Lee 2015

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 24

PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

ANNUAL
REVIEWS Further How Party Polarization
Click here for quick links to
Annual Reviews content online,
including:
Affects Governance
• Other articles in this volume
• Top cited articles Frances E. Lee
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.

• Top downloaded articles


Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

• Our comprehensive search Department of Government and Politics, University of Maryland, College Park,
Maryland 20742; email: FLee1@umd.edu

Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015. 18:261–82 Keywords


First published online as a Review in Advance on public policy making, US Congress, US Presidency, US Supreme Court
February 4, 2015

The Annual Review of Political Science is online at Abstract


polisci.annualreviews.org
The purpose of this review is to take stock of how party polarization affects
This article’s doi: governance in the United States. The article begins by defining polariza-
10.1146/annurev-polisci-072012-113747
tion and discussing the means by which it can be measured. It is undeniable
Copyright  c 2015 by Annual Reviews. that the two parties have grown more sharply differentiated. Some evidence
All rights reserved
suggests that the substantive policy preferences of liberals and conservatives
diverge more widely, but the case for ideological polarization in the spatial
sense is not definitive. Effects on the institutional processes of US govern-
ment have entailed a hardening of party divisions and a tendency toward
centralization of power. Nevertheless, these more cohesive parties are not
more effective than their predecessors at enacting policies or managing rou-
tine governing responsibilities. The consequences for public policy seem
best characterized as “drift” (Hacker 2004, p. 246). There is little evidence
that party polarization has promoted ideologically extreme policy outcomes
or has systematically advantaged either liberalism or conservatism.

261
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

INTRODUCTION
“This country was founded on compromise,” remarked President Barack Obama at a December
2010 press conference (White House 2010). Though made at an unusually contentious moment,
Obama’s observation encapsulates a general truth: Governing any democracy without compromise
is impossible (Gutmann & Thompson 2012, p. 1). Compromise is foundational for governance in
the United States. The US Constitution is both the product and the producer of compromises.
The complex division of power it establishes—across coequal, separately elected branches with a
bicameral legislature—forces national leaders to seek cooperation from an array of independent
actors, all with their own bases of political power and formal authority. The system demands
exceptional skill at negotiation and conciliation.
The dramatic intensification of party conflict in US national politics over the past four decades
raises questions for a constitutional system that places such a premium on compromise. Adjec-
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.

tives such as “polarized” and “dysfunctional” are frequently deployed to describe contemporary
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

politics. In a recent political science bestseller, Mann & Ornstein (2012, p. 102) argue that a
fundamental “mismatch” exists between the separation-of-powers system and the “parliamentary-
style political parties” that have emerged. Unease about the prospects for successful negotiation in
such an environment underlies a recent American Political Science Association Task Force report
(Mansbridge & Martin 2013; see also Persily 2015). However, intense partisan conflict is hardly
new to US politics (Han & Brady 2007). In fact, it may well be the normal state of affairs, and the
long postwar period of muted party conflict may constitute a mere exception.
The purpose of this review is to take stock of how party polarization affects governance in
the United States. Governing is multifaceted. There is no single benchmark by which it can be
assessed. It obviously entails a capacity to enact policies both in response to social problems and
in accordance with the preferences of democratic majorities. Governing also encompasses the
ability to carry out routine functions such as budgeting, appropriations, and appointments to the
executive branch and judiciary. In addition, governance includes the management of interbranch
relationships, such as congressional oversight of the executive branch and presidential leadership
of Congress. Finally, governance involves questions of systemic sustainability: Are governing
institutions gaining or losing power relative to one another, and is the system of checks and
balances being maintained?
The essay begins by defining polarization and discussing the means by which it can be measured.
On the basis of the available data, it is undeniable that the two parties in the United States have
grown more sharply differentiated, and each party has become more cohesive and more likely to
come into conflict with the other. Some evidence suggests that liberals and conservatives diverge
more widely than in the past in terms of the substantive content of their policy preferences, but
the case for ideological polarization in the spatial sense is far from definitive. Rising party conflict
may also be driven, at least in part, by an environment of intensified party competition for the
control of governing institutions.
Next, the essay examines the effects of growing partisan differentiation on both institutional
processes and policy outcomes. Within and across institutions, the broad story has been one of
hardening party divisions and increasing centralization of power. Under circumstances of fierce
party competition, leaders have also been empowered to take responsibility for partisan messaging
aimed at shaping public opinion. But it is by no means clear that these more cohesive parties are any
more effective at governance or at shaping either policy or politics to their liking. The substantive
effects on public policy are best characterized as “drift” (Hacker 2004, p. 246; Mettler 2014,
p. 14). There is little evidence that party polarization has promoted ideologically extreme policy
outcomes or has systematically advantaged either liberalism or conservatism.

262 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

DEFINING AND MEASURING POLARIZATION


In a layman’s definition, “polarization” denotes “division into two sharply contrasting groups”
(Oxford Univ. Press 2000). Notably, political polarization need not entail party polarization. The
civil rights movement during the 1950s and 1960s and the Vietnam War both raised profoundly
polarizing sets of issues, but they did not clearly divide Republicans from Democrats (Hetherington
2009). Likewise, the issue of slavery was highly polarizing, but before the collapse of the Whig
Party and the founding of the Republican Party, the issue was not polarized along partisan lines;
instead, top leaders of both major parties sought to straddle the explosive question (Sundquist
1983). Moreover, party polarization may or may not entail societal polarization. In fact, compared
with the “creedal passion” (Huntington 1981, p. 4) and social unrest that characterized other
periods of American politics, the post-1980s era seems relatively quiescent. The Tea Party and
the Occupy movements are but pale shadows of the turmoil and grassroots activism engendered
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.

by antislavery agitation, Prohibition, the Vietnam War, and the push for African American civil
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

rights.
Although a lay definition of polarization is simply division into two groups, the term has a
more technical meaning in political science. In its most rigorous form, the concept of polarization
is grounded in spatial theory. It rests upon a theorized choice space in which policy preferences
are ranged along a preexisting continuum, understood generically as extending from left to right.
“For parties to be polarized,” write Poole & Rosenthal (2011, p. 105), “they must be far apart on
policy issues, and the party members must be tightly clustered around the party mean.” In other
words, parties become polarized when (a) the preferences of members become more distinctly
bimodal and (b) the two modes move farther apart.
Polarization in the spatial sense thus means more than increased partisan distinctiveness or
division into two groups. The term does not apply if the parties are just better organized into
competing “long coalitions” wrangling over control of political offices or logrolling distributive
benefits (Aldrich 1995, pp. 32–43). Nor is polarization occurring if Democrats and Republicans
merely get better organized as teams, such that members more loyally adhere to the party plat-
forms they hammer out among their factions and allied interests. Instead, party polarization as
understood in spatial theory refers to changes in the distribution of policy preferences within and
across the parties.
What makes measurement of polarization so complicated is that the parties can become more
distinctive even if liberals and conservatives do not move farther apart in substantive policy terms.
Parties can become better “sorted” ideologically—with conservatives confined to one party and
liberals to the other—but liberals and conservatives themselves might be no farther apart on
substantive policy than they were in the past (Fiorina & Abrams 2009, pp. 61–70). Parties can also
become more distinct from one another on issues that do not bear on larger ideological questions
(Lee 2009). “Valence issues” (Stokes 1963, p. 373)—in which one party accuses the other of
incompetence or corruption—typically trigger ferocious party conflict, even as both parties profess
the same underlying preferences for honesty and competency in government. When congressional
leaders stage an increased number of message votes—votes designed to highlight the differences
between the parties—overall party conflict goes up, even in the absence of ideological shifts among
members (Lee 2009, 2011).
There is strong evidence of increased party distinctiveness in American politics. The pattern
is unmistakable in Congress, where party conflict has been rising since the mid-1970s. In an
increasing proportion of congressional votes, more than 90% of one party votes against 90%
of the other party (Van Houweling 2003). When party conflict occurs, both representatives and
senators exhibit far more loyalty to their parties than they did in the past. In the 1950s, 1960s,

