expected returns, variance of returns and covariance of returns are known
for all assets and pairs of assets. [1]
Investors are never satiated. At a given level of risk, they will always prefer a
portfolio with a higher return to one with a lower return. [1]
Investors dislike risk. For a given level of return they will always prefer a
portfolio with lower variance to one with higher variance. [1]
E(Si)=Ei
V(Si)=Vi
and CAB is the covariance between the returns of Asset A and Asset B.
VB − C AB
xA = .
VA − 2C AB + VB
[1]
= 0.4EA . [½]
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
and xB = 2. [½]
= –0.5EA . [½]
[Max 4]
(iii) (a) The variance of the return on the portfolio in (b) is:
= 0. [½]
In part (i) the majority of students stated all the assumptions of MVPT but
marks were only available for the main assumptions (as asked for in the
question).
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Q3 (i) The market portfolio is the weighted portfolio of the risky securities in the
market, [½]
consequently ErM = 18% = w1Er1 + w2 Er2 . [½]
Eri − r f
βi = [1]
ErM − r f
A straightforward question and many students scored full marks. Part (i) was
well answered by all students but most students didn’t define the market
portfolio when deriving its composition.
(ii) The results follow from the fact that the factor beta of a portfolio on a given
factor is the portfolio-weighted average of the individual securities’ betas on
that factor. This also applies to the constant and the random part. [1]
Working as follows:
Asset A B C
Weights
P1 0.33 0.33 0.33
P2 –0.5 1.5 0
P1 P2
aP 0.06 0.06
bP,1 1.83 4
bP,2 –0.17 5
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Hence:
(iii) The required portfolio has weights such that the portfolio-weighted averages
of the betas equal to the target beta. Hence, we need to solve the linear
system:
xA
1 3 1.5 2
−4 2 1.5 xB = 1 [1½]
x
C
Part (i) was well answered by almost all students. Part (ii) was also answered
well, but some students wrote the expected return on the portfolio in terms of
the return on the indices rather than the expected values of the indices.
Most students correctly derived the equations to solve in part (iii) with the
majority also solving the equations correctly.
Q5 (i)
• Market crashes appear more often than one would expect from a normal
distribution. (The real world distribution has “fat tails”.) [½]
• Days with no change, or very small change, also happen more often than
the normal distribution suggests. (The real world distribution is “more
peaked”.) [½]
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
• It can be argued that expected returns on shares are likely to vary with
bond yields, which contradicts the assumption of a constant mean. [½]
(ii)
• A cross-sectional property fixes a time horizon and looks at the
distribution over all the simulations. [1]
• For example, we might consider the distribution of inflation next year. [½]
• For example, we might consider one simulation and fit a distribution to the
sampled rates of inflation projected for the next 1,000 years. [½]
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
pt + St ≥ Ke−r(T−t) . [1]
So pt ≥ Ke−r(T−t) − St . [1]
(ii)
• (b) should be greater than (a) because the underlying asset is more volatile.
[1]
• (c) should be £0.26 by put/call parity (assuming that (a) is correct). [1]
[Alternatively, (a) should be £3.79 if (c) is correct, or both could be
incorrect.]
• (d) should be higher than (c) because the strike price is higher. [1]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
• (e) should be higher than (d) because an American option is always worth
at least as much as a European option. [1]
[Total 9]
Part (i) was largely well answered, though common mistakes included using
incorrect portfolios or trivial arguments that did not really constitute a proof.
Part (ii) was well answered by the majority of students, though few identified
all five differences. Some students calculated theoretical prices using the
Black-Scholes formula, but this was time-consuming and not necessary to
identify the discrepancies. Many students failed to check the lower bound for
the put option despite having proved it in part (i).
Q7 (i) The market is arbitrage free if and only if there exists a probability measure
under which discounted asset prices are martingales. [1]
In this case, the probability exists if and only if d < erΔt < u. [1]
Using the figures in the question, 0.95 < e0.25 × 0.05 < 1.1 [1]
er − d
Alternatively we need 0 < q < 1 where q = [1]
u−d
[Max 2]
(ii)
Stock price tree
Time 0 1 2 3
50.00 55.00 60.50 66.55
47.50 52.25 57.48
45.13 49.64
42.87
[1 mark for the final prices; the bottom one is not necessary]
The price C0 of the option is computed via risk-neutral valuation; let p̂ denote
the risk-neutral probability of an up movement, then:
and
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
CALL
Time 0 1 2 3
2.62 5.56 10.71 16.55
0.97 2.69 7.48
0.00 0.00
0.00
(iii) The only relevant trajectories, given the barrier set at 48, are the up-up-up, up-
up-down and up-down-up (i.e. the ones leading to a state in which the call
option is in the money). [1]
Workings as follows:
K 50.0000
Split the stock tree DOC barrier b 48.0000
0 1 2 3 PATH min Payoff Probs Exp.
Value
50.0000 55.0000 60.5000 66.5500 uuu 55.0000 16.5500 0.0471 0.7797
50.0000 55.0000 60.5000 57.4750 uud 55.0000 7.4750 0.0833 0.6229
50.0000 55.0000 52.2500 57.4750 udu 52.2500 7.4750 0.0833 0.6229
50.0000 55.0000 52.2500 49.6375 udd 49.6375 0.0000 0.1474 0.0000
50.0000 47.5000 52.2500 57.4750 duu 47.5000 0.0000 0.0833 0.0000
50.0000 47.5000 52.2500 49.6375 dud 47.5000 0.0000 0.1474 0.0000
50.0000 47.5000 45.1250 49.6375 ddu 45.1250 0.0000 0.1474 0.0000
50.0000 47.5000 45.1250 42.8688 ddd 42.8688 0.0000 0.2607 0.0000
D0 2.0003
Therefore option value = value of standard call option from part (ii) – the
value of the payoff under the duu path [1]
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) If the barrier is at 40, the barrier option is equivalent to the vanilla call option
in part (ii), so the price is 2.62 [1]
as it is never knocked-out. [1]
[Total 11]
This was well-answered with the majority of students scoring full marks.
Some students simply defined arbitrage in part (i) rather than stating the
conditions for the market to be arbitrage free.
Rejecting the negative root gives σ = 32% (or may quote variance = 10%) [½]
(iii) Under the risk-neutral probability measure Q, the fair price of the option is
ce–rT Q(S1/S0 < kS) Q(R1/R0 < kR) [2]
(iv) Under the Black-Scholes model , if the stocks are perfectly correlated then
S1/S0 = R1/R0. [1]
So if kS < kR then the option only depends on stock S and has value
ce–rT Q(S1/S0 < kS) [1]
Similarly if kS > kR then the option only depends on stock R and has value
ce–r TQ(R1/R0 < kR) [½]
If kS = kR then the option can be defined in terms of the price of either stock as
ce–rT Q(S1/S0 < kS) = ce–rT Q(R1/R0 < kS) [½]
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
So overall the option can be defined in terms of the lower of kS and kR , and
either of the stock increases, i.e. has value
ce–rT Q(R1/R0 < min(kS,kR)) = ce–rT Q(S1/S0 < min(kS,kR)) [1]
[Max 3]
= 50e–0.02 Q(S1 < 0.8 × 40) Q(R1 < 0.6 × 30) [1]
Most students scored full marks in parts (i) and (ii). A number of students
used trial and error to find the volatility instead of simply solving the quadratic
equation.
Students struggled with parts (iv) and (v) with many only scoring low marks.
Most students calculated part (v) using the distribution of the share price
rather than Φ(d2) as an alternative solution. The best students showed their
workings so that some marks could be awarded even if the final answer was
not correct.
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
dX d2X dX
= eat , 2 = 0, = aeat rt . [1]
dr dr dt
And hence:
dX t = deat rt = abeat dt + σeat dWt . [½]
t
at
( at
)
e rt = r0 + b e − 1 + σ e as dWs [1]
0
t
and hence, as required, rt = r0e − at
(
+ b 1− e − at
) + σe − a( t − s )
dWs . [½]
0
[Max 4]
Page 14
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
(iii) From Result 3.2 of the Core Reading, rt follows a Normal distribution [1]
with mean:
(
Ert = r0 e − at + b 1 − e − at ) [1]
and variance
t
2
= E σ e ( ) dWs
2 − −
Var ( rt ) = E ( rt − Ert )
a t s
[1]
0
t
−2 a( t − s )
= σ 2 e ds [1]
0
σ2
=
2a
(
1 − e −2 at . ) [½]
[Max 3]
[Total 11]
Q10 (i) Under the Merton model the value at redemption is min(F(T), £100m), where
F(t) is the gross value of the company at time t. [1]
where C is a call option on the total value of the company with strike £100m
and time to maturity five years. [1]
[Max 4]
Page 15
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Alternatively:
At time T, if:
• F(T) ≥ L, the shareholders will repay the debt and E(T) = F(T) – L [½]
• F(T) < L, the shareholders will default and E(T) = 0 [½]
i.e. the shares are equivalent to a European call option on the assets of the
company with maturity T and a strike price equal to the par value of the debt,
L, and a current price of C. [1]
where C is a call option with a term of five years and a strike price of £100m.
[1]
[Max 4]
(ii) Put-call parity gives a share price of £105.37 (= 27.55 + 100e–0.05 – 17.3) [1]
hence the total value of all shares in issue is £105.37m. [½]
(iii) The sensitivity of the share price to a change in the company’s gross value is
dSt/dVt . [1]
From the Black-Scholes formula and the volatility above we find that
d1 = 2.145 [1]
so delta = Φ(d1) = 0.984, [1]
so a £1m increase in asset value will give a £0.984m increase in the total share
value [½]
and a £0.016m increase in total bond value. [1]
This is an increase of £0.984 in the share price and an increase of £0.016 in the
bond price per £100 nominal. [½]
[Max 4]
(iv) The current value of the company is well in excess of the nominal value of the
bonds… [½]
Page 16
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2016 – Examiners’ Report
… and the share price moves almost in line with the value of the company.
[½]
(v) If the company value was lower then the value received by the bondholders at
maturity would be more likely to fall short of the nominal amount. [½]
So any change in company value would impact the bond price more (and
hence impact the share price less). [½]
[Total 14]
Part (i) was standard bookwork with most students scoring well.
Students struggled with parts (ii) and (iii), but many picked up some marks by
showing all their working.
Page 17
1
2 INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
3
4
5
6
7 EXAMINATION
8
9
19 April 2016 (am)
10
11
Subject CT8 – Financial Economics
12
Core Technical
13
14 Time allowed: Three hours
15
INSTRUCTIONS TO THE CANDIDATE
16
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
17 booklet.
18
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
19 supervisor.
20
3. Mark allocations are shown in brackets.
21
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
22
23 5. Candidates should show calculations where this is appropriate.
24
Graph paper is NOT required for this paper.
25
26
AT THE END OF THE EXAMINATION
27
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
28 question paper.
29
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
30 and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
31
32
33
34
CT8 A2016 Institute and Faculty of Actuaries
35
1 An investor measures the utility of her wealth using the utility function U(w) = ln(w)
for w > 0.
(i) Derive the absolute and relative risk aversions for this investor’s utility
function, and the first derivative of each. [4]
(ii) Comment on what this tells us about the proportion of her assets that this
investor will invest in risky assets. [2]
The investor has £100 available to invest in two possible assets, Asset A and Asset B.
The future value of Asset A depends on an uncertain future event.
Every £1 invested in Asset A will be worth £1.30 with probability 0.75 and £0.40
with probability 0.25.
The investor does not discount future asset values when making investment decisions.
She decides to invest a proportion a of her wealth in Asset A and the remaining
proportion 1 – a in Asset B.
(iv) Determine the amount that she should invest in each of Asset A and B to
maximise her expected utility, using your result from part (iii). [5]
[Total 13]
2 Consider an asset whose return follows the probability density function f(x).
(i) Write down a formula for the variance of the return on the asset, defining any
additional notation you use. [1]
(ii) Write down a formula for the shortfall probability for the return on the asset
below a level L. [1]
The returns on an asset follow a Normal distribution with mean µ = 6% per annum
and variance σ2 = 23% per annum. An investor buys €500 of the asset.
(iii) Determine the shortfall probability for the value of the asset in one year’s time
below a value of €480. [2]
(iv) Explain what can be deduced about an investor’s utility function if the investor
makes decisions based on:
CT8 A2016–2
3 Consider a market with N securities. Let xi denote the weight of security i in a
portfolio, Vi the variance of the return on security i and Cij the covariance between the
returns on security i and security j.
(i) Write down an expression for V, the variance of the return on the portfolio. [1]
(iii) Show that investors can diversify away specific risk by investing equal
amounts in an increasing number of independent securities. [3]
(iv) Show that the result in part (iii) still holds true when the securities are
correlated. [3]
[Total 12]
4 In a market where the assumptions of the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) hold,
there are a risk-free asset and two risky assets with the following attributes:
5 (i) Define the three forms of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. [3]
(ii) State two reasons why it is hard to test whether any of the three forms hold in
practice. [2]
[Total 5]
Consider a stock paying a continuous dividend at a rate δ and denote its price at any
time t by St.
Let Ct and Pt be the price at time t of a European call option and European put option
respectively, written on the stock S, each with strike price K and maturity T ≥ t.
(i) Show that the fair price at t = 0 of a forward contract on the share maturing at
time T is K = S0erT. [5]
(ii) Calculate the fair price at t = 0 of a forward contract written on the share with
delivery at t = 2. [1]
(iii) Give an expression for the value to the investor of the forward contract in part
(ii) at time t 2, in terms of St , t and r. [2]
An investor enters into the above forward contract at time t = 0. At time t = 1 the
risk-free rate of interest has increased to 4% per annum. The share price has not
changed.
(iv) Calculate the value to the investor of the forward contract at t = 1. [1]
(v) Determine each of the following Greeks for the contract value at time t = 1:
delta
theta
vega
[3]
[Total 12]
CT8 A2016–4
8 Consider a three-period binomial tree model for the stock price process St.
Let S0 = 100 and let the price rise by 10% or fall by 5% at each time step.
Assume also that the risk-free rate is 4% per time period, continuously compounded.
(i) (a) State the conditions under which the market is arbitrage free.
(ii) Calculate the price of a European call option on this stock, with maturity at the
end of the third period and a strike price of 103. [4]
A special option, called a European “Paylater” call option, has the following payoff at
maturity T:
( ST K c) if ST K
and zero otherwise. K is the strike price and c is the premium paid for the option.
The premium is paid at maturity, and is only paid if the option expires in-the-money.
Further, the option premium is set such that the value of the option at time t = 0 is
zero.
Consider a three-state credit model for a company in discrete time. The states are
Healthy (H), Unhealthy (U) or Defaulted (D). Transition probabilities from state i to
state j, pij, are constant:
pHU = 0.1
pUH = 0.05
pHD = 0.02
pUD = 0.3
pDj = 0 for all j ≠ D
Denote the probability that the company is in state i at time t (years) as pi(t).
(ii) Calculate pD(2), i.e. the probability that the company is in the Default state at
time 2. [2]
The company issues a zero-coupon bond at time 0, with maturity at time 2 and
nominal value £100. The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 4%
per annum.
Assume that the bond returns its nominal value at time 2 if the company is not in
default, or x% of its nominal value at time 2 if the company is in default.
(iii) Calculate the value of x, the assumed percentage recovery on default. [2]
(v) Comment on the impact on the current price of the bond if it returned x% of its
nominal value at the time of default rather than at time 2. [1]
[Total 10]
CT8 A2016–6
10 In the Vasicek model, the short rate of interest under the risk-neutral probability
measure is given by:
t
rt e kt (r0 ) e k (t u ) dWu
0
t
Rt rs ds
0
(i) Show that Rt has a Normal distribution with mean and variance given by:
1 e kt
E ( Rt ) t (r0 ) and
k
2 2(1 e kt ) 1 e 2 kt
Var(Rt ) t . [6]
k 2 k 2k
Let P(0,t) be the price at time 0 of a zero-coupon bond with redemption date t > 0.
Var Rt
E Rt
P (0, t ) e 2 . [3]
(iii) Show, by using the results from parts (i) and (ii), that:
B(t ) r0
P(0, t ) A(t )e
1 e kt
where B(t )
k
2 2
and A(t ) exp ( B (t ) t ) 2 B (t ) 2 . [4]
2k 4k
(iv) State the main drawback of the above model for the term structure of interest
rates. [1]
[Total 14]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2016–7
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2016 (with mark allocations)
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping candidates, both
those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers as a revision aid and
also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The Examiners have
access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and will generally base
questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core Reading specifically or
exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in this
report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions, particularly the
open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points than the Examiners
will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances may
have changed if using these reports for revision.
F Layton
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2016
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to construct
asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are also required to
communicate with other financial professionals and to critically evaluate modern financial
theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to those
shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate. Marks for the
methodology are also awarded.
1. Students performed relatively well on bookwork questions, although many missed the
opportunity to be awarded full marks for these due to relatively superficial knowledge.
2. The majority of the students though seemed to struggle on the applications part of the
questions, through not being able to put together the pieces of information given and use
them. In a few instances this resulted in students re-calculating given data from basic
principles and therefore running out of time. Further, there is often a lack of knowledge of
how to use the distribution tables to compute probabilities (in the specific case of this
exam paper, the normal distribution), and relative sloppiness in getting the details right.
C. Pass Mark
Solutions
= 1/w [½]
=1 [½]
R’(w) = 0 [½]
[Total 4]
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) R’(w) =0 thus the log utility function exhibits constant relative risk aversion.
[1]
or:
This must be negative because of the square terms, hence this is a local
maximum. [1]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Early parts of this question were largely completed well, though some
students used the incorrect formulae despite them appearing in the tables
(sign problems mainly). The majority of the students were able to correctly
identify the nature of the utility function in terms of index of relative risk
aversion but failed to comment about the proportion of the assets that the
investor will invest in risky assets. The majority of students also failed to
express the expected utility of wealth, and calculated the utility of expected
wealth instead.
∞
−∞ (μ − x)
2
f ( x)dx ,
where μ is the mean return at the end of the chosen period. [1]
L
(ii) Shortfall probability = f ( x)dx . [1]
−∞
(iii) The shortfall probability required is the probability that the return is lower
than 480/500 – 1 = –4% i.e. P(N(6%, 23%) ≤ 4%) [1]
= P(Z≤ (–4% – 6%)/√(23%)) [½]
= P(Z ≤ –0.20851) [½]
= 0.417 [1]
[Max 2]
(iv) (a) This may imply that the investor has a quadratic utility function. [1]
Well prepared students scored well on the bookwork parts of this question,
although some students failed to define in full the notation used in part (i).
Many students had problems in calculating the shortfall probability using the
distribution of the normal random variable, and in recognising that the
corresponding utility function has a discontinuity.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Σi xi = 1 [1]
and expectation of return E = EP, say, in order to plot the minimum variance
curve. [1]
To find the minimum we set the partial derivatives of W with respect to all the
xi and λ and μ equal to zero. [1]
In this space, with expected return on the vertical axis, the efficient frontier is
the part of the curve lying above the point of the global minimum of standard
deviation. [1]
Any portfolio on this efficient frontier is an efficient portfolio. [1]
[Max 5]
(iii) Where all assets are independent, the covariance between them is zero and the
formula for variance becomes:
V = Σi xi2 Vi . [1]
If we assume that equal amounts are invested in each asset, then with N assets
the proportion invested in each is 1/N. Thus:
V = Σi (1/N)2 Vi [1]
= 1/N[Σi Vi/N] = 1/N [1]
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
As N gets larger and larger, the variance of the portfolio approaches zero. [1]
[Max 3]
(iv) With equal investment, the proportion invested in any one asset xi is 1/N and
the formula for the variance of the portfolio becomes:
Factoring out 1/N from the first summation and (N − 1)/N from the second
yields:
This shows that the individual risk of securities can be diversified away. [1]
Early parts of this question were largely completed well. The majority of the
students proceeded without problems although a few provided answers only
for the general case of dependent assets. Some students answered parts (iii)
and (iv) using the single index model despite the question being clear that
mean-variance portfolio theory was being examined.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Consequently:
3
ErM = wi Eri = 16.97% [1]
i =2
3
2
= E wi ri − ( ErM ) = 3.57% .
2
std. dev ( rM ) = σ M [2]
i = 2
( )
The market price of risk is given by ErM − r f / σ M [1]
(iii) ( )(
From the Security Market Line it follows that βi = Eri − r f / ErM − r f . [1])
Hence β2 = 1.40 and β3 = 0.83 . [1 mark each]
[Max 2]
Many students answered all parts of this question correctly. A few either
made calculation mistakes, or did not cover a wide enough range of
limitations of the CAPM. Some students confused calculating the market
price of risk with the risk premium.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Q5 (i) The three forms are: Strong – market prices reflect all current information
relevant to the stock, including information which is not public. [1]
Weak – market prices reflect all information available in the past history of the
stock price. [1]
[Total 3]
(ii) Tests need to make assumptions (which may be invalid) such as normality of
returns or stationarity. [1]
Transaction costs may prevent the exploitation of anomalies, so that the EMH
might hold net of transaction costs. [1]
Allowance for risk: the EMH does not preclude higher returns as a reward for
risk; however the EMH does not tell us how to price such risks. [1]
The assumptions made about how security prices should react to new
information may be invalid. [1]
[Max 2]
[TOTAL 5]
• Portfolio A: holding the call (long position) and a sold put (short position)
at time t. [1]
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Q7 (i) Let K be the forward price. Now compare the setting up of the following
portfolios at time 0:
In particular, at time 0 both portfolios must have value zero (since the value of
a forward contract at t = 0 is zero). [1]
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
Early parts of this question were answered well. The majority of the students
though confused the forward price (i.e. the delivery price) with the value to the
investor of the forward contract in part (iii), and consequently struggled with
the remaining parts, even if the large majority knew the definition of each
Greek.
Q8 (i) (a) The market is arbitrage free if and only if there exists a probability
measure under which discounted asset prices are martingales. [1]
In this case, the probability exists if and only if d < er Δt < u. [1]
(b) d = 0.95 < e 0.04 < 1.1 = u hence the condition is verified. [1]
[Max 2]
(ii)
Stock tree
Time 0 1 2 3
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
and
3
3
( )
+
C0 = e − rT pˆ k (1 − pˆ )
3− k
S0u k d 3− k − K
k
k =0
( )
= e− rT pˆ 3 × 30.10 + 3 pˆ 2 (1 − pˆ ) ×11.95 = 10.52. [4]
[Max 4]
CALL
Time 0 1 2 3
(iii) As the premium is set so that the option price is zero, by risk-neutral valuation
it follows that:
C0
c = erT [2]
ˆ
P( ST > K )
C0
= e rT [2]
pˆ + 3 pˆ 2 (1 − pˆ )
3
= 18.09 [1]
[Max 3]
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
= 18.09 [1]
[Max 3]
[TOTAL 9]
Q9 (i)
λ2j(t) j
2 λj2(t)
λj,n-1(t)
λn-1,j(t)
λ12(t)
λ21(t)
1 n-1
λ2n(t)
λ1n(t) λn-1,n(t)
λij(t) are the deterministic transition intensities from state i to state j at time t
under the real world measure P. [1]
[Max 4]
[1½ marks for diagram applied to specific example – 3 states model]
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
(v) The impact on cashflows would be that the bond might return the x% of its
nominal value earlier than time 2, so the value of the bond would increase.
[Total 1]
[TOTAL 10]
Generally, students answered this question correctly, although in the first part
quite a few considered only the particular case of the three states given in the
rest of the question (but which had not yet been introduced for part (i)). A few
students used the Merton formula for default to solve part (iii) of the question,
which was not appropriate for this model.
Rt = θ t . [1]
+ ( r −θ )
(1 − e ) − kt
[2]
0
k
t
+
σ
k
0
(
1 − e ( ) dWs
−k t −s
) [3]
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
− t r ds
s
P ( 0, t ) = E e 0 [2]
= E e− Rt ( ) [1]
Var( Rt )
− E ( Rt )+
=e 2 . [2]
Equivalently, use the results regarding the mean of the lognormal random
variable as per the Formulae & Tables.
[Max 3]
σ2 1 − e− kt 1 − e −2 kt
Var ( Rt ) = t − B ( t ) − + [2]
k 2 k 2k
σ2 σ 2 1 − e − kt 1 − e −2 kt
= − 2 ( B (t ) − t ) + −2 +
k 2k k2 k2
σ2 σ 2
2 ( ( )
B t −t) −
2
=− B (t ) .
k 2k
Page 14
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2016 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) The main drawback of the Vasicek model is that the short rate can take
negative values with positive probability. [1]
[TOTAL 14]
There was a wide range of quality of answers for this question. Generally,
students answered correctly the first and last parts of this question. Many
students managed to get through a few steps for part (ii), though often with
algebra issues; whilst in part (iii) there were relatively few comprehensive
attempts.
Page 15
1
2 INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
3
4
5
6
7 EXAMINATION
8
9
7 October 2015 (am)
10
24
Graph paper is NOT required for this paper.
25
26
AT THE END OF THE EXAMINATION
27
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
28 question paper.
29
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
30 and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
31
32
33
34
35 CT8 S2015 © Institute and Faculty of Actuaries
1 Describe the definitions, assumptions and key results of consumer choice theory. [8]
(i) Write down the absolute and relative risk aversion for this utility function. [2]
The investor currently has wealth of £100, and using her utility function
U(100) = 610.
The investor is offered a gamble with a profit of £20 with probability p, and a loss of
£20 with probability (1 p). She will accept this gamble only if p ≥ 0.55.
(ii) Explain what this implies about the investor’s risk aversion. [1]
The investor accepts the gamble and wins. She now has wealth of £120.
The investor is offered the same gamble again, with a profit of £20 with probability p,
and a loss of £20 with probability (1 p). Based on her new wealth, she will now
accept this gamble only if p ≥ 0.5625.
(iv) Determine the maximum wealth for which the function U(w) satisfies the
requirement of non-satiation. [2]
[Total 9]
(ii) State the assumptions required for the existence of efficient portfolios. [2]
Suppose an investor invests his wealth in N securities, i = 1, ..., N, with xi denoting the
proportion of wealth invested in security i.
(iii) Write down a formula for the expected return on this portfolio. [1]
(iv) Write down a formula for the variance of the return on this portfolio. [1]
(v) Derive the proportion xA that should be invested in security A to minimise the
portfolio variance. [4]
[Total 9]
CT8 S2015–2
4 (i) Describe the Arbitrage Pricing Theory (APT) using a two-index model for
illustration. [5]
A two-index APT model has been built, using a market (traded) index, IM, and a
currency index, IC . The model for expected returns is:
where:
λM and λC are the expected returns on the market and currency indices
respectively.
bi,M and bi,C are the sensitivities of the returns of security i with respect to the
market and currency indices respectively.
Suppose that a traded security has return R and the market has the following
characteristics:
Cov(R,IM) = 0.02.
Var(IM) = 0.04.
Var(IC) = 0.01.
The correlation between IM and IC is Corr(IM,IC) = 0.4.
The expected return on the security is ER = 0.09.
λM = 0.07 and λC = 0.02.
where:
(ii) Calculate the amount, A, that the actuary will need to invest in the shares to
give a 40% probability of having savings of at least €20,000 in five years’
time. [3]
(i) Show that the fair price of a forward contract on the share maturing at time T
is K = S0erT. [4]
(ii) Calculate the fair price at t = 0 of a forward contract written on the share with
delivery at t = 4. [1]
An investor enters into the above forward contract at time t = 0. At time t = 1 the
share price has increased to £6.
(iii) Calculate the value to the investor of the forward contract at t = 1. [2]
[Total 7]
CT8 S2015–4
7 A non-dividend paying share currently trades at S0 = $10. An investor is considering
buying a European call option on the share with a strike price of $12 and expiry in
five years. The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 4% p.a.
(i) Determine lower and upper bounds for the price of the call option at time 0.
[2]
The call option is currently priced at $1.50. The assumptions of the Black-Scholes
model apply.
(iii) Determine the corresponding hedging portfolio in shares and cash for 100 call
options. [2]
[Total 8]
(i) Prove that Y is a U(0,1) random variable i.e. P(Y < y) = y for 0 ≤ y ≤ 1. [2]
Suppose that St is the price at time t (in years) of a share in a Black-Scholes market
with S0 = £1.11, the continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest r = 2% p.a.
and the volatility σ = 22% p.a.
(ii) Determine the values of a and b such that Φ((ln S2 − a)/b) is a U(0,1) random
variable under the risk-neutral measure, where Φ is the cumulative
distribution function of the standard normal distribution. [3]
Suppose that another derivative security pays the amount D2 at time t = 2, but only if
D2 is at least £25.
(iv) Determine the fair price of this derivative. [3]
[Total 11]
Assume that the share price will not change on issue and that the assumptions of the
Black-Scholes model apply.
(ii) Write down the relationship between the current equity value of the company
and FT, the final gross value of the company’s assets. [1]
(iii) Estimate F0+, the gross value of the company’s assets just after the bond issue,
using the Black-Scholes formula and interpolation. [7]
where:
• t is time.
• B(s,t) is the price of a zero coupon bond at time s maturing at time t with a
nominal value of £100.
(i) Calculate the values of (a), (b), (c) and (d) in the table above. [4]
CT8 S2015–6
At time 0 an investor buys £1,000 nominal of zero coupon bonds maturing at time 2,
and £2,000 nominal of zero coupon bonds maturing at time 4. At time 1 interest rate
expectations have changed as set out below.
t F(t 1,t)
1 -
2 5%
3 4%
4 6%
(ii) Calculate the loss the investor will make if she sells the bonds at time 1. [3]
The investor decides to keep the bonds rather than selling them at time 1.
(iii) Comment on whether the investor can restructure her portfolio to recover her
loss if interest rates remain unchanged. [2]
[Total 9]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2015–7
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2015
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping candidates, both
those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers as a revision aid and
also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The Examiners have
access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and will generally base
questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core Reading specifically or
exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in this
report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions, particularly the
open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points than the Examiners
will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances may
have changed if using these reports for revision.
F Layton
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2015
1. The aim of the Financial Economics subject is to develop the necessary skills to construct
asset liability models and to value financial derivatives. These skills are also required to
communicate with other financial professionals and to critically evaluate modern financial
theories.
2. The marking approach for CT8 is flexible in the sense that different answers to those
shown in the solution can earn marks if they are relevant and appropriate. Marks for the
methodology are also awarded.
The general performance was good. Candidates found some questions challenging, but well-
prepared candidates scored consistently across the whole paper. As in previous diets,
questions that required an element of application of the core reading to situations that were
not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates. A significant number of
candidates failed to read some questions carefully enough to identify the relevant section of
the course being examined.
C. Comparative pass rates for the past 3 years for this diet of examination
Year %
September 2015 50
April 2015 60
September 2014 56
April 2014 55
September 2013 51
April 2013 51
Reasons for any significant change in pass rates in current diet to those in the
past:
The pass rates are comparable with standard pass rates for CT8, even if slightly lower than
recent diets. The paper was standard but candidates struggled with some questions.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
Solutions
1.1.1 Definitions
“Utility” is the satisfaction that a consumer obtains from a particular course of action.
The amount of one good that a consumer is prepared to swap for one extra unit of
another good is known as the “marginal rate of substitution”.
An “indifference curve” joins all the consumption bundles of equal utility. The slope
of a consumer’s indifference curves will depend on his or her individual preferences
and is equal to the marginal rate of substitution.
A given combination of goods (e.g. two apples and five bananas) is called a
“consumption bundle”.
A consumer can rank different bundles, and therefore can pick a set of
consumption bundles that give the same utility.
This means that if it takes, say, n extra apples to persuade a consumer to give
up one banana, it will take more than another n extra apples to persuade her to
give up yet another banana. Indifference curves are “convex to the origin”.
These two assumptions determine which consumption bundles are affordable. The
budget line joins all points that a consumer can afford, assuming that all income is
spent.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
1.4 Implications
Combining the budget line with indifference curves, we can determine the
consumption bundle which a consumer will choose. A rational consumer will choose
a consumption bundle such that the marginal rate of substitution is equal to the slope
of the budget line – that is, where the ratios of marginal utilities equal the ratios of
prices.
(ii) For a gamble with an equal size gain or loss, the requirement that p ≥ 0.55
implies that the investor is risk averse. (Alternatively, they have increasing
absolute and relative risk aversion.)
(iii) With w =100, the (certain) utility if the gamble is rejected is:
whereas the expected utility if the gamble is accepted with p = 0.55 is:
whereas the expected utility if the gamble is accepted with p = 0.5625 is:
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
a = (17,080 – 25 * U(120)) / 3
b = (U(120) – 610) / 9
c = (U(120) – 610) / 3,600
Early parts of this question were largely completed well, though some
students used the incorrect formulae despite them appearing in the
tables. Many students identified the simultaneous equations to solve, but only
the best students proceeded to solve them.
Q3 (i) A portfolio is efficient if the investor cannot find a better one in the sense that
it has a higher expected return with the same variance, or a lower variance
with the same expected return.
Mean return, variance (or standard deviation) and co-variances are known for
all assets.
(iv) V xi x j Cij where Cij is the covariance of the returns on securities i and j
i j
and we write Cii = Vi.
V xA2VA (1 xA )2VB 2 xA (1 xA )C AB
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
dV
2 x AVA 2(VB x AVB ) 2(1 2 x A )C AB
dx A
VB C AB
xA
V A VB 2C AB
d 2V
2VA 2VB 4C AB 0
dx A2
Generally well answered, though not all students stated the requirements for
an efficient portfolio in both directions.
Q4 (i) Arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is an equilibrium market model that does not
rely on the strong assumptions of the capital asset pricing model (CAPM).
APT requires that the returns on any stock be linearly related to a set of factor
indices as shown below
where Ri is the return on security i, ai and ci are the constant and random parts
respectively of the component of return unique to security i, I1 ... IL are the
returns on a set of L indices,
We have
E[ci] = 0,
E[cicj] = 0 for all i, j where i ≠ j,
and Cov(ci,I) = 0 for all stocks and indices.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
This is exactly the same as the multi-index model for returns on individual
securities. The contribution of APT is to describe how we can go from a
multi-index model for individual security returns to a equilibrium market
model. Non-mathematically, the argument can be made as follows. Consider a
two index model. The return on the ith security is given by
Ri = ai + bi,1 I1 + bi,2 I2 + ci .
For investors who hold well-diversified portfolios the specific risk of each
security, represented by ci can be diversified away so an investor need only be
concerned with expected return, bi,1 and bi,2 in choosing his portfolio.
Now, consider what would happen if another portfolio Q existed, with exactly
the same values of b1 and b2 but a higher expected return. Both portfolios
would have the same degree of systematic risk but Q would have a higher
expected return than P. Rational investors would therefore sell P and buy Q,
and this would continue until the forces of supply and demand had brought
portfolio Q onto the same plane as portfolios 1, 2 and 3.