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 263


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

and 1970s, the typical member of Congress voted with his party on party-dividing questions just
over 60% of the time; in the 1980s, over 70% of the time; and in the 1990s, over 80% of the time.
Since 2000, members have voted with their parties more than 87% of the time (Ethridge 2012,
Weyl 2014).
One of the most important sources of increased partisan cohesion has been the protracted
realignment that has sorted economic and racial conservatives into the same party. For decades
after the New Deal, race and economics had been crosscutting issues in Congress. Southern
Democrats were vital to the passage of many social welfare programs, even while remaining
staunch segregationists (Katznelson 2013). Republicans were friendlier to civil rights than were
southern Democrats but generally less supportive of social welfare programs and business regu-
lations. Through a long process in which politicians and activists (Schickler 2013) as well as intel-
lectuals (Noel 2013) played key roles, racial liberalism and economic liberalism eventually became
linked. After the enactment of the Civil Rights Act of 1964 and the Voting Rights Act of 1965,
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

southern white conservatives steadily left the Democratic Party for the Republican Party, greatly
diminishing sectionalism as a source of partisan disunity in Congress (Rohde 1991, Theriault
2008). These changes made the parties more clearly distinct, but it is not clear that they moved
liberals and conservatives farther apart in spatial terms.
Sharper partisan distinctions in government draw inspiration and reinforcement from outside
government. Republican and Democratic activists—the grassroots volunteers who build and staff
the parties’ organizations and turnout operations—hold policy positions that are more strongly
differentiated than in the past. In great part, this increased differentiation is a result of more
“attitude constraint” (Converse 1964, p. 207), which means that activists’ policy positions correlate
more consistently across different issues. Surveys of convention delegates reveal that, compared
with previous decades, Republicans exhibit marked increases in attitude constraint; Democrats
have shown no declines (Layman et al. 2010, p. 338). Beyond the increases in constraint, the
policy preferences of the two parties’ activists also diverge more substantively on some repeatedly
polled items, with Democrats’ views moving toward the left and, especially, Republicans’ views
migrating to the right (Layman et al. 2010, p. 336).
Other studies have shown that the most politically engaged and knowledgeable citizens in the
United States are also the most ideologically consistent (Abramowitz 2010, Ellis & Stimson 2012,
Fiorina & Abrams 2009). Although only a minority of Americans exhibit ideological constraint, the
share is larger than in the past. According to a recent study (Pew Res. Cent. 2014), the percentage
of Americans who hold either consistently conservative or consistently liberal positions on major
issues doubled between 1994 and 2014, reaching one in five Americans.
The extensive organizational networks that now surround each of the two parties also fos-
ter partisan distinctiveness. Orbiting each party is an array of organizations, including advocacy
groups, media outlets, ideological foundations, lobbying firms, 527s, and think tanks (Grossmann
& Dominguez 2009, Herrnson 2009). The two parties’ networks are highly distinct from one an-
other (Karol 2009, Koger et al. 2009). They are also much larger than in the past. This growth has
been fueled by an explosion of advocacy organizations (Berry 1997, Skocpol 1999), a proliferation
of think tanks (Rich 2004), and extensive innovations in campaign finance (La Raja 2013). The
liberal advocacy network aligned with the Democratic Party emerged first; the Republican Party’s
developed afterward (Berry 1997), according to a pattern often described as the conservative
countermobilization (Hacker & Pierson 2010, pp. 116–36; Skocpol 2007; Teles 2008).
The question of polarization in the spatial sense of wider policy differences between liberals and
conservatives in government is much more difficult to settle. According to their stated platforms,
the two major parties in American politics have almost always been highly distinct on issues

264 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

(Gerring 1998). Are liberals and conservatives actually farther apart today in substantive policy
terms? Some data on convention delegates suggest that they are, though increases in partisan
consistency are at least as important as any movements of opinion toward the poles. But we lack
hard data on the distribution of officeholders’ policy preferences. We have no long-term polls
of elite opinion comparable with the ones we possess for the mass electorate or for convention
delegates.1
Instead, the measurement of elite preferences is inferred from behavior—in the case of lawmak-
ers, from their roll-call votes. Among the variety of alternative measures that have been developed
(Bonica 2014, Clinton et al. 2004, Groseclose et al. 1999), the most prominent is NOMINATE,
created by Poole & Rosenthal (1991, 1997). According to DW-NOMINATE (and results do not
differ greatly when alternative methodologies are used), the parties are farther apart than at any
point since the Civil War (McCarty et al. 2006, pp. 23–29). Furthermore, such methodologies
attribute much, albeit not all, contemporary party polarization to pronounced rightward moves
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

among Republicans, a pattern described as asymmetric polarization (Hacker & Pierson 2005,
Mann & Ornstein 2012, Theriault 2013, Theriault & Rohde 2011).
The question, of course, is how well patterns in roll-call voting can gauge underlying substantive
policy positions. The widespread acceptance of ideal point estimates derives in great part from their
face validity. These methodologies yield rank orderings of lawmakers that correspond well with
scholars’ and journalists’ impressions of who in Congress is most liberal and most conservative.
First-dimension DW-NOMINATE scores also work remarkably well at summarizing individual
members’ behavior across issues and over their whole careers.
Even so, there is reason for skepticism about the ability of these scores to measure change
in substantive policy preferences over time. NOMINATE and other vote-scaling methodologies
cannot distinguish partisan teamsmanship from ideology as influences on roll-call voting (Lee
2009, pp. 47–73; Noel 2013, pp. 122–42; Poole & Rosenthal 1991, p. 230). The raw data on which
these scores are based—a matrix of zeros and ones—can generate only an ordinal ranking of
members, a map of who votes with whom. To draw inferences about the policy distances between
members, i.e., to go from an ordinal ranking to estimates of cardinal distances in a theorized choice
space, requires additional, debatable assumptions (Clinton 2012).
One must assume sincere spatial voting—that is, that members cast votes by calculating policy
distances from their own ideal points (Poole & Rosenthal 1991, 1997). There are other bases on
which members cast roll-call votes, and there is no reason to think that these alternative decision
criteria entail calculations of policy proximity (Cooper & Young 2002, pp. 100–4). For example,
members might cast votes to enhance their party’s brand name with various constituencies. Such
explicitly political votes can entail reflexively opposing measures proposed by leaders or presidents
of the other party (Lee 2009). Under this criterion, members might even vote against measures
they favor on policy grounds (Gilmour 1995), such as when Republicans voted in 2010 against
a bipartisan debt commission they had previously sponsored (Mann & Ornstein 2012, pp. ix–x;
Theriault 2013, pp. 140–41).2 Considerations of partisan brands may well take higher priority in

1
Surveys of convention delegates, if restricted on the basis of vocation, could serve as a reasonable proxy for officeholder
preferences. But such surveys contain only a limited number of repeatedly asked identical questions that permit direct com-
parisons across time. Repeatedly polled items tend to be abstract and are likely to trigger different substantive content and
policy connotations for respondents in different eras.
2
Another nonspatial logic is “hostage taking,” in which members refuse to support measures that are acceptable by their own
lights in order to win concessions on other policy dimensions (Aldrich & Rohde 2000a, pp. 59–62).

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 265


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

members’ decision making when party control of governing institutions seemingly hangs in the
balance.
Members also cast votes to shape their own individual political images. They may seek to
cultivate personal reputations for principled behavior, even if doing so requires them to reject
policies that are more spatially proximate to their own ideal points than the status quo—such
as when Sen. Russ Feingold (D-WI) voted against the Dodd-Frank reforms in 2010 because he
supported even tougher financial regulations (Kaiser 2013). During the Obama administration,
House Speaker John Boehner (R-OH) repeatedly encountered difficulty in persuading principled
conservatives to support compromise measures that could pass the House, even when their refusal
greatly weakened conservatives’ own bargaining position with a Democratic-controlled Senate
and presidency.
Finally, it is likely that most members of Congress will support their own party and committee
leaders as a default position and vote contrarily only when there is an affirmative reason to do
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

so (Kingdon 1981, Matthews & Stimson 1975). “Going along to get along” with fellow party
members requires no fine-grained calculations of policy distance.
The prevalence of spatial voting in Congress is an empirical question that cannot be resolved
by methodologies that begin by assuming spatial voting. Any vote that divides Republicans from
Democrats—regardless of its policy or ideological content—will map onto the first dimension
of DW-NOMINATE. Furthermore, vote-scaling methodologies will identify a single dominant
dimension organizing political conflict whenever the parties are sharply distinct in their voting
behavior, even if many dimensions actually shape members’ decision making (Aldrich et al. 2014).
The capacity of ideal point estimates to accurately measure the substantive policy distances
between members and parties is subject to far more doubt than their ability to summarize patterns
in congressional voting. To draw comparisons over time, one must also make assumptions about
how individual members’ preferences change, whether linearly or according to some other function
(Bailey 2007). One must grapple with how these scores are affected by changes in the policy agenda
and policy status quo (Lapinski 2013). Changes in congressional rules and practices may also skew
these scores (Roberts 2007, Roberts & Smith 2003; but see McCarty et al. 2006, pp. 54–59).
The face validity of these scores as measures of members’ substantive policy preferences is
open to skepticism. For example, one of the most striking trends presented in Congress: A Political-
Economic History of Roll Call Voting (Poole & Rosenthal 1997) is the steady rightward drift of
southern members of Congress (p. 62). If NOMINATE is interpreted as a measure of members’
liberalism and conservatism, southern Democrats of the 1890s were some of the most liberal
members ever to serve in Congress. It is certainly true that many southern congressmen during
this era held progressive or populist views—many were proponents of trust busting, railroad and
safety regulations, income taxes on the wealthy, and public utilities. But theirs was a “progressivism
for whites only” (Woodward 1951, pp. 369–95). One hesitates to speculate about how southern
Democrats of the 1890s would have reacted to Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, or the rights of
labor to organize, let alone equality for racial minorities, women, and gays and lesbians; however,
it seems doubtful that they would have appeared so liberal had they been presented with the policy
agenda of later eras. What it means to be liberal and conservative changes dramatically over time
(Karol 2009).
Questions about comparability of these scores over time greatly complicate any assessment of
the degree of contemporary ideological polarization relative to the past. Are liberals and conser-
vatives farther apart today than they were when conservatives resisted regulations establishing a
minimum wage, maximum working hours, and prohibitions on child labor? Today’s liberals and
conservatives no longer even debate restrictions on child labor, and few conservatives now oppose
the existence of minimum wage and overtime pay requirements. Are liberals and conservatives

266 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

farther apart today than they were when conservatives were denouncing the creation of Medicare?
In a 1961 radio address, Ronald Reagan characterized Medicare as one step toward the day when
“you and I are going to spend our sunset years telling our children and our children’s children,
what it was once like in America when men were free” (Reagan 1961). By contrast, Republican
Mitt Romney vigorously and repeatedly criticized Democrats’ cuts to Medicare spending during
his run for the presidency in 2012.
Questions about comparability are especially troubling for efforts to gauge polarization across
long periods. But difficult issues can arise even on a shorter timeline. For example, NOMINATE
shows that the Republican Party moved to the right throughout the years of unified Republican
control under President George W. Bush. But if one looks at the substance of public policy dur-
ing those years, the picture is far more complicated. These Republican Congresses cut income
taxes repeatedly, but they also steadily increased domestic discretionary spending, strengthened
the federal role in education, and expanded the Medicare entitlement to cover outpatient pre-
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

scription drugs. Despite these ideologically diverse policy moves, NOMINATE simply shows the
Republican Party becoming more extreme and the parties polarizing further.3
Conflict in recent Congresses is much more partisan than it had been for most of the twentieth
century, and the parties are now far better sorted in ideological terms. But whether the scope
of the substantive policy distances between liberals and conservatives in Congress is broader or
narrower than in previous periods is much more difficult to gauge. It is likely that such distances
are broader on some issues and narrower on others. Aggregating across the wide and changing
range of issues facing the federal government to arrive at a single summary measure of ideological
polarization raises thorny methodological questions.
In short, it is clear that US national party politics is polarized in the layman’s definition of the
term. The evidence for increased party distinctiveness is unequivocal and ubiquitous, as well as
highly consequential for the operation of the US political system. But whether the parties have
polarized in the spatial sense of the term is far more ambiguous.

PARTY POLARIZATION AND INSTITUTIONAL PROCESSES


The emergence of more internally cohesive, strongly differentiated parties has affected each insti-
tutional arena of national government in the United States: Congress, the executive branch, and
the federal judiciary. More cohesive and distinctive parties have centralized power in their efforts
to shape policy outcomes; at the same time, leaders across institutions also face a better organized
and more rigid party opposition.
Importantly, the ideological sorting out of the parties coincided with a period of intensified
competition for party control of national institutions. For roughly half a century after the New
Deal, Democrats were viewed as the natural majority party in Congress (Galvin 2010, pp. 17–
25). But since 1980, and especially since 1994, party control of Congress has shifted repeatedly,
and margins of control have been narrow by historical standards. Presidential elections have also
been close. There has not been a national landslide, where a presidential candidate has won
nearly all states, since 1988. Even the ideological and partisan balance on the Supreme Court
has been narrow. Uncompetitive circumstances weaken political parties by undercutting their
incentives to invest in organization; meanwhile, competitive parity spurs party organizational

3
Questions about how well NOMINATE scores measure substantive policy positions also make it difficult to nail down the
existence or extent of asymmetric polarization.

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 267


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

development (Schlesinger 1985). These changed competitive circumstances are likely to have
significant consequences for both polarization and governance.

Congressional Processes
As the parties have become more cohesive and distinct, members of Congress have empowered
their leaders in various institutional and procedural ways to expedite partisan legislation. Dur-
ing the same period, they have also charged their leaders with new responsibilities for political
leadership and management of the party’s public image. In the highly competitive post-1980s envi-
ronment, congressional party leaders have been charged with taking control of the party’s message
and with setting up issues with an eye to the next elections. These institutional changes not only
emerged out of increased party conflict but also created feedback loops that have deepened and
perpetuated it.
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

With regard to the power of leaders to prosecute party programs, subsequent institutional
developments have remarkably borne out Cooper & Brady’s (1981) predictions about how the
power of congressional leaders varies across time: The more internally unified and distinctive the
parties, the more willing their members will be to put up with strong, hierarchical leaders.4 Even
so, the trajectories of institutional change have been very different in the House and the Senate,
with the enhancement of leadership authority much less pronounced in the Senate.
As the congressional parties became more internally unified and distinct, members gave House
leaders new authority and institutional resources. Rohde (1991) details how the congressional
reforms of the 1970s strengthened Democratic Party leaders. Among these, the Speaker was
given the power to appoint majority party members to the Rules Committee, greatly enhancing
leadership control over the floor agenda (Oppenheimer 1977). The Speaker was also given the right
to refer a single bill to multiple committees, weakening the turf monopolies previously enjoyed by
committee chairs and granting an enhanced role for party leaders in brokering agreements across
committees (Sinclair 2012). Whip systems were revitalized and dramatically expanded (Sinclair
1995).
As the parties became more homogeneous, deference based on seniority drastically decreased.
The seniority system—under which the longest-serving majority party member on a given com-
mittee would automatically assume the chair of that panel—was historically one of the chief
constraints on the power of House leaders. It forced party leaders to broker agreements with
committee chairs who were both independent from the party’s leadership and unaccountable to
the party’s rank and file. Given the dominance of southern conservatives in key chairmanships, this
was a source of frustration to northern liberals and, not infrequently, to Democratic Party leaders
themselves (Zelizer 2004). The 1970s reforms made the committee chairs elective via secret ballot
in the House Democratic caucus. This change put committee chairs on notice, prompting them
to adjust their behavior to maintain the support of rank-and-file Democrats (Rohde 1991).
The seniority norm further deteriorated after the Republicans won majority control of the
House in the 1994 elections (Aldrich & Rohde 2000b). The new Republican majority reorganized
the committee system, abolishing three committees and two dozen subcommittees. Speaker Newt
Gingrich (R-GA) then chose several committee chairs in violation of seniority rank. House Re-
publicans also imposed term limits on their committee chairs, thus ensuring that chairs would have

4
Organizational changes strengthening party leaders are often attributed to party polarization in the spatial sense (see Aldrich
& Rohde 2000a). However, Cooper & Brady’s (1981) account does not rely on spatial theory per se. It posits that legislative
party leaders will be strong when the party rank and file are internally unified and when the two parties draw upon different
bases of constituency support (e.g., urban versus rural, industrial versus agricultural).

268 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

little opportunity to build power bases independent of leaders. In the contemporary Congress,
seniority still assists a member in becoming a serious candidate for a chairmanship, but it no longer
guarantees selection, particularly not among Republicans (Deering & Wahlbeck 2006). As one
might expect, party leaders select committee chairs with a proven record of party loyalty both in
votes and in fundraising (Cann 2008, Heberlig & Larson 2012).
Strengthened House leaders have tightened their control over floor procedure, constricting the
opportunities for rank-and-file members, especially members of the minority party, to participate.
Using their influence over the House Rules Committee, leaders structure the consideration of
legislation so as to maximize the chances of success on the floor. The use of restrictive and closed
rules has skyrocketed (Sinclair 2012, p. 151). Legislation is often brought to the floor for a vote
with so little time to read its provisions that it would be difficult for members to develop viable
amendments, even if they had an opportunity to offer them (Curry 2015). The result is a more
centralized, streamlined process in the House, in which a unified majority party can work its will
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