(ii) Since IM is a traded index it must satisfy the formula (**). But the portfolio
consisting of just the index has bM,M = 1 and bM,C = 0
and has expected return λM
so we must have λ0 = 0.
So,
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) Cov(R, IC) = bi,M Cov(IM,IC) + bi,C Var(IC) = 0.8235 * -0.008 + 1.6176 * 0.01
= 0.0096.
Well prepared students scored well here. Many made mistakes in the
calculations or tried to apply formulae for the single-index case to the two-
factor model.
(ii) To find the initial investment we need the 60th percentile of logSt, which is:
So:
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
This question was surprisingly poorly answered. Many students derived the
correct distribution but few calculated the parameter values using the
numbers in the question. Many students struggled to calculate the Value at
Risk correctly.
Q6 (i) Let K be the forward price. Now compare the setting up of the following
portfolios at time 0:
By the principle of no arbitrage these portfolios must have the same value at
all times before T.
In particular, at time 0, portfolio B has value S0 – KerT which must equal the
value of the forward contract.
This can only be zero (the value of the forward contract at t = 0) if K = S0erT.
(iii) Consider at time t = 1 portfolio A = the forward and 5.64e0.09 cash, portfolio
B = one share.
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
Part (i) was a standard proof that was largely well answered. In part (iii) some
students applied the risk-free rate to the share price or simply calculated the
value of a forward contract at time 1 using the £6 share price.
Sample values:
10% $0.97
15% $1.41
20% $1.84
25% $2.27
30% $2.69
35% $3.11
40% $3.51
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
It follows that, using the values for the parameters given, ln(S2) has a
N(0.09596,0.0968) distribution under Q
and so a = 0.09596, b = 0.31113.
Few students managed to score more than a few marks here, and some
didn’t attempt the question or scored zero. Many students managed part (ii).
It assumes that the shareholders are entitled to net assets of the company after
redemption of the loan.
Thus, if Lt is the loan value at time t, Ft is the gross asset value, Et is the equity
value at time t and the loan matures at time T , then LT = min(L,FT), where L is
the nominal amount of loan.
It follows that Et is the value of a call option on the gross assets with strike L
and Ft = Et + Lt.
(ii) We know from (i) that E0 = EQerT(FT L)+, where Q is the equivalent
martingale measure.
(iii) We know E0, L, r, T and σ so we only lack F0, the initial price in the Black-
Scholes formula for a call: E0 = F0Φ(d1) LerTΦ(d2).
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
Q10 (i)
t F(t 1,t) B(0,t) R(0,t) C(t)
0 - - - £100.00
1 2% £98.02 2.0% £102.02
2 4% £94.18 3.0% £106.18
3 3% £91.39 3.0% £109.42
4 5% £86.94 3.5% £115.03
i.e. (a) = 5%
(b) = £98.02
(c) = 3.0%
(d) = £109.42
(ii)
t F(t 1,t) B(0,t)
0 - -
1 - -
2 5% 95.12
3 4% 91.39
4 6% 86.07
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2015 – Examiners’ Report
(iii) Any portfolio consisting only of risk-free assets will return the risk-free rate of
interest if rates remain unchanged.
The investor would therefore need to invest in other risky assets, or assets
linked to another interest rate, in order to recoup her loss.
Well-prepared students scored full marks here, but a surprising number failed
to find all four values in part (i). Some students assumed interest was
compounded annually, which cannot be possible given the values in the table.
Page 13
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your
answer booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
(ii) State the conditions for an investor to be non-satiated and risk neutral in terms
of their utility function, U(w). [2]
(iii) Derive the relative risk aversion function for U(w). [2]
(iv) Describe how the relative risk aversion of U(w) changes with w. [1]
[Total 9]
2 Consider an asset the annual return, X, on which has probability density function f(x).
(ii) Define the expected shortfall of the return on this asset below 2%. [2]
(iv) Discuss the limitations of using Value at Risk to measure the downside risk in
an investment portfolio. [2]
[Total 7]
3 A share is currently priced at 640p. A writer of 100,000 units of a one year European
put option with an exercise price of 630p has delta-hedged the option with a portfolio
which holds cash and is short 24,830 shares. The continuously compounded risk-free
rate of interest is 3% p.a. and no dividends are payable during the life of the option.
(i) (a) Write down an expression for the delta of the option.
(ii) Prove that the volatility of the share implied by the delta is 7.1% p.a.
(assuming it is less than 100%). [5]
(b) Determine the value of the cash holding in the hedging portfolio. [4]
[Total 13]
CT8 A2015–2
4 Suppose that X is an AR(1) process given by the equation:
The process ln(Yt), with Yt the multiplicative increase in a retail price index in year t,
is believed to be an AR(1) process with the same parameters as X above.
(iv) Determine the long-run mean annual increase in the retail price index. [3]
[Total 11]
Let f(t,x) be a function, twice partially differentiable with respect to x, once with
respect to t.
(i) State the stochastic differential equation for f(t, Xt). [2]
(i) State and prove the put-call parity relationship for this share. [5]
1. a European call option maturing in two years, strike price $10.15, option price
$3.87
2. a European put option maturing in two years, strike price $10.15, option price
$0.44
(ii) Calculate the share price implied by the option prices. [2]
(iii) Determine the implied volatility of the share to the nearest 1%. [5]
[Total 12]
7 (i) Define delta, gamma and vega for an individual derivative. [3]
A bank is considering selling a European call option on a share, and wants to hedge
some of its risk. The share is non-dividend paying and has the following properties:
The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 3% p.a. and the vega for
this option is $29.00.
(iii) Identify a delta-hedged replicating portfolio using the share and the risk-free
asset. [2]
Assume that the volatility has instantaneously increased to 27% p.a., with everything
else except the option price remaining the same.
CT8 A2015–4
8 (i) State the main assumptions of mean-variance portfolio theory. [3]
The correlation between the returns on assets 1 and 3 is 0.75. The return on asset 2 is
uncorrelated with the returns on the other two assets.
(ii) Determine the Lagrangian function that can be used to find the minimum
variance portfolio for a given expected return. [3]
Let xi denote the weight of asset i (i = 1, 2, 3) in the minimum variance portfolio with
an expected return of 4%.
(iii) Show, by taking partial derivatives of the Lagrangian function in part (ii), that:
(iv) Comment on how the portfolio would change if short-selling was not allowed.
[1]
[Total 11]
(ii) Describe how the Merton model can be used to estimate the risk-neutral
probability of default. [2]
Let r be the constant continuously compounded risk-free rate and d be the constant
recovery rate for a defaultable zero-coupon bond in a two state model for credit rating
with a deterministic transition intensity.
(iv) Determine the risk-neutral default intensity if the zero-coupon bond price is
given by:
(v) Calculate the fair price of an insurance contract which pays £1,200,000
after two years if the bond defaults in the first year and the continuously
compounded risk-free rate is 2% p.a. [3]
[Total 11]
(i) Write down the formula for the price of a risk-free zero coupon bond at time t,
with bond maturity at time T, under the Vasicek model. [3]
In this market the parameters for the Vasicek model are a = 0.5, µ = 4% and s = 10%.
The short-rate at time 0, r(0), is 2% p.a. Bond X matures at time 1, and Bond Y
matures at time 3. Both bonds are for a nominal value of $100.
(iii) Derive the market-implied risk-free spot rate of interest with maturity 3 years.
[2]
(iv) Derive the market-implied risk-free forward rate of interest from time 1 to
time 3. [2]
[Total 10]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2015–6
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2015 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context at the date the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances
may have changed if using these reports for revision.
F Layton
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2015
1 (i) 1. Comparability
2. Transitivity
3. Independence
4. Certainty equivalence
(ii) Non-satiated: U ( w) 0
Risk neutral: U ( w) 0
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) VaR does not illustrate the size of the loss in the tail of the distribution, only
the likelihood.
The usefulness of VaR may be limited by a lack of data to determine the tail of
the distribution.
This question was relatively poorly answered for such a standard. Many candidates confused
the 5th and 95th percentiles. In part (iv) some students mentioned that VaR calculations often
assume a normal distribution, which was not relevant in the context of downside risk and
gained no marks.
(ii) = .2483 and so d1 = 0.68. It follows (rearranging the expression for d1)
that (.01575 + .03 + 0.52) = 0.68. Solving the quadratic equation we obtain
= 0.68 0.3709 = 0.07098 = 7.1% (choosing the root less than 1).
This question was relatively poorly answered for such a standard question. Few candidates
scored on part (i)(a) or seemed to realise that the delta of a put must be negative.
4 Regrettably, there was a mistake on the paper, giving an incorrect formula for the
variance of Xt. Candidates were not penalised for this as they were credited with the
greater of their actual score on this question and their average mark for the other
questions on the paper.
The calculations are given both for the incorrect formula and the correct one.
Since this is in the question the answers are given following through the mistake and
the correct answers afterwards in italics (except for (i)(b) itself).
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
(i) (a) Conditional on Xt, Xt+1 is normal, and has mean 0.75Xt and variance
0.252Var(et+1)= 0.252
(ii) (a) Taking the answer from part (i)(b), we see that the mean converges
and so does the variance, so the distribution converges to a Normal.
(b) The mean tends to 0 and the variance tends to (.25)2/(1 (.25)2)
= 1/15, so the limiting distribution is N(0,1/15).
CORRECT ANSWER
Conditional on Y0, logY3 is N(0.753log Y0, (0.754+0.752+1).252))=N(0.08042,
0.11743)
So E[logY3|Y0 = 1.21] = 0.253log1.21 = 0.08042 and Var(logY3|Y0 = 1.21) =
0.11743.
Thus E[Y3|Y0 = 1.21] = exp(0.08042 + ½ * 0.11743) = 1.14928.
CORRECT ANSWER
The long-run distribution is logNormal(0, 0.252/(1 0.752))
= logNormal(0, 0.14285), so the long-run mean annual increase is
e½*142851=1.07404 or 7.404%.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
5 (i)
This is actually from Taylor’s formula and the last line alone would have
scored full marks. Versions involving the integrals would also have scored full
marks.
= λeλtXtdt + eλtdXt
t
So U t U 0 e λs dWs
0
t
So X t e U t e X 0 e dWs
λt λt λ t s
This question was generally well-answered. However many candidates showed an eccentric
use of stochastic calculus in part (ii).
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
Since they have the same value at expiry and since the options cannot be
exercised before then they should have the same value at any time t < T, by
no-arbitrage: that is
ct + Ker(Tt) = pt + St
Sample values:
This question was generally well-answered. However it is a cause for concern that many
candidates were unable to calculate the implied volatility.
Delta = f/S
Gamma = 2f/S2
Vega = f/σ
(iii) The hedge is delta = 0.801 shares = and 17.91 – 0.801 * 60 = $30.15 short in
cash.
This question was generally well-answered. Very few candidates seemed to be able to use the
Vega to perform the approximation in part (iv) and instead opted to recalculate the option
price using the Black-Scholes formula. This still scored full marks if done correctly, but was
time-consuming and unnecessary.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
8 (i) Investors select their portfolios on the basis of the expected return and the
variance of that return over a single time horizon.
The expected returns, variance of returns and covariance of returns are known
for all assets and pairs of assets.
Investors are never satiated. At a given level of risk, they will always prefer a
portfolio with a higher return to one with a lower return.
(ii) Let the proportion invested in asset i, be xi, with expected return Ei, variance
Vi and correlation ρ12. Let E be the return on the portfolio of the three assets
and let λ and μ be Lagrange multipliers.
3
W xi 2Vi 21313 x1x3 ( E1x1 E2 x2 E3 x3 E ) ( x1 x2 x3 1)
i 1
W W
(iii) 32 x1 48 x3 2 0 288 x2 4 0
x1 x2
W
128 x3 48 x1 3 0
x3
Substituting the values given for xi, we obtain three equations for λ and μ,
solving these gives λ =64.8 and μ = 100.8 and we can check that these
values satisfy the constraints.
(iv) Without short selling, the only way to get an expected return of 4% is to invest
wholly in asset 2.
This question was generally answered quite well. Well answered on part (i) but many
students listed all assumptions rather than the main ones. Part (ii) was well answered but
some students did not know the formula for the Lagrangian function or the variance for the
portfolio of three assets. Many students took the “show” instruction in part (iii) to mean
prove by solving the equations rather than “verify” and spent a considerable amount of time.
Few scored on part (iv) with many making vague comments about the variance changing.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2015 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) In the Merton model, the company is modelled as having a fixed debt, L and
variable assets Ft. This means the equity holders can be regarded as holding a
European call on the assets with a strike of L. It follows from the Black-
Scholes model that we can deduce the (risk-neutral) default probability from
the share price.
(iii) In the two state model for credit rating with deterministic transition intensity,
the formula for the zero coupon bond price is
(iv) It follows that the risk-neutral default intensity is given by λ(s) = s2/2.
There has been an average performance on this question. Many candidates seem unfamiliar
with this standard material. Many candidates did not know the formula for the bond price
with deterministic, but varying, transition intensity. Some candidates only listed the three
forms of credit model and others struggled with part (iv). Some also ended up with answers
for (v) in terms of delta, and/or (T t), demonstrating a lack of competence with simple
differentiation.
Page 8
Suubject CT8 (Financial
(F Ecconomics Coore Technical) – April 20
015 – Exam
miners’ Repo
ort
10 (i)
(ii) τ =1
b(τ)) = (1 – exp(0.5
e * 11)) / 0.5 = 0.7869
0
1
(iii) R(t , T ) n B(t , T ) for t T
ln
T t
1 B(t , T )
(iv) F (t , T , S ) ln for t T s
S T B(t , S )
END
D OF EXA
AMINER
RS’ REPORT
Page 9
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
Please note, regarding Question 9: The five marks for part (v) of
Question 9 should have been split as two marks for part (iv) and
three marks for part (v).
1 Outline consumer choice theory. [9]
(ii) State which assumption of the mean-variance portfolio theory can be relaxed.
[1]
(iii) Calculate the expected return and the standard deviation of a portfolio which is
invested three quarters in S and one quarter in M. [2]
A new study suggests that in the future, S will make more sales to M, when M is
delivering strong profits.
(v) Describe the effect this will have on portfolios composed of M and S,
including the minimum-variance portfolio. [3]
[Total 10]
(i) Calculate the probability of the event that Z1 > 0 and Z 2 < 0. [5]
(iii) Explain why the standard Brownian motion is less suitable than the geometric
Brownian motion as a model of stock prices. [2]
[Total 8]
CT8 S2014–2
4 A non-dividend paying stock currently trades at $65. Every two years the stock price
either increases by a multiplicative factor 1.3, or decreases by a multiplicative factor
0.8. The effective risk-free rate is 4% p.a.
Calculate the price of an American put option written on the stock with strike price
$70 and maturity four years, using a two period binomial model. [9]
5 Let S be the price of a non-dividend paying share, and let r be the continuously
compounded risk-free rate.
(i) Derive the forward price at time zero for the forward contract on S with
maturity T. [4]
Assume that, at time zero, the share price is 500, and that the forward contract has
maturity two years. The share pays a dividend of 5% of the share price every six
months with the next dividend due in two months, and the continuously compounded
risk-free rate is 3% p.a.
(iii) Comment on whether the high dividend yield relative to the risk-free rate
offers an arbitrage opportunity. [2]
[Total 10]
Consider a specific bond with maturity T1, suppose its price satisfies the following
Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE) under the real-world probability measure P:
where W is a standard Brownian Motion, m(t, T1) is the drift and S(t, T1) is the
volatility.
(c) Show how it can be used in transforming the SDE above from the real-
world probability measure P to a risk-neutral probability measure Q.
[4]
(iii) Show how the above results would be used in calculating zero-coupon bond
prices. [3]
(i) Derive the probability density function of max0≤s≤t (Bs+ μs), where μ is a
constant, using the formula in section 7.2 of the Actuarial Formulae and
Tables. [3]
(ii) Give the expression for the fair price at time t of a derivative written on S
paying an amount DT at time T, defining any terms you use. [3]
Suppose that S has an initial price of S0 = £1.20 and a volatility σ = 30% p.a. and that
the continuously compounded risk-free rate is r = 3% p.a.
(iii) Calculate the fair-price at time zero of the derivative paying £10 at time T = 2
if and only if max0≤s≤T (Bs + μs) > £1.44. [4]
[Total 10]
Suppose that the stock price at time zero is S0 = $100, the continuously compounded
risk-free rate is 3% and that a European call option written on S with strike price
$109.42 and maturity t = 1 year has a delta of Δ = 0.42074.
(ii) Find the implied volatility of the stock to the nearest 1%. [3]
An exotic option written on S with strike prices K1 and K2 and exercise times τ and T
is defined as follows:
• The option may be exercised at time τ in which case the holder receives $100 if
and only if the price of the underlying, Sτ is at least K1.
• If the option is not exercised at time τ, then the holder will receive an amount c if
and only if the price at expiry T, ST, satisfies ST / Sτ ≥ K2.
(iii) Explain why, if c ≤ $100, the option will always be exercised at time τ when
Sτ is at least K1. [2]
(iv) Give a formula for the value of the option just after the first exercise time τ
(i.e. just after the first exercise option has expired). [2]
(v) Explain why this value does not depend on the stock price at time τ. [2]
(vi) Determine the fair price of the exotic option just after time one and hence at
time one and at time zero. [3]
[Total 13]
CT8 S2014–4
9 A company has issued a loan in the form of a zero-coupon bond which redeems in one
year from now. The bond is priced at £92.78 per £100 nominal and the recovery rate
in the event of a default is assumed to be 50%. The continuously compounded risk-
free rate for one year is 3% p.a.
(i) Write down the formula for the bond price under the two-state model, defining
all the terms used. [2]
(ii) Calculate the risk-neutral probability that the bond defaults. [3]
Assume that the Merton model holds and that the annual volatility of the company’s
total assets is 13%.
(iii) Give an expression for the risk-neutral probability that the company defaults,
defining any other terms you use. [3]
(iv) Calculate the ratio of nominal loan to total asset value, assuming that the risk-
neutral default probability is the same as calculated in (ii).
(v) Calculate the ratio of loan value to total asset value and hence determine the
percentage of total assets represented by equity value at time zero. [5]
[Total 13]
10 (i) (a) Describe the lognormal model for securities prices including the
definition of the parameters used.
(b) State the corresponding mean and variance for the security price. [4]
(ii) Determine the parameter values for the corresponding lognormal model. [3]
[Total 7]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2014–5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2014 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context at the date the
examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that circumstances
may have changed if using these reports for revision.
F Layton
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
November 2014
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good. Candidates found some questions challenging, but well-
prepared candidates scored consistently across the whole paper. As in previous diets,
questions that required an element of application of the core reading to situations that were
not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates. A significant number
of candidates failed to read some questions carefully enough to identify the relevant section
of the course being examined.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Definitions
The amount of one good that a consumer is prepared to swap for one extra unit
of another good is known as the “marginal rate of substitution”.
A given combination of goods (e.g. two apples and five bananas) is called a
“consumption bundle”.
A consumer can rank different bundles, and therefore can pick a set of
consumption bundles that give the same utility.
The assumptions
The budget line joins all points that a consumer can afford, assuming that all
income is spent.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Implications
Combining the budget line with indifference curves, we can determine the
consumption bundle which a consumer will choose. A rational consumer will
choose a consumption bundle such that the marginal rate of substitution is
equal to the slope of the budget line – that is, where the ratios of marginal
utilities equal the ratios of prices.
[9]
This question was generally well answered by candidates who knew the bookwork on
consumer choice theory. A significant minority of candidates wrote about behavioural
finance (sometimes many pages) and scored few, if any, marks.
(ii) You can relax the assumption that investors solely select their portfolios on the
basis of the expected return and variance of that return. [1]
VM CSM 25 4 5 0.3
xS 0.655173
VS 2CSM VM 16 2 4 5 0.3 25
(v) The study suggests that the correlation between M and S will increase.
This means that portfolios containing positive amounts of M and S will have a
higher variance.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
If the correlation increases, then the minimum variance portfolio will contain
relatively higher amounts of S and relatively lower amounts of M. [3]
[Total 10]
Generally well answered. A surprising number of candidates went about deriving the
proportion of assets in the minimum variance portfolio from first principles. A number of
candidates also weren’t able to calculate the variance of a linear combination of correlated
random variables. Part (v) required thinking beyond the core reading, and the better
candidates scored here.
3 (i) One possible answer is as follows (other acceptable proofs could score full
marks):
We need:
W 0 ,
W X 0 X 0 and abs( X ) abs(W )
Where A, and are constants and Z t is the standard Brownian motion. [1]
(iii) However successful the Brownian motion model may be for describing the
movement of market indices in the short run, it is useless in the long run, if
only for the reason that a standard Brownian motion is certain to become
negative eventually.
It could also be pointed out that the Brownian model predicts that daily
movements of size 100 or more would occur just as frequently when the
process is at level 100 as when it is at level 10,000. [2]
[Total 8]
Many candidates found part (i) challenging, and skipped to other questions without having a
go at parts (ii) and (iii), which presented an opportunity for some relatively easy marks.
4 As the option is an American put, it may be optimal to exercise early and we have to
test at each node on the binomial tree.
First let us calculate the value of the European put option at each node starting from
expiry (the value of the American option is then the maximum of the value of the
European option and the intrinsic value at any node).
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
1.042 0.8
q 0.5632 .
1.3 0.8
The value of the option payoff for the European options at t = 4 is given by:
The value of the European option, and hence American options at time t = 2 are then:
Generally well answered. Most candidates realised that you can exercise an American
option early, but few managed to adjust the option price appropriately to allow for
this. Some candidates also slipped up over the two-year time steps.
5 (i) One possible answer is as follows (other acceptable proofs could score full
marks):
Let K be the forward price. Now compare the setting up of the following
portfolios at time 0:
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
By the principle of no-arbitrage these portfolios must have the same value at
all times before T.
In particular, at time 0, portfolio B has value S0 – K exp(−rT) which must
equal the value of the forward contract.
Following similar logic to part (i), with the dividend being reinvested in the
share at each dividend date we find that no arbitrage implies that the fair
forward price K = 500 exp(0.06) 1.054 = 436.79. [4]
(iii) This does not provide an arbitrage opportunity since the dividend is not risk-
free (and if the share price dropped significantly so would the dividend
amount, even if the yield remained the same). [2]
[Total 10]
Part (i) was well answered. In part (ii) many candidates made a decent attempt at allowing
for dividends, but few got to the right answer. A surprising number of candidates thought
that a high dividend yield presented an arbitrage opportunity, failing to appreciate that
dividends are not risk-free.
6 (i) We have started off with a process for r(t) which is not a tradable asset. An
arbitrage opportunity must relate to trading an asset, therefore arbitrage-free
models must allow for trading. [2]
m(t , T1 ) r (t )
(t , T1 ) .
S (t , T1 )
(b) γ(t,T1) represents the excess expected return over the risk-free rate per
unit of volatility in return for an investor taking on this volatility.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
= B(t,T) r (t ) dt S (t , T )dW (t )
where dW (t ) = dW(t) + (t)dt is the standard Brownian motion
under Q. [4]
(iii) For a one-factor model we have seen above the broad principal which
transforms from P to Q. In order to say more about the basic price processes
we must look at the effect of this transformation on r(t).
Thus
The final two lines give us the dynamics of r(t) under the artificial measure Q.
B(t,T) = EQ exp r (u )du t
T
t
(iv) When modellers use this approach to pricing, from the practical point of view
they normally start by specifying the dynamics of r(t) under Q in order to
calculate bond prices. Second, they specify the market price of risk as a
component of the model, and this allows us to determine the dynamics of r(t)
under P. [2]
[Total 11]
Part (i) was generally well answered, but very few candidates managed parts (iii) and (iv)
which were largely bookwork. Quite a few candidates tried solving the SDE for the log of the
ZCB price with no mention of transforming to the risk neutral probability measure.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
f(y) = ∂f/∂y
where φ is the standard normal density: it follows after a little algebra that
P max( Bs s ) 1.44
0 st
Comparing the Bs + s part of this expression with the expression inside the
share price formula, we might take:
r 0.52
= = 0.5
(although the value of was not given in the question so we award full marks
to any student who has derived the correct answer in terms of )
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
[4]
[Total 10]
Many candidates found this question tough and scored few marks. A number of candidates
were seemingly put off by part (i) and didn’t attempt the potentially easier marks available in
later parts.
8 (i) Δ is the first partial derivative of the option price with respect to the
underlying asset price. [1]
(ii) Using the formula for the Δ, we see that Φ(d1) = 0.42074 and hence d1 = 0.2.
Solving the quadratic gives σ = 20% or 60% and rejecting the negative value
gives σ = 20%. [3]
(iii) When Sτ is at least K1 then the holder is presented with a choice between $100
now and the possibility of $c later. Clearly if c ≤ 100, the holder will always
choose to exercise immediately. [2]
(iv) Just after τ, the optional element has expired and the holder is entitled to $c at
time T if and only if (ST/Sτ ≥ K2). And so the fair price after time τ is
Since this is greater than $100, the holder will never exercise the option at
time 1 and so
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Reasonably well answered. Many candidates tried to find the volatility by trial and error,
which was time-consuming compared to deriving and solving the quadratic equation. Some
candidates derived the quadratic equation then still solved it by trial and error. Several
candidates tried to determine the price of the exotic option as a call option for part (vi).
where B is the bond price, λ is the risk-neutral default rate, δ is the recovery
rate, and r is the risk-free rate. [2]
(iii) Under the Merton model, Q(default) = Q(FT < L), where L is the nominal loan
amount, and Ft is the gross asset value of the company at time t and Q is the
EMM.
Hence
(iv) Thus
so
and so
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
(v) Thus,
and so
where Et is the net equity value at time t and Lt is the loan value at time t. [5]
[Total 15]
Candidates scored well on parts (i), (ii) and (iii). Well prepared candidates scored full
marks but many did not attempt parts (iv) and (v). Many candidates thought that lambda was
the probability of default (rather than the integral of lambda) and tried to find lambda
without success.
10 (i) (a) The lognormal model has independent, stationary normal increments
for the log of the asset price.
The formulae for mean and variance will then change to:
E(St) = S0exp(μt)
and
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2014 – Examiners’ Report
It follows that
and
It follows that
Generally very well answered, with most students recalling and applying the bookwork
correctly.
Page 13
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a new page.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
2 (i) State the expression for the return on a security, i, in the single-index model,
defining all terms used. [2]
(ii) Explain the difference between the single-index model and the Capital Asset
Pricing Model. [1]
Suppose the market has expected return 6% and standard deviation 10%. Two
securities have expected returns 8% and 10%, and standard deviations 15% and 20%.
The correlation between these two securities and the market is 0.25 and 0.4
respectively. Assume the single-index model described in (i) holds.
(iii) Calculate the constant parameters in the expression for the return of these two
securities. [5]
(iv) Explain how a multi-index model would be expected to perform relative to the
single-index model in terms of fitting data and predicting future security price
moves. [2]
[Total 10]
(i) State the continuous-time log-normal model of a security price S, defining all
the terms used. [2]
(ii) (a) Find a function f such that f (t , Wt2 ) is a Ft-martingale, with F the
Brownian filtration.
(b) Use Ito’s lemma to show that f (t , Wt2 ) is a process with zero drift.
[4]
(iii) Derive the values of α and β for which X t defines a standard Brownian
motion. [6]
[Total 12]
CT8 A2014–2
4 Consider the following long position in European and American call options written
on a stock, with strikes and times to expiry as set out in the table below.
Rank these options in order of value to the extent that this is possible. [5]
(i) Comment on the suitability of this model for the short-rate. [4]
6 (i) State the equation for the capital market line in the Capital Asset Pricing
Model (CAPM), defining all the terms used. [3]
In a market where the CAPM is assumed to hold, the expected annual return on the
market portfolio is 12%, the variance is 4%% and the effective risk-free annual rate is
4%. An Agent wants an expected annual return of 18% on a portfolio worth
£1,200,000.
(ii) Calculate the standard deviation of the return on the corresponding efficient
portfolio. [2]
(iii) Calculate the amount of money invested in each component of the Agent’s
portfolio. [3]
[Total 8]
(i) Write down the partial differential equation (PDE) that g must satisfy,
including the boundary condition for time T. [3]
Suppose that the derivative pays STn / S0n−1 at time T, where n is an integer greater
than 1.
(ii) Show, using (i), that the price of the derivative at time t is given by
Dt = (Stn / S0n−1)eμ(T−t) for some μ which you should determine. [6]
[Total 9]
8 (i) State and prove the put-call parity for a stock paying no dividends. [5]
(ii) Estimate the implied volatility of the stock to the nearest 1%. [4]
A European put option on the same stock has strike price $121 and the same maturity.
An investor holds a portfolio which is long one call and short one put.
(iii) Sketch a graph of the payoff at maturity of the portfolio against the stock price
[2]
(iv) (a) Determine an upper and a lower bound on the value of the portfolio at
maturity.
9 Outline the evidence against normality assumptions in models of market returns. [8]
CT8 A2014–4
10 A company has two zero-coupon bonds in issue. Bond A redeems in 1 year and the
current price of £100 nominal is £92.50. Bond C redeems in 2 years and the current
price of £100 nominal is £74.72.
The continuously compounded risk-free rate is 2.5% p.a. for the next two years.
(i) Write down the formula for the general zero-coupon bond price in the two-
state model for credit ratings, defining all the terms used. [2]
(ii) Determine the implied risk-neutral probability of default for bond A, assuming
this model holds, and a recovery rate of 50% for bond A. [3]
If bond A defaults then bond C automatically defaults with a recovery rate of zero,
whereas if bond A does not default then bond C may still default in the second year,
but with a recovery rate of 50%.
(iii) Modify your answer to (i) to give a formula for the current price of bond C.
[3]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2014–5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2014 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
D C Bowie
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2014
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good. Candidates generally found this paper challenging, but
well-prepared candidates scored well across the whole paper and the best candidates scored
close to full marks. As in previous diets, questions that required an element of application of
the core reading to situations that were not immediately familiar proved more challenging to
most candidates.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Anchoring is a term used to explain how people will produce estimates. They then
adjust away from this initial anchor to arrive at their final judgement.
Prospect theory
A theory of how people make decisions when faced with risk and uncertainty. It
replaces the conventional risk averse / risk seeking decreasing marginal utility theory.
The way a choice is presented (“framed”) and, particularly, the wording of a question
in terms of gains and losses, can have an enormous impact on the answer given or the
decision made.
This is similar to prospect theory, but considers repeated choices rather than a single
“gamble”.
Estimating probabilities
Issues (other than anchoring) which might affect probability estimates include:
• Representative Heuristics – people find more probable that which they find easier
to imagine. As the amount of detail increases, its apparent likelihood may
increase (although the true probability can only decrease steadily).
• Availability – people are influenced by the ease with which something can be
brought to mind. This can lead to biased judgements when examples of one event
are inherently more difficult to imagine than examples of another.
Overconfidence
People tend to overestimate their own abilities, knowledge and skills. This may be a
result of:
• Hindsight bias – events that happen will be thought of as having been predictable
prior to the event, events that do not happen will be thought of as having been
unlikely prior to the event.
• Confirmation bias – people will tend to look for evidence that confirms their point
of view (and will tend to dismiss evidence that does not justify it).
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Mental accounting
People show a tendency to separate related events and decisions and find it difficult
to aggregate events.
Effect of options
• Primary effect – people are more likely to choose the first option presented, but
• Recency effect – in some instances, the final option that is discussed may be
preferred! (The gap in time between the presentation of the options and the
decision may influence this dichotomy.)
• Other research suggests that people are more likely to choose an intermediate
option than one at either end!
• Status Quo bias – people have a marked preference for keeping things as they are.
This question was generally well answered by candidates who knew the 8 key findings of
behavioural finance. A surprising number of candidates confused this question with the
Efficient Market Hypothesis. Some candidates discussed the shortcomings of assuming that
consumers are rational.
Ri= αi + βiRM+ εi
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) The single-index model is purely empirical and is not based on any theoretical
relationships between βi and the other variables, which are assumed in CAPM.
(iii) The βi are the ratio of the covariances of the securities with the market divided
by the variance of the market.
(iv) As you are fitting more parameters, in-sample results should give a better fit
(although not necessary a higher information criterion).
Part (i) was well answered by most candidates. Part (ii) was poorly answered by most
candidates. Part (iii) was well answered by most candidates. Some candidates failed to
derive both alpha and beta, but instead only provided a single set of parameters. Part (iv)
was well answered by most candidates. Several candidates failed to answer both parts of the
question (i.e. fitting the data and predicting future security prices). A number of candidates
also concluded that the multi-factor model would be better at predicting future security
prices.
3 St = S0 exp(μt + σWt)
( )
Using the hint, we see that E Wt2 − t | Fs = Ws2 − s for all s < t.
( )
t = Var(Xt) = t 2α Var Wt β = t 2α+β ⇒ 2α + β = 1
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
We can then consider the increment in the process from t = 1(when the value of Xt is
simplified). So suppose that t > 1:
( ) ( )
E ( t αWt β −W1 )2 = t 2α+β + 1 − 2t α min t β ,1 .
( )
E ( t αWtβ −W1 )2 = t − 1
( )
Since t 2α+β = t we must have t α min t β ,1 = 1, so α = 0 whence β = 1 if β > 0.
You may recognise the second solution to this problem as the time inversion property
of standard Brownian motion.
Alternatively:
Setting this equal to min(s, t) gives the two pairs of solutions required: α = 0, β = 1
and α = 1, β = −1.
Part (i) was well answered by most candidates. Part (ii) was well answered by most
candidates. Part (iii) was very poorly answered in general. Few if any considered the finite
moment condition. Only a few students managed to score more than a couple of marks in
part (iii) because they didn’t try to check the relevant Gaussian parameters.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
4 Call options with lower strike prices are more valuable, so A > C.
American call options are more valuable than European call options so A > D and
B > E.
American call options with longer time to expiry are more valuable so A > B.
So, A is the most valuable, B is more valuable than E, and we cannot pass comment
on the relative value of other pairs with the information available.
Most managed this quite well, though a lot of students who found the correct inequalities also
derived some spurious ones as well. The most common mistake seemed to be not
understanding American options and not noticing that dividends might be payable.
It is arbitrage-free.