while the minority party enjoys little opportunity to shape outcomes or even put the majority on
the record in awkward ways.
Contemporary Senate leaders take a more central role in the legislative process than did their
counterparts of earlier eras. However, the growth of leadership power in the Senate has been held
within strict bounds. The Senate’s rules permitting unlimited debate constitute the single biggest
obstacle to majority leadership power (Sinclair 2012, Smith 2007). In the Senate, unlike in the
House, a simple majority can neither force consideration of most legislative matters nor bring
debate to a close. In the absence of cloture—a procedure that allows a Senate supermajority of at
least 60 to bring a matter to a vote—debate continues as long as any senator seeks recognition.
This basic fact renders the majority party unable to control the floor agenda. Contemporary
majority leaders are more assertive than past ones in negotiating complex unanimous consent
agreements to manage the floor (Sinclair 2012). They have also taken recourse to a previously
obscure parliamentary device called “filling the tree” to limit amending activity (Smith 2014).
But there is no equivalent to House special rules for structuring floor debate. The supermajority
requirement of cloture empowers a Senate minority to block Senate majorities.
With a few exceptions, senators have declined to alter these supermajoritarian procedures.
Budget resolutions and reconciliation packages are the most important exceptions to unlimited
debate, and these procedures have allowed recent Senate majorities to enact some partisan agenda
items, such as the Bush tax cuts of 2001 and 2003 and the Affordable Care Act of 2010. In 2013,
a Senate majority overrode precedent to change Senate rules and limit debate on nominations
to positions other than Supreme Court Justice (Smith 2014). The reasons for no broader change
in Senate rules are a subject of scholarly debate, but it is clear that moving toward majority rule
would come at a great price to individual senators’ prerogatives (Wawro & Schickler 2006) and is
difficult to accomplish within the Senate’s existing rules (Binder 1997).
In light of the obstacles to stronger Senate leadership, the primary effect of growing party
conflict on that chamber has been the emergence of a “60-vote Senate” (Koger 2010, pp. 167–
87; Wawro & Schickler 2006). Even though the cloture process has been a feature of Senate
rules since 1917, it was rarely used before the 1960s, and although the 1970s and 1980s saw
marked increases in the number of cloture votes taken, filibustering in this era was more often the
“unrestrained activism” of individual senators than a coordinated minority party effort (Sinclair
1989, p. 88). It was only in the 1990s that the Senate minority party began to systematically deploy
filibustering to veto the majority party’s agenda (Sinclair 2012, pp. 153–54). In other words, these
changes reflect an evolution in practice rather than a change in rules (Binder & Smith 1997; Koger
2010; Mayhew 2010, pp. 142–54). The consequence is that a Senate majority party has enormous
difficulty recruiting bipartisan support or acting in the absence of it.

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 269


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Cloture is now a ubiquitous feature of Senate procedure (Sinclair 2012, p. 136; Smith 2014,
p. 20). Cloture votes, however, represent just the “tip of the iceberg” of Senate obstruction strate-
gies (Rawls 2009, p. 52), which encompass holds, nongermane amendments, and the whole range
of individual prerogatives that grow out of unlimited debate. The efforts of Senate leaders to assert
control over rampant obstruction have mired the body in parliamentary combat, a phenomenon
Smith (2014, p. 9) characterizes as “obstruct and restrict.” The warfare has escalated over time,
and “what seems like an extreme use of the filibuster at one time becomes a routine strategy later
on” (Binder & Smith 1997, p. 16). Far from streamlining Senate procedure, party polarization has
tied the chamber in knots, reducing the legislative productivity of Congress as a whole.
Taken together, party-polarized Congresses have transformed the legislative process. Con-
temporary congressional leaders have been continually innovating: cracking down on open par-
ticipation, bypassing committee consideration, modifying legislation after it is reported from
committee, relying on omnibus measures, negotiating creative unanimous consent agreements,
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

and utilizing alternatives to the conference committee process (Hanson 2014, Krutz 2001, Oleszek
2010). These “unorthodox lawmaking” processes offer no guarantee of success, but most successful
major legislation now takes an unorthodox route (Sinclair 2012, p. 263). Despite all this institu-
tional innovation, Congress has struggled even to carry out routine responsibilities of budgeting
and appropriations.5
The changing role of leaders is not confined to matters involving legislation. Congressional
leaders are now expected to take responsibility for their party’s efforts to maintain or win back
congressional majorities. This has not always been a central part of party leaders’ job description. In
fact, scholarship on Congress from the 1960s and 1970s had virtually nothing to say about majority-
seeking as a task for congressional leaders—likely because continued Democratic Party majorities
were taken for granted. But with the return of alternation in party control, the majority-seeking
function has become central to recent theories of congressional organization and leadership (Cox
& McCubbins 2005, Green 2010, Heberlig & Larson 2012, Smith 2007).
Leaders’ and members’ more intense focus on winning and holding party majorities has wide-
ranging consequences for congressional politics. A large part of leaders’ job now is to craft and
disseminate party messages for outside constituencies. The contemporary Congress is much more
oriented toward external audiences than was the textbook Congress (Malecha & Reagan 2012).
Congressional leaders take a higher public profile as media spokespersons (Harris 1998, 2013).
Since 1980, the number of people employed by party leadership offices in both House and Senate
has more than doubled, and half or more of the total increase is attributable to growth in the parties’
communications staffs. Leadership offices coordinate members’ talking points, floor speeches, and
media appearances (Groeling 2010, Harris 2005, Sellers 2010). They utilize events, websites, social
media, and the full range of communications technologies. The most ideologically consistent
and party-loyal members take the lead in these messaging efforts; moderate and cross-pressured
members tend not to participate (Grimmer 2013).
The principal goals of partisan communications are to burnish the public image of one party
and tarnish that of its opposition. To those ends, the minority party looks for every available
opportunity to force roll-call votes that can politically embarrass the majority (Lee 2011). The
majority tries to block the minority’s messaging efforts. The upshot in the Senate is constant
procedural wrangling over the minority’s right to offer amendments. Likewise, Senate majority

5
See “Reforming the Budget,” a Brookings Institution blog devoted to contemporary challenges of budgeting and appropri-
ations, at http://www.brookings.edu/blogs/fixgov/series/reforming-the-budget.

270 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

leaders frequently refuse to bring up appropriations and budget bills altogether so as to avoid the
politically painful “gotcha” votes that the minority will force (Cooper 2013, Hanson 2014).
A preoccupation with majority-seeking disincentivizes bipartisanship. The practice of setting
up roll-call votes for purposes of messaging has become a routine leadership function (Evans 2001;
Evans & Oleszek 2002; Lee 2011; Oleszek 2014, pp. 123–25). These votes fulfill their goal when
they show the two parties voting on opposite sides. As leaders strive to win seats held by the
other party, they also have a political motive to deny bipartisan cover to marginal members of the
opposition. One way of doing so is for the minority party to vote en masse against controversial
majority party initiatives, thus forcing the majority to muster the needed votes entirely from
within its own ranks. Another way is for party and committee leaders to deny opportunities for
legislative participation and success to marginal members of the opposition party, thus shunning
bipartisan cooperation with the members most likely to grant it. Political scientists have not yet
investigated these political dynamics sufficiently; however, it is apparent that messaging activity
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

and party competition for majority control contribute to the strident tone and pervasive extent of
partisan conflict in the contemporary Congress.

Presidential Leadership
Party polarization has far-reaching effects on presidential leadership. Increased ideological ho-
mogeneity eases the task of party leadership, a central role for presidents. Under conditions of
close party competition for institutional control, the bonds of shared party interest in winning and
maintaining power are also stronger. These partisan bonds are an asset to presidents as they work
with fellow party members in Congress as well as in the executive and judicial branches. But the
flip side is perhaps even more important: Party polarization forces presidents to confront a more
unified and better organized opposition.
The most obvious effects of party polarization relate to the presidential leadership of Congress.
Even in less partisan eras, party affiliation has always constituted the best predictor of congressional
voting behavior. In this sense, presidential leadership is always “at the margins” (Edwards 1990,
p. 3). As the parties have polarized, presidents have been able to count on markedly higher levels
of support from their fellow party members in Congress, but also dramatically lower levels of
cross-party support (Ethridge 2014, Jacobson 2003). Because major legislation can rarely pass
on the strength of one party alone (Mayhew 2005), enhanced support from the president’s party
cannot counterbalance the downsides of reduced support from the opposition.
Presidents’ difficulties in obtaining cross-party support loom large in the polarized era, espe-
cially because unified party control has been a feature of only 4 out of 18 Congresses (22%) since
1980. Instead, contemporary presidents typically encounter strong resistance from an opposition
party that controls one or both chambers of Congress. Even opposition party members represent-
ing swing districts or states resist the president almost as much as those representing constituencies
the president lost by a wide margin ( Jones 2014). There is no evidence that a presidential strategy
of “going public” (Kernell 2007, p. 1) can overcome these obstacles (Edwards 2003). By raising the
visibility and political stakes associated with an issue, going public may well make it even harder
to win support from cross-pressured or opposition party members (Covington 1987). Presidential
leadership tends to deepen the partisan divide on the issues presidents champion (Lee 2009).
Presidents’ increased difficulties with opposition party members in the polarized era extend
beyond the legislative arena. Polarization, especially in the context of divided government, also
makes it harder for presidents to staff the executive branch, postponing their ability to reorient
agency priorities (McCarty & Razaghian 1999). Delays and obstruction in the party-polarized
Senate have greatly extended the time required to make judicial appointments (Binder & Maltzman

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 271


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

2009). Commissioners have also polarized along party lines on independent agencies such as
the National Labor Relations Board, the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), the Federal
Election Commission, and many others. Opposition party appointees to these agencies are now
more likely to serve out their full terms, so that polarization also prolongs the time necessary
for presidents to appoint majorities to these commissions (Devins & Lewis 2008). Polarization,
especially in the context of divided government, also makes Congress less willing to delegate
additional authority to administrative agencies (Epstein & O’Halloran 1999). In recent decades,
presidents have undergone more vigorous oversight and investigatory activity from Congresses
controlled by the opposition party (Kriner & Schwartz 2008; Lee 2013; Mayhew 2005, pp. 223–26;
Parker & Dull 2013).
Although party polarization entails many difficulties for presidents, in some respects it also
fortifies them. Polarization makes it much more difficult for Congress to assert itself legislatively
vis-à-vis the president. In arenas where presidents can act unilaterally, they can expect less frequent
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

and effective checks from Congress (Howell 2003). A president facing a stalemated Congress
can make more unfettered use of the office’s powers and tools, such as executive orders, signing
statements, proclamations, and national security directives. It is hard to imagine the party-polarized
Congress successfully overriding a presidential veto on a major issue. Meanwhile, a president
enjoying unified party control can seemingly trust Congress to stand down in terms of executive
oversight and investigations (Mann & Ornstein 2006). Despite a frenzy of investigatory activity
under divided government, congressional oversight may be less effectual in the polarized era,
because of its obvious politicization and the dearth of critical voices from within the president’s
own party.
Being the leader of a more ideologically unified party enabled Reagan and subsequent pres-
idents to centralize power in the Executive Office of the President, giving rise to the “adminis-
trative presidency” (Nathan 1983, p. 1). Contemporary presidents more actively screen potential
appointees for ideological conformity with party goals (Lewis 2008). Presidents now appoint to
executive positions loyalists who have long been active in partisan networks and ideological think
tanks (Skinner 2011) rather than the technocrats, representatives of clientele groups, and personal
allies favored by presidents during the low polarization period (Milkis 1993, Polsby 1978). These
decisions about appointments, in turn, allow presidents to assert significant political control over
many agency outcomes (Wood & Waterman 1991). The regulatory authorities available to the
executive branch are vast and ambiguous, even if polarization limits Congress’s willingness to
expand them further.
Party polarization has transformed presidential leadership just as it has altered Congress. In
some respects, contemporary presidents have been strengthened, both by leading more homoge-
nous parties and as a side effect of a more gridlocked Congress. But in a system in which divided gov-
ernment is the norm, party polarization is more frequently an obstacle to presidents than an asset.

Judicial Processes
The Supreme Court has not been insulated from party polarization. Although ideological divisions
have been evident among justices at many points in US history, never before has the Supreme
Court been divided along strictly partisan lines (Devins & Baum 2014). After the retirement of
liberal Republican Justice John Paul Stevens in 2010, the Court became perfectly sorted by both
party and ideology. For the first time, all of the conservatives on the Court were Republican
appointees and all of the liberals were Democratic appointees.
Differences between Democratic and Republican judges are evident on a wide array of matters
that come before the federal courts. Democratic judges and justices are more likely to rule in favor

272 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

of the defendant in criminal cases, for the government in regulatory questions, and for plaintiffs
against corporations in civil cases (Segal & Spaeth 2002). The depth of the judicial party divide
varies across issues, and partisan division is starkest on civil rights cases (Epstein et al. 2013).
Even now, most Supreme Court cases are not decided on simple ideological lines. Notably, a
Supreme Court with a narrow conservative majority ruled largely in favor of the EPA’s authority
to regulate greenhouse gas emissions,6 upheld most of the Affordable Care Act,7 and unanimously
rejected President Obama’s recess appointments.8 However, the share of Supreme Court cases
decided by majorities of 5–4 reached all-time highs on the Roberts and Rehnquist courts, when
they accounted for approximately one-fifth of cases. Most of these narrow-margin decisions split
along ideological lines, with conservatives deciding the outcomes on hot-button issues such as
contraception coverage,9 campaign finance,10 and the Voting Rights Act.11
As is the case for other branches of government, the partisan and ideological sorting of the
Supreme Court represents the culmination of a long process. The considerations that drove the
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

selection of Supreme Court nominees in earlier eras were varied and sometimes idiosyncratic
(Abraham 2008, Yalof 1999). But since Reagan, presidents have taken more care to systematically
screen potential judicial nominees for conformity with the dominant ideological commitments of
their parties (Devins & Baum 2014). This vetting for ideological conformity filters down even to
the selection of law clerks. Liberal justices are now far more likely than in the past to hire clerks
who previously worked for judges appointed by Democratic presidents; similarly, conservative
justices hire clerks who worked for Republican-appointed judges (Liptak 2010).
A less proximate but not less important cause of judicial party polarization was the long organi-
zational effort of what Teles (2008) terms the conservative legal movement. Central to this story
is the founding of the Federalist Society, which has become vital for credentialing conservative
lawyers. Four of the Court’s current conservative justices are Federalist Society members, includ-
ing Justice Antonin Scalia, one of the original faculty advisors to the organization. Since the late
1970s, conservative legal foundations, public interest law firms, and academics have done much
to elaborate and legitimate conservative approaches to legal interpretation, such as originalism
and economic analysis of law. In 2001, liberals responded with the establishment of the American
Constitution Society, modeled explicitly on the Federalist Society. More broadly, liberalism re-
mains well ensconced in elite law schools and in many long-established legal organizations. As a
result, conservative and liberal judges now have diverging sets of professional reference groups in
these different legal communities (Devins & Baum 2014). Such developments in the wider legal
world reinforce and perpetuate party polarization on the Supreme Court and the federal judiciary
more generally.
Party polarization both empowers and threatens the federal judiciary. Like the president, the
Supreme Court gains sway as Congress becomes gridlocked (Epstein & Knight 1998). Stymied by
internal conflict, the contemporary Congress is far less likely to override the Court’s interpretations
of statutes (Hasen 2013). On the other hand, party polarization on the Supreme Court poses
dangers for its institutional legitimacy. Judicial legitimacy rests on the fundamental idea that
judges apply the law but do not write it. Chief Justice John Roberts recognizes this threat but has

6
Utility Air Regulatory Group v. EPA, 573 U.S. ____ (2014).
7
National Federation of Independent Business v. Sebelius, 567 U.S. ____ (2012).
8
National Labor Relations Board v. Noel Canning et al., 572 U.S. ____ (2014).
9
Burwell v. Hobby Lobby, 573 U.S. ____ (2014).
10
Citizens United v. Federal Election Commission, 558 U.S. ____ 2010.
11
Shelby County, Alabama v. Holder, 570 U.S. ____ (2013).

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 273


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

had only limited success promoting consensus among justices (Rosen 2013). If party conflict on
the Court becomes obvious and ubiquitous, it is likely to undercut the whole rationale for judicial
independence and lifetime appointment.

PARTY POLARIZATION AND POLICY OUTCOMES


Decisive action is always a challenge for a political system characterized by diffuse power and a mul-
titude of veto points. Pervasive, fierce partisan conflict undoubtedly multiplies those challenges.
This is especially true under contemporary conditions, given the narrowness of party majorities
and the frequency of divided government. “Polarization accentuates gridlock, that is status quo
bias” (McCarty et al. 2006, p. 165; see also Krehbiel 1998). Various empirical studies show that
policy stalemate has trended upward along with party polarization (Binder 2003, Jones 2001,
Lapinski 2008). The frequency of divided government is by no means the only factor, because
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

polarization also makes lawmaking tougher under conditions of unified government. A party in
control of Congress and the presidency can still find itself blocked by a minority party filibuster,
as shown by Republicans who were thwarted on drilling in the Arctic National Wildlife Refuge
and some other energy priorities during the George W. Bush administration.
Does gridlock have a substantive ideological bias? Scholars disagree on this point. McCarty
et al. (2006) and Hacker & Pierson (2010) argue that polarization has a conservative impact on
social policy because it freezes existing laws in place and prevents them from being adjusted to
cope with rising economic inequality. During the party-polarized era, for example, the minimum
wage has dramatically declined in real value, and adjustments to it have been less frequent and
more modest. Grossmann (2014, p. 5), in contrast, argues that “status quo bias is ideologically
asymmetric” in advantaging liberals. Drawing on data from Erikson et al. (2002, pp. 374–80), he
points out that the majority of important postwar legislative enactments have expanded the role
of government and moved policy in a liberal direction, whereas less than 10% of these enactments
have moved policy in a conservative direction. Many established policies have constituencies who
exploit veto points to block retrenchment. Programs indexed to inflation, such as Social Secu-
rity, can maintain themselves on autopilot despite partisan deadlock (Patashnik 2008). Regulatory
agencies, too, retain the power to assert their authority in new ways—such as the Obama admin-
istration’s EPA issuing new carbon emission standards or its Department of Homeland Security
deferring deportations of some undocumented immigrants. Given such considerations, status quo
bias often impedes conservatives’ efforts to restrict the scope of government.
Although points can be scored on both sides of this debate, Mayhew (2010, p. 162) is likely
correct in observing that “the status quo side is not the same thing as the conservative side.”
The ideological effect of gridlock differs from policy to policy. This is by no means to say that
the consequences of gridlock are ideologically neutral. Its effects depend on what types of policy
changes or institutional reforms are being proposed and blocked at any given time.
The substantive effects of polarization on public policy are probably best characterized as
“drift” (Hacker 2004, p. 246), meaning unguided policy change. Public policy does not remain
static, even when Congress is gridlocked. Indeed, the effects of policy can shift dramatically as a
result of societal or economic changes even when laws remain the same. The growth in student
loan indebtedness and the rise of the for-profit higher education sector offer key examples of the
transformation of federal policy in the absence of congressional action (Mettler 2014). Drift’s
consequences for governance are hardly benign. A government that cannot adjust its fiscal or
entitlement policy as its demography changes grows increasingly out of step with society’s needs.
A government that cannot respond to emerging challenges such as global climate change puts its
citizens and the broader world at increased risk.