(ii) Since the Vasicek model is an Ornstein-Uhlenbeck process we can solve the
SDE for the short rate to get:
( ) + σe
u
− a ( u −t ) − a( u −t )
r (u ) = r (t ) e ∫e
− au as
+ μ 1− e dZ s .
t
Hence
T T T T u
− a ( u −t )
du + μ ∫ ⎡⎢1 − e ( ) ⎤⎥ du + σ ∫ e− au ∫ eas dZ s du
− a u −t
∫ r ( u ) du = r ( t ) ∫ e ⎣ ⎦
t t t t t
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
1− e ( ) 1− e ( )
T − a T −t T − a T −s
∫ r ( u ) du = μ ( t − t ) + ⎡⎣r ( t ) − μ ⎤⎦ a
+ σ∫
a
dZ s
t t
T
So, ∫ r ( u ) du is a Gaussian random variable.
t
Students scored well on part (i) which was standard bookwork. In part (ii) many students
only solved the Vasicek SDE rather than deriving an expression for the integral as asked.
rP − r0 = σP / σM(rM − r0),
where
(iii) The efficient portfolio is a mix of the market portfolio and the risk-free asset.
If the weights (which sum to 1) are wM and w0 then the expected return is
12wM + 4 w0 so 8 wM = 14 and wM = 1.75, wM = −0.75.
Thus the efficient portfolio has £2,100,000 in the market portfolio and is short
£900,000 in cash.
Some weaker students confused the variance with the standard deviation when applying the
formula for CAPM. Others lost marks for minor calculation errors.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
½σ2x2gxx+ (r −q)xgx – rg + gt = 0
(ii) The proposed solution implies that for this derivative the function g is given
by g(t, x) = (xn / S0n−1)eμ(T−t), where n is an integer great than 1.
Not generally well-answered. Most students managed part (i) but few got any marks for part
(ii). A surprising number of students answered part (i) correctly but failed to try the obvious
route of substituting the equation from part (ii) into the formula from part (i).
8 (i) Consider the portfolio which is long one call plus cash of Ke−r(T−t) and short
one put.
Since this is the value of the stock at time T, the stock price should be the
value at any time t < T: that is
Ct + Ke−r(T−t) − Pt = St.
so that
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
(iii)
S1 −121 ≤ D ≤ S1 −120.
(v) The Black-Scholes price (using the formula in the tables) is $18.35.
Most students scored highly with the proof of the put-call parity.
Part (ii): a lot of students checked two trial values, and then interpolated to get something at
or near 30%. They didn't always check that their answer gave the right answer.
Part (iii): few students managed to sketch the graph correctly. There was often confusion
over the payoff profile between 120$ and 121$.
Part (iv): few students understood the question, mainly because they hadn’t sketched the
graph in part (iii).
Part (v): a common mistake was using put-call parity to work out the value of the put and not
spotting that it had a different strike.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
• market crashes appear more often than one would expect from a normal
distribution. While the random walk produces continuous price paths, jumps or
discontinuities seem to be an important feature of real markets.
• Furthermore, days with no change, or very small change, also happen more often
than the normal distribution suggests. This would seem to justify the consideration
of Levy processes.
• Q-Q plots of the observed changes in the FTSE All Share index against those
which would be expected if the returns were lognormally distributed show
substantial differences. This demonstrates that the actual returns have many more
extreme events, both on the upside and downside, than is consistent with the
lognormal model.
• a quintic polynomial distribution whose parameters have been chosen to give the
best fit to the data, clearly provides an improved description of the returns
observed, in particular more extreme events are observed than is the case with the
lognormal model. The rolling volatilities of a simulation from the non-normal
distribution show significant differences over different periods. This volatility
process has the same characteristics as the observed volatility from the equity
market.
This question was very poorly answered by most candidates, with very few candidates
scoring more than 4/8. Several candidates scored zero marks for providing a discussion on
the normal distribution itself, as opposed to the assumption of normality in market returns.
Candidates were generally able to generate the first two points (market crashes occur more
often than expected, jumps, etc. and that there are a larger number of days with little or no
movement). Almost no one discussed the use of Q-Q plots or a quintic polynomial. Again,
some candidates noted the points highlighted by Anna Bishop around the Hausdorff fractal
dimension.
10 (i) B(t,T) = e−r(T−t)[1 − (1 − δ)(1 − exp(− ∫ Tt λ s ds))] , where B is the bond price, λ
is the risk-neutral default rate, δ is the recovery rate, and r is the risk-free rate.
so that
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2014 – Examiners’ Report
Thus
(iv) From the second expression in (iii) and the answer to (ii) we obtain
Page 12
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
(ii) Explain of the concepts of non-satiation and risk aversion, showing how they
can be expressed in terms of a utility function. [2]
(iii) Calculate the value of b and the range over which U(.) satisfies the condition
of non-satiation. [3]
[Total 10]
2 (i) Describe the single-index model of security returns, defining any terms used.
[2]
The single-index model is to be used in a particular market.
(iii) Show that investors can diversify away specific risk in this model by holding
equal weights in an increasing number of securities. [4]
(iv) State the potential impact of adding additional indices to the model:
3 (i) Outline the three forms of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis (EMH). [3]
(ii) Discuss the following two scenarios in the light of the EMH:
Scenario 1: Company A’s share price falls suddenly, immediately after news
of an earthquake in the capital city of one of its major markets.
Scenario 2: Company B’s share price falls suddenly, when a long-awaited and
publicly negotiated merger is completed.
[3]
[Total 6]
CT8 S2013–2
4 In the Wilkie model, the force of inflation in year t, I(t), is modelled as an AR(1)
process as follows:
where, for any t, all Z(t) are independent, identically distributed N(0, σ2) random
variables.
Let m = 0.03; a = 0.6 and σ2 = 2.5 ×10−5. The force of inflation was 3.3% in 2012.
(i) Calculate a 95% confidence interval for the force of inflation in 2013. [3]
A final salary pension fund is assuming inflation of 1% p.a. for the period 1 January
2012 to 31 December 2013.
(ii) Comment on the appropriateness of this assumption assuming that the Wilkie
model is correct. [2]
[Total 5]
5 The share price in Santa Insurance Co, St , is currently 97p and can be modelled by
the stochastic differential equation:
(b) Calculate the expectation and variance of the Santa Insurance Co share
price in two years’ time. [6]
The share price in Rudolf Financial Services plc, Rt , is also currently at 97p and can
be modelled by the stochastic differential equation:
Let Ut = e0.4t Rt
(i) Calculate the value of the call option today using a risk-neutral pricing
approach. [3]
Assume that the real world probability of the stock price moving up in each of the
next three month periods is 0.7
(ii) (a) Calculate the values of the state price deflator after six months
(b) Calculate and the value of the call option today using your answers to
part (ii)(a).
Assume that the real world probability has now dropped from 0.7 to 0.6.
(iii) (a) Explain, without performing any further calculations, how the state
price deflator would change in value.
(b) Comment on the impact that this would have on the option price. [2]
[Total 10]
7 The continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is r, and a stock, with maturity
T, pays dividends continuously at rate q.
(i) Determine the forward price at time 0 for a forward contract on the stock. [3]
(ii) Show that there exists a portfolio that earns the risk free rate r, containing:
• the stock
• a European call option on the stock
• and a European put option on the stock [4]
[Total 7]
8 (i) Write down a stochastic differential equation for the short rate r in the Vasicek
model defining any notation used. [1]
(ii) List the desirable and undesirable features of this model for the term structure
of interest rates. [4]
(iii) (a) Solve the stochastic differential equation from your answer to part (i).
(b) Comment on the statistical properties of rT , T > t.
[7]
[Total 12]
CT8 S2013–4
9 A one-year European call option on a non-dividend paying stock in Company ABC
has a strike of $150.
The continuously compounded risk-free rate is 2% p.a. The current stock price is
$117.98. Assume that the market follows the assumptions of a Black-Scholes model.
(iii) Calculate the price of a one-year put on the same stock with a strike of $150.
[2]
The investor retains their holding of call options and trades in the put and the stock to
achieve a delta and gamma-hedged portfolio.
(iv) Calculate the investor’s new holdings of the put and the stock. [4]
[Total 12]
10 (i) Describe the Merton model for pricing a bond subject to default risk. [4]
A very highly geared company – XYZ plc – has issued zero-coupon bonds payable in
four years’ time. The debt is a nominal $120m.
(ii) Give expressions for the value of the debt in four years’ time and today,
adopting a Black-Scholes model for the value of XYZ plc. [4]
The current gross value of XYZ plc is $180m. The continuously compounded risk-
free interest rate is 2% p.a. and the continuously compounded credit spread on the
bond is 4.5% p.a.
(iv) Estimate to the nearest 1% the implied volatility of the value of XYZ. [3]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2013–5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2013 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
D C Bowie
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2013
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good and broadly in line with the previous session (April
2013). Candidates generally found this paper challenging, but well-prepared candidates
scored well across the whole paper and the best candidates scored close to full marks. As in
previous diets, questions that required an element of application of the core reading to
situations that were not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates.
The comments that follow the questions concentrate on areas where candidates could have
improved their performance. Candidates approaching the subject for the first time are advised
to include in their revision these areas and the ability to apply the core reading to similar
situations.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
1 (i) (a) The expected utility theorem states that a function, U(w) can be
constructed representing an investor’s utility of wealth, w, at some
future date. Decisions are made on the basis of maximising the
expected value of utility under the investor’s particular beliefs about
the probability of different outcomes.
(b) The expected utility theorem can be derived formally from the
following four axioms.
1. Comparability
2. Transitivity
3. Independence
4. Certainty equivalence
(ii) It is usually assumed that people prefer more wealth to less. This is known as
the principle of non-satiation and can be expressed as:
U′(w)>0 or U is strictly increasing.
U ( w)
A( w) .
U ( w)
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
Which for the utility function given can be calculated by taking derivatives as,
2b
.
1 2bw
This bookwork question was largely well-answered although some candidates appeared to be
unaware that non-satiation and absolute risk aversion do not have identical meanings.
Ri = αi + βiRM + εi
Ei = Ri i i RM i αi + βi .EM,
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
(iii) Using the results from (ii), the variance of portfolio returns on a portfolio of N
equally weighted securities is
N
1
V N 2 Cov Ri , R j
i , j 1
N N
1 1
N2
(i2VM Vi ) βi . βj .VM
N 2 i , j 1, i j
i 1
1 N 2
= i VM plus terms which tend to zero as N .
N
i 1
In other words, the limiting portfolio variance depends on the average value of
the i s and the variance of the market but not the specific risk of any
individual security.
Alternative solution:
The single index model for a portfolio P of N assets held in proportions xi, …,
xN is:
RP = P + PRM + P
N N N
where P = xi i , P = xii and P = xi i
i 1 i 1 i 1
VP = 2PVM V P
2
N N
= xii VM var xi i
i 1 i 1
1
If xi = then:
N
2
1 N 1 N
VP = 2 i VM 2 Vi
N i 1 N i 1
1
= 2VM V
N
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
Where is the average of the individual i’s and V is the average of the
Vi ’s.
(iv) More factors will always improve the fit of a regression to historic data, in
other words reduce the residual errors in relation to the data fitted, although
market correlation typically has the most explanatory power.
Again this was a largely well-answered question, although some candidates didn’t define
notation despite the explicit instruction to do so. Surprisingly few candidates used the results
they had derived in part (ii) to prove part (iii). Some candidates confused this model with
CAPM.
3 (i) Strong form EMH: market prices incorporate all information, both publicly
available and also that available only to insiders.
(ii) Scenario 1: The first event tells us nothing about the EMH-assuming this
earthquake was not predictable, its happening could not have been discounted
in market prices.
However, although the price drop was quick, we have no idea how accurate it
was. It is possible that the market has over or under reacted to the bad news
and will correct itself later. If this is the case, then it suggests markets are not
efficient.
Some earthquake specialists (insiders) may have known about the earthquake
shortly in advance but there is no mention of price movements before the
earthquake, perhaps this suggests the market is also strong form efficient.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
Indeed, given the public nature of the negotiations, this seems even to
contradict the semi-strong form (and by implication the strong form) of the
EMH although perhaps markets were pricing in a significant probability of the
merger failing or overreacting to the benefits and then correcting themselves.
This question was reasonably answered, although some candidates simply related the same
form of EMH to both scenarios. Many candidates missed the fact that the merger had already
been publicly negotiated and so wasn’t new information.
(ii) Not at all appropriate, since 1% does not lie in the 95% confidence interval for
2013 and it was 3.3% in 2012!
The pension scheme may have a view that inflation will fall next year, e.g. due to
a forecast recession. The Wilkie model parameters are estimated as averages over
a historic time period (they are longitudinal estimates) and therefore may not
reflect future conditions.
A surprising number of candidates were unable to calculate a confidence interval, and there
were many calculation slips. The majority of candidates struggled to interpret part (ii) of the
question.
dSt
0.4dt 0.5dBt .
St
dSt 0.5
d log St 2 (dSt ) 2 0.275dt 0.5dBt .
St St
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
or, finally,
St S0e0.275t 0.5 Bt .
St
So has a lognormal distribution with parameters 0.275t and 0.25t,
S0
or equivalently St is lognormally distributed with parameters log S 0
+ 0.275t and 0.25t.
S2 97e0.8 215.877 p
Var S2 97 2 (e0.55 ) 2 Var e0.5 B2
= 97 2 (e0.55 ) 2 e0.5 e0.5 1
=30,232.41p = (173.87)2 = (£173.87)2 = £2 3.0232
2
Consider U t Rt e0.4t
t
(b) so U t U 0 0.5 e0.4 s dBs
0
and hence
t
Rt R0e 0.4t
0.5 e0.4( s t ) dBs .
0
Now since
t 0.4 s t
0.5 e dBs 0,
0
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
and
2 0.25
Var R2 Var 0.5e0.4 s 2 dBs
0.8
1 e 1.6 0.2494 p 2
0
Overall well-answered but some candidates did seem to struggle applying Ito’s Lemma and
with calculating the expectation and variance; Some candidates confused the Normal and
LogNormal distributions, while others simply stated the answer rather than deriving it.
1
V = q 300 q 330 70 q 300 1 q 330 10 1 q 300 q 270 10 0
1.022
= 29.143.
(ii) (a) Using the results from (i) we can calculate the values of the state-price
deflator:
q 300 q 330
A 360 0.71793
0.7 1.02 2
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
A 240
1 q 300 1 q 270 1.75146.
(0.3 1.02) 2
V = EP (A2V2)
= 0.7 2 A 360 70 2 0.7 0.3 A 300 10
0.32 A 240 0
= 29.143.
(c) This is the same answer as under part (i) as expected – under a given
model the option price should not vary depending on how we evaluate
the model.
(iii) (a) A(360) would rise as the denominator decreases; A(240) and A(300)
would shrink as the denominator rises.
(b) Overall the option price would remain unchanged as it does not depend
on real-world probabilities.
Generally reasonably answered, although some candidates only calculated one risk-neutral
probability instead of three and many struggled to calculate correct state price deflators or
more surprisingly confused real-world and risk-neutral probabilities.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
7 (i) Let K be the forward price and denote the stock price at time t by St . Now
compare the setting-up of the following two portfolios at time 0:
By the principle of no-arbitrage these portfolios must have the same value at
all times before T.
So K = e( r q )T S0 .
At expiry:
If ST K , the put option expires worthless, the call option will be exercised
(or be worthless if ST K ) and the stock will be delivered in return for K.
I.e. the value of the portfolio will be K.
If ST K , the call option will not be exercised, and the stock can be sold via
the put option for K, so the value of the portfolio will be K.
Since the portfolio will be worth a known, fixed amount at time T, by the
principle of no-arbitrage it must earn the risk free rate up to time T.
This question differentiated between the stronger and weaker candidates. Candidates who
knew how to adjust the portfolio construction arguments to forward pricing scored well.
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
8 (i) The stochastic differential equation for the short rate r is:
where B is a standard Brownian motion, σ is the volatility, and α and μ are the
drift parameters. [1]
(ii) Desirable:
Arbitrage-free
Instantaneous and other rates mean reverting
Ease of computation/pricing of derivatives and bonds
Undesirable:
Consider ut rt eαt
T
so uT ut μ(e αT
e ) σ eαs dBs
αt
σ e
T
α(T t ) α T t α(T s )
and hence rT rt e μ 1 e dBs .
t
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
(b) From this we see that under the risk-neutral measure rT follows a
Gaussian distribution
with mean
rt e μ 1 e
α T t α T t
and variance
σ2
2α
1 e .
2α T t
Largely, well-answered bookwork question, although the candidates found the later sections
of this question progressively more difficult.
9 (i) The Δ of the call holding must be minus the Δ of the shareholding, which, by
definition is – 18673, so the Δ of a call is ΔC = 0.18673.
(iv) Using C to denote the call option, P the put option and S the stock we know
that:
ΔC ΔP = ΔS =1
ΓC Γ P and Γ S 0
So since we hold 100,000 call options, we must be short 100,000 put options
and 100,000 shares to get a gamma and delta neutral portfolio.
Candidates found this question difficult, especially the latter part which only the strongest
candidates answered well.
Page 13
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
10 (i)
Merton’s model assumes that a corporate entity has issued both equity and
debt such that its total value at time t is F(t). F(t) varies over time as a
result of actions by the corporate entity which does not pay dividends on
its equity or coupons on its bonds.
The corporate entity will default if the total value of its assets, F(T) is less
than the promised debt repayment at time T i.e. F(T) < L. In this situation,
the bond holders will receive F(T) instead of L and the equity holders will
receive nothing.
This can be regarded as treating the equity holders of the corporate entity
as having a European call option on the assets of the company with
maturity T and a strike price equal to L.
[Alternative expressions are fine, as per the first part of (ii) (a).]
Page 14
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – September 2013 – Examiners’ Report
Candidates struggled to gain many marks on this question, and many seemed to be short of
time reflecting the importance of time management in these exams.
Page 15
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
• Variance of return
• Downside semi-variance of return
• Shortfall probability
• Value at Risk
• Tail Value at Risk
[10]
2 Consider a mean-variance portfolio model with two securities, SA and SB , where the
expected return and the variance of return for SB are twice the corresponding values
for SA . Suppose the correlation between the returns on the two securities is ρ.
(i) (a) Determine the values of ρ which allow the possibility of constructing a
zero-risk portfolio, by calculating the variance of the return on a
portfolio with weights xA and xB invested in the two assets.
(b) Calculate the portfolio weights that lead to the most efficient zero-risk
portfolio.
(c) Calculate the expected return on the portfolio in part (i)(b) in terms of
the expected return on SA .
[5]
(b) if the investor can short sell at most one unit of either security and the
total he has to invest is one unit.
[2]
(iii) Calculate the expected return on the minimum variance portfolio if the
covariance between the two securities is 60% of the variance of SA . [2]
[Total 9]
3 An analyst states that “It is common practice in actuarial modelling to use the same
data set to specify the model structure, to fit the parameters, and to validate the model
choice. A large number of possible model structures are tested, and testing stops
when a model is found which passes a suitable array of tests.”
Indicate, giving evidence and examples, why this procedure may be inappropriate.
[5]
CT8 A2013–2
4 In a market where the CAPM holds there are five assets with the following attributes.
Asset A B C D E Probability
of being in
state
Annual return in
State 1 3% 3% 3% 3% 3% 0.25
State 2 5% 7% 2% 8% 3% 0.5
State 3 7% 5% 8% 1% 3% 0.25
Market Capitalisation 10m 20m 40m 30m
(i) Calculate the expected annual return on the market portfolio and σM, the
standard deviation of the annual return on the market portfolio. [4]
5 (i) State the five key features of a standard Brownian motion Bt . [5]
dX t = Yt dBt + At dt ,
(ii) Write down Ito’s lemma for f (t , X t ) , where f is a suitable function. [2]
(ii) Write down an equation for the instantaneous change in the value of the
portfolio, including cash inflows and outflows, at time t. [2]
(iv) Define a replicating strategy for a derivative with payoff X at a future time U,
contingent on the path taken by at , bt and ct . [2]
(v) Describe how the no-arbitrage condition and a self-financing strategy can be
used to value the derivative in (iv) at time 0. [2]
Denote by Puu the value of the payoff if both stock price moves are up, Pud for the
value of the payoff if one move is up and one is down (this is the same whichever
order the price moves occur), and Pdd for the value of the payoff if both stock price
moves are down. The price of the stock is to be modelled using a binomial tree
approach with annual time steps.
(i) Derive, and simplify an equation for Puu in terms of Pud and Pdd . [4]
(ii) Calculate, using your answer to part (i), or otherwise, the range of values that
Puu could take. [2]
(iii) Determine the value of the option in each of the two cases below, assuming
that Puu takes its maximum possible value:
CT8 A2013–4
8 (i) Describe three limitations of one-factor term structure models. [5]
(ii) Write down, defining all terms and notation used, the two-factor Vasicek
model. [3]
[Total 8]
(i) Calculate Q(Maxt<1St < 2), where Q is the EMM, using the formula in the
actuarial tables and the representation of a geometric Brownian Motion. [3]
(ii) (a) Write down an expression for the price of this option at time 1. You
should consider separately the two cases (Maxt<1St) < 2 and
(Maxt<1St) ≥ 2.
(b) Show that the value of this option at time 1 is $11.348 in the case
(Maxt<1 St )< 2.
(c) Determine, using the result in (i), the fair price at time 0 for the option.
[9]
[Total 12]
Company A’s bonds are modelled according to a two-state model. Company A has
two zero-coupon bonds in issue, both with a recovery rate of δ = 60%. Bond 1
matures in one year, bond 2 in two years’ time. Bond 1 has a continuously
compounded credit spread of 4%, bond 2 has a continuously compounded credit
spread of 5%. The continuously compounded risk-free rate is 1.5% p.a.
(ii) (a) Calculate the price per $100 nominal of each bond in one year and in
two years’ time.
(iii) Determine the implied values of the default intensities, assuming that they are
constant for each of the two years. [3]
[Total 13]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2013–5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2013 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
The report is written based on the legislative and regulatory context pertaining to the date that
the examination was set. Candidates should take into account the possibility that
circumstances may have changed if using these reports for revision.
D C Bowie
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
July 2013
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good and better than on the previous session (September 2012).
Candidates generally found this paper challenging, but well-prepared candidates scored well
across the whole paper and the best candidates scored close to full marks. As in previous
diets, questions that required an element of application of the core reading to situations that
were not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates. The comments
that follow the questions concentrate on areas where candidates could have improved their
performance.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
1 Variance of return
Credit risky bonds have an asymmetric return distribution and as defaults are often
co-dependent on economic downturns portfolios can have fat tails.
Shortfall probability
For a portfolio of bonds, the shortfall probability will not give any information on:
It allows a manager to manage risk where returns are not normally distributed.
Portfolios exposed to credit risk, systematic bias or derivatives may exhibit non-
normal distributions.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
The further one gets out into the “tails” of the distributions, the more lacking the data
and, hence, the more arbitrary the choice of the underlying probability distribution
becomes.
Relative to VaR, TailVaR provides much more information on how bad returns can be
when the benchmark level is exceeded.
It has the same modelling issues as VaR in terms of sparse data, but captures more
information on tail of the non-normal distribution.
In general, and given that this was a straightforward question, this was surprisingly poorly
answered with students losing marks for not knowing basic definitions.
2 Let the expected return on S A be E A and the variance of return be V A . Then the
expected return on S B is 2 E A and the variance of return is 2 V A .
(i) (a) The only zero risk portfolio can occur if the correlation is either 1 or
−1. By considering diversification, the most efficient portfolio will
occur when it is −1.
2+2
(c) So the expected return on the overall portfolio E = E A . .
2 +1
(ii) (a) In this case the maximum expected return is infinite (obtained by
selling unlimited amounts of security S A to purchase unlimited
amounts of security S B ).
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
(b) In this case the maximum expected return is obtained by selling one
unit of S A to purchase two units of S B . The maximum expected
return is then 3 E A .
(iii) In this case we have, using results from the core reading,
2VA − 0.6VA 7 2
xA = = = 0.7777 and so xB = = 0.2222
3VA − 1.2VA 9 9
11
And so the expected return is E A = 1.2222 E A .
9
This question was surprisingly poorly answered with most candidates missing the point of the
question, which was to test their understanding of basic ideas about correlated assets.
3 We may not be justified in accepting a model simply because it passes the tests. Many
of these tests (for example, tests of stationarity) have notoriously low power, and
therefore may not reject incorrect models.
Indeed, even if the “true” model was not in the class of models being fitted, we would
still end up with an apparently acceptable fit, because the rules say we keep
generalising until we find one.
This process of generalisation tends to lead to models which wrap themselves around
the data, resulting in an understatement of future risk, and optimism regarding the
accuracy of out-of-sample forecasts.
For example, Huber recently compared the out-of-sample forecasts of the Wilkie
model to a naïve “same as last time” forecast over a 10 year period. The naïve
forecasts proved more accurate.
May candidates had not studied basic material covered in this question and answered poorly.
4 (i) The market portfolio is in proportion to the market capitalisation since every
investor holds risky assets in proportion to that portfolio. Thus the market
portfolio is 0.1A + 0.2B + 0.4C + 0.3D (asset E is the risk-free asset).
Asset A B C D E Probability
of being in
state
Annual return in
State 1 3% 3% 3% 3% 3% 0.25
State 2 5% 7% 2% 8% 3% 0.5
State 3 7% 5% 8% 1% 3% 0.25
Market Capitalisation 10m 20m 40m 30m
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) Most of the assumptions of the basic model can be attacked as unrealistic.
Empirical studies do not provide strong support for the model. There are
basic problems in testing the model since, in theory, account has to be taken of
the entire investment universe open to investors, not just capital markets.
Regrettably, there was an inconsistency with the CAPM in the question data.
Accordingly candidates could obtain full marks to part (iii) by giving either of the two
answers above.
In general the question was answered well, with most candidates showing good familiarity
with the CAPM.
B0 = 0.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
∂f ⎡ ∂f ∂f 1 ∂2 f 2 ⎤
(ii) df ( t , X t ) = Yt dBt + ⎢ + At + Yt ⎥ dt
∂x ⎢⎣ ∂t ∂x 2 ∂x 2 ⎥⎦
This question was very well answered in general, with most candidates fully conversant with
the basic properties of Brownian Motion and with Ito’s Lemma.
6 (i) It means that at , bt and ct are known based on information up to but not
including time t.
(ii) The instantaneous change in the value of the portfolio is given by:
dVt = at dAt + dat At + dat dAt + bt dBt + dbt Bt + dbt dBt + ct dCt + dct Ct + dct dCt
(iii) The portfolio is self-financing if the instantaneous change in the value of the
portfolio is equal to the pure investment gain.
VU = aU AU + bU BU + cU CU = X .
(vi) The market is complete if for any contingent claim X there is a replicating
strategy ( at , bt , ct ) .
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
1
1.01 −
q= 1.2 = 0.481818
1
1.2 −
1.2
50 p =
1
1.01 2 (q P
2
uu + 2q(1 − q ) Pud + (1 − q)2 Pdd )
So
(ii) Puu represents the payoff from an option so cannot be negative. Likewise, it
takes its maximum value when Pud and Pdd are zero. So
0 < Puu < 219.70826 p.
(iii) (a) If Puu takes its maximum value then Pud and Pdd are both zero.
If first stock price move is up then the new value of the option is:
qP
V = uu = 104.8113.
1.01
(b) As Pud and Pdd are both zero if the first stock price move is down then
the option will expire worthless.
Many candidates seemed uncomfortable with a basic binary tree calculation, despite these
being well-explained in the Core Reading. Those with some familiarity scored very well.
8 (i)
• Not perfect correlation across maturities.
Firstly, if we look at historical interest rate data we can see that changes in the
prices of bonds with different terms to maturity are not perfectly correlated as
one would expect to see if a one-factor model was correct. Sometimes we even
see, for example, that short-dated bonds fall in price while long-dated bonds
go up.
Recent research has suggested that around three factors, rather than one, are
required to capture most of the randomness in bonds of different durations.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
Secondly, if we look at the long run of historical data we find that there have
been sustained periods of both high and low interest rates with periods of both
high and low volatility. Again these are features which are difficult to capture
without introducing more random factors into a model.
This issue is especially important for two types of problem in insurance: the
pricing and hedging of long-dated insurance contracts with interest-rate
guarantees; and asset-liability modelling and long-term risk-management.
dr ( t ) = α r ( m ( t ) − r ( t ) ) dt + σ r1dW1 ( t ) + σ r 2 dW2 (t )
dm ( t ) = α m ( μ − m ( t ) ) dt + σ m1dW1 ( t )
where r(t) is the short rate, and m(t), the local mean-reversion level for r(t) and
W1 (t ) and W2 (t ) are independent, standard Brownian motions under the risk-
neutral measure Q.
Answers were mixed. Again, knowledge of basic Core Reading made all the difference to
candidates scores on this question.
9 (i) Q(Maxt<1St ≥ 2)
= Q(maxt<1σBt + (r − ½σ2)t ≥ ln 2)
= Q(maxt<1Bt + (r − ½σ2)t/σ ≥ ln 2/σ)
= Φ([−ln 2 + (r − ½ σ2)]/σ) + exp(2(r − ½σ2) ln 2/σ2) Φ(−[ln 2 + (r − ½σ2)]/σ)
= Φ(−2.7776) + 0.9727 × Φ(−2.7676)
= 0.00274 + 0.9727 × 0.00282
= 0.00548
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) (a) Denoting by Q the EMM and by F1 the information available at time 1,
the risk neutral pricing formula gives the following price C1 for the
option at time 1:
C1 = C1 (low) = e−rEQ[100.Max(S2/S1−1;0)|F1]
C1 = C1 (up) = 0
(b) In the case {(Maxt<1 St )< 2}, we need to compute the following
conditional expectation: C1 (low) = e−rEQ[100.Max(S2/S1−1;0)|F1]
(c) Thus, the fair price at time 0 of the option is C0 = E[e−r C11{Maxt<1St < 2}]
where 1{Maxt<1St < 2} is the indicator of the event {Maxt<1St < 2}, so takes
the value 1 if {Maxt<1St < 2} occurs and 0 otherwise.
So C0 = 0.99452e−r C1(low)
C0 = $10.952
This question was very poorly answered, with most candidates unable to cope with path-
dependent option, even though the steps to solution were laid out in the question. Familiarity
with the actuarial tables would also have been helpful.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) – April 2013 – Examiners’ Report
10 (i) In the two state model, the company defaults at time-dependent rate λ(t) if it
has not previously defaulted. Once it defaults it remains permanently in the
default state. It is assumed that after default all bond payments will be reduced
by a known factor (1 − δ), where δ is the recovery rate. Now we need to
change to the risk neutral measure, which will change the default rate to λ′(t ) .
This rate is that implied by market prices.
where R(t) is the effective rate for a ZCB with redemption at t, λs is the risk
neutral default rate at time s and At is the event that there has been no default
by time t.
This was a difficult question and many candidates clearly didn’t know the relevant material.
A smaller number did and consequently performed well.
Page 11
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
Recovery rates on the bonds in the event of default are zero and there are no frictional
costs.
(i) Calculate the risk neutral implied default probability of each bond. [2]
(ii) Calculate the 95% VaR and 95% TailVaR at the end of the year for the
following portfolios, assuming defaults by AA and BB are independent:
2 A non-dividend-paying stock has a current price of S0 = 400 p . Over each of the next
three years its price could increase by 20% (so St +1 = 1.2St ), or decrease by 20% (so
St +1 = St /1.2 ). The continuously compounded risk-free rate is 6% p.a. The stock
price move in each year is independent of the move in other years.
A non-standard derivative pays off S3 after three years, provided that at some point
over three years the stock price has moved up in one year and then immediately down
in the following year. Otherwise, the derivative pays zero.
3 (i) State the three main assumptions of Modern Portfolio Theory. [3]
(ii) Write down equations for the expected return, E and variance, V of a portfolio
of N securities, defining any notation used. [3]
CT8 S2012–2
4 A non-dividend paying stock is currently priced at S0 = £80 . Over each of the next
two three-month periods it is expected to go up by 6% or down by 5% on each period.
The continuously compounded risk free interest rate is 5% p.a.
(i) Calculate the value of a six-month European call option with a strike price of
£82. [5]
(ii) Calculate the value of a six-month European put option with a strike price of
£82.
(iii) Explain whether, if the put option were American, it would ever be optimal to
exercise early. [4]
[Total 14]
6 (i) State the Stochastic Differential Equations for the short rate r(t) in the Vasicek
model and the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model. [2]
(ii) Explain the impact of a movement in the short rate on the volatility term in
both models. [2]
[Total 4]
The continuously compounded risk free rate is 0.5% p.a. The current stock price is
$1.20. Assume all the Black-Scholes assumptions hold.
(i) Calculate the implied volatility for the underlying stock to within 1% p.a. [2]
It is known that in three months Universal Widget Inc will embark on a major
restructuring. It is anticipated that this will double the volatility of the stock price
thereafter.
(ii) Write down a formula in terms of the underlying Brownian motion, Z, for the
stock price in three months’ and in six months’ time. [3]
(iii) Derive the corresponding price of a six month European put on the Universal
Widget Inc stock with strike price $1.20
[6]
[Total 11]
A very highly geared company, Risky plc, has issued zero coupon bonds payable in
three year time for a nominal amount of £3,200m.
The current gross value of the company is £6,979m. The continuously compounded
risk-free interest rate is 2% p.a. and the price of £100 nominal of the bond is £92.603.
An insurance company is offering default insurance on Risky plc. They will charge a
premium of £55,000 for a contract which pays £1m at the end of three years if Risky
plc defaults.
9 Consider a market where there are two risky assets A and B and a risk free asset. Both
risky assets have the same market capitalisation.
(ii) Derive the expressions for the variance of the market portfolio and for the beta
of each asset, in terms of the variance of each asset and of their covariance. [4]
Assume now that the risk-free rate is rf = 10%, the expected return of the market
portfolio is rM =18%, the variance of asset A is 4%, the variance of asset B is 2% and
their covariance is 1%.
(iii) Derive the value for the expected return on asset A and asset B. [4]
(v) Derive the corresponding standard deviation using the Capital Market Line. [2]
[Total 13]
CT8 S2012–4
10 Let A and B be two investment portfolios taking values in [a,b] with cumulative
probability distribution functions of returns FA and FB respectively, and let the
investor’s smooth utility function be U.
(i) Write down the equation that the function U satisfies if the investor prefers
more to less. [1]
(ii) Explain what it would mean for portfolio A to first order stochastically
dominate portfolio B. [2]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2012–5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2012 examinations
Introduction
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and using past papers
as a revision aid and also those who have previously failed the subject.
The Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. The
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, and
will generally base questions around it but are not required to examine the content of Core
Reading specifically or exclusively.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report; other valid approaches are given appropriate credit. For essay-style questions,
particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, the report may contain more points
than the Examiners will expect from a solution that scores full marks.
D C Bowie
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2012
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good and better than on the previous session (April 2012).