274 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Does party polarization promote extreme policies? If the parties have moved substantively
farther apart in ideological terms, then it stands to reason that they would push through more
extreme policies on the rare occasions when they have an opportunity to do so. The Affordable
Care Act, for example, is landmark legislation and the largest expansion of the social welfare safety
net since the Great Society. Certainly, Republicans saw it as an ideologically extreme policy shift.
Similarly, the Bush tax cuts were strongly criticized as being “off center” relative to public priorities
(Hacker & Pierson 2005, p. 3). It is perhaps worth noting that the enactment of these policies relied
on both unified party control and procedural protection from filibusters. In that sense, they are
not representative of what is generally feasible. Furthermore, and despite the harsh criticisms they
received, many elements of these policies were publicly popular and acceptable to both parties.
The individual mandate had first been proposed by the Heritage Foundation in 1989, and other
Republican priorities were incorporated into the Affordable Care Act (Rigby et al. 2014). Since
the enactment of the Affordable Care Act, a growing number of Republican governors have been
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

willingly participating in the program. Even at the time of this writing, it is by no means clear
that a future unified Republican government will seek to repeal the program. Along similar lines,
all of the Bush tax cuts affecting incomes below $400,000 per year were made permanent under
President Obama through the American Taxpayer Relief Act of 2012, which was supported 89–8
in the Senate and 257–167 in the House, with more Democrats than Republicans voting yea in
both chambers.
Many other controversial recent policies that were harshly criticized at the time of their passage
were subsequently acquiesced in after a change of party majorities. Democrats enjoying unified
party control in the 111th Congress, for example, did not attempt to undo Medicare Part D, No
Child Left Behind, expanded National Security Agency surveillance, or the partial-birth abortion
ban, even though, when they were in the minority, they forcefully criticized all these policies at
the time of adoption. Overall, it is difficult to make the case that party polarization has promoted
extremism in policy outcomes (Brady et al. 2008).
Finally, in evaluating the effect of party polarization on gridlock, it is important to recognize that
the ebbs and flows of legislative productivity are simply not well understood by political science.
Certainly, it is true that the postwar “Congress enacted the vast majority of its significant legislation
during its least polarized period” (McCarty et al. 2006, p. 181). A lack of party polarization during
this period likely contributed to its outsized legislative success, but it is hard to know whether
low polarization was a necessary or a sufficient condition. This period also corresponded with
an activist “public mood” that extended across presidential administrations of both parties and
across both unified and divided government (Mayhew 2010, p. 160). More broadly, government
policy making in the United States seems to be characterized by long periods of stasis punctuated
by occasional large departures (Baumgartner et al. 2009). Political scientists have been forced to
conclude that the story of policy making is largely one of different epochs that do not correspond
closely to divided party government, party politics, or other institutional factors (Grossmann 2014;
Howell et al. 2000, pp. 297–302; Jones et al. 1998).

PARTY POLARIZATION AND THE CONSTITUTIONAL SYSTEM


Schattschneider (1942, p. 8) characterized American political history as “the story of the unhappy
marriage of the parties and the Constitution, a remarkable variation of the case of the irresistible
force and the immovable object.” His observation applies even better to the contemporary era
than to his own. Parties are a more potent force in American politics today than they were at the
middle of the twentieth century. They are more ideologically coherent and distinctive, headed by
institutionally stronger leaders inside government, and bolstered by committed activists and large

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 275


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

networks of party-allied organizations outside government. But the constitutional system blocks
today’s stronger parties at least as effectively as their weaker forebears. Contemporary parties
remain, in Rossiter’s (1960, p. 64) words, “contractors unable to deliver on many of their most
solemn promises to the electorate.”
In the midst of a ferociously competitive political era, these more distinctive parties are locked
in an ongoing contest for control of national institutions. No party has the upper hand in American
government for long, and divided government predominates. Regardless of whether liberals and
conservatives are polarized in the spatial sense—that is, farther apart in ideological terms—a
pervasive, rigid conflict between two evenly matched political parties poses significant challenges
for the Madisonian system.
Contrary to the hopes of an earlier generation of political scientists (Am. Polit. Sci. Assoc. 1950),
there is little reason to think that stronger, more coherent parties will yield a more responsible two-
party system. Indeed, the contemporary environment of intense party competition for institutional
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

control may well foster a more irresponsible party system, as politicians focus on electioneering
rather than policy making. With control of institutions hanging in the balance, politicians have
more reason to postpone tough decisions, hoping for better advantage after the next elections.
In the meantime, they “kick the can down the road” with short-term reauthorizations that leave
the key controversies and policy questions unsettled. Administrative agencies struggle to plan and
budget through these policy uncertainties. Routine appointments, budgets, and appropriations fail
to get approved in a timely manner. Meanwhile, officeholders concentrate on messaging, scoring
political points, and positioning themselves before external constituencies.
The key outstanding question is whether the contemporary impasse between the parties and the
constitutional system is sustainable. Certainly, the system is not static. Recent decades have seen
an enormous amount of institutional innovation. Congress, the president, and to some extent even
the courts have undergone significant institutional development under the pressures of rising party
conflict. Despite these developments, there is still reason to doubt that a system as fragmented
as that of the United States can continue to be responsive to public problems in the face of
institutionalized party warfare across so many different dimensions of public policy. Empirical
work consistently suggests that party conflict compromises the government’s ability to act. It
preserves status quo policies, even as they become poorly adapted to present circumstances, and it
inhibits new policy departures. More qualitatively, since 2010 Americans have witnessed repeated
spectacles of high-stakes brinksmanship over the debt limit and other policies, a downgrade of
US Treasury debt, and a two-week shutdown of most federal government operations. It is little
wonder that public trust in government has fallen to historic lows.
There is no guarantee that the constitutional system will remain workable under current con-
ditions. Even if party polarization was the norm throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth
centuries, the responsibilities of the federal government today are so much broader that policy
stalemate has far more wide-ranging consequences. In the end, American political science does
not yet offer a sufficiently complete account of the drivers of public policy making to confidently
predict the long-term consequences of contemporary party polarization. Weighing uncertain fu-
ture possibilities, one might do worse than to contemplate the confidence of Charles Beard (1943,
p. 38), a fierce critic of the Constitution who yet maintained that “in our system the matured will
of an undoubted and persistent majority will prevail in the long run.”

DISCLOSURE STATEMENT
The author is not aware of any affiliations, memberships, funding, or financial holdings that might
be perceived as affecting the objectivity of this review.

276 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
For helpful comments on an initial draft of this paper, I thank Eric Schickler, Sarah Binder,
Joe Cooper, David Karol, Emery Lee, and Daniel Stid. For research assistance, I thank Kelsey
Hinchliffe and Cory Maks.

LITERATURE CITED
White House. 2010. Obama’s news conference to address the tax-cut plan. New York Times, Jan. 7
Abraham HJ. 2008. Justices, Presidents, and Senators: A History of the U.S. Supreme Court Appointments from
Washington to Bush II. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littlefield
Abramowitz AI. 2010. The Disappearing Center: Engaged Citizens, Polarization, and American Democracy. New
Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press
Aldrich JH. 1995. Why Parties? The Origin and Transformation of Party Politics in America. Chicago: Univ.
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.