Candidates generally found this paper challenging, but well-prepared candidates scored well
across the whole paper and the best candidates scored close to full marks. As in previous
diets, questions that required an element of application of the core reading to situations that
were not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates. The comments
that follow the questions concentrate on areas where candidates could have improved their
performance.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
1 (i) Let the risk neutral default probability for AA be p AA . Consider the equation
of value for a £100 investment in AA:
£106
100 = (1 − p AA ) × + p AA × 0 ⇒ p AA =1.8868%,
1.04
and similarly
£108
100 = (1 − pBB ) × + pBB × 0 ⇒ pBB = 3.7037%.
1.04
£106 p AA
= £106
p AA
£108 pBB
= £108
pBB
(iii) Investing in diversified (i.e. not perfectly correlated) assets generally leads to a
lower dispersion of returns and hence lower risk.
Portfolio (c) is diversified compared to (a) and (b). However, the 95% VaR
for portfolio (c) is higher than for either (a) or (b) where it is zero. So an
increase in VaR could, in this circumstance, correspond to a decrease in risk.
The 95% TailVaR for portfolio (c) is lower than (a) and (b).
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
The question was framed sufficiently openly that candidates could quote values at risk
relative to the maximum return, the expected return or the initial investment. Full marks
were available for any approach if it was followed through correctly although the below sets
out answers relative to the maximum return.
In general, this was poorly answered with candidates struggling to gain more than a few
marks. Some candidates calculated the transition rates in part (i) instead of the probability or
calculated the probabilities assuming a continuous time model. In part (ii), many candidates
calculated VaR and TailVaR using a continuous model instead of the discrete model in the
question. Some candidates confused VaR and variance.
e6% − 1/1.2
q= = 0.62319 [1]
1.2 − 1/1.2
There are eight possible paths the option could take. The paths, probabilities of those
paths, final stock prices and option payoffs are shown in the following table.
If candidates worked in units of £s rather than p, they will have found an answer of
£0.805 (or 80.5p) and full marks were available.
Also, if candidates took a down movement to mean 0.8St rather than St/1.2 then full
marks were available in this case.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
Largely well answered. Some candidates didn’t calculate the price correctly because they
miscalculated the number of paths to the nodes with non-zero payoffs. Some candidates
miscalculated the probability by using e-r rather than er. A few candidates calculated the
probability according to classical probability theory (favourable outcomes / possible
outcomes) rather than risk-neutral.
(a) That investors select their portfolios on the basis of the expect return
and the variance of that return over a single time horizon.
(b) Investors are never satiated. At a given level of risk, they will always
prefer a portfolio with a higher return to one with a lower return.
(c) Investors dislike risk. For a given level of return they will always
prefer a portfolio with lower variance to one with higher variance.
N
RP = ∑xi Ri ,
i =1
N
E = E [ RP ] = ∑xi Ei ,
i =1
The variance is
N
V = Var [ RP ] = ∑ xi x j Cij ,
i , j =1
where Cij is the covariance of the returns on securities i and j and we write
Cii =Vi .
(iii) A portfolio is efficient if the investor cannot find a better one in the sense that
it has both a higher expected return and a lower variance.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
When there are N securities the aim is to choose xi to minimise V subject to the
constraints
Σi xi = 1
and
E = EP, say,
To find the minimum we set the partial derivatives of W with respect to all the xi and
λ and μ equal to zero. The result is a set of linear equations that can be solved.
The usual way of representing the results of the above calculations is by plotting the
minimum standard deviation for each value of EP as a curve in expected return –
standard deviation (E − σ) space. In this space, with expected return on the vertical
axis, the efficient frontier is the part of the curve lying above the point of the global
minimum of standard deviation.
Largely well answered. Some candidates forgot the “single time period” assumption in part
(i) or included simplifying assumptions such as “no transaction charges etc.” as major
assumptions. Some candidates confused efficient portfolios with optimal portfolios.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
S 1 = 84.8
q
S2 = 80.762
q
S 0 = 80 S 1 = 76.194
S2 = 72.562
Payoff
Call at 82 Put at 82
7.888 0
0 1.238
0 9.438
1
e5%/4 −
Now q = 1.05 = 0.55936.
1
1.06 −
1.05
5%
−
(ii) (a) Similarly, p0 = e 2 ⎡(1 − q )2 × 9.438 + 2q (1 − q ) ×1.238⎤ = 2.38248
⎢⎣ ⎥⎦
5%
−
(b) The put-call parity entails c0 + 82e 2 = p0 + 80
Using the value for the call found in question (i), we get p0 = 2.38248.
(iii) Early exercise would happen at time zero or after three months.
At time zero, the value of the American put option is at least as great as the
European put option, i.e. greater than 2.38248. The intrinsic value of the
option is 2. Therefore early exercise is not optimal.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
After three months, if the first move is up the option is out of the money, so
early exercise is not optimal.
After three months, if the first move is down, the intrinsic value of the option
is 82 − 76.19048 = 5.8095. The value of holding on to the option until 6
months is given by
5%
−
e 4
( q ×1.238 + (1 − q ) × 9.438) = 4.7909.
So, it would be optimal to exercise the option early if the first move was
down.
Largely well answered with most candidates earning full marks in parts (i) to (iii). The
majority of candidates discussed whether it was optimal to exercise American put options in
general in part (iv), or even American call options, rather than the particular option in the
question.
The short rate and other interest rates should exhibit some form of mean-reverting
behaviour.
The model should be flexible enough to cope properly with a range of derivative
contracts.
Generally well done as straightforward book work. Some candidates answered this with a
series of questions such as "is it easy to calculate? does it fit historical data?... In this
situation marks were awarded according to the extent that the candidates identified the key
points set out below. Some candidates did write other assumptions like “constant volatility”
or “the share follows geometric Brownian motion”.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
6 (i) Under the risk neutral measure Q the short rate under the Vasicek model has
the dynamics
dr ( t ) = α ( μ − r ( t ) ) dt + σdW (t )
The short rate under the Cox-Ingersoll-Ross model has the dynamics
dr ( t ) = α ( μ − r ( t ) ) dt + σ r (t ) dW (t )
(ii) So, if the short-rate changes, the volatility of the process is unchanged in the
Vasicek model, but it will change in the CIR model (an increase in the short
rate will lead to an increase in the volatility).
Most candidates gained full marks in part (i). Some candidates wrote about how a change in
volatility could affect the short-term rate rather than vice versa. One or two candidates only
included the sigma in the volatility term of the CIR model. Many candidates gave generic
statements about the interest rate models in answer to part (ii), rather than responding to the
question.
(ii) Under the risk free measure, the stock price S0.25 = S0 exp(σ Z0.25 −
0.5σ2(0.25) + 0.25r)
Full marks were available if candidates provided the formulae under the real
world probability measure.
(iii) Since Z has stationary independent increments, S0.5 has the same distribution
as
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
so
In general, this was poorly answered. There was evidence of candidates spending a
significant amount of time in part (i) but many then proceeded with an assumed value for the
volatility and were awarded full marks where they completed parts (ii) and (iii) in a self-
consistent way. Most candidates forgot the volatility doubled between time three and six.
Several candidates managed to calculate a value in part (iii) using their assumed values from
part (i).
8 (i) Merton’s model assumes that a corporate entity has issued both equity and
debt such that its total value at time t is of F(t).
F(t) varies over time as a result of actions by the corporate entity which does
not pay dividends on its equity or coupons on its bonds. Part of the corporate
entity’s value is zero-coupon debt with a promised repayment amount of L at a
future time T. At time T the remainder of the value of the corporate entity will
be distributed amongst the equity holders and the corporate entity will be
wound up.
The corporate entity will default if the total value of its assets, F(T) is less than
the promised debt repayment at time T, i.e. F(T)<L. In this situation, the bond
holders will receive F(T) instead of L and the equity holders will receive
nothing.
This can be regarded as treating the equity holders of the corporate entity as
having a European call option on the assets of the company with maturity T
and a strike price equal to the value of the debt.
The Merton model can be used to estimate either the risk-neutral probability
that the company will default or the credit spread on the debt.
(ii) Under the Merton model, the value at redemption is min(F(T), £3,200m),
where F(t) is the gross value of the company at time t.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
The market value of the equity (i.e. the call option on the company’s assets is
then £6,979m − £2,963.3m = £4,015.7m.
We can calculate the implied volatility of the company’s assets as 29.8%
The risk neutral price for the insurance (ignoring credit risk of the insurer
themselves) is then:
Candidates had no major problems in part (i) describing the Merton model. Some
candidates did confuse the facts that shareholders had a call option while bondholders had a
put, although given put-call parity there are various ways to value these options. Only some
candidates managed to answer part (ii) and some did answer it by reference to valuing a put
option rather than the call in the marking schedule for which full marks were awarded.
(ii) Let rM denote the return of the market portfolio, rA (resp. rB) denote the return
of asset A (resp. asset B).
BetaA = cov(rA,rM)/V(rM)
= (0.5 * V(rA) + 0.5 * cov(rA,rB))/ 0.52 * V(rA) + 0.52 * V(rB)
+ 2 * 0.52 cov(rA,rB)
ri = rf + Betai (rM – rf) where ri is the expected return of asset i (for i = A,B).
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
rP = w0 rf + wM rM
where w0 is the weight of the risk-free asset in the portfolio P and wM is the
weight of the market portfolio in the portfolio P.
where sigmaP (resp. sigmaM) is the standard deviation of the portfolio P (resp.
the market portfolio.
This question posed little difficulty to well-prepared candidates. Some included the risk-free
asset in their answer to part (i). In part (ii), a lot of candidates defined beta in terms of the
market portfolio rather than the risky assets as asked for in the question. Part (iii) posed
little problem for the majority of candidates although some struggled to calculate a
numerical value for beta. Only a handful of candidates included the risk-free asset in part
(iv). The majority only included the risky assets.
10 (i) U ′ ( w) > 0 .
(ii) This means that the probability of portfolio B producing a return below a
certain value is never less than the probability of portfolio A producing a
return below the same value and exceeds it for at least some value of x .
Alternative answer:
b
E [U A ] = ∫ U ( w ) dFA ( w ) ,
a
Page 12
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – September 2012 – Examiners’ Report
b
E [U B ] = ∫ U ( w ) dFB ( w ) .
a
Thus, if A is preferred to B
b b
b
⎡U ( w) ( FA ( w ) − FB ( w ) ) ⎤ − ∫ U ′ ( w ) [ FA ( w ) − FB ( w )]dw.
b
⎣ ⎦a
a
Page 13
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
(iii) Explain what an examination of past option prices tell us about the
assumptions in (i) and (ii). [4]
[Total 9]
2 In a market where the CAPM holds there are five risky assets with the following
attributes per year.
Asset number 1 2 3 4 5
(ii) Deduce the market capitalisation of asset 4 and the betas of all the other assets.
[3]
(iii) Calculate the beta of a portfolio P which is equally weighted in the five assets
and the risk-free asset. [1]
(iv) Explain whether or not this portfolio P lies on the Capital Market Line. [2]
[Total 7]
3 A non-dividend paying stock has a current price of S0 = 150p and trades in a market
which is arbitrage free and has a constant effective risk-free rate of interest r. After
one year the price of the stock could increase to 280p, or decrease to 120p. Over the
following year the price could increase from 280p either to 420p or to 322p. If the
stock price had decreased to 120p, then over the following year it could increase to
168p or decrease to 112p.
(i) Determine the range of values that the annual risk-free rate of interest could
take. [3]
(ii) Calculate the price at time 0 of a non-standard derivative which pays off
( S 2 − 100) 2 at the end of two years. [6]
[Total 9]
CT8 A2012–2
4 Let c be the price of a four- month European call option on a dividend paying share.
Assume the strike price is $30, the underlying is currently valued at $28 and a
dividend of $0.50 is expected in 2 months. The continuously compounded risk-free
rate is constant and equal to 5% p.a.
(i) Derive upper and lower bounds on the price c of this call option, taking into
account the dividend. [5]
The price of a put option with the same underlying, the same strike price and the same
maturity is $3.
5 Let X be a random variable denoting the rate of return on the fund ABC. The
(
distribution of X is N μ, σ2 . )
(i) Define VaRα ( X ) with α ∈ [ 0,1] . [1]
(
VaRα = − μ + σΦ −1 ( α ) )
where Φ denotes the cumulative Normal distribution function.
1
TailVaRα = E ( X |X < VaRα ) . [4]
α
An investor holds £350m invested in ABC, the expected return on the fund is 10%
and the standard deviation of that return is 25%.
(iv) Calculate the VaR and TailVaR of this investment when α = 0.01. [2]
[Total 11]
(ii) State the type of process of which the Vasicek model is a particular example.
[1]
(v) Derive the expected value and the second moment of r(t) for t given. [3]
7 The remuneration package for the CEO of a quoted company in the tax year 2012/13
includes a bonus proportional to the excess of the share price over 100p at
5 April 2013 at a rate of £50,000 per penny.
The company’s Finance Director wants to hedge the cost of this bonus as at 6
April 2012. The share price at that date is S0 = 90p.
The continuously compounded interest rate is 1% p.a. and the share price volatility is
18% p.a.
(i) Explain the bonus in terms of an option on the share price. [2]
(ii) Calculate the hedging portfolio of shares and cash the Finance Director should
hold to hedge the liability for the CEO’s bonus. [3]
The CEO will be liable to tax at 80% on the excess over £1m of this bonus and at
40% up to £1m. The Finance Director realises that if she purchases for the CEO a
portfolio of a call options with a strike of 100p and −b call options with a strike of
120p and gives this portfolio to the CEO on 6 April 2012 then the proceeds will be
liable for tax at only 40%.
(iii) (a) Calculate the values of a and b which ensure that the CEO would
receive the same net bonus. [5]
(b) Calculate the amount this transaction will save the company. [2]
[Total 12]
CT8 A2012–4
8 In a Black-Scholes market, a special option with strike price a and maturity T on an
underlying (non-dividend bearing) stock with price process S, pays 100p at time T if
and only if the stock price at time T, ST, is more than a. Let Ia (x) denote the function
which takes the value 1 if x>a and 0 otherwise.
(i) Write down a formula, in terms of expectation, Ia, and the underlying stock
price, for the price D0(a) at time 0 of this security, specifying any other
notation that you use. [2]
(ii) Write down an equation connecting the price, C0(K) of the call option on S
with maturity T and strike price K, to the price of the special option on S, using
∞
the fact that max(x−k,0) = ∫ I a ( x ) da . [2]
k
(iii) Find a formula for the price of the special option on S, by differentiating the
Black-Scholes formula with respect to K. [3]
Suppose S0 = 110p, the continuously compounded risk-free rate is 1% p.a., and the
volatility of S is 20% p.a.
(iv) Calculate the price for a derivative security which pays S1 − 20p if S1 > 120p
and 0 otherwise. [3]
[Total 10]
9 (i) Describe the two state model for credit ratings and its generalisation to the
Jarrow-Lando-Turnbull model. [4]
Companies A and B are joint investors in a high risk project to build a new space
plane. Each of the two companies’ zero-coupon bonds are modelled according to a
two-state model. Company A’s bonds have a recovery rate of δA = 60%, while
Company B’s have a recovery rate of δB = 50%. All bonds mature in nine months.
Company A’s bonds have a current price of $82 per $100 nominal, Company B’s
bonds have a current price of $79 per $100 nominal. The continuously compounded
risk-free rate is 1.5% p.a.
(ii) Calculate the implied risk-neutral default intensities λA and λB, assuming that
they are constant. [4]
A competitor to the space plane project now starts to sell a derivative security which
pays $100,000 at the end of nine months if and only if both companies default within
the nine months (a double-default). The current price for the derivative is $7900.
(iii) Calculate the implied risk neutral probability of a double-default and the
corresponding constant rate. [2]
(iv) Calculate the maximum price for this derivative, by considering the maximum
possible double-default rate.
[4]
[Total 14]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2012–6
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2012 examinations
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and who are using
past papers as a revision aid, and also those who have previously failed the subject. The
Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. Although
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, the
Examiners are not required to examine the content of Core Reading. Notwithstanding that,
the questions set, and the following comments, will generally be based on Core Reading.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report. Other valid approaches are always given appropriate credit; where there is a
commonly used alternative approach, this is also noted in the report. For essay-style
questions, and particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, this report contains
all the points for which the Examiners awarded marks. This is much more than a model
solution – it would be impossible to write down all the points in the report in the time allowed
for the question.
T J Birse
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
July 2012
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was good and better than on the previous session (September 2011).
Candidates generally found this paper challenging, but well-prepared candidates scored well
across the whole paper and the best candidates scored close to full marks. As in previous
diets, questions that required an element of application of the core reading to situations that
were not immediately familiar proved more challenging to most candidates. The comments
that follow the questions concentrate on areas where candidates could have improved their
performance. Candidates approaching the subject for the first time are advised to concentrate
their revision in these areas and the ability to apply the core reading to similar situations.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
3. The risk-free rate of interest is constant, the same for all maturities and the
same for borrowing or lending.
The candidates who were familiar with the bookwork scored very well.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
2 (i) EM = 9%
(ii)
Asset number 1 2 3 4 5
(iii) βP = 19/24
(iv) P does not belong to the Capital Market Line because (except in degenerate
cases) portfolios on the efficient frontier consist of linear combinations of the
market portfolio and the risk-free asset.
Generally answered well by candidates. Most candidates were able to score full marks on
parts (i) and (ii). The rest of the question proved to be a bit more difficult.
At the current time, this implies that 0.8 < 1 + r < 1.8667 .
q1 S 1 = 280
S2 = 322, payoff is 2222 = 49, 284 .
q3
S 0 = 150 S 1 = 120 S 2 = 168, payoff is 682 = 4, 624 .
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
144 − 112
and q3 = = 0.57143.
168 − 112
1
V= ⎡⎣102, 400q1q2 + 49, 284q1 (1 − q2 ) + 4, 624 (1 − q1 ) q3 + 144 (1 − q1 ) (1 − q3 ) ⎤⎦
(1 + r )2
= 15, 984.
4 (i) Consider a portfolio, A , consisting of a European call on the share and a sum
5% 5%
− −
of money equal to $30e 3 + $0.50e 6 .
After 4 months, portfolio A has a value which is equal to the value of the
underlying share plus the dividend invested for two months, provided that the
share value is above $30. If the value of the share is below $30, then the
payoff from portfolio A is great than that from the share with the dividend
reinvested. So
5% 5%
− −
c + $30e 3 + $0.50e 6 ≥ $28
⇒ c ≥ −$2
The call option gives the holder the right to buy the underlying share for $30.
So the payoff is always less than the value of the share after 4 months.
Therefore the value of the call option must be less than or equal to the value of
the share:
c0 ≤ $28.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
5% 5%
− −
A: one call option plus cash of $30e 3 + $0.50e 6
B: one put option plus one share
After four months both portfolios have value
5%
−
max {$30, S4 months } + $0.50e 6 .
Therefore they should have the same value at any time before 4 months, so
5% 5%
− −
c0 + $30e 3 + $0.50e 6 = $3 + $28,
and so c0 = 1.
Generally answered well by candidates. Most candidates were able to score full marks on
part (i).
α = P ( X < −VaRα )
⎛ X − μ −VaRα − μ ⎞
= P⎜ < ⎟
⎝ σ σ ⎠
⎛ −VaRα − μ ⎞
= P⎜ Z < ⎟
⎝ σ ⎠
⎛ −VaRα − μ ⎞
Therefore = Φ ⎜ ⎟
⎝ σ ⎠
−VaRα − μ
⇒ Φ −1 ( α ) = ,
σ
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
−VaRα
1
=− ∫ xϕμ,σ ( x ) dx
α
−∞
− Φ −1( α )
σ
= −μ − ∫ xϕ0,1 ( x ) dx
α
−∞
σ − Φ −1( α )
= −μ − ⎡⎣ −ϕ0,1 ( x ) ⎤⎦
α −∞
=
σ
α
(
ϕ Φ −1 ( α ) − μ )
(iv) VaR = −£350m [10% − 25% × 2.32635] = £168.56m
⎡ 25% 1 − 2×2.32635 ⎤
1 2
There were typographical errors in the question which should have defined
TailVaRα = E( − X |X < −VaRα ) . Generous consideration was given to all scripts containing
any reasonable attempt in the marking of this question.
( )
ds ( t ) = d r ( t ) eαt =αeαt r ( t ) dt + eαt dr ( t )
= αμeαt dt + σeαt dW ( t ) .
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
t
( )
Thus s ( t ) = s ( 0 ) + μ eαt − 1 + σ ∫ eαs dW ( s ) ,
0
t
and r ( t ) = r ( 0 ) e −αt
(
+ μ 1− e −αt
) + σ∫ e α ( s −t )
dW ( s ) .
0
⎛ t
⎞
( )
E ( r ( t ) ) = E ⎜ r ( 0 ) e −α t + μ 1 − e −α t + σ ∫ eα ( s −t ) dW ( s ) ⎟
⎝ 0 ⎠
Hence,
E ( r ( t ) ) = r ( 0 ) e −α t + μ (1 − e −α t )
⎛⎛ ⎞ ⎞
2
( )
t
E ( r (t )) = E ⎜ r ( 0) e + μ 1 − e ( α ( s −t )
)
dW ( s ) ⎟ ⎟
2
⎜ −α t −α t
+σ ∫ e
⎜⎝ ⎠ ⎟⎠
⎝ 0
( ) = (r ( 0 ) e
t
E (r ( t )
2 −α t
+ μ 1− e( −α t
)) 2
+σ 2
∫e
2α ( s − t )
ds
0
(vi) The process may become negative which is undesirable in a nominal interest
rate model
This was again standard material from the core reading and more successful candidates
tended to score well, although this question proved to be generally challenging.
7 (i) The CEO essentially holds 5,000,000 call options on the stock with strike
100p and maturity 1 year.
so that C = 3.2009p.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
(iii) (a) For 120 > S > 100, we need a and b to satisfy
so a = 5,000,000;
We can then check that the constant terms agree in this equation, too.
(b) The amount saved is the cost of b call options with the higher strike.
So C ′ = .4932p
The saving is 3,333,333 ×.004932 = £16,440.
Question 7 was generally found to be difficult. While part (i) was generally straightforward
for most candidates, parts (ii) and (iii) proved to be very challenging and were only answered
well by the best candidates.
∞
(ii) Since C0(K) = e−rTE[max(ST − K,0)] = e − rT E[ ∫ I a ( ST )da ], we see that
k
∞
C0(K) = ∫k D0 (a )da.
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
(iv) We can decompose the payoff for this security as the sum of a call with strike
120 and 1 special option also with strike 120p.
This question proved to be a bit challenging, despite being well within the syllabus..
9 (i) In the two state model, the company defaults at time-dependent rate λ(t) if it
has not previously defaulted. Once it defaults it remains permanently in the
default state. It is assume d that after default all bond payments will be
reduced by a known factor (1 − δ), where δ is the recovery rate. Now we need
to change to the risk neutral measure, which will change the default rate to
λ′(t ). This rate is that implied by market prices.
and
so
and
(iii) Let p denote the risk-neutral double-default probability, then if V is the price
of the derivative security we have
V = 100,000 e−.75rp,
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
So
(iv) Now we get a double-default when both companies default, so this can’t
happen at rate faster than min(λA, λB) = λB = .68583. This would give rise to a
price for the derivative of V ′ = 100000e−.75r p ′ , where p ′ = 1 − exp(− .75 λB)
= 0.40212 so V ′ = $39,763.
Clearly, we would not be willing to pay more than this for the derivative.
10 (i) APT requires that the returns on any stock be linearly related to a set of factor
indices as shown below
ai and ci are the constant and random parts respectively of the component of
return unique to security i,
The more general result of APT, that all securities and portfolios have
expected returns described by:
The principal strength of the APT approach is that it is based on the no-
arbitrage conditions.
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) – April 2012 – Examiners’ Report
(ii) Weaknesses:
(2) We also need to come up with the correct factor forecasts. The hard part
is the factor forecasts: finding the amount of expected excess return to
associate with each factor. The simplest approach is to calculate a history
of factor returns and take their average. This implicitly assumes an
element of stationarity in the market.
This was standard material from the core reading and more successful candidates tended to
score well, although some struggled to get all points required for full marks.
Page 12
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
A market consists of two assets A and B. Annual returns on the two assets (RA and
RB) have the following characteristics:
(ii) (a) Calculate the proportion that would be invested in each of the two
assets in a minimum variance portfolio.
Where:
(i) Describe three categories of model that could be used to help choose the
factors I1, I2 and I3. [6]
(ii) List examples of the variables that could be used for the factors I1, I2 and I3,
for two of these three categories of model. [2]
[Total 8]
CT8 S2011—2
3 An investor wishes to save for a retirement fund of £100,000 in 10 years’ time. The
instantaneous, constant continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest is 4% per
annum. The investor can purchase shares on a non-dividend paying security with
price St governed by the Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE):
where:
(b) Calculate the amount, A, that the investor would need to invest in
shares to give a 50:50 probability of building up a retirement fund of
£100,000 in 10 year’s time.
[4]
(ii) Calculate the following risk measures applied to the difference between the
value of the fund and £100,000, if the investor invests A.
(a) Variance
(b) Shortfall probability relative to £90,000
(c) 99% Value at Risk
[6]
The investor decides that they do not need more than £100,000 so they write a call
option giving up any upside return above £100,000. They also buy a put option to
remove the downside risk of receiving less than £100,000.
(iii) Calculate the net cost at time zero of purchasing enough shares to give
themselves a 50:50 chance of building up a retirement fund of £100,000,
writing the call option on those shares and buying the put option on the shares.
[2]
[Total 12]
Let St be the spot price of one ton of the asset at time t and let r be the continuously
compounded risk-free rate of interest per annum which is assumed to be constant.
Derive the current price of a forward contract written on one ton of the asset with
maturity T years where (6 months < T < 1 year). [8]
5 (i) List the desirable characteristics of a model for the term structure of interest
rates. [4]
(ii) Write down the stochastic differential equation for the short rate rt under _ in
the Hull-White model. [1]
(iii) Indicate whether or not the Hull-White model shows the characteristics listed
in (i). [4]
[Total 9]
6 Under the real-world probability measure, P , the price of a zero-coupon bond with
maturity T is given by:
⎧⎪ σ2 ⎫⎪
B(t, T) = exp ⎨−(T − t )rt + (T − t )3 ⎬
⎩⎪ 6 ⎭⎪
where rt is the short rate of interest at time t and satisfies the following stochastic
differential equation under the real-world measure P :
(i) Derive a formula for the instantaneous forward rate f(t, T), based on this
model. [2]
(iii) Deduce the stochastic differential equation for rt under the risk-neutral
measure _ defining all terms used. [2]
[Total 8]
CT8 S2011—4
7 A non-dividend-paying stock, St, has a current price of 200p. After 6 months the
price of the stock could increase to 230p or decrease to 170p. After a further 6
months, the price could increase from 230p to 250p, or decrease from 230p to 200p.
From 170p the price could increase to 200p or decrease to 150p. The semi-annually
compounded risk-free rate of interest is 6% per annum and the real-world probability
that the share price increases at any time step is 0.75. Adopt a binomial tree approach
with semi-annual time-steps.
(ii) Calculate, using the state-price deflator from (i), the price of a non-standard
option which pays out max{0, log(S1 − 180)} one year from now. [4]
(iii) State how the answer to (ii) would change if the real-world probability of a
share price increase at each time step was 0.6. [1]
[Total 10]
(i) (a) Explain how the option should be priced after t = 1 (assuming that it is
not exercised at t = 1).
(ii) Denoting the price just after 1 year by p1+, explain why the fair price, p1, at
t = 1, is given by p1 = max(p1+, 500) if S1 < $2 and by p1 = p1+ if S1 > $2. [2]
(iii) (a) Show that a holder should exercise the option at t = 1 if S1 > k for a
suitable value of k.
(i) Calculate the common strike price, quoting any results that you use. [3]
(iii) Construct the corresponding hedging portfolio in shares and cash for 5000 of
the call options. [2]
[Total 9]
10 (i) In the Wilkie model, the force of inflation, I(t), is a mean-reverting AR(1)
process.
(b) Show that the mean of I(t) converges to m, using the formula:
where the Z(t)’s are iid N(0, σ2) random variables and 0 < a < 1.
[4]
(ii) Discuss the differences between and suitability of mean-reverting and random
walk models for share prices, interest rates and inflation. [5]
[Total 9]
CT8 S2011—6
11 (i) Draw a diagram to illustrate the Jarrow-Lando-Turnbull model for credit
default, defining any notation used. [4]
λ1,2 = 1; λ1,3 = 0; λ2,1 = 0.25, λ2,3 = 0.75; λ3j = 0 for all j and λ1,1 = λ2,2 = −1.
It follows that if pi(t) is the probability that the economy is in state i at time t then:
dp1 (t )
= − p1 (t ) + 0.25 p2 (t )
dt
and
dp2 (t )
= p1 (t ) − p2 (t ) .
dt
dh(t )
(ii) (a) Show that = −1.5h(t ).
dt
(iv) (a) Deduce the price under this model for a zero-coupon bond in this
country with a redemption value of 100 and a redemption date in two
years’ time.
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2011—7
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2011 examinations
The Examiners’ Report is written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of helping
candidates, both those who are sitting the examination for the first time and who are using
past papers as a revision aid, and also those who have previously failed the subject. The
Examiners are charged by Council with examining the published syllabus. Although
Examiners have access to the Core Reading, which is designed to interpret the syllabus, the
Examiners are not required to examine the content of Core Reading. Notwithstanding that,
the questions set, and the following comments, will generally be based on Core Reading.
For numerical questions the Examiners’ preferred approach to the solution is reproduced in
this report. Other valid approaches are always given appropriate credit; where there is a
commonly used alternative approach, this is also noted in the report. For essay-style
questions, and particularly the open-ended questions in the later subjects, this report contains
all the points for which the Examiners awarded marks. This is much more than a model
solution – it would be impossible to write down all the points in the report in the time allowed
for the question.
T J Birse
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2011
Subject CT8 introduces the main concepts and principles of financial economics. These are
developed in later subjects in the ST series of exams. This subject combines various types of
skills. In particular, along with CT7, it is one of the first where candidates are expected to
write lengthy passages of reasoned thought, rather than just complete calculations. This is a
skill that will be new to many, and candidates are advised to pay particular attention to the
answers to this type of question by studying many past papers.
The general performance was slightly worse than in April 2011 and candidates found this
paper more challenging, but well-prepared candidates scored well across the whole paper and
the best candidates scored close to full marks. As in previous diets, questions that required an
element of application of the core reading to situations that were not immediately familiar
proved very challenging to most candidates. The comments that follow the questions
concentrate on areas where candidates could have improved their performance. Candidates
approaching the subject for the first time are advised to concentrate their revision in these
areas and the ability to apply the core reading to similar situations.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
1 (i) A portfolio is efficient if the investor cannot find a better one in the sense that
it has the same expected return and a lower variance, or the same variance and
a higher expected return.
(ii) We have:
V = x 2AVA + xB2VB + 2 x A xB C AB
Which is a minimum at
VB − C AB
xA =
VA − 2C AB + VB
= 0.5
So xB = 0.5
Generally candidates scored well on this question. Some students struggled to calculate the
weighting in each asset class or failed to distinguish between the correlation and the
correlation coefficient.
These use observable economic time series as the factors. They could include
factors such as the annual rates of inflation and economic growth, short term
interest rates, the yield on long term government bonds, and the yield margin
on corporate bonds over government bonds. A related call of model uses a
market index plus a set of industry indices as the factors.
Commercial fundamental factor models are available which use many tens of
factors. They are used for risk control by comparing the sensitivity of a
portfolio to one of the factors with the sensitivity of a benchmark portfolio.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
The candidates who were familiar with the bookwork scored very well. Some candidates
were able to score some marks using economic knowledge from subject CT7.
1 −1
d log St = dSt + 2 (dSt ) 2
St 2 St
⎛ σ2 ⎞
= ⎜μ − ⎟⎟ dt + σdZt
⎜ 2
⎝ ⎠
⎛ σ2 ⎞
log St = log S0 + ⎜ μ − ⎟ t + σZt .
⎜ 2 ⎟⎠
⎝
⎪⎧⎛ σ2 ⎞ ⎫⎪
Or, finally, St = S0 exp ⎨⎜ μ − ⎟ t + σZt ⎬ .
⎜ 2 ⎟⎠
⎩⎪⎝ ⎭⎪
⎛ σ2 ⎞
So, St has a lognormal distribution with parameters ⎜ μ − ⎟ t = 0.08875t and
⎜ 2 ⎟⎠
⎝
σ2t = 0.0625t.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
£100, 000
= £41,168 = A
exp(0.08875 ×10 + 0.25 × 0)
2
Var( St ) = e2μt (eσ t − 1) or equivalently,
P(£41,168 S10 < £90,000) = P (S10 < 2.1862) = P (logS10 < 0.7821)
= P((log S10 – 0.8875)/ 0.625 <− 0.1333) = 0.4470
(iii) In this case the investor has removed all risk, so by the principle of no
arbitrage the portfolio will earn the risk free rate. Therefore, the amount they
need to invest at time 0 is:
£100, 000
= £67,032.
e10×4%
Many candidates scored well on part (i) which was a fairly standard proof using Ito's
lemma.
Many struggled with manipulating the log-normal distribution and calculating risk metrics
relating to it.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
4 The proof of this result is an adaptation of that of the standard no arbitrage approach
to pricing forward contracts. For ease of exposition we use 100x% rather than x% in
the calculations.
Portfolio A: entering into the forward contract to receive one ton of the asset at time
T. Its value at time zero is zero, and at time T it is ST − F0T .
Using the absence of arbitrage opportunity, both portfolios should have the same
value at any intermediate time, in particular at time 0. Hence:
( x + r )(T − 12 )
F0T = S0e( x + r )T − ye .
Many candidates struggled with the concept of creating two portfolios using the principle of
no arbitrage. They were unable to apply the core reading to a related situation. The
question was challenging overall, with many candidates struggling to score well.
This was standard material from the core reading and more successful candidates tended to
score well, although some struggled to get all points required for full marks.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
m(t , T ) − rt
γt = ,
S (t , T )
where
Now,
∂B(t , T ) ⎡ σ2 ⎤
= B(t , T ) ⎢ rt − (T − t ) 2 ⎥
∂t ⎣⎢ 2 ⎦⎥
∂B(t , T )
= B(t , T )[−(T − t )]
∂rt
∂ 2 B (t , T )
= B (t , T )(T − t ) 2
∂rt2
and so
μrt
γt = .
σ
(iii) The stochastic differential equation for rt under the risk-neutral measure is
given by
drt =
⎛ μr dt ⎞
= μrt dt + σ ⎜ dZ − t ⎟
⎝ σ ⎠
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
= σdZ .