Chicago Press
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Aldrich JH, Montgomery JM, Sparks DB. 2014. Polarization and ideology: partisan sources of low dimen-
sionality in scaled roll call analyses. Polit. Anal. 22(4):435–56
Aldrich JH, Rohde DW. 2000a. The consequences of party organization in the House: the role of the majority
and the minority parties in conditional party government. In Polarized Politics: Congress and the President
in a Partisan Era, ed. JR Bond, R Fleisher, pp. 31–72. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Aldrich JH, Rohde DW. 2000b. The Republican revolution and the House Appropriations Committee.
J. Polit. 62:1–33
Am. Polit. Sci. Assoc. 1950. Toward a more responsible two-party system: a report of the committee on
political parties. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 44:1–14
Bailey MA. 2007. Comparable preference estimates across time and institutions for the Court, Congress, and
Presidency. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 51:433–48
Baumgartner FR, Berry JM, Hojnacki M, Leech BL, Kimball DC. 2009. Lobbying and Policy Change: Who
Wins, Who Loses, and Why. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
Beard CA. 1943. The Republic: Conversations on Fundamentals. New York: Viking
Berry JM. 1997. The Interest Group Society. New York: Longman
Binder SA. 1997. Minority Rights, Majority Rule. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Binder SA. 2003. Stalemate: Causes and Consequences of Legislative Gridlock. Washington, DC: Brookings Inst.
Binder SA, Maltzman F. 2009. Advice & Dissent: The Struggle to Shape the Federal Judiciary. Washington, DC:
Brookings Inst.
Binder SA, Smith SS. 1997. Politics or Principle: Filibustering in the United States Senate. Washington, DC:
Brookings Inst.
Bonica A. 2014. Mapping the ideological marketplace. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 58:367–86
Brady DW, Ferejohn J, Harbridge L. 2008. Polarization and public policy: a general assessment. In Red and Blue
Nation? Consequences and Correction of America’s Polarized Politics, ed. PS Nivola, DW Brady, pp. 185–216.
Washington, DC: Brookings Inst.
Cann DM. 2008. Modeling committee chair selection in the U.S. House of Representatives. Polit. Anal.
16:274–89
Clinton J, Jackman S, Rivers D. 2004. The statistical analysis of roll call data. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 98:355–70
Clinton JD. 2012. Using roll call estimates to test models of politics. Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 15:79–99
Converse P. 1964. The nature of belief systems in mass publics. In Ideology and Discontent, ed. DE Apter,
pp. 206–61. New York: Free Press Glencoe
Cooper J. 2013. The modern Congress. In Congress Reconsidered, ed. BI Oppenheimer, LC Dodd, pp. 401–36.
Washington, DC: CQ Press
Cooper J, Brady DW. 1981. Institutional context and leadership style: the House from Cannon to Rayburn.
Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 75:411–25
Cooper J, Young G. 2002. Party and preference in congressional decision making: roll call voting in the
House of Representatives, 1889–1999. In Party, Process, and Political Change in Congress, ed. D Brady,
M McCubbins, pp. 64–106. Stanford, CA: Stanford Univ. Press

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 277


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Covington CR. 1987. “Staying private”: gaining congressional support for unpublicized presidential prefer-
ences on roll call votes. J. Polit. 49:737–55
Cox GW, McCubbins MD. 2005. Setting the Agenda: Responsible Party Government in the U.S. House of Repre-
sentatives. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Curry JM. 2015. Legislating in the Dark: Information and Power in the House of Representatives. Chicago: Univ.
Chicago Press
Deering CJ, Wahlbeck PJ. 2006. U.S. House committee chair selection: Republicans play musical chairs in
the 107th Congress. Am. Polit. Res. 34:223–42
Devins N, Baum L. 2014. Split definitive: how party polarization turned the Supreme Court into a partisan court.
Res. Pap. 09-276, William & Mary Law School, Williamsburg, VA
Devins N, Lewis DE. 2008. Not-so independent agencies: party polarization and the limits of institutional
design. Boston Univ. Law Rev. 88:459–98
Edwards GC. 1990. At the Margins: Presidential Leadership of Congress. New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press
Edwards GC. 2003. On Deaf Ears: The Limits of the Bully Pulpit. New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.

Ellis C, Stimson JA. 2012. Ideology in America. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Epstein D, O’Halloran S. 1999. Delegating Powers: A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy Making Under
Separate Powers. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press
Epstein L, Knight J. 1998. The Choices Justices Make. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Epstein L, Landes WM, Posner RA. 2013. The Behavior of Federal Judges: A Theoretical and Empirical Study of
Rational Choice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univ. Press
Erikson RS, MacKuen MB, Stimson JA. 2002. The Macro Polity. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Ethridge E. 2012. 2011 vote studies: party unity. CQ Wkly. Jan. 16:111–16
Ethridge E. 2014. 2013 vote studies: presidential support. CQ Wkly. Feb. 3:170–76
Evans CL. 2001. Committees, leaders, and message politics. In Congress Reconsidered, ed. LC Dodd, BI Op-
penheimer, pp. 217–43. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Evans CL, Oleszek WJ. 2002. Message politics and Senate procedure. In The Contentious Senate: Partisanship,
Ideology, and the Myth of Cool Judgment, ed. CC Campbell, NC Rae, pp. 107–30. New York: Rowman &
Littlefield
Fiorina MP, Abrams SJ. 2009. Disconnect: The Breakdown of Representation in American Politics. Norman: Univ.
Okla. Press
Galvin D. 2010. Presidential Party Building: Dwight D. Eisenhower to George W. Bush. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Univ. Press
Gerring J. 1998. Party Ideologies in America, 1828–1996. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Gilmour JB. 1995. Strategic Disagreement: Stalemate in American Politics. Pittsburgh, PA: Univ. Pittsburgh
Press
Green MN. 2010. The Speaker of the House: A Study of Leadership. New Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press
Grimmer J. 2013. Representational Style in Congress: What Legislators Say and Why It Matters. New York:
Cambridge Univ. Press
Groeling TJ. 2010. When Politicians Attack: Party Cohesion in the Media. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Groseclose T, Levitt SD, Snyder JM Jr. 1999. Comparing interest group scores across time and chambers:
adjusted ADA scores for the U.S. Congress. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 93:33–50
Grossmann M. 2014. Artists of the Possible: Governing Networks and American Policy Change Since 1945. Oxford,
UK: Oxford Univ. Press
Grossmann M, Dominguez CBK. 2009. Party coalitions and interest group networks. Am. Polit. Res. 37:767–
800
Gutmann A, Thompson DF. 2012. The Spirit of Compromise: Why Governing Demands It and Campaigning
Undermines It. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Hacker JS. 2004. Privatizing risk without privatizing the welfare state: the hidden politics of social policy
retrenchment in the United States. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 98:243–60
Hacker JS, Pierson P. 2005. Off Center: The Republican Revolution and the Erosion of American Democracy. New
Haven, CT: Yale Univ. Press
Hacker JS, Pierson P. 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer—and Turned Its
Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon & Schuster

278 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Han H, Brady DW. 2007. A delayed return to historical norms: congressional party polarization after the
Second World War. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 37:505–31
Hanson PC. 2014. Abandoning the regular order: majority party influence on appropriations in the U.S.
Senate. Polit. Res. Q. 67(3):519–32
Harris DB. 1998. The rise of the public speakership. Polit. Sci. Q. 113:193–212
Harris DB. 2005. Orchestrating party talk: a party-based view of one-minute speeches in the House of Rep-
resentatives. Legis. Stud. Q. 30:127–41
Harris DB. 2013. Let’s play hardball: congressional partisanship in a television era. In Politics to the Extreme:
American Political Institutions in the Twenty-First Century, ed. SA Frisch, SQ Kelly, pp. 93–115. New York:
Palgrave Macmillan
Hasen RL. 2013. End of the dialogue? Political polarization, the Supreme Court, and Congress. South. Calif.
Law Rev. 86:2012–65
Heberlig ES, Larson BA. 2012. Congressional Parties, Institutional Ambition, and the Financing of Majority Control.
Ann Arbor: Univ. Mich. Press
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Herrnson PS. 2009. The roles of party organizations, party-connected committees, and party allies in elections.
J. Polit. 71:1207–24
Hetherington MJ. 2009. Review article: putting polarization in perspective. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 39:413–48
Howell WG. 2003. Power Without Persuasion: The Politics of Direct Presidential Action. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Univ. Press
Howell WG, Adler S, Cameron C, Riemann C. 2000. Divided government and the legislative productivity of
Congress, 1945–94. Legis. Stud. Q. 25:285–312
Huntington SP. 1981. American Politics: The Promise of Disharmony. Cambridge, MA: Belknap
Jacobson GC. 2003. Partisan polarization in presidential support: the electoral connection. Congr. Pres. 30(1):1–
36
Jones BD, Baumgartner FR, True JL. 1998. Policy punctuations: U.S. budget authority, 1947–1995. J. Polit.
60:1–33
Jones DR. 2001. Party polarization and legislative gridlock. Polit. Res. Q. 54:125–41
Jones DR. 2014. Partisan control of government and public policy. In Guide to U.S. Political Parties, ed. MR
Hershey, pp. 347–57. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Kaiser RG. 2013. Act of Congress: How America’s Essential Institution Works, and How It Doesn’t. New York:
Knopf
Karol D. 2009. Party Position Change in American Politics: Coalition Management. New York: Cambridge Univ.
Press
Katznelson I. 2013. Fear Itself: The New Deal and the Origins of Our Time. New York: Liveright
Kernell S. 2007. Going Public: New Strategies of Presidential Leadership. Washington, DC: CQ Press
Kingdon JW. 1981. Congressmen’s Voting Decisions. New York: Harper & Row
Koger G. 2010. Filibustering: A Political History of Obstruction in the House and Senate. Chicago: Univ. Chicago
Press
Koger G, Masket S, Noel H. 2009. Partisan webs: information exchange and party networks. Br. J. Polit. Sci.
39:633–53
Krehbiel K. 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
Kriner D, Schwartz L. 2008. Divided government and congressional investigations. Legis. Stud. Q. 33:295–
321
Krutz GS. 2001. Hitching a Ride: Omnibus Legislating in the U.S. Congress. Columbus: Ohio State Univ. Press
La Raja RJ. 2013. Why super PACs: how the American party system outgrew the campaign finance system.
Forum 10:91–104
Lapinski JS. 2008. Policy substance and performance in American lawmaking, 1877–1994. Am. J. Polit. Sci.
52:235–51
Lapinski JS. 2013. The Substance of Representation: Congress, American Political Development, and Lawmaking.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Layman GC, Carsey TM, Green JC, Herrera R, Cooperman R. 2010. Activists and conflict extension in
American party politics. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 104:324–46