Question 6 was generally challenging. While part (i) was generally straightforward for most
candidates, part (ii) where application of first principles was necessary was only answered
well by the best candidates.
q (200)q (230)
A2(250) = = 0.742
(0.75 × 1.03) 2
[1 − q (200)][1 − q (170)]
A2(150) = = 3.004
(0.25 ×1.03) 2
V = EP (A2V2)
= 2.784
This question was overall well answered, showing that many candidates have understood the
broad concept of state price deflators. Well- prepared candidates were able to score near full
marks on all three parts of the question.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
Some candidates lost marks through ignoring the semi-annual interest rate. Part (iii) was
designed to test the understanding of the candidates on how option pricing theory works in
practice, but disappointingly many candidates got this part wrong.
8 (i) If the first exercise date has passed then the owner now has a derivative
contract which pays $1000 at time 2 years if and only if the stock price S2 < 2.
pt = EQ[e−r(2−t)C|Ft],
(ii) At t=1 the holder can choose between the value of the residual contract: p1+
and the current immediate exercise reward of $500 if S1 > 2 (and 0 otherwise).
A rational holder will maximise value by choosing whichever has a greater
current value.
There was a typo in the question where the inequalities were the wrong way
around, full credit will be given to students who assumed this part was correct
and had the inequalities the other way around.
In other words, an acceptable answer would be: At t=1 the holder can choose
between the value of the residual contract: p1+ and the current immediate
exercise reward of $500 if S1 < 2 (and 0 otherwise).
(iii) (a) Since the current exercise value increases with S1 and the value of
p1+ decreases with S1, the holder will choose to exercise the option at
t = 1 if and only if the stock price is greater than some critical value k.
(b) At the critical value the holder should be indifferent i.e. we should
have p1+ = $500. So we seek k such that
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
Generally answered well by candidates. Most candidates were able to score full marks on
part (i) and proceed to score well on parts (ii) and part (ii).
10 (i) (a) Mean reversion means that the force of inflation will tend to move
towards its average value.
(b) Denote by i(t) the mean value of I(t), then taking expectations in the
formula, we see that i(t) = m + a(i(t −1) − m)
or i(t) − m = a(i(t − 1) − m). It follows that i(t) − m tends to zero at a
geometric rate.
(ii) A random walk process can be expected to grow arbitrarily large with time.
If share prices follow a random walk, with positive drift, then those share
prices would be expected to tend to infinity for large time horizons.
However, there are many quantities which should not behave like this. For
example, we do not expect interest rates to jump off to infinity, or to collapse
back to zero.
Instead, we would expect some mean reverting force to pull interest rates back
to some normal range. In the same way, while inflation can change
substantially over time, we would expect them, in the long run, to form some
stationary distribution, and not run off to infinity. Similar considerations
apply to the annual rate of growth in share prices.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
In each case, these quantities are not independent from one year to the next;
times of high interest rates or high inflation tend to bunch together i.e. the
models are auto-regressive.
The question was straightforward bookwork. Candidates struggled to score full marks on
part (ii) but were generally able to describe the basic concepts of the two models.
Unfortunately many candidates chose to write extensive details about share price models and
their characteristics rather than focus on the question about the random walk versus mean
reverting models.
11 (i)
λij (t ) are the deterministic transition intensities from state i to state j at time t
under the real world measure P.
(ii) (a) h′(t ) = 2 p1′ (t) − p2′ (t) = − 3p1(t) + 3/2p2(t) = −3/2h(t).
Similarly
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — Examiners’ Report, September 2011
(iv) (a) The bond price is thus e−.04 (1 − p3(2))£100 + p3(2)£60) = £68.729.
Few candidates failed to score well on parts (i) and (ii). In contrast, very few students were
able to apply the results to part (iii) where scores were disappointing and often nil.
Candidates did not understand the relevance of h(t) and k(t) and they may have gotten further
if they had worked with them. Marks were picked up in question (iv) where candidates
continued with the question.
Page 12
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
(ii) Give the four defining characteristics of a Brownian Motion Z, such that
Z0 = 0.
[5]
The correlation between assets 1 and 2 is 0.75; while the correlation between asset 3
and both of the other two assets is zero.
(ii) (a) State the Lagrangian function that can be minimised to find the
minimum variance portfolio associated with a given expected return,
defining any notation used.
3 A securities market has only three risky securities, A, B and C with the following
annual return attributes:
Assume that:
(i) Calculate σM, the standard deviation of the annual return on the market
portfolio. Quote any results that you use. [1]
(iii) Calculate the covariance of the annual returns on each asset with the annual
return on the market portfolio. State any further results that you use. [4]
[Total 7]
CT8 A2011—2
4 (i) Outline the three forms of the efficient market hypothesis. [6]
XYZ has just announced that its profits are up by 52% on last year. On the
announcement XYZ shares fell in price by 20%. Analysts had been predicting a rise
in profits of 65%. A friend says that this shows that the efficient markets hypothesis
is false.
5 Assume that a non-dividend-paying security with price St at time t can move to either
St u or St d at time t + 1. The continuously compounded rate of interest is r, and u >
er > d. A financial derivative pays α if St+1 = St u and β if St+1 = St d.
A portfolio of cash (amount x) and the underlying security (value y) at time t exactly
replicates the payoff of the derivative at time t + 1.
(ii) Derive an expression for the risk-neutral probability of the security having
value St u at time t + 1 in terms of (x + y), r, α and β. [2]
(iii) (a) Calculate the prices of at-the-money call and put options.
(b) Check that the put-call parity holds for this model.
[4]
[Total 10]
A security price, St, is assumed to follow a lognormal model with drift μ = 4.28% per
annum and volatility 12% per annum. The price now is S0 = €1.83. The continuously
compounded risk-free rate of interest is 2% per annum.
(ii) Calculate, as at this date, the probability, p, that (S1 > €2.20). [2]
Someone now offers you an option which will pay €1000 if and only if the stock price
S1 > €2.20. They propose to charge €1000e−0.02p.
(iii) Explain whether or not you would buy this option. [4]
Assume now that the value of 4.28% for μ has been estimated from observations of
the security price over 10 years using the estimator μ′ ={log(S0) − log(S−10)}/10.
(v) (a) Explain how your answer to (iii) would change if you knew that μ <
1.28% rather than 4.28%.
(b) Comment on this in the light of your answer to part (iv)(b). [3]
[Total 15]
7 (a) List five factors that effect the price of a European put option on a non-
dividend paying share.
(b) State how the premium for a European put option would change if each of
these factors increased.
[5]
CT8 A2011—4
8 Assume the Black-Scholes model applies.
(i) State an expression for the price of a derivative security with payoff D at
maturity date T in terms of the risk-neutral measure. [2]
An at the money European call option on a stock has an exercise date one year away
and a strike price of £118.57. The option is priced at £10. The continuously
compounded risk-free rate is 1% per annum.
(b) Calculate the corresponding hedging portfolio in shares and cash for
1000 options on the share, quoting any results that you use.
(iii) Price a put on the same stock with the same expiry date and a strike price of
£110. [2]
The hedging portfolio of the call option has the same value, the same Delta and the
same Vega as the option.
The Delta of the put option is −0.29975 and its Vega is 39.435.
(iv) Determine the hedging portfolio of the call option in terms of shares, cash and
the put option. [4]
[Total 18]
9 In an extension of the Merton model, a very highly geared company has two tiers of
debt, a senior debt and a junior debt. Both consist of zero coupon bonds payable in
three years time. The senior debt is paid before the junior debt.
Let Ft be the value of the company at time t, L1 the nominal of the senior debt and L2
the nominal of the junior debt.
The current gross value of the company is £3.2m. The nominal of the senior debt is
£1.2m and that of the junior debt is £2m. The continuously compounded risk-free rate
is 4% per annum, the volatility of the value of the company is 30% per annum and the
price of £100 nominal of the senior bond is £88.26.
(ii) Calculate the theoretical price of £100 nominal of the junior debt. [6]
[Total 10]
(i) Write down two equations for the price of a zero-coupon bond, one of which
uses the risk-neutral approach to pricing and the other of which uses the state-
price-deflator approach to pricing. [2]
(ii) State the Stochastic Differential Equation (SDE) of the short rate rt under Q
for the Vasicek model and the general type of process this SDE represents. [3]
(iii) Solve the SDE for the short rate rt from (ii). [5]
(iv) Deduce the form of the distribution of the zero-coupon bond price under this
model. [2]
[Total 12]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2011—6
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2011 examinations
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
T J Birse
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
July 2011
Overall the paper was answered well and candidates’ performance was satisfactory. The
comments below each question indicate where candidates had the most difficulty.
3. The risk-free rate of interest is constant, the same for all maturities and
the same for borrowing or lending.
Candidates seemed to know this material well, and had no particular problems with this
question.
2 (i)
• It is assumed that investors select their portfolios on the basis of the
expected return and the variance of that return over a single time horizon.
• Investors are never satiated. At a given level of risk, they will always
prefer a portfolio with a higher return to one with a lower return.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
• Investors dislike risk. For a given level of return, they will always prefer a
portfolio with lower variance to one with higher variance.
(ii) (a) Let the proportion invested in asset i, be xi , with expected return Ei ,
variance Vi and correlation ρ12. Let E be the return on the portfolio of
the three assets and let λ and μ be Lagrange multipliers. Then, the
Lagrangian function W satisfies:
3
W= ∑ xi2Vi + 2ρ12σ1σ2 x1x2 − λ( E1x1 + E2 x2 + E3 x3 − E ) − μ( x1 + x2 + x3 − 1)
i =1
∂W
(b) = 0 ⇒ 72x1 + 108x2 − 4λ − μ = 0
∂x1
∂W
= 0 ⇒ 108x1 + 288x2 − 6λ − μ = 0
∂x2
∂W
= 0 ⇒ 648x3 − 8λ − μ = 0
∂x3
∂W
= 0 ⇒ 4x1 + 6x2 + 8x3 = 5
∂λ
∂W
= 0 ⇒ x1 + x2 + x3 = 1
∂μ
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
Although most candidates could write down the Lagrangian, several missed the factor of 2
in front of the covariance term. The handling of the Lagrangian showed that many
candidates could write down the partial differential equations for optimisation, but were
unable to solve them simultaneously.
3 (i) The market price of risk is (EM − r)/σM so σM = (EM − r)/0.1 = .02/.1 = 20%
(ii) The market portfolio is in proportion to the market capitalisation since every
investor holds risky assets in proportion to that portfolio. Thus the market
portfolio is .2A +.3B + .5C and so EM = .2EA + .3EB + .5EC so
EB = (.053 − .2×.04 − .5×.06)/.3 = 5%.
(iii) Assets all lie on the securities market line, so Ei − r = βi(EM −r), where
βi = Cov(Ri, RM)/Var(RM).
Then Var(RM) = .04 (from part (i)) so Cov(RA, RM) = 0.014, Cov(RB, RM) =
0.034 and Cov(RC, RM) = 0.054.
Strong form EMH: market prices incorporate all information, both publicly
available and also that available only to insiders.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
(ii) Any reasonable comments:-the market was expecting more and reacted
efficiently on the release of insider information. This does suggest that Strong
form EMH doesn’t hold. It doesn’t seem to contradict weak or semi-strong
EMH. However, the price fall could be an over-reaction which would
contradict the semi-strong form.
Part (i) was well-answered by most candidates. In part (ii) the comments on the statement
were disappointingly unclear.
5 (i) Consider an investment of x in cash and y in the stock at time t. Equating the
value of this portfolio to the value of the derivative at time t = 1 we find the
two simultaneous equations:
xer + yu = α,
xer + yd = β.
Rearranging we find:
α −β
y= , and
u−d
β u − αd
x = e−r .
u−d
( x + y )e r − β
So q = .
α −β
y = 55 95 , x = −44 94 , and so x + y = 11 19 .
x = 55 95 , y = −44 94 , and so x + y = 11 19 .
(b) The strike price (for the at-the-money option) is just St = 100.
Therefore, the put-call parity relation holds.
Several candidates misread the question and took y to denote the number of shares rather
than their initial value. There were also a significant number of careless errors in the
calculation.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
6 (i) The lognormal model has independent, stationary normal increments for the
log of the asset price. Thus, if Su denotes the stock price at time u, then
log(St /Ss) ~ N(µ(t − s), σ2(t − s)) where µ is the drift and σ is the volatility
parameter.
(ii) p = P(S1 > €2.20) = P(log(S1/S0) > log(2.2/1.83)) = P(N(0,1) > (log(2.2/1.83)
− .0428)/.12) = 1 − Φ(1.17784) = 0.1194
(iii) No, I would not buy the contract. Assuming the log normal model, we are in a
Black-Scholes market and the fair price for the option is f = EQ[e−.02 C] where
C is the contract value at expiry date, and Q is the EMM. Under the EMM, the
discounted stock price will be a martingale i.e S will be lognormal with drift
.02 − ½ σ2 = .0128 and volatility σ. Now f = €1000e−.02 p′ ,
where p′ = Q(S1 > €2.20), and since S has a smaller drift under Q than under
the real-world measure, this will be a smaller price than I am being offered.
(v) (a) If the true value of µ is <0.0128 then p is smaller than p′ and so the
option is a bargain!
The poorer candidates answered this question in a way that is inconsistent with the Core
Reading, taking the drift parameter to refer to the parameter in the Black Scholes model.
This resulted in incorrect numerical answers.
7 According to the Core Reading the factors and the effect they would have are:
(1) The premium would decrease as the underlying share price increased.
(2) The premium would increase as the strike price increased.
(3) The premium would increase as the time to expiry increased.
(4) The premium would increase as the volatility of the underlying share
increased.
(5) The premium would decrease as interest rates increased.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
(ii) (a) Standard interpolation using the Black-Scholes formula gives σ = 20%
as follows:
Thus σ = 20%.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
(iv) If we have a portfolio of a shares, b puts and m cash we require to match the
value, Delta and Vega of the option. This gives three equations:
(1) aS + bp + m =10
(2) a + b ΔP = ΔC
(3) bVP = VC
This question was generally not well answered, with errors being made in simple
calculations of hedging portfolios.
9 (i) (a) Under the Merton model, the value, Ft, of the firm follows a
Geometric BM under the EMM. It follows that the terminal value of
the debt is min(FT, L1), where Li is the tier i nominal debt (since FT is
available to pay the senior debt).
(b) Subtracting this value from the value of the firm we see that the assets
available to redeem the junior debt are max(FT − L1 ,0). It follows that
the terminal value of the junior debt is min(L2, max(FT − L1 ,0)).
(ii) Using a Black-Scholes approach, the current value of the senior debt is V1 =
E[e−rT min(FT, L1)] = E[e−rT (FT − max(FT − L1,0)] = F0 − C1, where C1 is
the initial value of a call on the value of the firm with strike L1. The current
value of the junior debt is V2 = E[e−rTmin(L2, max(FT − L1 ,0))].
With some notable exceptions, this question was generally very poorly answered.
Candidates were unable to perform calculations related to the Merton model, and were
unable to identify the payoffs from simple contingent contracts.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — Examiners’ Report, April 2011
⎡ ⎤
B (t , T ) = EQ ⎢exp ⎛⎜ − ∫ ru du ⎞⎟ ⏐Ft ⎥
T
⎣ ⎝ t ⎠ ⎦
E P { A(T )⏐Ft }
B (t , T ) =
A(t )
(ii) The dynamics of the short rate rt under Q for the Vasicek model are:
t
Thus st = s0 + μ(eαt − 1) + σ ∫ eαu dZu
0
and consequently
t
rt = e−αtr0 + μ(1 − e−αt) + σ ∫ eα (u −t ) dZu
0
(iv) So rt has a Normal distribution and hence from (i), B(t, T) has a lognormal
distribution.
This question was largely from a section of the core reading with which some candidates
seemed unfamiliar. Candidates need to study the sections relating to interest rate models
more carefully. Candidates who knew the bookwork performed well.
Page 9
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all nine questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate
sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2010 © Institute of Actuaries
1 An investor holds an asset that produces a random rate of return, R, over the course of
a year. The distribution of this rate of return is a mixture of normal distributions,
i.e. R has a normal distribution with a mean of 0% and standard deviation of 10% with
probability 0.8 and a normal distribution with a mean of 30% and a standard deviation
of 10% with a probability of 0.2.
S is the normally distributed random rate of return on another asset that has the same
mean and variance as R.
(iii) Comment on what the variance and shortfall probabilities at both benchmark
levels illustrate about the asset returns, by referring to the calculations in (i)
and (ii). [3]
[Total 10]
3 Discuss whether one-factor models are good models for the short-rate of interest
(instantaneous risk free rate). Include discussion of extensions that may be
considered to improve the model. Illustrate your discussion by defining and referring
to particular models. [10]
Two companies have zero coupon defaultable bonds in issue. Bond A has £2m
nominal in issue. Bond B has £3m nominal in issue. Both bonds redeem in exactly
2 years time.
Under a risk neutral measure, each bond defaults (not necessarily independently) at a
constant rate. Both bonds have a 60% recovery rate.
CT8 S2010—2
Assume:
(iii) Evaluate the two default rates (under a risk-neutral measure). [4]
There is also a traded derivative security, D, priced at £52 which pays £100 after
2 years if (and only if) at least one of the bonds defaults.
(iv) (a) Determine a hedging portfolio for the security which pays £100 after
2 years if and only if both bonds default by considering fixed
portfolios consisting of bond A, bond B and security D and a risk-free
zero-coupon bond paying £100 at redemption in exactly 2 years.
(b) Calculate the fair price for the security that pays £100 if and only if
both bonds default.
[8]
[Total 23]
A European call option on a stock has an exercise date one year away and a strike of
£6. The underlying stock has a current price of £5.50. The option is priced at 60p.
The stock price volatility has been estimated from other option prices as 20%.
(ii) Estimate the risk free rate of interest to within 0.5% p.a. assuming the Black-
Scholes model applies. [5]
A new derivative security has just been written on the underlying stock. This will pay
a random amount D in one year’s time, where D = S12.
(iii) Calculate the fair price for this new derivative security, quoting any further
results that you use. [5]
(iv) Determine the initial hedging portfolio (in units of the underlying stock and
cash) for this new derivative security. [4]
[Total 16]
where:
7 (i) Define delta, gamma and vega for an individual derivative. [3]
(ii) Explain how gamma and vega can be used in the risk management of a
portfolio that is delta-hedged. [4]
[Total 7]
8 Consider a particular stock and denote its price at any time t by St . This stock pays a
dividend D at time T ' .
Let Ct and Pt be the price at time t of a European call option and European put option
respectively, written on S, with strike price K and maturity T ≥ T ' ≥ t . The
instantaneous risk-free rate is denoted by r.
Prove the put-call parity in this context by adapting the proof of standard put-call
parity.
[Hint: assume that when the dividend is paid it is used to pay off any borrowed
positions required as part of the proof.] [7]
CT8 S2010—4
9 Consider a two-period binomial model for a non-dividend paying stock whose current
price is S0 = 100. Assume that:
• over each of the next six-month periods, the stock price can either move up by a
factor u = 1.2 or down by a factor d = 0.8
(ii) Calculate the price of a standard European call option written on the stock S
with strike price K = 100 and maturity one year. [5]
Consider a special European call option with strike price K = 100 and maturity one
year. The owner of such an option has the right to exercise her option at the end of
the year only if the stock price goes above the level L = 130 during or at the end of
the year.
(b) Comment on the relationship between the price of the special call
option and the option in (ii). [4]
[Total 11]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2010—5
INSTITUTE AND FACULTY OF ACTUARIES
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2010 examinations
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
T J Birse
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2010
Prob(R < 0) = 0.8 * N(0; 0, 10%) + 0.2 * N(0; 30%, 10%) = 0.8 * 0.5 + 0.2 *
0.00135 = 0.4 + 0.00027 = 0.40027
Prob(R < −10%) = 0.8 * N(−10%; 0, 10%) + 0.2 * N(−10%; 30%, 10%) = 0.8
* 0.1587 + 0.2 * 0 = 0.1269
2 (i) Excessive volatility is when the change in market value of stocks (observed
volatility), cannot be justified by the news arriving. This is claimed to be
evidence of market over-reaction which was not compatible with efficiency.
2. Abnormal excess returns for both the parent and subsidiary firms
following a de-merger. Another example of the market being slow to
recognise the benefits of an event.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — September 2010 — Examiners’ Report
3 One-factor models
All are arbitrage-free.
Vasicek: easy to implement but problem of possible negative interest rates
CIR: more tricky to implement but positive rates (for suitable choice of parameter
values).
HW: more flexible as time-inhomogeneous, so better fit to market data (in particular
option prices)., but negative rates are possible
Limitations:
1) historical data shows changes in the prices of bonds with different terms to
maturity are not perfectly correlated
2) there have been sustained periods of both high and low interest rates with
periods of both high and low volatility
3) we need more complex models to deal effectively with more complex derivative
contracts e.g. any contract which makes reference to more than one interest rate
should allow these rates to be less than perfectly correlated
Multiple-factor models: to capture more features of market data, better for pricing
exotic derivatives.
There is no perfect model. A good model depends on the data available and the use of
the model (basic assets, plain vanilla derivatives, more exotic derivatives, short or
long maturities…).
4 (i) (a) A credit event is an event which will trigger the default of a bond and
includes the following:
(b) The outcome of a default may be that the contracted payment stream
is:
• rescheduled
• cancelled by the payment of an amount which is less than the
default-free value of the original contract
• continues but at a reduced rate
• totally wiped out
[any three of the above]
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — September 2010 — Examiners’ Report
(c) In the event of a default, the fraction of the defaulted amount that can
be recovered through bankruptcy proceedings or some other form of
settlement is known as the recovery rate.
(ii) The model is in continuous time; it has two states N (not previously defaulted)
and D (previously defaulted).
Under this simple model it is assumed that the default-free interest rate term
structure is deterministic with r(t) = r for all t.
(iii) The formula for the unit ZCB price is e−rT(1 − (1 − δ)(1 − e−λ(i)T)), where δ is
the recovery rate and λ(i) is the (constant) default rate for bond i and T is the
redemption time.
Thus
so λ(A) = 0.2361
and
λ (B) = 0.4029
If this is to perfectly hedge the security then its value at time 2 should
be zero unless both bonds default, in which case it should be 100.
100a + 100b + c = 0;
60a + 100b + 100d + c =0;
100a + 60b + 100d + c = 0
60a + 60b + 100d + c = 100
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — September 2010 — Examiners’ Report
(b) Since this is a perfect hedge, the initial value of the hedging portfolio is
the fair price for the new security, so the fair price is
500e−0.06 − 250(1.6/2) − 250(2.2/3) − 52 = £34.55
(iv) The amount of stock to hold in the hedging portfolio is Delta = ∂f/∂S, where f
is the price as a function of current stock price S. Thus the initial hedging
portfolio holds 2S0exp(r + σ2)=13.235 units of stock and is short £S02exp(r +
σ2) =£36.40.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — September 2010 — Examiners’ Report
∂f ∂f
Δ= ≡ (t, St ).
∂s ∂s
∂2 f
Γ=
∂s 2
ν = ∂f
∂σ
(ii) If the portfolio is Delta-hedged and has a high value of Γ then it will require
more frequent rebalancing or larger trades than one with a low value of
gamma. The need for rebalancing can, therefore, be minimised by keeping
gamma close to zero.
The value of a portfolio with a low value of vega will be relatively insensitive
to changes in volatility. Since σ is not directly observable, a low value of
vega is important as a risk-management tool. Furthermore, it is recognised
that σ can vary over time. Since many derivative pricing models assume that
σ is constant through time the resulting approximation will be better if ν is
small.
8 The proof of this result is an adaptation of that of the standard call-put parity. Two
(self-financing) portfolios are considered:
• Portfolio A: buying the call and selling the put at time t. Its value at time t is
Ct – Pt and at time T, it is ST − K in all states of the universe.
Using the absence of arbitrage opportunity, both portfolios should have the same
value at any intermediate time, in particular at time t. Hence:
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — September 2010 — Examiners’ Report
144
120
100 96
80
64
(ii) To price the call option, we use the risk-neutral pricing formula. We use the
following simplifying notation:
( ) ( )
+ + +
Cuu = u 2 S0 − K = 44 ; Cud = ( udS0 − K ) = 0 ; Cdd = d 2 S0 − K = 0.
(iii) (a) Only one path is relevant for this barrier option “up-up”. Its
probability of occurrence is q2 and the associated payoff is Xuu = 44.
Using the risk-neutral valuation formula, we get:
( )
X 0 = exp ( −2r ) q 2 X uu = 16.72
(b) In practice this option “clearly” has less value than the option (ii)
because it pays off in fewer cases. However it has the same price
when calculated using the binomial tree approach – this reinforces the
need for choosing binomial trees carefully when pricing derivatives.
Page 7
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all nine questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate
sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2010 © Institute of Actuaries
1 Let ( X t ; t ≥ 0 ) be a stochastic process satisfying:
t t
X t = X 0 + ∫ μ s ds + ∫ σ s dWs
0 0
(ii) Prove that the solution of this stochastic differential equation is given by:
t
X t = X 0 exp ( −γt ) + σ ∫ exp ( γ ( s − t ) ) dWs [6]
0
[Total 8]
2 Consider a stock paying a dividend at a rate δ and denote its price at any time t by St .
The dividend earned between t and T, T ≥ t, is St (eδ(T −t ) − 1) .
Let Ct and Pt be the price at time t of a European call option and European put option
respectively, written on the stock S, with strike price K and maturity T ≥ t . The
instantaneous risk-free rate is denoted by r.
Prove put-call parity in this context by adapting the proof of standard put-call parity
that applies to put and call options on a non-dividend paying stock. [8]
CT8 A2010—2
3 Consider a two-period binomial model for a non-dividend paying stock whose current
price is S0 = 100. Assume that:
• over each six-month period, the stock price can either move up by a factor u = 1.2
or down by a factor d = 0.8
(ii) Calculate the price of a standard European call option written on the stock S
with strike price K = 100 and maturity one year. [5]
Consider a special type of call option with strike price K = 100 and maturity one
year. The underlying asset for this special option is the average price of the stock
over one year, calculated as the average of the prices at times 0, 0.5 and 1 measured in
years.
(iii) Calculate the initial price of this call option assuming it can be exercised only
at time 1. [5]
[Total 12]
4 Consider the following stochastic differential equation for the instantaneous risk free
rate (also referred to as the short-rate):
dr (t ) = a ( b − r (t ) ) dt + σdWt
t
r ( t ) = r0 exp ( −at ) + b (1 − exp ( −at ) ) + σ exp ( −at ) ∫ exp ( as ) dWs
0
T
1 − exp ( −a (T − t ) ) σ
T
∫ r ( u )du = b (T − t ) + ( r (t ) − b ) a a
( )
+ ∫ 1 − exp ( −a (T − s ) ) dWs
t t
(i) Derive the price at time t of a zero-coupon bond with maturity T. [10]
(ii) (a) State the main drawback of such a model for the short-rate.
(i) Estimate the stock price volatility to within 0.5% p.a. assuming the Black-
Scholes model applies. [5]
A new derivative security has just been written on the underlying stock. This will pay
a random amount D in one year’s time, where D is 100 times the terminal value of the
call option capped at 1p (i.e. 100 times the lesser of the terminal value and 1p).
(ii) (a) State the payoff for this derivative security in terms of two European
call options.
(iii) Calculate the risk neutral probability that the stock price is greater than 320p.
[4]
[Total 14]
6 (i) Describe the-two state model for credit ratings under the real world measure.
[9]
(ii) Explain how the two state model is generalised in the Jarrow-Lando-Turnbull
model. [3]
[Total 12]
(ii) Derive the value of a which makes exp(σBt – at) a martingale when B is a
standard Brownian Motion. [3]
A derivative security written on this stock in the same market has price:
CT8 A2010—4
8 Outline the main points you would make in a discussion of the statement:
The efficient markets hypothesis states that the market price is always correct and
therefore it is not possible for investors to make money from investing in shares.
[10]
9 An asset is worth 100 at the start of the year and is funded by a senior loan and a
junior loan of 50 each. The loans are due to be repaid at the end of the year; the
senior one with interest at 6% p.a. and the junior one with interest of at 8% p.a.
Interest is paid on the loans only if the asset sustains no losses.
Any losses of up to 50 sustained by the asset reduce the amount returned to the
investor in the junior loan by the amount of the loss. Any losses of more than 50
mean that the investor in the junior loan gets 0 and the amount returned to the investor
in the senior loan is reduced by the excess of the loss over 50.
The probability that the asset sustains a loss is 0.25. The size of a loss, L, if there is
one, follows a uniform distribution between 0 and 100.
(i) Calculate the variances of return for the investors in the junior and senior
loans. [8]
(ii) Calculate the shortfall probabilities for the investors in the junior and senior
loans, using the full return of the amounts of the loans as the respective
benchmarks. [2]
[Total 10]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2010—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
R D Muckart
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
July 2010
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
∂f (t , X t ) ∂f (t , X t ) 1 ∂ 2 f (t , X t )
df (t , X t ) = dt + dX t + ( dX t )2
∂t ∂x 2 ∂x 2
1 ∂ 2 f (t , X t ) 2
=
∂f (t , X t )
∂t
dt +
∂f (t , X t )
∂x
( μt dt + σt dWt ) +
2 ∂x 2
(
σt dt )
⎛ ∂f (t , X t ) ∂f (t , X t ) 1 ∂ 2 f (t , X t ) 2 ⎞ ∂f (t , X t )
= ⎜ + μt + σ ⎟ dt + σt dWt
⎜ ∂ t ∂ x 2 ∂ 2 t ⎟ ∂ x
⎝ x ⎠
Then
Thus
t
Ut = U0 + σ ∫ e γs dWs
0
and consequently
t
+ σ ∫ e ( ) dWs
−γt −γt γ s −t
Xt = e Ut = X 0e
0
2 The proof of this result is an adaptation of that of the standard call-put parity. Two
(self-financing) portfolios are considered:
• Portfolio A: buying the call and selling the put at time t. Its value at time t is
Pt − Ct and at time T, it is ST − K in all states of the universe.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
Using the absence of arbitrage opportunity, both portfolios should have the same
value at any intermediate time, in particular at time t. Hence:
Ct − Pt = St exp ( −δ (T − t ) ) − K exp ( −r (T − t ) ) .
3 (i) There is no arbitrage in the market since d = 0.8 < exp(0.05) < u = 1.2.
(ii) To price the call option, we use the risk-neutral pricing formula. We use the
following simplifying notation:
( )
+
Cuu = u 2 S0 − K = 44;
+
Cud = ( udS0 − K ) = 0;
( )
+
Cdd = d 2 S0 − K = 0.
exp ( r ) − d
q= = 0.628 .
u−d
At time 0,
C0 = exp ( −r ) ⎡⎣ qC1 (u ) + (1 − q ) C1 (d ) ⎤⎦ .
Hence
C0 = 15.71 .
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
(iii) For the special option, we need to compute the average for the different
possible trajectories, the probability of each path and the associated payoff:
( +
X 0 = exp ( −2r ) q 2 ( X uu − K ) + q (1 − q ) ( X ud − K )
+
) = 8.744 .
4 (i) The price of a zero-coupon bond can be written as
⎡ ⎛ T ⎞ ⎤
B (t , T ) = E ⎢ exp ⎜ − ∫ r ( s )ds ⎟ Ft ⎥ .
⎢ ⎜ ⎟ ⎥
⎣ ⎝ t ⎠ ⎦
T
Since ∫ r ( u )du is a Gaussian random variable, we can compute explicitly the
t
price of the zero-coupon bond in terms of the expected value and variance
T
(conditional) of ∫ r ( u )du :
t
⎡ ⎡T ⎤ 1 ⎡T ⎤⎤
B (t , T ) = exp ⎢ − E ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ + V ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ ⎥
⎢ ⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ 2 ⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ ⎥⎦
⎣
⎡T ⎤ ⎛ 1 − exp ( − a (T − t ) ) ⎞
where E ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ = b (T − t ) + ( r ( t ) − b ) ⎜ ⎟ and
⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ ⎜ a ⎟
⎝ ⎠
⎡T ⎤ σ2 σ2 2σ 2
( ) (
V ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ = 2 (T − t ) − 3 exp ( −2a (T − t ) ) − 1 + 3 exp ( −a (T − t ) ) − 1 .
⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ a 2a a
)
(ii) Main issue: possibility to have negative interest rates when using the Vasicek
model. An alternative is the CIR model:
dr (t ) = a ( b − r (t ) ) dt + σ r ( t )dWt .
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
5 (i) Try σ = 10%. Black Sholes formula gives a price of p10 = 44.05.
Try σ = 40%. Black Sholes formula gives a price of p40 = 76.05.
p21.9 = 54.75.
Using the Black-Scholes formula, the price of the second call option is 52.06p
(iii) The option essentially pays £1 if the final security price is greater than 320p.
Thus its price is approximately e−rP(S1 > 320) (where P is the EMM).
So
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
6 (i) A model can be set up, in continuous time, with two states N (not previously
defaulted) and D (previously defaulted). Under this simple model it is
assumed that the default-free interest rate term structure is deterministic with
r(t) = r for all t. If the transition intensity, under the real-world measure P,
from N to D at time t is denoted by λ(t), this model can be represented as:
λ(t)
No default, N Default, D
If X(t) is the state at time t. The transition intensity, λ(t), can be interpreted as:
⎛ T ⎞
PrP(X(T) = N | X(t) = N) = exp ⎜ − ∫ λ s ds ⎟
⎜ ⎟
⎝ t ⎠
⎛ T ⎞
PrP(X(T) = D | X(t) = N) = 1 − exp ⎜ − ∫ λ s ds ⎟
⎜ ⎟
⎝ t ⎠
⎧0 if τ > t ,
N(t) = ⎨
⎩1 if τ ≤ t.
Then τ can be interpreted as the time of default and N(t) can be interpreted is
the number of defaults up to and including time t.
It is assumed that if the corporate entity defaults all bond payments will be
reduced by a known, deterministic factor (1 − δ) where δ is the recovery rate,
i.e. for a zero-coupon bond which is due to pay 1 at time T, the actual
payment at time T will be 1 if τ > T and δ if τ ≤ T.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
⎛ ⎛ ⎛ T ⎞⎞⎞
P ( t , T ) = B ( t , T ) ⎜1 − (1 − δ ) ⎜1 − exp ⎜ − ∫ λ s ds ⎟ ⎟ ⎟
⎜ ⎜ ⎜ ⎟⎟⎟
⎝ ⎝ ⎝ t ⎠⎠⎠
Where P(t,T) is the price at time t of a risky zero-coupon bond and B(t,T) is
the price at time t of a risk-free zero-coupon bond.
(ii) A more general and more realistic model with multiple credit ratings rather
than the simple default/no default model, used above was developed by
Jarrow, Lando and Turnbull. In this model there are n – 1 credit ratings plus
default.
λ2j(t) j
2 λj2(t)
λj,n-1(t)
λn-
λ12(t) ()
λ21(t)
1 n-
1
λ2n(t)
λ1n(t) λn-1,n(t)
In this n-state model transfer is possible between all states except for the
default state n, which is absorbing.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
(1) Write the martingale condition and consider the expected value of the
process at time t, conditional on the filtration up to an earlier time s.
(2) Write Ito’s formula for the function f(t,Bt) = exp(sigma Bt – at), and set
the drift term equal to 0.
(iii) We know that e−rt St is a martingale under the EMM and so is e−rtDt. So,
setting Wt = Bt + ct we can write e−rt St = S0exp(0.2Wt − (r + 0.2c − 0.2)t) and
we require r + 0.2c − 0.2 = 1/2(0.2)2 = 0.02.
8
• EMH states that market fully reflects all available information and the implication
is therefore that investors are not able to make “excess” returns (rather than any
returns at all!).
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
• Investors taking higher risks may earn higher returns – this does not contradict the
EMH.
• EMH does not specify how information is priced, so very difficult to test.
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2010 — Examiners’ Report
Alternative answers:
J = 0.08 with probability 0.75, −1 with probability 0.25 * 0.5 and U − 1 with
probability 0.25 * 0.5 with U uniformly distributed over [0,1]
The expected value is then E(J) = −0.1275 and the variance is V(J) = 0.1552
S = 0.06 with probability 0.75, 0 with probability 0.25 * 0.5 and U − 1 with
probability 0.25 * 0.5 with U uniformly distributed over [0,1].
The expected value is then E(S) = −0.0025 and the variance is V(S) = 0.0441.
Page 10
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2009 © Institute of Actuaries
1 (i) State the general form of the equation used in multifactor models of security
returns, defining any terms you use. [3]
(ii) Describe the different categories of factors that are used in these models and
illustrate your answer with suitable examples. [6]
[Total 9]
2 (i) In the context of time series models of financial markets explain the difference
between cross-sectional and longitudinal properties of statistical distributions.
[2]
3 A small bank wishes to improve the performance of its investments by investing £1m
in high returning assets. An investment bank has offered the bank two possible
investments:
The chief executive of the bank says that if one investment has a better expected
return and a lower variance than the other then it is the best choice.
(i) (a) Calculate the expected return and variance of each investment A
and B.
CT8 S2009—2
(ii) Calculate the following risk measures for each of the two investments A and
B:
(iii) (a) Define other suitable risk measures that could be calculated.
(b) Discuss what the risk measures in (iii) (a) would show. [4]
(i) State the expected return and variance of his portfolio. Define any notation
you use. [2]
Securities with the properties in the table below are available to an investor. The
statistics in the table refer to the next year.
A B
Expected return 4% 3%
Variance of return 16%% 4%%
Correlation coefficient between assets ρAB = 1
(ii) Calculate the relative amount which should be invested in each security to
give a portfolio with the minimum possible variance. (Note: you may assume
that short selling securities is allowable.) [4]
(iii) Show that if it is possible to borrow at the rate of 1% p.a. over the next year, it
is possible for the investor to make a risk free profit over the year without
using any of his own capital. [4]
[Total 10]
Assume that S satisfies St = S0exp(σ Bt + (r −1/2 σ2)t) under the risk neutral measure,
where B is a standard Brownian motion and r is the risk-free rate of interest.
(i) Derive the probability density of max0≤s≤t Bs + μs. (Hint: use the formula in
section 7.2 of the Formulae and Tables for Actuarial Examinations). [4]
(ii) Determine an expression for pt, the fair price of the derivative security at time
t. You need not evaluate the resulting integral. [4]
[Total 8]
In a two state model a zero-coupon defaultable bond is due to redeem at par in two
years’ time. If default occurs the recovery rate is δ. The continuously compounded
risk free rate of return is r, Under the probability measure Pλ, the default intensity is
constant and equal to λ and the defaultable bond price is Dt, given by:
(ii) Show that Pλ is an equivalent martingale measure for this model. [3]
A derivative contract pays $1,000 after two years if and only if the bond has
defaulted.
(iii) (a) Determine a constant portfolio in the defaultable bond and cash which
replicates the derivative.
(iv) Explain how your answer to (iii) relates to the fact stated in part (ii). [3]
[Total 15]
7 (i) State the main assumptions underlying the Black-Scholes model for a security
price. [4]
CT8 S2009—4
8 (i) Define a state-price deflator in the context of continuous time models for
security prices. [3]
(ii) Give a formula for the state-price deflator in the Black-Scholes model when
the risk-free rate of interest is r and the stock price satisfies:
A derivative contract pays exp(γZ1) if Z1 > 1, and zero otherwise, where Z0 = 0 and γ
= (μ − r) / σ.
(iii) Calculate the price pt, at each time t, of this derivative contract, using your
answer to part (ii), or otherwise. [5]
[Total 11]
11 (i) Define the market price of risk in the context of pricing zero coupon bonds
using diffusion models for the short-rate of interest. Define any notation you
use. [2]
(ii) Prove that the market price of risk at a given time t is constant for all zero-
coupon bonds with maturities T > t in the case where the diffusion model for
the short-rate of interest has only one factor. Define any notation you use. [5]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2009—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINERS REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
R D Muckart
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2009
Comments for individual questions are given with the solutions that follow.
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
1
(i) Ri = ai + bi,1 I1 + bi,2 I2 + .......+ bi,L IL + ci
Where
ai and ci are the constant and random parts respectively of the component of
return unique to security i.
I1 ........ IL are the changes in a set of L factors which explain the variation in Ri
about the expected return.
Examples: rate of inflation, economic growth, short term interest rates, yields
on long-term government bonds, yield margin on corporate bonds over
government bonds.
Examples: level of gearing, price earnings ratio, the level of R & D spending,
the industry group to which the company belongs
These indices are unlikely to have any meaningful economic interpretation and
may vary considerably between different data sets.
2
(i) Cross-sectional property fixes a time horizon and looks at the distribution over
all the simulations. E.g. what will inflation be next year? The estimates are
implicitly conditional on past information. They can be deduced from prices
of options and other derivatives.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
Longitudinal property looks at the distribution over a long period of time. E.g.
what will the distribution of inflation be over the next 1000 years? Unlike
cross sectional properties does not reflect market conditions at a particular
time.
(ii)
a. Estimates are the same — random walk returns are independent across
years.
b. The main point is longitudinal volatilities are higher. Longitudinal
volatilities represent unconditional values whilst cross-sectional
volatilities depend on the information set. The difference between the
two shows the value of extra information. Over long horizons the two
values converge to the same point. Students might draw a graph similar
to that on Unit 6 page 13.
Equity Price and Real Dividend Volatility
20%
12%
10%
8%
6%
4%
2%
0%
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44 46 48 50
Time (years)
3
(i) Investment A
Expected return = E[0.1 + N] = 0.1 + 1 = 1.1
Variance = 1
Investment B
Expected return = 1.5 0.99 5.0 0.01 = 1.435
Variance = (1.435 1.5)2 0.99 + (1.435 – ( 5))2 0.01 = 0.418275
Investment B has both higher expected return and lower variance so would be
preferred on this basis. However there is an issue with the possibility of very
bad returns. Also there might be an issue with the estimated probabilities of
investment B being somewhat unreliable as they are probably derived from the
fat tail part of a distribution. Thus it might be wise to have a margin of error
regarding this calculation in particular.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
(ii)
a. Investment A
Semivariance = 0.5
Investment B
Semivariance = (1.435 –( 5))2 0.01 = 0.41409
b. Investment A
Shortfall probability of return below 0.
This is probability of the return from N(1,1) being below
0.1 = 0.13567.
Investment B
Shortfall probability of return below 0 is 0.01.
c. Investment A
Shortfall probability of return below 2.
This is probability of the return from N(1,1) being below
2.1 = 0.00097.
Investment B
Shortfall probability of return below –2 is 0.01.
(iii) Definitions of VAR, Tail VaR and Expected Shortfall. (Unit 1, page 3)
Clearly will show high but unlikely risk in the tail of Investment B.
Might not always be best to optimise on basis of expected return and variance.
Variance is i j xi xj Cij
where Cij is the covariance of the returns on securities i and j and Cii = Vi
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
(Unit 2 page 2)
From (Unit 2 page 3) or can fairly easily be calculated from first principles
Now if we borrow at 1% p.a. can invest in the portfolio in (ii) make a return of
2% pay back the loan and will have make 1% over the year.
5
(i) The formula states that
–d/dy( (( y + t) / t) + e2 y ( (y + t) / t))
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
(ii) We need to price the derivative under the risk neutral measure. Under this
measure,
6
(i) The model is a continuous time Markov with two states: N (not previously
defaulted) and D (previously defaulted). Under this simple model it is
assumed that the default-free interest rate term structure is deterministic with
r(t) = r for all t. If the transition intensity, under the real-world measure P,
from N to D at time t is denoted by λ(t), this model can be represented as:
(t)
No default, N Default, D
If X(t) is the state at time t, the transition intensity, λ(t), can be interpreted as:
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
(iii) Seeking a portfolio of the form aD + bB, we need the value to be 1000 at time
2 if default has occurred, so we need a + b = 1000. Similarly we need the
value to be zero at time 2 if default has not occurred, so we need a + b = 0.
Hence b = a and b = 1000/(1 ).
The fair price for the derivative must be the set-up cost for this portfolio which
is be-2r +aD0=1000/(1 )( e-2r- e 2r( (1 e 2 ) + e 2 ))=1000 e-2r(1- e 2 )
(iv) We need to check that the initial value of this portfolio is E[e 2rV] under P :
under P , E[e 2rV]= 1000e 2rP(default)= 1000e 2r(1- e 2 ) as required (V is
the final value of the derivative).
This then accords with the fact that if we can hedge without arbitrage
then the price is that given by the EMM
7
(i) The assumptions underlying the Black-Scholes model are as follows:
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
Distributions of share returns tend to have fatter tails than suggested by the
log-normal model, invalidating assumption 1.
8
(i) A corollary to the Cameron-Martin-Girsanov theorem states that there exists a
process t such that, for any FT -measurable derivative payoff X at time T ,
EQ [ X Ft ] EP T X Ft
t
rt
Define At e t
(ii) If we define t = exp( Zt ½ 2t), where = ( r)/ , then the state price
deflator is At = te rt. [3]
(iii) If a contract has terminal value V then its price at time t is EP[ATV/At|Ft]. So in
this case we obtain
9
The real-world probability measure P can be interpreted in the following way. Let A
be some event contained in F (for example, suppose that A is the event that S1 is
greater than or equal to 100). Then P( A) is the actual probability that the event A
will occur. On a more intuitive level with m independent realisations of the future
instead of one we would find that the event A occurs on approximately a proportion
P( A) occasions (with the approximation getting better as m gets larger and larger).
Two measures P and Q which apply to the same sigma-algebra F are said to be
equivalent if for any event E in F : P( E ) 0 if and only if Q( E ) 0 , where P( E )
and Q( E ) are the probabilities of E under P and Q respectively.
In the context of the binomial model and using the above definition of equivalence the
only constraint on the real-world measure P is that at any point in the binomial tree
the probability of an up move lies strictly between 0 and 1. The only constraint on Q
is the same but this can be equated to the requirement that the risk-free return must lie
strictly between the return on a down move and the return on an up move. This gives
us considerable flexibility in the range of possible equivalent measures.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
10
Consider an investor holding an American call. She needs some cash at time t T .
Two strategies are available for her:
(i) She sells the options on the market and gets the price of it in exchange CtA ,
(ii) She exercises the option and obtains the intrinsic value St K.
As a consequence, the first strategy is better and it is never optimal for the agent to
exercise her option early.
11
(i) B(t,T) = Zero-coupon bond price
= price at t for £1 payable at T
r(t) = instantaneous risk-free rate of interest at t
Take a specific bond with maturity at T1. Suppose its SDE under the real-
world measure P is
where, besides S(t, T1), m(t, T1) might be stochastic. The market price of risk
is defined as
m(t T1 ) r (t )
(t T1 )
S (t T1 )
and
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics. Core Technical) — September 2009 — Examiners’ Report
S (t , T1 ) B(t , T1 )
at =
S (t , T2 ) B(t , T2 )
S (t1T1 ) B(t , T1 )
B(t , T2 )
S (t , T2 ) B(t , T2 )
1 m(t , T2 ) B(t , T1 ) S (t , T1 )
Bt m(t , T1 ) B(t , T1 )
rt Bt S (t , T2 )
B(t , T1 )
Simplifying:
S (t , T1 ) 1 m(t , T2 ) S (t1T1 )
m(t , T1 ) 1
S (t , T2 ) rt S (t , T2 )
m(t , T1 ) rt m(t , T2 ) rt
S (t , T1 ) S (t , T2 )
Page 10
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2009 © Institute of Actuaries
1 Describe what is meant by an arbitrage opportunity. [3]
2 One of your colleagues says that the stock market is not efficient because some
accounting ratios have been shown to have predictive powers.
(i) Explain which of the main forms of efficiency is most relevant to this
situation. [2]
(iii) Explain the difference between active and passive fund management in terms
of the concept of market efficiency. [2]
[Total 6]
3 (i) Outline the relevant empirical evidence and theoretical arguments regarding
the behaviour of stock prices for each of the properties below.
(ii) (a) Discuss the extent to which a continuous time lognormal model of
security prices can capture the statistical properties empirically
observed or expected in the stock market.
4 (i) State how investors are assumed to make decisions in modern portfolio theory
(MPT). [1]
An investor can invest in only three assets which are uncorrelated with one another.
The assets have the following characteristics:
(iii) Calculate the efficient frontier for the investor taking into account the numbers
provided in the table above. [8]
(iv) Explain how an investor with a quadratic utility function would select a
portfolio from those making up the efficient frontier. [1]
[Total 11]
CT8 A2009—2
5 (i) Define the market price of risk in the CAPM. [1]
The table below gives the annual returns conditional on the state of the economy for
all the assets in an investment market.
(ii) Calculate the market price of risk given that the risk free annual rate of return
is 2.5%. [4]
(iii) Discuss the particular issue a young investor might face in using the CAPM.
[2]
[Total 7]
7 (i) Set out a formula for the stock-price, St, in the Black-Scholes model under the
equivalent martingale measure. [2]
A European call option on a stock has an exercise date one year away and a strike
price of £2. The underlying stock has a current price of £1.80. The continuously
compounded risk free rate of interest is 5% p.a. The option is priced at 20p.
(ii) Estimate the volatility of the stock price process to within 1% p.a., assuming
the Black-Scholes model applies. [5]
A new derivative security has just been written on the underlying stock. This will pay
a random amount D in one year’s time, where D is £1 if S0.5 > £2 and S1 > 2S0.5, is
50p if S0.5 < £2 and S1 > 2 S0.5 and is zero otherwise.
(ii) Define the delta of a derivative, defining all notation and terms used other than
those already defined in your answer to (i). [2]
(iii) Explain how delta and self-financing are used in the martingale approach to
valuing derivatives. [4]
[Total 10]
(i) State how the price of a zero-coupon bond is related to the instantaneous
forward rate. [2]
Using Itô calculus, it is possible to prove that the dynamics for the zero-coupon bond
price are given under Q as follows:
dB (t , T )
= m(t , T )dt + S (t , T )dWt ,
B (t, T )
where
2
T ⎛T ⎞
m(t , T ) = r (t ) − ∫ a (t , s )ds + ⎜ ∫ σ(t , s )ds ⎟
⎜ ⎟
t ⎝t ⎠
T
S (t , T ) = − ∫ σ(t , s )ds.
t
(ii) Explain the relationship between a and σ under the condition that the bond
market is complete. Give reasons for your answer. [6]
[Total 8]
CT8 A2009—4
10 Consider a three-period binomial model for a stock with the following parameters:
u = 1.2, d = 0.9 and S0 = 60. Assume that the discretely compounded risk-free rate of
interest is r = 11% per period.
(ii) Calculate the price of a standard European call option with maturity date in
three periods and strike price K = 60. [7]
If the value of the stock crosses the level 80 during the whole life of the
option, the contract holder has the right to obtain the difference between the
value of the stock at maturity (in three periods) and 60.
11 Consider a forward contract on gold. Suppose that there is a fixed storage cost of £c
per ounce, paid at the end of the period and c is the same for any time period less than
one year. Let St be the spot price of one ounce of gold at time t and r be the
continuously compounded risk-free rate of interest which is assumed to be constant.
Derive the price at time t of a forward contract written on one ounce of gold at the
start of the year, with maturity T years (T < 1).
[8]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2009—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2009
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
R D Muckart
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2009
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
1 Put in simple terms, an arbitrage opportunity is a situation where we can make a sure
profit with no risk. This is sometimes described as a free lunch. Put more precisely
an arbitrage opportunity means that:
(a) We can start at time 0 with a portfolio which has a net value of zero (implying
that we are long in some assets and short in others).
This may not violate market-efficiency as the ratios may be acting as a proxy
for risk.
(iii) Active managers believe market is not fully efficient hence they attempt to
detect mispricings.
Passive managers believe in efficiency and just diversify across the whole
market.
3 (i) (a) Direct statistical evidence shows volatility varies over time. Volatility
implied from option prices also shows volatility/volatility expectations
vary over time.
(b) Good theoretical reasons to expect this to vary over time. Equities
should give a risk premium over bonds and bond yields vary over time.
Empirically difficult to test.
(c) Empirically unsettled. Some evidence for mean reversion but rests
heavily on the aftermath of a few dramatic crashes also conversely
some evidence of momentum effects.
(d) Strong empirical evidence that prices are non-normal. Crashes happen
more than would be expected. In addition more days with small/no
changes than one would expect.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
(ii) Some problems with random walk. Can consider the points in (i) again:
(d) Random walk does assume normality. Quite a few alternatives. Levy
processes, jump processes like Poisson.
4 (i) Select on the basis of expected return and variance of return over a single time
horizon.
(ii) A portfolio is efficient if an investor cannot find a better one in the sense that
it has both a higher expected return and a lower variance.
(iii) The basic idea is that the efficient frontier is a straight line which is the
tangent to the efficient frontier (of risky assets) which passes through the point
in (s.d., return) space corresponding to the risk-free asset.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
Need to maximise
x is found to be 0.4969
When x is 0.4969
Expected return of risky portfolio is 0.069876
Standard deviation of risky portfolio is 0.09808
Thus the efficient frontier is the straight line through (0.04.0) and (0.069876,
0.09808).
(iv) Portfolio would be that corresponding to the point where the utility
indifference curve of the investor touched the efficient frontier.
= 4.08%
= 0.00022736
= 1.0479
(iii) The investor should consider their own human capital which is likely to be
large and unpredictable compared to their other assets.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
6 Structural models
Structural models are explicit models of a corporate entity issuing both equity and
debt. They aim to link default events explicitly to the fortunes of the issuing
corporate entity. An example of a structural model is the Merton model.
Reduced form models are statistical models which use observed market statistics
rather than specific data relating to the issuing corporate entity. The market statistics
most commonly used are the credit ratings issued by credit rating agencies such as
Standard and Poor’s and Moody’s.
Reduced form models use market statistics along with data on the default-free market
to model the movement of the credit rating of the bonds issued by a corporate entity
over time. The output of such models is a distribution of the time to default.
Intensity-based models
Intensity-based models model the factors influencing the credit events which lead to
default and typically (but not always) do not consider what actually triggers the credit
event.
(ii) Apply B-S formula with K = 2, S = 1.8, r = 0.05, t = 1 and sigma = 0.2, gives
c = 0.10. With sigma = 0.4, c = 0.24. Try sigma = 0.2 + 0.2 * 0.1/0.14 = 0.34
and get c = 0.20.
(iii) The unique fair price is V = EP[e−rTD], where P is the EMM. Thus
V = e−r[P(S0.5>£2 and S1 > 2S0.5) + 0.5 P(S0.5 < £2 and S1> 2S0.5)]
Where Phi is the cumulative standard normal distribution function and phi is
the standard normal density function. Standard deviation of ln(S_0.5) is
0.34/sqrt(2) = 0.24.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
There is another way to solve the problem and the price can be calculated
directly from
P(S0.5 > 2 and S1 > 2 S0.5) = P(S0.5 > 2 and S1/S0.5 > 2)
= P(S0.5 > 2) * P(S1/S0.5 > 2) since S1/S0.5 is independent of S0.5.
with
Similarly, defining
we get
8 (i) Suppose that at time t we hold the portfolio (φt , ψ t ) where φt represents the
number of units of St held at time t and ψt is the number of units of the cash
bond held at time t . We assume that St is a tradeable asset as described
above. The only significant requirement on (φt , ψ t ) is that they are previsible:
that is, that they are Ft − -measurable (so φt and ψt are known based upon
information up to but not including time t ).
Now consider the instantaneous pure investment gain in the value of this
portfolio over the period t up to t + dt : that is, assuming that there is no
inflow or outflow of cash during the period [t , t + dt ]. This is equal to
φt dSt + ψt dBt
The instantaneous change in the value of the portfolio, allowing for cash
inflows and outflows, is given by
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
(ii) Delta is just one of what are called the Greeks. The Greeks are a group of
mathematical derivatives which can be used to help us to manage or
understand the risks in our portfolio.
∂f ∂f
Δ= ≡ (t , St ).
∂s ∂s
(iii) In the martingale approach we showed that there exists a portfolio strategy
(φt , ψ t ) which would replicate the derivative payoff. We did not say what φt
actually is or how we work it out. In fact this is quite straightforward.
Vt = e − r (T −t ) EQ [ X | Ft ]
∂V
φt = (t , St ).
∂s
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
B (t , T ) = exp ⎡⎢ − ∫ f (t , u )du ⎤⎥ .
T
9 (i)
⎣ t ⎦
(ii) Since the bond market is complete, the discounted price of a zero-coupon
bond is a martingale with respect to the risk-neutral probability measure.
Using Itô, the dynamics for the discounted zero-coupon bond price B (t , T ) are:
d B (t , T )
= ( m(t , T ) − r (t ) ) dt + S (t , T )dWt
B (t,T )
( m(t , T ) − r (t ) ) = 0
In other words
2
T ⎛T ⎞
∫ a (t , s ) ds =
⎜∫
⎜ σ (t , s ) ds ⎟ .
⎟
t ⎝t ⎠
10 (i) (a) There is no arbitrage in the market since d = 0.9 < 1.11 < 1.2 .
(b)
103.68
86.4
72 77.76
60 64.8
54 58.32
48.6
43.74
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
(ii) To price the call option, we use the risk-neutral pricing formula. We use the
following simplifying notation:
( );
+
Cuuu = u 3 S0 − K
= ( u dS − K ) ;
+
2
Cuud 0
= ( ud S − K ) ;
+
2
Cudd 0
= (d S − K ) .
+
3
Cddd 0
1
C2 ( uu ) = ⎡ qCuuu + (1 − q ) Cuud ⎤⎦ ,
1+ r ⎣
1
C2 ( ud ) = ⎡ qCuud + (1 − q ) Cudd ⎤⎦
1+ r ⎣
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
1
C2 ( dd ) = ⎡ qCudd + (1 − q ) Cddd ⎤⎦ ,
1+ r ⎣
q=
(1 + r ) − d .
u−d
1
C1 ( u ) = ⎡ qC2 ( uu ) + (1 − q ) C2 ( ud ) ⎤⎦ ,
1+ r ⎣
1
C1 ( d ) = ⎡ qC2 ( ud ) + (1 − q ) C2 ( dd ) ⎤⎦ .
1+ r ⎣
At time 0,
1
C0 = ⎡ qC1 (u ) + (1 − q ) C1 (d ) ⎤⎦ .
1+ r ⎣
Hence
C0 = 16.68 .
(iii) Two paths are relevant for this knock-in option: “up-up-up” and “up-up-
down”. The associated payoff are respectively Cuuu with probability
q 3 and Cuud with probability q 2 (1 − q ) . The price at time 0 of the option is
therefore:
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2009 — Examiners' Report
11 The proof of this result is an adaptation of that of the standard spot-forward parity.
Two (self-financing) portfolios are considered:
• Portfolio A: buying the forward contract at time t. Its value at time t is 0 and at
time T, it is ST − FtT .
• ( )
Portfolio B: buying the underlying asset and borrowing FtT − c exp ( − r (T − t ) )
( )
at time t. Its value at time t is then FtT − c exp ( − r (T − t ) ) − St . Its value at
Using the absence of arbitrage opportunity, both portfolios should have the
same value at any intermediate time, in particular at time t. Hence:
FtT = St exp ( r (T − t ) ) + c .
Page 11
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2008 © Institute of Actuaries
1 Two assets are available for investment. Asset 1 returns a percentage 4B%, where B
is a Binomial random variable with parameters n = 3 and p = 0.5. Asset 2 returns a
percentage 2P%, where P is a Poisson random variable with parameter µ = 3.
Assume a benchmark return of 3%.
(i) Calculate the following three measures of investment risk for each asset:
(a) variance
(b) semi-variance and
(c) shortfall probability [6]
(ii) Explain which asset the investor should choose assuming a utility function of
the form:
2 (i) State the form of an equation that is appropriate to determine the relationship
between the observed historical returns of a number of securities and a set of
explanatory factors. Define all the terms you use. [2]
3 (i) (a) Define Beta in the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
(b) Explain why Beta is used in pricing securities.
[2]
In a market where the CAPM holds the following parameters are known:
CT8 S2008—2
(iii) An investor is evaluating the risk and expected return of a portfolio of N
securities.
4 One of your colleagues tells you that the work of Shiller conclusively proves that the
stock-market overreacts.
Derive the price at time t of the forward contract, using the no-arbitrage principle. [8]
• over a single period, the stock price can either move up to 60 or down to 30
• the continuously compounded risk-free rate is r = 5% per period
(ii) Calculate the price of a European call option with maturity date in one period
and strike price K = 45 using each of the following methods:
(ii) Derive a formula for V0, the value of the derivative contract. [5]
(iii) Calculate the value at time 0 of a derivative which delivers one unit of the
stock at time T if and only if the stock price at time T, ST, is at least K. [3]
(iv) Calculate the value of a derivative which delivers 150,000 shares of the stock
if and only if the stock price at time T, ST, satisfies $1.2 ≤ ST < $1.5. [6]
[Total 17]
(ii) Derive a formula for the Vega of a European call option on a non-dividend
paying stock in a market where the assumptions underpinning Black-Scholes
apply. [4]
(iii) (a) Determine the PDE satisfied by Vega by differentiating the Black-
Scholes PDE.
(b) Show that if a portfolio is Gamma-hedged, then its Vega satisfies the
Black-Scholes PDE. [4]
[Total 11]
CT8 S2008—4
11 (i) Describe the Merton model for assessing credit risk. [5]
A company has just issued a zero-coupon bond of nominal value £8m with maturity
of one year. The value of the assets of the company is £10.009m and this value is
expected to grow at an average of 10% per annum compound with an annual volatility
of 20%. The company is expected to be wound up after one year when the assets will
be used to pay off the bond holders with the remainder being distributed to the equity
holders. Shares in the company are currently traded at a market capitalisation of
£2.9428m.
(ii) Estimate the risk-free rate of interest in the market to within 1% p.a., stating
any additional assumptions that you make. [10]
[Total 15]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2008—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
September 2008
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
R D Muckart
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
November 2008
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
(ii) Maximising the expected utility corresponds to minimising the lower semi-
variance, hence choose asset 2.
These use observable economic time series as the factors. They could include
factors such as the annual rates of inflation and economic growth, short term
interest rates, the yields on long term government bonds, and the yield margin
on corporate bonds over government bonds.
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
(b) Beta is useful because it allows the expected return of any security to
be expressed as a linear function of that security’s covariance with the
market as a whole.
(iii) (a) Need expected return for each security N, variance of each security N,
covariance between each pair of securities N(N - 1)/2.
(b) Just need Beta for each security, expected market return, and market
variance. Total of N + 2.
4 (i) The claim of “excessive volatility” was first formulated into a testable
proposition by Shiller in 1981. He considered a discounted cashflow model of
equities going back to 1870. By using the actual dividends that were paid and
some terminal value for the stock he was able to calculate the perfect foresight
price, the “correct equity” price if market participants had been able to predict
future dividends correctly. The difference between the perfect foresight price
and the actual price arise from the forecast errors of future dividends. If
market participants are rational we would expect no systematic forecast errors.
Also if markets are efficient broad movements in the perfect foresight price
should be correlated with moves in the actual price as both react to the same
news.
Shiller found strong evidence that the observed level of volatility contradicted
the EMH.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
• possible non-stationarity of the series, i.e. the series may have stochastic trends
which invalidate the measurements obtained for the variance of the stock price
5 Standard Brownian motion (also called the Wiener process) is a stochastic process
{Bt , t ≥ 0} with state space S = R and the following defining properties:
• B0 = 0.
• (Note that the stationarity property is not needed separately if the Gaussian
property is set out in detail.)
6 The proof of this result is an adaptation of that of the standard spot-forward parity.
Two (self-financing) portfolios are considered:
• Portfolio A: take a long position in the forward contract at time t. Its value at time
t is 0 and at time T, it is ST − FtT .
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
Using the absence of arbitrage opportunity, both portfolios should have the same
value at any intermediate time, in particular at time t. Hence:
3 3
7 (i) There is no arbitrage in the market since d = < exp ( 0.05 ) < u = .
4 2
(ii)
• First method: we construct a risk-neutral portfolio with 1 underlying asset
and m call options. We choose the value of m such that this portfolio is risk
neutral (its value in the upper state and in the lower state at time 1 should
coincide). In this case, m = −2 . Then, we use a no arbitrage argument:
since the portfolio is risk-neutral, it should have the same rate of return as
the risk-free asset. Hence, the initial value of the call:
so C0 = 5.732 .
Hence C0 = 5.732 .
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
(iii) If we are long one unit of this derivative and short K units of the derivative in
part (ii) then we effectively hold a call option. Thus the value of this derivative
must be the sum of the value of the call and KV0 i.e S0Φ(d1).
(iv) If we go long 150,000 contracts of the type in part (iii) with a strike of 120p
and short 150,000 such contracts with a strike of 150p then we have duplicated
the contract. Thus the fair price is
9 (i) The value of a portfolio with a low value of vega will be relatively insensitive
to changes in volatility. Put another way: it is less important to have an
accurate estimate of σ if vega is low. Since σ is not directly observable, a
low value of vega is important as a risk-management tool. Furthermore, it is
recognised that σ can vary over time. Since many derivative pricing models
assume that σ is constant through time the resulting approximation will be
better if ν is small.
(ii) Let f denote the price of a call option, then f(s,T) = sΦ (d1) - K e-rTΦ(d2),
where d1 = (ln(S0/K) + (r + ½σ2)T)/ σ√T and d2 = d1 - σ√T. It follows (since
Φ’(x) = exp(-x2/2)/√2π) that V= s (exp(-d12/2)/√2π)∂d1/∂σ - K e-rT
(exp(-d22/2)/√2π)∂d2/∂σ = s (exp(-d12/2)/√2π)∂ (d1 - d2)/∂σ
= s (exp(-d12/2)/√2π)√T.
Then, since Γ=∂2f /∂s2, we see that in the case where Γ=0 we have
∂V /∂t + rs∂V /∂s+½σ2s2∂2V /∂s2=rV.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
Zero-coupon bond prices are related to the spot-rate and forward-rate curves in the
following way:
−1
R (t , T ) = log B(t , T ) for t < T
T −t
1 B(t , T )
F (t , T , S ) = log for t < T < S
S −T B(t , S )
∂
f (t , T ) = lim F (t , T , S ) = − log B(t, T )
S →T ∂T
B (t , T ) = exp ⎡⎢ − ∫ f (t , u )du ⎤⎥ .
T
or
⎣ t ⎦
⎡ ⎤
B (t , T ) = EQ ⎢exp ⎛⎜ − ∫ r (u )du ⎞⎟ r (t ) ⎥
T
⎣ ⎝ t ⎠ ⎦
11 (i) Merton’s model assumes that a corporate entity has issued both equity and
debt such that its total value at time t is of F(t). F(t) varies over time as a
result of actions by the corporate entity which does not pay dividends on its
equity or coupons on its bonds. Part of the corporate entity’s value is zero-
coupon debt with a promised repayment amount of L at a future time T. At
time T the remainder of the value of the corporate entity will be distributed
amongst the equity holders and the corporate entity will be wound up.
The corporate entity will default if the total value of its assets, F(T) is less than
the promised debt repayment at time T i.e. F(T) < L. In this situation, the bond
holders will receive F(T) instead of L and the equity holders will receive
nothing. This can be regarded as treating the equity holders of the corporate
entity as having a European call option on the assets of the company with
maturity T and a strike price equal to the value of the debt.
The Merton model can be used to estimate either the risk-neutral probability
that the company will default or the credit spread on the debt.
(ii) We assume the Merton model, so the value of the company is the value of a
call on the assets. The underlying is the gross value and the strike is the debt.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2008 — Examiners’ Report
Thus S0 = 10.009, σ = 0.2, T = 1, K = 8, and 2.9428 is the value of the call (at
time 0).
Page 8
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 11 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the Formulae
and Tables and your own electronic calculator from the approved list.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2008 © Institute of Actuaries
1 Define Gamma and Vega for a derivative written on a portfolio of assets in a market
where the assumptions underpinning the Black-Scholes model hold. [3]
2 State the stochastic differential equation for geometric Brownian motion and its
solution. (No proof is required.) [4]
• over each of the next two periods, the stock price can either move up by 10% or
move down by 10%
(ii) Calculate the price of a one-year European call option with a strike price
K = 100 . [4]
[Total 5]
4 (i) Outline the two-state model for credit ratings assuming constant transition
intensity. [5]
(ii) State the formula for the zero-coupon bond price in terms of the risk-neutral
default rate λ, when this rate is deterministic. [3]
[Total 8]
Asset 1 Asset 2
Return (%) Probability (%) Return (%) Probability (%)
-1 81/3 0 50
11 912/3 20 50
(ii) Explain which asset an investor with a quadratic utility function would choose.
[2]
(iii) State the reasons why variance of return is frequently used as a measure of
risk. [3]
[Total 9]
CT8 A2008—2
6 (i) Outline the assumptions used in modern portfolio theory regarding investor
behaviour that are necessary to specify efficient portfolios. [3]
(ii) An investor can construct a portfolio using only two assets X and Y. The
statistical properties of the two assets are shown below:
X Y
(a) Determine the composition of the portfolio which will give the investor
the highest expected return.
(b) Calculate the composition of the portfolio which will give the investor
the minimum variance.
[3]
(iii) Explain and sketch how the investor would choose a utility maximising
portfolio. [3]
[Total 9]
7 (i) State the assumptions, additional to those used in modern portfolio theory, that
allow the capital asset pricing model (CAPM) to be consistent with an
equilibrium model of prices in the whole market. [5]
(ii) Explain why in the CAPM all investors should hold all risky assets in
proportion to the market capitalisation of those assets. [2]
In an investment market there are three risky assets available. The table below shows
the returns each of the assets will earn in the three possible states of the world and the
current market capitalisation of the assets. Assume a risk free rate of return of 4% is
available.
1 0.4 5% 6% 7%
2 0.1 8% 2% 1%
3 0.5 3% 5% 4%
Market Capitalisation 30,000 50,000 30,000
(iii) Calculate the market price of risk under the CAPM. [4]
[Total 11]
(ii) Explain what the model implies about market efficiency. [2]
(iii) Outline the empirical evidence for and against the model. [5]
[Total 10]
9 Consider two call options, which are identical (same maturity, same underlying asset)
except for the strike price. Denote by C(K) the price at time 0 of the call option with
strike price K. Stating the key arguments required, prove that, if there are no arbitrage
opportunities, the following relation holds true, for K1 ≤ K 2 .
dr (t ) = a ( b − r (t ) ) dt + σdWt
(i) State the general expression r(t) of the solution of this stochastic differential
equation. [2]
T
(ii) Derive an expression for ∫ r (u)du , where t and T are given.
t
Hint: consider the stochastic differential equation of r(u), for u ≥ t .
[6]
T
(iii) State the distribution of ∫ r (u)du . [1]
t
(iv) Derive the price of a zero-coupon bond at time t with maturity T ≥ t related to
T
the distribution of ∫ r (u)du . [6]
t
[Total 15]
CT8 A2008—4
11 A stock is currently priced at €8.20. A writer of 100,000 units of a one year European
call option on this stock with an exercise price of €8 has hedged the option with a
portfolio of 75,000 shares and a loan. The annual risk-free interest rate (continuously
compounded) is 7% and no dividends are payable during the life of the option.
(ii) Calculate the implied volatility of the stock to within 0.1% p.a., assuming that
it is below 100%. [5]
(iii) Calculate:
(iv) (a) Calculate the current price of a one year European put option with the
same exercise price.
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2008—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
April 2008
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M A Stocker
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2008
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
1 Gamma
∂2 f
Γ=
∂s 2
Vega
ν = ∂f
∂σ
f is the price of the derivative; s is the price of the underlying asset; σ is the volatility
of the stochastic process of the price of the underlying
(
log St = log S0 + α − ½σ2 t + σBt )
or, finally,
( )
St = S0 exp ⎡ α − ½ σ2 t + σBt ⎤ .
⎣ ⎦
(ii) To price the call option, we use the risk-neutral pricing formula. The risk-
neutral probability of an upward move is
exp(r ) − d
q= = 0.9164.
u−d
⎧Cuu = (u 2 S0 − K ) + = 21
⎪⎪ ⎧C1 (u ) = exp(− r )(qCuu + (1 − q )Cud ) = 17.7655
+
⎨Cud = (udS0 − K ) = 0 ⇒ ⎨
⎪ 2 + ⎩C1 (d ) = exp(− r )(qCud + (1 − q )Cdd ) = 0
⎪⎩Cdd = ( d S 0 − K ) = 0
⇒ C0 = exp(−r )(qC1 (u ) + (1 − q )(C1 (d )) = 15.0292
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
4 (i) The two-state model for credit ratings with a constant transition intensity.
A model can be set up, in continuous time, with two states N (not previously
defaulted) and D (previously defaulted). Under this simple model it is
assumed that the default-free interest rate term structure is deterministic with
r(t) = r for all t. If the transition intensity, under the real-world measure P,
from N to D at time t is denoted by λ(t), this model can be represented as:
λ(t)
No default, N Default, D
T
(ii) B(t,T) = e-r(T-t) [1 - (1 - δ)(1 - exp(- ∫ λ ( s )ds ))]
t
Variance of Return
Semi-Variance of Return
Shortfall Probability
Asset 1 81/3%
Asset 2 0%
(ii) Both have same expected return. The variance is appropriate risk measure in
this case.
(iii)
• Mathematically tractable.
• Leads to elegant solutions for optimal portfolios.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
6 (i) Investors select their portfolios on the basis of the expected return and the
variance of the return over a single time horizon.
Investors are never satiated. At a given level of risk, they will always prefer a
portfolio with a higher return to one with a lower return.
Investors dislike risk. For a given level of return they will always prefer a
portfolio with lower variance to one with higher variance.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
• All investors can borrow or lend unlimited amounts at the same risk-free
rate.
• The markets for risky assets are perfect. Information is freely and
instantly available to all investors and no investor believes that they can
affect the price of a security by their own actions.
(ii) If investors have homogeneous expectations, then they are all faced by the
same efficient frontier of risky securities. If in addition they are all subject to
the same risk-free rate of interest, the efficient frontier collapses to the straight
line in E − σ space which passes through the risk-free rate of return on the E-
axis and is tangential to the efficient frontier for risky securities.
All rational investors will hold a combination of the risk-free asset and the
portfolio of risky assets at the point where the straight line through the risk-
free return touches the original efficient frontier. Because this is the portfolio
held in different quantities by all investors it must consist of all risk assets in
proportion to their market capitalisation. It is commonly called the “market
portfolio”. The proportion of a particular investor’s portfolio consisting of the
market portfolio will be determined by their risk-return preference.
= 4.8273%
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
= 83.89%
There appears to be some evidence for some mean reversion in markets, but
the evidence rests heavily on the aftermath of a small number of dramatic
crashes. Furthermore, there also appears to be some evidence of momentum
effects, which imply that a rise one day is more likely to be followed by
another rise the next day.
In particular, market crashes appear more often than one would expect from a
normal distribution.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
9 The idea is to assume that the converse inequality holds true and show that this leads
to an arbitrage opportunity. More precisely, let us assume that
• At time 0: we sell one call with strike price K3 = λK1 + (1 − λ ) K 2 and buy λ calls
with strike K1 and (1− λ ) calls with strike K 2 . We lend the difference. The total
value of the portfolio at time 0 is equal to 0.
At time 0
sell C (K3) C (K3)
buy λC (K1) − λC (K1)
buy (1 − λ) C(K2) − (1 – λ) C(K2)
lend the difference M ≡ λC (K1) + (1 − λ) C(K2) − C(K3)
Total 0
t
r ( t ) = r0 exp ( − at ) + b (1 − exp ( −at ) ) + σ exp ( − at ) ∫ exp ( as ) dWs .
0
u
( )
r ( u ) = r (t ) exp ( − a ( u − t ) ) + b 1 − exp ( − a ( u − t ) ) + σ exp ( − au ) ∫ exp ( as ) dWs .
t
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
Hence
T T T T u
( )
∫ r ( u )du = r (t )∫ exp ( −a ( u − t ) )du + b∫ 1 − exp ( −a ( u − t ) ) du + σ∫ exp ( −au ) ∫ exp ( as ) dWs du.
t t t t t
T
1 − exp ( −a (T − t ) ) σ
T
∫ r ( u )du = b (T − t ) + ( r (t ) − b ) a
+
a∫
( )
1 − exp ( −a (T − s ) ) dWs .
t t
T
(iii) Hence, ∫ r ( u )du is also a Gaussian random variable.
t
(iv) Since the bond market is complete, the price of a zero-coupon bond can be
written as
⎡ ⎛ T ⎞ ⎤
B (t , T ) = E ⎢ exp ⎜ − ∫ r ( s )ds ⎟ Ft ⎥ .
⎢ ⎜ ⎟ ⎥
⎣ ⎝ t ⎠ ⎦
T
Since ∫ r ( u )du is a Gaussian random variable, we can compute explicitly the
t
price of the zero-coupon bond in terms of the expected value and variance
T
(conditional) of ∫ r ( u )du :
t
⎡ ⎡T ⎤ 1 ⎡T ⎤⎤
B (t , T ) = exp ⎢ − E ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ + V ⎢ ∫ r ( s )ds Ft ⎥ ⎥ .
⎢ ⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ 2 ⎢⎣ t ⎥⎦ ⎥⎦
⎣
where
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2008 — Examiners’ Report
∂d1/∂s = ∂d2/∂s
and
we see that the last two terms in the expression for Δ cancel and we are just
left with Δ = Φ (d1).
(ii) Δ = .75 and so d1 = 0.6745. It follows (rearranging the expression for d1) that
(.02469 + .07 + 0.5σ2) = 0.6745σ. Solving the quadratic we obtain (choosing
the root less than 1) σ = 0.6745 ± √0.26557 = 0.159165 = 15.9%.
Clearly, the value of the loan is = £519,772 and the option price is
(iv) Use put-call parity. This merely assumes that borrowing is allowed and the
market is arbitrage free.
Page 9
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 8 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2007 © Institute of Actuaries
1 (i) Define the Δ, Γ, θ, λ, ρ and ν for an individual derivative security. [6]
(ii) Explain put-call parity and use it to calculate the delta and gamma of a
European call option on a non-dividend paying stock with the same strike and
maturity as the put option. [4]
A portfolio with a delta of zero consists of cash, European put options, P, on a stock
and 1 million shares of the underlying (non-dividend paying) stock . The delta of a
single put option is –0.212, while the gamma is 0.377.
Two further derivatives on the stock are also traded: a European call option, C, with
the same strike and maturity as P and another derivative security, D, with a delta of
0.222 and a gamma of 0.111.
(iii) Calculate n, the number of put options in the original portfolio of cash, stock
and P. [2]
(iv) Calculate the numbers of derivatives D and C that have to be purchased and
added to the portfolio so that both the delta and gamma of the expanded
portfolio are zero. [4]
[Total 16]
(i) Calculate the risk neutral probability measure for this model. [3]
The value of S0 is 100. A derivative security with price Dt at time t pays the following
returns at time 2:
D2 = 1 : if S2 = 156.25
D2 = 2 : if S2 = 100
D2 = 0 : if S2 = 64.
(ii) Determine D1 when S1 = 125 and when S1 = 80 and hence calculate the value
of D0. [5]
(iii) Derive the corresponding hedging strategy, i.e. the combination of the
underlying security and the risk free asset required to hedge an investment in
the derivative security. [4]
(iv) Comment on your answer to (iii) in the light of your answer to part (ii). [1]
[Total 13]
CT8 S2007—2
3 (i) State the assumptions underlying the Black-Scholes option pricing formula
and discuss how realistic they are. [6]
(iii) Explain why the discounted stock price (under P ) is not a martingale. [1]
(iv) State the SDE satisfied by St under the equivalent martingale measure. [2]
[Total 14]
4 (i) State the general zero-coupon bond pricing formula in terms of random short
rates. Define all notation used. [2]
(ii) State the SDEs defining the dynamics of the short rates under the risk-neutral
measure for each of the Vasicek, Cox-Ingersoll-Ross and Hull & White
models. Define all notation used. [6]
(iii) State the zero-coupon bond price formula for the Vasicek model. [3]
5 Consider a special company that has just issued a zero-coupon bond of nominal value
£10m with maturity 10 years. The value of the assets of the company is £20m and
this value is expected to grow at an average of 10% per annum compound with an
annual volatility of 40%. The company is expected to be wound up after 10 years
when the assets will be used to pay off the bond holders with the remainder being
distributed to the equity holders.
Calculate the credit spread on the debt for the zero-coupon bond. State any additional
assumptions that you make.
A 9 20
B 6 20
C 3 10
(i) Calculate the variance of the returns of each asset and the covariances between
the returns of each pair of assets. [5]
Efficient portfolios for this model are of the form ( 92 , 92 , 95 )T + c(4, 1, -5)T , for a
suitable choice of c, where the vector represents proportions of the investor’s capital
invested in assets A, B and C respectively.
(b) Deduce the global minimum variance and the portfolio that attains it.
[4]
Assume that the risk-free rate of interest is 4% p.a.
(iv) (a) Determine the tangent that passes through (0%, 4%) to the original
efficient frontier in (standard deviation, mean return) space.
(b) Deduce the market capitalisations of the three assets consistent with
the Capital Asset Pricing Model if the total market capitalisation is
£180 bn. [6]
[Total 17]
CT8 S2007—4
7 Consider a corporate bond that will return £1 per bond to an investor at the end of a
year provided the borrower does not default during the year. The constant annual
probability of default is 4%.
Investor 1 holds one thousand such bonds that depend on the same borrower.
Investor 2 holds one thousand such bonds, each of which depends on a different
borrower. Each borrower defaults (or not) independently of the other borrowers, but
with the same probability of 4%.
8 (i) Outline the three forms of the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. [3]
(ii) State two reasons why it is hard to test whether any of the three forms hold in
practice. [2]
[Total 5]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2007—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATIONS
September 2007
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M A Stocker
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
December 2007
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
1 (i) The Greeks are the derivatives of the price of a derivative security with respect
to the different parameters needed to calculate the price. Thus:
∂f ∂2 f ∂f ∂f ∂f ∂f
Δ= ;Γ = 2 ;θ= ;λ = ;ρ= ;ν = ;
∂s ∂s ∂t ∂q ∂r ∂σ
where f is the value of the derivative, s is the price of the underlying security,
q is the continuous dividend yield on the security, σ is the volatility, r is the
interest rate and t is time. In each case the relevant Greek measures sensitivity
(rate of change) of the option price to change in that variable.
(ii) Suppose we hold one European call option with strike k and maturity T and
are short one put with the same strike and maturity. Our payoff at maturity is
exactly the same as if we held one share of the underlying and were short k
zero coupon bonds with maturity T. The value at time 0 of such a payoff,
under the assumption of no arbitrage, is S0 − ke−rT , where St is the price of the
stock and r is the risk-free interest rate. Thus is P and C are the price at time 0
of the put and call, we have:
C = P + S0 - ke-rT
Hence ΔC = ΔP + 1 and ΓC = ΓP .
(iii) Since the original portfolio is delta-hedged, and the delta of a share is 1, we
must have
-.212n + 1M = 0 ⇒ n = 4716981.
(iv) Using the formulae in part (ii), the delta and gamma of the call are .788 and
.377 respectively. The Γ of the original portfolio is
1M × .377 = 377,000,
so we need:
.222d + .788c = 0
and
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
2 (i) We need to equate the expected average return on the stock and the return on a
bond: so we solve solve 1.25p + 0.8q = 1.1 ⇒ p = 23 . Thus, under Q, the risk-
neutral measure, S is a multiplicative random walk with up-jump
probability 23 .
(iii) to hedge at time 1 if S1 = 125 we let the amount invested in the stock be φ and
the amount invested in cash be ψ and solve:
1.25φ + 1.1ψ = 1
0.8φ + 1.1ψ = 2
which gives
20
φ= = -2.22222 (the equivalent shareholding is
9
-2.2222/125 = -.017778)
340
and ψ = = 3.4343.
9
If S1 = 80 then we solve
1.25φ + 1.1ψ = 2
0.8φ + 1.1ψ = 0
which gives
40
φ= = 4.4444 (the equivalent shareholding is
9
4.4444/80 = .0556),
320
and ψ = − = -3.2323.
99
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
Finally, we solve
which gives
1.2121
φ = 0 and ψ = = 1.1019.
11
(iv) This last is obvious since the value of D1 doesn’t depend on S1 and hence we
must hedge using the risk-free asset only.
3 (i) No frictions; short-selling permitted; small investor (i.e. does not “move
market”); market is arbitrage-free; stock price is given by dSt = μtStdt + σStdBt
for some process μt, where B is a Brownian motion.
S can be written as
where
2
f(x, t) = cosh(σx)e−σ t .
1
dSt = f x dZt + ( ft + f xx )dt
2
2 1 2
= σ sinh(σZt )e −σ t dZt + ( σ2 cosh(σZt ) − σ2 cosh(σZt ))e−σ t dt
2
2 1 2
= σe −σ t sinh(σZt )dZt − σ2e −σ t cosh(σZt )dt
2
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
2 1
= σ e −2σ t − St2 dZ t − σ 2 St dt.
2
(c) The drift term would be zero under the risk-neutral measure: the dZ
term would be unchanged, therefore we’d get:
2
dSt = σ e −2σ t − St2 dZt ,
T
B(t, T) = E[exp(- ∫t rs ds ) | Ft ],
where B(t, T) is the price at time t of the ZCB with maturity T, and r is the
random short rate.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
historically, there have been sustained periods of both high and low interest
rates with periods of both high and low volatility — features which are
difficult to capture without more random factors;
5 Assume no other debt, frictionless markets, perfect information, black scholes type
model for the movement of the assets
Use black scholes to calculate the value of a call option based on the value of the
assets exceeding a strike of 10 after 10 years. Equal to equity of firm = E = 15.07631
1 8
Solve 10*exp(-10 rb) = B ⇒ rb = − ln = 7.085%
10 10
(ii) An efficient portfolio is one with minimum variance of return for the given
expected return, or maximum expected return for the given variance.
2 2 2
⎛2 ⎞ ⎛2 ⎞ ⎛5 ⎞
⎜ + 4c ⎟ × .04 + ⎜ + c ⎟ × .04 + ⎜ − 5c ⎟ × .01
⎝9 ⎠ ⎝9 ⎠ ⎝9 ⎠
⎛2 ⎞⎛ 2 ⎞ ⎛2 ⎞⎛ 5 ⎞ ⎛2 ⎞⎛ 5 ⎞
−2 × .01⎜ + 4c ⎟ ⎜ + c ⎟ − 2 × .01⎜ + c ⎟ ⎜ − 5c ⎟ − 2 × .01⎜ + 4c ⎟ ⎜ − 5c ⎟
⎝9 ⎠⎝ 9 ⎠ ⎝9 ⎠⎝ 9 ⎠ ⎝9 ⎠⎝ 9 ⎠
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
(iv) It follows from previous answers that the efficient frontier consists of points of
the form (σc, rc) with c ≥ 0, rc = .05 + .27c and σc = .001111 + 1.35c 2 . Now
the tangent at the point parametrised by c has gradient
rc′ .001111+1.35c 2
gc = σ′c
= .27 1.35c
.27(.001111+1.35c 2 )
p = rc - gcσc = .05 + .27c - 1.35c
.
2
c = .27 × .001111/.0135 = .02222 = .
90
7 (i) Investor 1:
Investor 2:
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2007 — Examiners’ Report
(ii) Investor 2 is clearly holding a more diversified portfolio, but two of four
measures of risk would suggest the diversified portfolio was riskier.
Value at risk is highly sensitive to the confidence level chosen with 90% level
suggesting investor 2 is riskier than investor 1 and 95% level vice versa.
Strong — stock prices reflect all current information relevant to the stock,
including information which is not public.
Weak — stock prices reflect all information available in the past history of the
stock price.
(ii) Tests need to make assumptions (which may be invalid) such as normality of
returns or stationarity.
Transaction costs may prevent the exploitation of anomalies, so that the EMH
might hold net of transaction costs.
Allowance for risk: the EMH does not preclude higher returns as a reward for
risk; however the EMH does not tell us how to price such risks.
Page 8
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 9 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
© Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2007 © Institute of Actuaries
1 (i) Derive an expression for the theta of an option under the Black-Scholes model
involving delta and gamma. [4]
(ii) Explain why a deep out of the money call option in the Black-Scholes world
will experience a rate of return close to the risk-free rate of return. [2]
[Total 6]
(i) Derive an expression for the variance of a portfolio of N such assets where xi
is the relative weight of asset i in the portfolio. Assume that the weights sum
to unity and that short selling is prohibited. [3]
(ii) Show that the variance of the returns of a very large portfolio of equally
weighted allocations to the assets depends mainly on the average covariance
between the asset returns. [5]
[Total 8]
3 Consider a two period recombining binomial model for St, the price of a non-dividend
paying security at times t = 0, 1 and 2, with real world dynamics:
St +1 = St u with probability p
= St d with probability 1 − p
There also exists a risk-free instrument that offers a continuously compounded rate of
return of 5% per period.
The state price deflator in this model after one period is:
(iii) Calculate the price at time 0 of a derivative that pays 1 at time 2 if S2 > S0
using the risk-neutral probability measure derived in (ii). [2]
[Total 9]
CT8 A2007—2
4 An investor is contemplating an investment with a payoff of R, where R has the
probability density function f, given by:
Calculate the following two measures of risk for the net return when the cost of the
investment is 0.7:
K
Ri = αi + ∑ βij I j + εi
j =1
where:
Ri = return on security i
(i) Derive an expression for the covariance between the returns of two securities
in terms of the statistical properties of the factors using the model above. [4]
(ii) Explain the implications of your expression in (i) for constructing a diversified
portfolio. [3]
(iii) Explain how the multifactor model above can be used to form an asset pricing
theory when combined with the principle of no-arbitrage. [5]
[Total 12]
(ii) State the advantages of the Hull & White model over the single factor Vasicek
model. [4]
(iii) Explain the limitations of using a model with only one factor, taking into
account both theoretical and empirical considerations. [4]
[Total 12]
7 Consider a special type of scheme that has an obligation to pay £10,000 in exactly one
year. There is currently £9,000 in the fund created to meet this obligation and it is
invested in the shares of an infinitely divisible non-dividend paying security with
price St governed by the SDE:
dSt = St ( μ dt + σ dZt )
where:
(ii) Calculate the following risk measures applied to the surplus of the scheme
where the surplus of the scheme is defined as the difference between the value
of the fund and the obligation at the end of the year:
(a) variance
(b) shortfall probability relative to a benchmark surplus of £0
[6]
(iii) Calculate the cost of a put option to protect against the surplus being negative
at the end of the year. [3]
[Total 13]
CT8 A2007—4
8 (i) Explain the difference between an efficient market and an arbitrage-free
market. [4]
(ii) Explain what this means about the distribution of returns. [2]
(iii) Explain how mean-reversion in the stock market can be consistent with an
efficient market. [2]
(iv) Outline the claim and test of excessive volatility in stock markets made by
Shiller, along with four criticisms made of the test. [7]
[Total 15]
Assume that a company has fixed debt of £40m with term 10 years, the value of the
equity in the company is £20m and the Merton model for credit risk holds true. The
risk free rate of return is 5% p.a. and there are no other dividends or interest
payments.
(ii) Explain how to calculate the (risk neutral) probability of default. You do not
have to calculate the probability, but should state how each value would be
calculated. [6]
In a particular two state model for credit rating with deterministic transition intensity,
the risk free rate is a constant, r, the recovery rate is δ and the zero coupon bond price
is given by:
⎡ ⎛ −
(T 2 −t 2 ) ⎞ ⎤
B (t , T ) = e − r (T −t ) ⎢1 − (1 − δ) ⎜1 − e 4 ⎟⎥ .
⎢ ⎜ ⎟⎥
⎢⎣ ⎝ ⎠ ⎥⎦
(iii) (a) State the general formula for the zero coupon bond prices in a two state
model for credit ratings.
(b) Deduce the risk-neutral default intensity for the particular two state
model above.
[4]
[Total 16]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2007—5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
April 2007
EXAMINERS’ REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M A Stocker
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2007
Comments
No comments given.
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
∂f
1 (i) Θ=
∂t
∂f ∂f 1 ∂2 f
+ rs + σ2 s 2 2 = rf
∂t ∂s 2 ∂s
1
or Θ + rsΔ + σ2 s 2Γ = rf
2
(ii) Deep out of the money, delta and gamma will be close to zero which implies
that theta will equal the risk free rate of return.
2 (i) The expression for the variance of the portfolio can be rewritten as:
V = Σi xi2 Vi + ∑ xi .x j .Cij
i≠ j
(ii) If we assume that equal amounts are invested in each asset, then with N assets
the proportion invested in each is 1/N. Thus:
V = Σi (1/N)2 Vi + ∑ (1/N)(1/N).Cij
i≠ j
Factoring out 1/N from the first summation and (N − 1)/N from the second
yields:
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
The alternative approach shown below is possible for (i) and (ii), students
were given full credit for either approach.
(i) and (ii) p and q, the risk neutral probability measure, can be obtained by
solving the equation for the state price deflator (Unit 11 Page 9 of Core
Reading)
A1 = e-rq/p if S1 = S0u
= e-r(1 - q)/(1 - p) if S1 = S0d
Note if this approach is used it is not necessary to know that the price of the
derivative is 0.1448.
The solution to (iii) given above assumes that ud = 1, students who worked on
this basis were given full credit as this is a common presumption in this type
of work. However, some students realized that the strict definition of a
recombining model is that ud = du. In this case
If ud = 1 the solution given above holds i.e. price = 0.3257 (only upper node
pays off)
There is another possible case where ud > 1 (upper and middle nodes both
pay off)
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
μ
∫ 0.5 (t − μ)
2
4 (a) SV = Downside semi-variance = f (t ) dt
∞
∞ c ⎤
μ = ∫ tf (t )dt = − ⎥ = 0.75
0.5 2t 2 ⎦ 0.5
SV = c {∫ 0.75 −2
0.5
t dt − 2μ
0.75 −3
∫ 0.5 t dt + μ 2
0.75 −4
∫ 0.5 t dt }
⎧ ⎡ t −2 ⎤
0.75 −3 0.75 ⎫
⎪ 0.75 2⎡ t ⎤ ⎪
= c ⎨−t ] 0.5 − 1.5 ⎢ − ⎥ + 0.75 ⎢ − ⎥ ⎬
⎢⎣ 2 ⎥⎦ 0.5 ⎢⎣ 3 ⎥⎦ 0.5 ⎪
⎩⎪ ⎭
= 0.02083
(in units of (£m)2)
OR
∞ ∞
(t − μ)2 (t − μ) 2
SV = ∫ t4
dt − ∫ t4
dt
0.5 0.75
SV = 0.1875 – 0.16666
= 0.02083
∞
c
∫ f (t )dt = 3 x
−3
(b) P(R > x) =
x
c
= 1 - (0.7 − t )−3
3
For 5% VaR:
c
Pr[S ≤ -t] = 1 - (0.7 – t)-3 = 0.05
3
⇒ t = 0.1914
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
+ ∑ βik Cov( I k , ε j )
k
+ ∑ β jk Cov( I k , εi )
k
(ii) low covariance if betas are low, i.e. pick stocks with different sensitivities to
the factors
(iii) This is exactly the same as the multi-index model for returns on individual
securities. The contribution of APT is to describe how we can go from a
multi-index model for individual security returns to a equilibrium market
model. Non-mathematically, the argument can be made as follows. Consider a
two index model. The return on the ith security is given by
Ri = ai + bi,1 I1 + bi,2 I2 + ci .
For investors who hold well diversified portfolios the specific risk of each
security, represented by ci can be diversified away so an investor need only be
concerned with expected return, bi,1 and bi,2 in choosing his portfolio.
Suppose we hypothesize the existence of three widely diversified portfolios,
represented by the points (Ei , bi,1, bi,2) in E − b1 − b2 space where i = 1, 2, 3.
These three portfolios define a plane in E − b1 − b2 space with equation
Now, consider what would happen if another portfolio Q existed, with exactly
the same values of b1 and b2 but a higher expected return. Both portfolios
would have the same degree of systematic risk but Q would have a higher
expected return than P. Rational investors would therefore sell P and buy Q,
and this would continue until the forces of supply and demand had brought
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
The more general result of APT, that all securities and portfolios have
expected returns described by the L-dimensional hyperplane
6 (i) The Hull & White (HW) model does this by extending the Vasicek model in a
simple way. We define the SDE for r(t) under Q as follows
where W1 (t ) and W2 (t ) are independent, standard Brownian motions under the
risk-neutral measure Q. This looks superficially like the Hull & White model,
but the HW model has a deterministic mean-reversion level, whereas here m(t)
is stochastic.
(ii) We will now look at a simple extension of the Vasicek model. Recall the
SDEs for both the Vasicek and CIR models gave us time-homogeneous
models. This means that bond prices at t depend only on r(t) and on the term
to maturity. This results in a lack of flexibility when it comes to pricing related
contracts. For example, on any given date theoretical bond prices will
probably not match exactly observed market prices. We can re-estimate r(t) to
improve the match and even re-estimate the constant parameters α, µ and σ but
we will still, normally, be unable to get a precise match.
(iii) One factor models have certain limitations which it is important to be familiar
with. First, if we look at historical interest rate data we can see that changes in
the prices of bonds with different terms to maturity are not perfectly correlated
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
Second, if we look at the long run of historical data we find that there have
been sustained periods of both high and low interest rates with periods of both
high and low volatility. Again these are features which are difficult to capture
without introducing more random factors into a model. This issue is especially
important for two types of problem in insurance: the pricing and hedging of
long-dated insurance contracts with interest-rate guarantees; and asset-liability
modelling and long-term risk-management.
1 ⎛ 1 ⎞
dSt + ½ ⎜ − 2 ⎟ ( dSt )
2
d log St =
St ⎜ ⎟
⎝ St ⎠
( )
= μ − ½ σ2 dt + σ dZt .
( )
log St = log S0 + μ − ½ σ2 t + σZ t
or, finally,
( )
St = S0 exp ⎡ μ − ½σ2 t + σZt ⎤ .
⎣ ⎦
Should insert the parameters given in the question, i.e. μ = 0.1 and σ = 0.2.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
(ii) The properties of the lognormal distribution give us the expectation and
variance of St:
(( ) )
E ( St ) = exp μ − ½σ2 t + ½ σ2t = eμt ,
2
Var( St ) = e 2μt (eσ t − 1)
Need to look at
X = 9000 S1 – 10,000
(b) Pr[X < 0] = Pr[S1 < 10/9] = Pr[log S1 < log 10/9], then use normal
distribution to get 0.55
Use put call parity (or Black Scholes formula for put option directly) to get
price of put = price of call + 10,000*exp(-0.05) – 9,000 = 1021.42.
8 (i) Attempts to explain this phenomenon gave rise to the efficient markets
hypothesis, which claims that market prices already incorporate the relevant
information. The market price mechanism is such that the trading pattern of a
small number of informed analysts can have a large impact on the market
price. Lazy (or cost conscious) investors can then take a free ride, in the
knowledge that the research of others is keeping the market efficient.
(ii) One measure of these non-normal features is the Hausdorff fractal dimension
of the price process. A pure jump process (such as a Poisson process) has a
fractal dimension of 1. Random walks have a fractal dimension of 1½.
Empirical investigations of market returns often reveal a fractal dimension
around 1.4.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
(iii) Even mean reversion can be consistent with efficient markets. After a crash,
many investors may have lost a significant proportion of their total wealth; it
is not irrational for them to be more averse to the risk of losing what remains.
As a result, the prospective equity risk premium could be expected to rise.
(iv) Several observers have commented that stock prices are “excessively volatile”.
By this they mean that the change in market value of stocks (observed
volatility), could not be justified by the news arriving. This was claimed to be
evidence of market over-reaction which was not compatible with efficiency.
Shiller found strong evidence that the observed level of volatility contradicted
the EMH. However, subsequent studies using different formulations of the
problem found that the violation of the EMH only had borderline statistical
significance. Numerous criticisms were subsequently made of Shiller’s
methodology, these criticisms covered
• possible non-stationarity of the series, i.e. the series may have stochastic
trends which invalidate the measurements obtained for the variance of the
stock price
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) — April 2007 — Examiners’ Report
structural models: these are explicit models of a corporate entity issuing both
debt and equity. They aim to link default events explicitly to the fortunes of
the issuer.
reduced-form models: these are statistical models which use market statistics
(such as credit ratings) rather than specific data relating to the issuer, a nd give
statistical models for their movement.
intensity-based models: these model the factors influencing the credit events
which lead to default and typically do not consider what triggers these events.
(ii) In the Merton model, the company is modelled as having a fixed debt, 40 with
term 10 years and variable assets St. The equity holders can be regarded as
holding a European call on the assets with a strike of 40.
(iii) In the two state model for credit rating with deterministic transition intensity,
the formula for the Zero Coupon Bond price is
T
−∫ λ ( s ) ds
B(t, T) = e-r(T-t) (1 – (1 - δ) (1 - e t
)).
( s ) = s/2.
λ
Page 10
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 8 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2006 Institute of Actuaries
1 An investor is contemplating an investment with a return of £R, where:
R = 250,000 100,000N,
2 A non-dividend-paying stock has a current price of 800p. In any unit of time (t, t + 1)
the price of the stock either increases by 25% or decreases by 20%. £1 held in cash
between times t and t + 1 receives interest to become £1.04 at time t + 1. The stock
price after t time units is denoted by St.
(i) Calculate the risk-neutral probability measure for the model. [4]
(ii) Calculate the price (at t = 0) of a derivative contract written on the stock with
expiry date t = 2 which pays 1,000p if and only if S2 is not 800p (and
otherwise pays 0). [4]
[Total 8]
(ii) Define the delta of a derivative, defining all notation and terms used other than
those already defined in your answer to (i). [2]
(iii) Explain, in general terms, how delta and self-financing are used in the
martingale approach to valuing derivatives. [5]
[Total 11]
CT8 S2006 2
4 The Wilkie model has been used to produce stochastic simulations of inflation rates.
(i) Explain why you would expect the standard deviations calculated in each run
to be different. [4]
(ii) State the conditions under which the standard deviations in the two runs would
be expected to be the same. [2]
(iii) Discuss the advantages and disadvantages of using economic theory rather
than statistical models to construct and calibrate a stochastic model. [5]
[Total 11]
5 (i) List five desirable characteristics of a model for the term structure of interest
rates. [5]
(ii) State the Stochastic Differential Equation satisfied by the short rate in the
Vasicek model for the term structure of interest rates. [1]
(iii) Comment on the appropriateness of the Vasicek model in the light of your
answer to part (i). [5]
[Total 11]
6 An investor can invest in only two assets with the following characteristics
(annualised):
(i) Show that the efficient frontier for the investor is a straight line passing
through the points (0, 0.05) and (0.1, 0.075) in (standard deviation, expected
return) space. [5]
expected return 5%
. [6]
standard deviation
(iii) Using (ii), or otherwise, show that the new efficient frontier using A, B and C
passes through the point (0.1, 0.0769). [6]
[Total 17]
Ri = i + i1I1 + i2I2 + i
where:
Ri = return on security i
i, i1, i2 are security-specific parameters
I1 and I2 are the changes in the 2 factors on which the model is based
2
i is an independent random normal variate with variance i.
(i) Describe briefly three categories of model that could help in choosing the
factors, I1 and I2. [6]
Suppose the factors I1 and I2 are chosen to be total return indices with I1 based on the
whole market and I2 based on the 50 stocks with the highest dividend yield.
(ii) Explain in detail how the two factors can be transformed into two orthogonal
factors, one of which is the same as the index on which I1 is based. [3]
(iii) Derive an expression for the variance of the returns on the security in terms of
the variances of the changes of the orthogonal factors and i2 . [3]
8 (i) State the SDE of a non-dividend paying stock price in the Black-Scholes
model, under the EMM defining all symbols used. [2]
(ii) Give the general formula for the price of a derivative security which has a
terminal value of C at time T. [2]
(iii) A special option on a share pays £1 at time T if (and only if) the share price at
time T lies in the interval [a, b].
2
x
ln r T
S0 2
e-rT[ (d(b)) - (d(a)] where d(x) =
T
CT8 S2006 4
A fund manager currently charges an annual management fee of 0.5% of the value of
the funds under management at the end of a one-year contract.
The value of the funds under management are governed by the following SDE:
The owner of the funds wishes to change the management fee to be performance-
related.
0.1% if S1 S0
K 1% if S1 U
0.5% otherwise
(iv) Calculate the value at time 0 of the management fee under the original fee
structure if S0 = 100. [1]
(v) Calculate U so that the management fee under the performance-related fee
structure has the same value at time 0 as the fixed fee in (iv). [10]
Hint: the fee can be written as a basic fee plus two call options plus two
options of the form in (iii). [Total 20]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2006 5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATIONS
September 2006
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M A Stocker
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
November 2006
Comments
© Faculty of Actuaries
© Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
⎡ 1 ⎤
EQ ⎢ St +1⏐Ft ⎥ = St;
⎣1 + r ⎦
so, if we set
then
Thus the unique pricing measure makes S a multiplicative random walk with
up-jump probability of 8/15.
(ii) The price of the derivative is P = EQ[X/(1 + r)2], where X is the terminal value
of the derivative.
Thus,
P = 1,000Q(S2 ≠ 800)/1.042
= 1,000 × ((8/15)2 + (7/15)2)/1.042
= 464.33p
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
3 (i) Suppose that at time t we hold the portfolio (ϕt, ψt) where ϕt represents the
number of units of St held at time t and ψt is the number of units of the cash
bond held at time t.
(ii) Let Ft be the discounted value of a derivative (priced using the EMM) then
since it’s martingale, there is (by martingale representation) a ϕt such that
dFt = ϕtdDt, where D is the discounted price of the underlying. This ϕt is the
derivative’s delta.
(iii) It follows from the above that if we hold ϕt in the underlying asset and
ψt = Ft - ϕtDt in the bond, then the discounted value of our holding is Ft.
The holding is self-financing, since dV(t) = d(ertFt) = rert Ftdt + ert dFt
= rertFtdt + ert ϕtdSt + rert (Ft - ϕtDt) dt = ϕtdSt + ψt dBt.
The final discounted value of our holding is FT, and so we have hedged the
derivative with terminal value of VT.
4 (i) In the Wilkie model, the force of inflation, I(t), over the period t -1 to t is an
autoregressive model of order 1, AR1: It+1 = (1 - α) m + αIt + et, where the et
are iid normal errors.
Consequently we will get the unconstrained s.d., whereas the s.d. from
repeated one year simulations (cross-sectional) will depend strongly on initial
conditions.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
(iii) In a statistical model, the model structure is derived from past time series,
together with some intuition regarding what model formulae look reasonable.
However, these statistical models can produce some odd results. It can be
useful to impose additional economic constraints on model behaviour. The
advantage of using more economic theory is that it gives us a more concrete
way of interpreting model output. For example, if we model a market which is
broadly governed by rational pricing rules, we can apply those same pricing
rules to simulated output from a model. This gives us a market-based way of
comparing strategies, and deciding which strategy is most valuable. The
difficulty with this approach is that the model’s optimal strategy may not be
the strategy that managers wish to follow. In this context, a more flexible
judgmental approach may better meet the client’s needs.
(ii) The stochastic differential equation for the short rate r is:
6 (i) Since the efficient frontier consists of pairs of points (in (s.d., return)
coordinates) such that no higher return is available for the same or lower s.d.
we see that to get a return of r, greater than or equal to .05, we need a portfolio
of ((r - .05)/.05, 1 –((r - .05)/.05) = (20r – 1, 2 – 20r), this portfolio has a
standard deviation 0.2 (20r -1), hence the efficient frontier is the straight line
(4r – 0.2, r) which does indeed pass through the two specified points.
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
we see (after a lot of algebra) that the optimal x is 5/9, so the optimal portfolio
is (5/9, 4/9).
(iii) The efficient frontier in the presence of a risk free asset is the tangent to the
efficient frontier (without a risk free asset) which passes through the point in
(s.d., return)-space corresponding to the risk free asset.
Clearly this is the line through (0, .05) with maximal gradient which passes
through some point of the efficient frontier.
Hence the new efficient frontier is a straight line which passes through (0, .05)
and (√(.04(5/9)2 + .01(1 – 5/9)2), .06 + .04 × 5/9).
This is the line y = .05 + .2692x, which clearly passes through (.1, .076926).
These use observable economic time series as the factors. They could include
factors such as the annual rates of inflation and economic growth, short term
interest rates, the yields on long term government bonds, and the yield margin
on corporate bonds over government bonds. Once the set of factors has been
decided on, a time series regression is performed to determine the sensitivities
for each security in the sample.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
(ii) Denoting the changes in the two indices by It and Jt, let Kt = Jt - c It, where c
= Cov(It, Jt)/Var(It), then the two factors I and K are orthogonal. We can
check: Cov(It, Kt) = Cov(It, Jt) –c Var(It) = 0. Alternatively, we may regress
index J on index I to obtain J = a + bI + d2, and set K = d2, where a is a
constant and d2 is uncorrelated with I.
(iii) Suppose that Ri = αi + βi,1I + βi,2K + εi, then Var(Ri) = βi,12 Var(I) + βi,22
Var(K) + σi2.
8 (i) Under the Black Scholes assumptions, the unique risk-neutral measure is Q,
where, under Q,
(ii) The unique fair price for a derivative security which pays C at time T is
V0 = EQ [e−rTC].
V0 = EQ [e−rT1[a,b](ST)]
ST
Because B is a Brownian motion ln is normally distributed (under Q) with
S0
⎛ σ2 ⎞
mean ⎜ r − ⎟⎟ T and standard deviation Tσ .
⎜ 2
⎝ ⎠
x ⎛ σ2 ⎞
ln −⎜r − ⎟T
S0 ⎜⎝ 2 ⎟⎠
Hence Q(ST < x) = Φ(d(x)) where d(x) =
Tσ
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics)) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
= 100Φ(0.325) – 100e-0.05Φ(0.075)
= 12.33599
⎛S ⎞
ln ⎜ 0 ⎟ + (r + ½σ2 )
= S0Φ(d3) - Ue-0.05 Φ(d3 - σ) where d3 = ⎝ ⎠
U
c2
σ
⎛ σ2 ⎞
−⎜r − ⎟⎟
⎜
c3 = 100[e-0.05(1 - Φ(d4))] where d4 = ⎝ 2 ⎠ = −r + σ
σ σ 2
= 100[0.5040495] = 50.40495
⎛U ⎞ ⎛ σ2 ⎞
ln ⎜ ⎟ − ⎜ r − ⎟⎟
⎜
⎝ S 0 ⎠ ⎝ 2 ⎠
c4 = e-0.05(1 - Φ(d5)) where d5 =
σ
⎛S ⎞ ⎛ σ2 ⎞
− ln ⎜ 0 ⎟ − ⎜ r − ⎟
⎝ U ⎠ ⎜⎝ 2 ⎟⎠
=
σ
= − ( d 3 − σ)
Value = 0.1
+ 12.33599 × .004
+ 50.40495 × .004
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics) — September 2006 — Examiners’ Report
⎛ 0.35096376 ⎞
⇒ d3 = Φ −1 ⎜ 1 − ⎟
⎝ 0.5 ⎠
= -0.52995
100
⇒ ln = -0.52995 × 0.25 – 0.05 – ½0.252
U
⇒ U = 123.83
Page 8
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 9 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2006 Institute of Actuaries
1 An investor can construct a portfolio using only two assets A and B with the
following properties:
A B
(i) Derive a formula for and determine the composition of the investor s
minimum variance portfolio. [3]
2
Asset
State A B C D Probability of state
1 5% 5% 5% 2% 0.3
2 4% 7% 5% 6% 0.2
3 7% 3% 5% 9% 0.5
Value of asset 10,000 20,000 n/a 10,000
The table above gives the returns on all four assets in an investment market under the
three possible states of the world.
3 (i) State five key defining properties of a standard Brownian motion. [5]
(ii) Outline the advantages and disadvantages of using the continuous time
Lognormal model for stock prices by considering both the theoretical features
of the model and its consistency with empirical evidence. [6]
[Total 11]
CT8 A2006 2
4 (i) List the desirable characteristics of a term structure model. [4]
Under the real world probability measure, P, the price of a zero coupon bond with
maturity T is given by:
(ii) Derive:
(ii) Explain why it is not straight forward to identify when the semi-strong form of
stock market efficiency holds. [3]
(iii) Comment on the implications of stock market efficiency for passive and active
fund managers. [2]
[Total 7]
Qmu = 0.03
QA = 0.55
QSD = 0.45
(i) Calculate the 95% confidence interval for the force of inflation over the
following year given inflation over the past year was 2.75%. [4]
(ii) Explain an economic justification for using an AR(1) process for inflation. [1]
(iii) Explain whether a model of the form that is used for inflation is also suitable
for share prices. [3]
[Total 8]
(ii) State and compare the risk-neutral and state price deflator approaches to
valuing derivatives. [4]
[Total 7]
CT8 A2006 4
8 An employer contracts with his staff to give each of them 1,000 shares in one year s
time provided the share price increased from its current level of £1 to at least £1.50 at
the end of the year.
(i) Calculate the value of the contract with each employee by considering the
terms of the Black-Scholes formula, [6]
The employer now wishes to limit the gain to each employee to £2,000.
(iii) An employee has said that he believes the original uncapped contract is worth
£300. He has determined this by saying that he believes there is a 30% chance
of the share price being at least £1.50 therefore 30% £1 = 30p.
(a) Compare the approach taken by the employee and the approach used
in (i).
(b) Comment on the implications of the differences in (iii) (a) if there were
a market in such contracts.
[4]
[Total 16]
risk free interest rate r = 4% p.a. (equivalent to 0.016% per trading day)
continuously compounded
the ratio of the share price after an up jump compared with the share price before
the jump is given by u = exp( . 250 ½)
There are 250 trading days per year and ignore dividends except where specifically
mentioned.
(i) Calculate the price at time 0 of a European-style put option with a strike price
of 101p that expires in 2 days time. [6]
(ii) (a) Sketch a graph of the delta of a put option against share price with
exercise price 100.
(b) Explain the key features of the graph. [6]
(iii) Derive, using the binomial lattice, the price of a European-style call option
with exercise price 101p expiring in 2 days time. [1]
(v) Compare the result of (iii) to the result of (i) using put-call parity. [2]
Assume now that an investor holds a call option and a put option, both with exercise
prices of 101p, that can be exercised at the investor s option at the end of day 1 or the
end of day 2. At the end of day 1, just before the investor is allowed to exercise the
options, the company announces unexpectedly that a dividend of 3p per share will be
paid at the end of day 2 immediately prior to the expiry of the options.
(vi) (a) Construct the binomial lattice of share prices allowing for the dividend
payment.
(b) Explain the conditions under which the holders of the put and call
options will exercise at the end of day 1 after the announcement of the
dividend. [8]
[Total 27]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2006 6
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
April 2006
EXAMINERS REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with the aim of
helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around Core Reading as the
interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are working. They have however given
credit for any alternative approach or interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M Flaherty
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
June 2006
Comments
Faculty of Actuaries
Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
2 2
1 (i) Let V = VA A (1 A) VB 2 A (1 A )C AB
V
= VA 2 A 2(1 A )VB (2(1 A) 2 A )C AB
A
0 = VA 2 A (2 2 A )VB 2(1 2 A )C AB
0= A (V A VB 2C AB ) VB C AB
VB C AB
A =
VA VB 2C AB
In this case
= 28.2%
71.8% of asset B
(ii) As a portfolio is diversified, the return on the portfolio is less exposed to the
specific risk of any one component.
= 5.225%
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
2
2 10, 000 5% 20, 000 5% 10, 000 2%
m = 5.225% 0.3 +
40, 000
2
10, 000 4% 20, 000 7% 10, 000 6%
5.225% 0.2 +
40, 000
2
10, 000 7% 20, 000 3% 10, 000 9%
5.225% 0.5
40, 000
= 4.4312 10 5 = 0.66567%2
= 33.8%.
(ii) Empirical studies do not provide strong support for the model.
It does not account for taxes, inflation or where there is no riskless asset.
3 (i) Credit should be awarded for any five from the following:
(e) B0 = 0.
(f) Cov(Bs, Bt) = min (s, t) since, for s > t, Cov(Bt, Bt) = t and Cov(Bs Bt,
Bt) = 0.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
1
B1 (t ) Bct
c
B2 (t ) tB1/ t
(ii) Advantages
The mean and variance of return are proportional to the length of the time
interval considered.
Cannot use past history to identify whether prices are cheap or dear
implying weak form market efficiency consistent with empirical
observations.
Disadvantages
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
4 (i)
The model should be arbitrage free.
Interest rates should be positive.
Interest rates should exhibit some element of mean reversion.
The model should be computationally tractable.
Gives a reasonable range of possible yield curves.
Fits historical data.
Can be calibrated to current market data.
Flexible to cope with a range of derivatives.
Please note that there was a typographical error in this question where the first T in the
expression should have been a minus sign.
Candidates who identified this and proceeded on the assumption that there had been a
typographical error were given appropriate credit, as were candidates who noted that the
expression led to inconsistencies. The solution below shows the correct technical
approach applied to the question as it stood. All candidates scripts were assessed to take
into account any additional impact of this error.
dB(t, T) = B(t, T) (-Trtdt ½ 2(T t)2dt + T(T - t) drt + ½T2(T t)2 2dt)
s(t, T) = (T t) . T
(rt (T (T t ) 2) ½(T t ) 2 2
(T 2 1))
Therefore (t) =
T (T t )
(b) SDE for rt is drt = dzt under the risk neutral measure Q
rt ( (T (T t ) 2) ½(T t ) 2 2
(T 2 1))dt
drt = dzt
T (T t )
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
5 (i) If a market is strong form efficient then senior managers could not make
abnormal profits. The existence of a ban suggests abnormal profits could be
made, which suggests markets are not strong form efficient.
(ii) Different stock exchanges have different disclosure levels therefore different
markets have different levels of efficiency.
(iii) In aggregate, active managers hold the market, which is identical to the
passive manager. Therefore the average active manager should perform in
line with the passive manager.
The existence of active managers suggests a belief that markets are inefficient.
Q(t 1)
= 1.0275 = eI(t 1)
Q(t 2)
The 95% confidence interval for I(t) is therefore at the upper level
= 0.910
= 0.854
Candidates who used 0.045 as in the original Wilkie calibration (instead of 0.45) were given
appropriate credit.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
(iii) The model used for inflation is not suitable for share prices for the following
reasons:
(1) Strong mean reversion implies prices are predictable so high returns
are possible with little risk through active market timing. This runs
counter to much empirical evidence.
(2) Lots of evidence for share price jumps in market prices that are not
reflected in the model.
(3) Share prices tend to increase rather than mean revert therefore a
stationary process is not suitable.
(4) The model permits negative share prices, which is highly unrealistic.
7 (i) The martingale approach gives much more clarity in the valuation process. By
providing an explicit expectation to evaluate.
(ii)
Risk neutral pricing approach is the same as the martingale approach, i.e.
values are derived from the risk neutral world.
The approach is the same as risk-neutral pricing, the only difference is that
calculations are presented using the real world measure and a stochastic
adjustment factor versus a risk neutral measure. Intuitively the deflator
approach can also give information about real world expected outcomes.
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
8 (i) The value of the promise can be thought as part of a call option contract. A
call option consists of a contract to deliver a share in return for the payment of
an exercise, where the share price exceeds the exercise price.
The promise made to the employees is the first part of the call option, the
promise to deliver a share provided the price exceeds a certain level.
Therefore, the first component of the Black Scholes formula gives the value
2
ln s / k r ½
Value = S.N(d1) where d1 = T
T
1
ln 0.04 ½0.32
1.5
= 1,000 N
0.3
= N( 1.0682) 1,000
= £142.70
(ii) Limiting the gain under the contract can be represented by a portfolio of the
above promise less a call option with exercise price of £2.
where
d1 = 2.027
d2 = 2.327
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
(iii) (a) The employee has taken a view about the expected growth in share
price. The result is a value that is not consistent with risk neutral
pricing.
This means that, if there were a market in these contracts the price the
employee has derived is not equal to the price the market would place
on it.
(b) If the employer were willing to buy such promises at their suggested
price, an arbitrageur would sell of £300 and hedge their position at
£142.70. Resulting in substantial risk free profits.
9 (i)
102.562 Put payoff nil
101.273
98.743
e0.016% 0.98743
q =
1.01273 0.98743
= 0.50316
= 1.3635
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
(ii) (a)
0
(2)
Delta
(1)
1.0
0 100 200
Delta is negative as the value of a put option falls when share price
rises.
(1) When the share price is very low the value is almost 100
therefore delta is almost 1.
(2) When share price is high the value is almost nil therefore delta
is almost nil.
(iv) Put call parity means for all time t < T, then
ct + ke r(T t) = pt + s t
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
Consider
By the principle of no arbitrage since the payoffs are identical at time T the
value of the portfolios must be identical at time t < T.
= 0.4063
This is not equal to the value above because the binomial model is a discrete
time approximation to a continuous model. Therefore, the difference in value
is due to discretisation error.
99.562
9.562
101.273
100 97
98.743
94.502
Call option
If the option holder exercise at day 1 when the share price has risen they will
have a positive gain. Therefore, exercising early, if the share price has risen
will be advantageous.
Page 11
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2006 Examiners Report
Put option
It is clear that it is not advantageous for the option holder to exercise early as
follows:
Page 12
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 S2005 Institute of Actuaries
1 An investor is contemplating an investment with a return of £R, where:
R = 300,000 500,000U
A 40%
B 20%
C 10%
The correlation between the returns on each pair of distinct securities is 0.5.
(i) Prove that the expected returns on A, B and C are 40%, 20% and 10%
respectively if the CAPM is assumed to hold. [9]
(ii) Derive a single index model (with the index equal to RM, the random return on
the market portfolio) with the same expected returns and variances as in the
CAPM. You are required to calculate the values of all parameters in the model.
[4]
(iii) Prove that this single index model is not completely consistent with the CAPM
model. [3]
[Total 16]
CT8 S2005 2
3 (i) Define in words , , , , , and for an individual derivative. [6]
(ii) Explain how and can be used in the risk management of a portfolio that is
delta-hedged. [4]
[Total 10]
4 (i) State the assumptions underlying the Black-Scholes option pricing formula
and discuss how realistic they are. [6]
(ii) By using the hedging position and the Black-Scholes formula for the value of
the option, derive two equations satisfied by N and , the bank s assumed
volatility. [3]
Xt+1 = b if St+1 = St
= a if St+1 = St
A portfolio of cash (amount y) and stock (value x) at time t exactly replicates the
payoff of the derivative at time t + 1.
(iii) Suppose that r = 0%. Two derivatives each have a payoff of a if St+1 = St,
but the first derivative pays 2a and the second 3a if St+1 = St. The price at
time t of the first derivative is 10. Derive an expression, in terms of a, for the
price at time t of the second derivative. [3]
[Total 8]
(ii) Determine a fair (forward) price for a forward contract on a share (currently
priced at £10) with delivery in 20 months when the share pays a dividend of
3% of the share price every six months, the continuous risk-free rate is 7% p.a.
and the next dividend is due in one month s time.
[You may assume that dividends are immediately re-invested.] [5]
[Total 9]
7 Consider the following discrete time models for (log) share prices and (log) dividend
yields:
where
Wt and Zt are both serially uncorrelated standard normal random variables but are
correlated with each other and , , and are positive parameters and 0 < < 1.
(i) Explain the magnitude and sign of the correlation coefficient you would
expect between Zt and Wt . You do not have to calculate the correlation
coefficient or derive an expression for it. [2]
(ii) State two properties of the dividend yield model and comment on their
realism. [2]
(iii) State three properties of the share price model and comment on them relative
to empirical evidence and, if relevant, the efficient markets hypothesis. [3]
[Total 7]
CT8 S2005 4
8 Suppose that under the unique Equivalent Martingale Measure, Q, for a term structure
model, the SDE satisfied by the instantaneous interest rate r is
where > 0, and are fixed parameters and, under Q, Z is a standard Brownian
Motion.
t
Xt = rt b(T t) r ds,
0 s
[Hint: First show that dXt = Atdt + BtdZt where At = b(T t) and Bt = b(T t)]
(ii) (a) Find a differential equation which the function a must satisfy for
f(Xt, t) to be a martingale.
t
B(t, T) = f(Xt, t) exp r ds . [4]
0 s
[Total 10]
9 The following model has been suggested for the short term interest rate at time t, rt:
drt = rt dt + rt dZt
(i) Outline three properties of this model and comment on their desirability. [3]
(ii) Outline the properties of the following two models for interest rates:
(ii) Explain to what extent the results of such tests should affect the assessment of
the validity or otherwise of the efficient markets hypothesis. [3]
END OF PAPER
CT8 S2005 6
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
September 2005
EXAMINERS REPORT
Faculty of Actuaries
Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
Thus
So,
and
and
2
M = [2 Cov(RM, RA) + 3 Cov(RM, RB) + 2 Cov(RM, RC)] / 7 = .03674.
Finally, solving
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
Ri = (1 i) r0 + i RM + i
where the i s are uncorrelated with each other and with RM, and i has
variance equal to
2 2
Var(Ri) i M ,
so that, setting
2 2 2 2
Var( i) = i, A = 0.0320, B = 0.0131 and C = 0.0055.
(iii) The single index model is not the same as the CAPM model because
the covariances of asset returns are different in the two models: in the
single index model
2
Cov(Ri, Rj) = i j M,
3 (i) Delta: the rate of change in derivative price with respect to change in the price
of underlying asset.
Gamma: the rate of change of delta with respect to change in the price of
underlying asset.
Theta: the rate of change in the value of the derivative with respect to change
in time to expiration.
lambda: the rate of change in the value of the derivative with respect to change
in the assumed continuous dividend yield on the underlying asset.
rho: the rate of change in the value of the derivative with respect to change in
the risk-free rate of interest.
vega: the rate of change in the value of the derivative with respect to the
(assumed) volatility of the underlying asset.
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
(ii) Assuming that the portfolio under management is delta hedged at discrete
times, the two most important Greeks are gamma and vega. Between
rebalancing at the trading times, delta will drift away from zero as the
underlying asset prices move. If the portfolio is gamma-hedged at the discrete
trading times then the amount of such drift will be small (comparable to the
square of the change in underlying price).
4 (i) No frictions; short-selling permitted; small investor (i.e. does not move the
market ); market is arbitrage-free; stock price is given by
(ii) Let N be the number of options written, then N (d1) = 250,000. Now the
value of the bank s portfolio is
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
(iv) Consequently,
5 (i) Consider an investment of x in the stock and y in cash at time t: the value of
the holding at time t + 1 is
x + y(1 + r),
x + y(1 + r),
x + y(1 + r) = b, (1)
x + y(1 + r) = a, (2).
x = (b a) / ( ) and
y = (a b )/( )(1 + r)
(ii) x + y = Xt = [qb + (1 q)a](1 + r) 1
(iii) Using (3), we see from the first derivative that q = (10/a) 1, while, from the
second we see that q = (c2/2a) 1/2, so we deduce that c2 = 20 a.
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
6 (i) Consider a portfolio which is, initially, short one forward contract, holds 1
share and is short c in cash. At the delivery date for the forward contract, the
portfolio contains 1 share and is short cert, where r is the risk free rate and t is
the duration of the contract.
So, immediately after delivery the portfolio contains zero shares and is short
cert p in cash, where p is the forward price.
Setting c = pe rt, the portfolio contains nothing. It follows that the portfolio
should have a zero set-up cost so, so p = S0ert.
(ii) Consider a portfolio which is, initially, short one forward contract, holds s
shares and is short c in cash. At each dividend date the dividend is used to buy
more shares. At the delivery date for the forward contract, the portfolio
contains 1.034s shares and is short cert, where r is the risk free rate and t is the
duration of the contract.
So, immediately after delivery the portfolio contains 1.034s 1 shares and is
short cert p in cash, where p is the forward price.
(iii) Not mean-reverting: consistent with weak form EMH. Empirical evidence is
mixed.
Normal distribution: markets jump and returns have fat tails, so inconsistent
with empirical evidence.
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
f(Xt, t) = e a (T t) Xt
t
Now Xt = b(T t)rt + r ds
0 s
(T t ) (T t )
e rt dt 1 e ( rt )dt
(r t )
rt dt 1 e dZt
(T t ) (T t )
1 e dt 1 e dZt
tdt + BtdZt
Using Ito
f f f 1 2f 2
df(Xt, t) = Bt dZt At Bt dt
x t x 2 x2
= f ( X t , t ) Bt dZt f ( X t , t ) a (T t )dt
1
f ( X t , t ) At dt f ( X t , t ) Bt2 dt
2
1 2
f ( Xt , t) a (T t ) At Bt dt Bt dZt
2
1 2
a (T t ) = At Bt
2
1 2 2
= b(T t ) b (T t )
2
a(0) = 0
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
9 (i) This means short term interest rates would in the long term increase if >0
geometrically. This is not desirable as it does not reflect reality.
The model also has the following properties:
The model requires constant volatility over time. This is not desirable as
volatility of short term interest rates changes over time.
Under-reaction
However, some of the tests (such as accounting ratios) may not allow properly
for risk and the results are therefore not incompatible with the EMH.
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) Sept 2005 Examiners Report
(iii) Assume that investors are non satiated (always prefer more expected return to
less) and risk averse (in the sense of wanting to avoid volatility of returns).
An efficient portfolio is one with the highest expected return for a given level
of volatility and the lowest volatility for the expected return.
Page 9
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
1. Enter all the candidate and examination details as requested on the front of your answer
booklet.
2. You must not start writing your answers in the booklet until instructed to do so by the
supervisor.
4. Attempt all 10 questions, beginning your answer to each question on a separate sheet.
Hand in BOTH your answer booklet, with any additional sheets firmly attached, and this
question paper.
In addition to this paper you should have available the 2002 edition of the
Formulae and Tables and your own electronic calculator.
Faculty of Actuaries
CT8 A2005 Institute of Actuaries
1 An investor holds a portfolio consisting of N assets in equal proportions.
Derive an expression for the variance of the portfolio as N gets very large.
[You may assume that all assets have variance less than a certain level Vmax. You may
also assume that the average covariance is c .]
[6]
2 An investor wishes to measure the investment risk presented by an asset which has the
following distribution:
1 10% 0.5
2 20% 0.3
3 50% 0.2
(i) Evaluate three different measures of investment risk for this asset. Where
necessary, you may assume a benchmark return of 25%. [4]
3 An investor has the choice of the following assets that earn rates of return as follows
in each of the four possible states of the world:
1 0.2 5% 5% 6%
2 0.3 5% 12% 5%
3 0.1 5% 3% 4%
4 0.4 5% 1% 7%
CT8 A2005 2
4 Let Ri denote the return on security i given by the following multifactor model
ai and ci are the constant and random parts respectively of the component of the return
unique to security i.
5 The following unusual model has been proposed for the (real-world) stochastic
behaviour of the short term interest rate:
drt = rt dt + dZt,
where > 0 and are fixed parameters and Z is a standard Brownian motion under
the proposed real-world measure P.
Under the same measure P, a (zero coupon) bond with maturity T has price at time t
B(t, T) = exp( (T t) rt + 2(T t)3/6).
(b) Determine the market price of risk and deduce the corresponding SDE for r,
under the risk neutral measure Q.
[7]
You may assume that the basic Black-Scholes framework is used to price the options.
(i) Explain why the option price has fallen even though the expected return has
increased according to the analysts. [3]
(ii) State any requirements for the option price to have fallen to its level on 2
November. [3]
[Total 6]
7 (i) Outline the approach adopted by Shiller to test for excessive volatility and
state the criticisms of his work. [7]
(ii) State one difficulty of testing the strong form of the efficient market
hypothesis and state the general conclusion of studies carried out on it. [2]
[Total 9]
8 (i) State the martingale representation theorem, including conditions for its
application, defining all terms used. [3]
Let St denote the price of an underlying security at time t; r denotes the risk free rate
of return expressed in continuously compounded form, Bt represents an accumulated
bank account at time t that earns the risk free rate of return.
Let X be any derivative payment contingent on FT, payable at some fixed future time
T, where FT is the sigma algebra generated by Su for 0 u T.
You may assume that, under the equivalent measure Q, the process
Dt = e rt St is a martingale
and that
CT8 A2005 4
9 (i) Describe the role that the inflation model plays within the Wilkie model. [3]
The Wilkie model proposes an AR(1) process for the continuously compounded rate
of inflation I(t) that can be written as:
Where (t) ~ N(0, t2) and a and b are constants with 1 < b < 1.
(ii) Derive an expression for the long term average rate of inflation in terms of a
and b. [1]
(iii) Explain why a model of the form above would not be suitable for share prices.
[3]
(iv) Explain why a lognormal model may be used for share prices and state its
weaknesses. [8]
[Total 15]
10 An investment bank has issued a derivative on a share (with share price, S, of 100)
that provides for the following payoff after two months:
There exists a risk free asset that earns 5% per month, continuously compounded.
The expected effective rate of return on the share is 2% per month.
The monthly standard deviation of the log share price is 10%.
(i) By using a two period recombining model of future share prices, derive the
state price deflators at time 2. The parameters determining the share price
after an up-jump and down-jump should be determined by considering the
standard deviation of the log share price. [9]
(ii) Using the state price deflators from (i) derive the value at time zero of the
option. [3]
The delta of this derivative at time zero is 7% and the gamma is 10%. The bank
which issued the derivative wishes to delta hedge its position in the most efficient
manner. Assume that the share price can also be modelled in continuous time with a
geometric Brownian motion with volatility (diffusion parameter) of 0.1 consistent
with a Black-Scholes framework.
(iii) Determine the delta hedging portfolio, as a combination of the risk free asset,
the underlying share, and a European Call option on the share with term of
3 months and exercise price of 100. [13]
[Total 25]
END OF PAPER
CT8 A2005 5
Faculty of Actuaries Institute of Actuaries
EXAMINATION
April 2005
EXAMINERS REPORT
Introduction
The attached subject report has been written by the Principal Examiner with
the aim of helping candidates. The questions and comments are based around
Core Reading as the interpretation of the syllabus to which the examiners are
working. They have however given credit for any alternative approach or
interpretation which they consider to be reasonable.
M Flaherty
Chairman of the Board of Examiners
15 June 2005
Faculty of Actuaries
Institute of Actuaries
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
1 1
V= 2
Vi Cij
i N i j i N2
1 1
Let V = Vi , and c = Cij
N N ( N 1) i j i
1 ( N 1)
V = V c
N N
As N
1 1 1
V 0 because V Vmax
N N N
1
and Vmax 0 as N
N
therefore V c as N
2 (i) The mean return is 0.1 0.5 + 0.2 0.3 + 0.5 0.2 = 21%
Variance of return
(0.1 0.21)2 0.5 + (0.2 0.21)2 0.3 + (0.5 0.21)2 0.2 2.29%%
Shortfall probability
Page 2
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
(ii) (a)
It is a statistical measure of downside risk.
It assesses the potential minimum loss over given time with given
degree of confidence.
3 The market price of risk is (Em r)/ m where asset 1 is the risk free asset so r = 5%.
= 5.79472%
2
m = 0.2 (0.17546 5% + 0.82454 6% 5.79472%)2
= 0.000045402
= (0.674%)2
= 1.179 = 118%
Page 3
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
(ii) The single index model requires the return on the market, plus
for each security: i, i and i .
L( L 1)
covariances
2
N ai s
NL sensitivities
N standard deviations of ci
L( L 3)
Therefore N ( L 2) data items are required
2
Page 4
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
where
6 (i) Options are priced by relative valuation techniques (i.e. risk neutral
valuation).
This approach is equivalent to building a hedging strategy for the option and
does not take account of the expected return on the share. Since the hedging
strategy involves holding some shares, the drop in price will result in a drop of
the value of the option even though the expected future share price has
remained the same.
(ii) Unless the option is deep in the money, the drop in price of the option will be
less than proportional to the share price and hence some combination of the
following must also have occurred:
dividends increased
share price volatility decreased
risk free interest rate decreased
7 (i) Shiller used a discounted cashflow model of equities going back to 1870.
A perfect foresight price was determined using actual dividends paid and a
terminal value for the stock.
If markets are rational there would be no systematic forecast errors (i.e. error
between the perfect foresight price and the actual price).
If markets are efficient, the perfect foresight price matches with share price.
(ii)
Page 5
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
8 (i) Suppose Xt is a martingale with respect to a measure P, that is for any t < s
EP[Xs Ft] = Xt
t
Yt = Y0 + s dX s
0
dEt = tdDt
Let t = Et tDt
tunits of asset St
t of cash Bt
Page 6
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
t St + tBt = Vt
tdSt + tdBt
= Bt[dEt + rEtdt]
= dVt
9 (i) The Wilkie model can be described as a cascade or hierarchical model, with
inflation being the key component. Variations of dividend yields, growth and
interest rates are affected by shocks in the inflation model and moving
averages of past inflation.
(ii) I = a + bI
a
I =
1 b
Page 7
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
(iii)
AR process is stationary, share prices have tended to increase over time.
(iv) Log-normal distribution makes the maths for option pricing simple (i.e.
tractable solutions).
Weaknesses:
d = 1/1.10517 = 0.904837
122.14 (1)
110.52
90.48
81.87 (3)
Page 8
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
Since the real world expected return is 2% per month, we can derive the real
world probability of an up-jump
(102 90.48)
p= = 57.5%
(110.52 90.48)
e5% 0.904837
q= = 73.1%
1.10517 0.904837
Node
2
0.1 q
(1) e = 1.4624
p
0.1 q 1 q
(2) e = 0.72809
p 1 p
2
0.1 1 q
(3) e = 0.36249
1 p
(ii) The value is EP[A2 f (S2)] where S2 is the share price at time 2.
= 2.4972
Page 9
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
100
log (0.05 ½0.12 ) 3
Where d1 = 100 = 0.95263
0.1 3
100
log (0.05 ½0.12 ) 3
d2 = 100 = 0.7794256
0.1 3
Therefore value is
= 15.642
S 2
log (r ½ )t
= (d1) where d1 = K
t
= 0.95263
= 0.82961
2
(d1 ) (0.95263) 1 e ½ 0.95263
= = = .
s t 100 0.1 3 2 100 0.1 3
= 1.46%
Clearly the risk free rate has nil delta and gamma.
Page 10
Subject CT8 (Financial Economics Core Technical) April 2005 Examiners Report
0.1
x3 = = 6.8493
0.0146
x2 = 5.6123
x1 = 456.59
Therefore
Page 11