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 279


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Lee FE. 2009. Beyond Ideology: Politics, Principles and Partisanship in the U.S. Senate. Chicago: Univ. Chicago
Press
Lee FE. 2011. Making laws and making points: Senate governance in an era of uncertain majorities. Forum
9(4). doi: 10.2202/1540-8884.1488
Lee FE. 2013. Presidents and party teams: the politics of debt limits and executive oversight, 2001–2013. Pres.
Stud. Q. 43:775–91
Lewis DE. 2008. The Politics of Presidential Appointments: Political Control and Bureaucratic Performance.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Liptak A. 2010. A sign of the Court’s polarization: choice of clerks. New York Times, Sept. 6. http://www.
nytimes.com/2010/09/07/us/politics/07clerks.html?pagewanted=all
Malecha GL, Reagan DJ. 2012. The Public Congress: Congressional Deliberation in a New Media Age. New York:
Routledge
Mann TE, Ornstein NJ. 2006. The Broken Branch: How Congress Is Failing America and How to Get It Back On
Track. New York: Oxford Univ. Press
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Mann TE, Ornstein NJ. 2012. It’s Even Worse than It Looks: How the American Constitutional System Collided
with the New Politics of Extremism. New York: Basic Books
Mansbridge J, Martin CJ. 2013. Negotiating Agreement in Politics. Washington, DC: Am. Polit. Sci. Assoc.
Matthews DR, Stimson JA. 1975. Yeas and Nays: Normal Decisionmaking in the U.S. House of Representatives.
New York: John Wiley & Sons
Mayhew DR. 2005. Divided We Govern: Party Control, Lawmaking, and Investigations, 1946–2002. New Haven,
CT: Yale Univ. Press
Mayhew DR. 2010. Partisan Balance: The Presidency, the Senate, and the House. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ.
Press
McCarty N, Poole KT, Rosenthal H. 2006. Polarized America: The Dance of Ideology and Unequal Riches.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press
McCarty N, Razaghian R. 1999. Advice and consent: Senate responses to executive branch nominations,
1885–1996. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 43:1122–43
Mettler S. 2014. Degrees of Inequality: How the Politics of Higher Education Sabotaged the American Dream. New
York: Basic Books
Milkis SM. 1993. The President and the Parties: The Transformation of the American Party System Since the New
Deal. New York: Oxford Univ. Press
Nathan RP. 1983. The Administrative Presidency. New York: Wiley
Noel H. 2013. Political Ideologies and Political Parties in America. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Oleszek WJ. 2010. Whither the role of conference committees, or is it wither? Extension of Remarks, Newsl.
Legis. Stud. Sect., Am. Polit. Sci. Assoc., 33
Oleszek MJ. 2014. Collaborative relationships and lawmaking in the U.S. Senate: a perspective drawn from
firsthand accounts. In The Evolving Congress, pp. 107–28. Comm. Rules Admin., US Senate. S. Prt. 113-30,
Dec. http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/CPRT-113SPRT89394/pdf/CPRT-113SPRT89394.pdf
Oppenheimer BI. 1977. The Rules Committee: new arm of leadership in a decentralized House. In Congress
Reconsidered, ed. LC Dodd, BI Oppenheimer, pp. 96–116. New York: Praeger
Oxford Univ. Press. 2000. Oxford English Dictionary. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press
Parker DCW, Dull M. 2013. The weaponization of congressional oversight: the politics of the watchful
eye, 1947–2010. In Politics to the Extreme: American Political Institutions in the Twenty-First Century, ed.
SA Frisch, SQ Kelly, pp. 47–70. New York: Palgrave Macmillan
Patashnik E. 2008. Reforms at Risk: What Happens After Major Policy Changes Are Enacted. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton Univ. Press
Pew Res. Cent. 2014. Political Polarization in the American Public: How Increasing Ideological Uniformity and Parti-
san Antipathy Affect Politics, Compromise, and Everyday Life. Washington, DC: Pew Res. Cent. http://www.
people-press.org/files/2014/06/6-12-2014-Political-Polarization-Release.pdf
Persily N, ed. 2015. Solutions to Political Polarization in America. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Polsby NW. 1978. Presidential cabinet making: lessons for the political system. Polit. Sci. Q. 93:15–25
Poole KT, Rosenthal H. 1991. Patterns of congressional voting. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 35:228–78

280 Lee
PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Poole KT, Rosenthal H. 1997. Congress: A Political-Economic History of Roll Call Voting. New York: Oxford
Univ. Press
Poole KT, Rosenthal HL. 2011. Ideology and Congress. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction
Rawls WL. 2009. In Praise of Deadlock: How Partisan Struggle Makes Better Laws. Washington, DC: Woodrow
Wilson Cent.
Reagan R. 1961. Radio address on socialized medicine. Am. Rhetor. Online Speech Bank. http://www.
americanrhetoric.com/speeches/ronaldreagansocializedmedicine.htm
Rich A. 2004. Think Tanks, Public Policy, and the Politics of Expertise. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Rigby E, Clark JH, Pelika S. 2014. Party politics and enactment of “Obamacare”: a policy-centered analysis
of minority party involvement. J. Health Polit. Policy Law 39:57–95
Roberts JM. 2007. The statistical analysis of roll-call data: a cautionary tale. Legis. Stud. Q. 32:341–60
Roberts JM, Smith SS. 2003. Procedural contexts, party strategy, and conditional party voting in the U.S.
House of Representatives. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 47:305–17
Rohde DW. 1991. Parties and Leaders in the Postreform House. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Rosen J. 2013. Can the judicial branch be a steward in a polarized democracy? Daedalus 42(2):25–35
Rossiter C. 1960. Parties and Politics in America. Ithaca, NY: Cornell Univ. Press
Schattschneider EE. 1942. Party Government. New York: Farrar & Rinehart
Schickler E. 2013. New Deal liberalism and racial liberalism in the mass public, 1937–1968. Perspect. Polit.
11:75–98
Schlesinger JA. 1985. The new American political party. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 79:1152–69
Segal JA, Spaeth HJ. 2002. The Supreme Court and the Attitudinal Model Revisited. New York: Cambridge Univ.
Press
Sellers P. 2010. Cycles of Spin: Strategic Communication in the U.S. Congress. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Sinclair B. 1989. The Transformation of the U.S. Senate. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press
Sinclair B. 1995. Legislators, Leaders, and Lawmaking. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press
Sinclair B. 2012. Unorthodox Lawmaking: New Legislative Processes in the U.S. Congress. Washington, DC: CQ
Press
Skinner RM. 2011. Barack Obama and the partisan presidency. In The State of the Parties: The Changing
Role of Contemporary American Parties, ed. JC Green, DJ Coffey, pp. 309–22. Lanham, MD: Rowman &
Littlefield
Skocpol T. 1999. Advocates without members: the recent transformation of American life. In Civic Engagement
in American Democracy, ed. T Skocpol, MP Fiorina, pp. 461–509. Washington, DC: Brookings Inst.
Skocpol T. 2007. Government activism and the reorganization of American civic democracy. In The Trans-
formation of American Politics: Activist Government and the Rise of Conservatism, ed. P Pierson, T Skocpol,
pp. 39–67. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press
Smith SS. 2007. Party Influence in Congress. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Smith SS. 2014. The Senate Syndrome: The Evolution of Procedural Warfare in the Modern U.S. Senate. Norman:
Univ. Okla. Press
Stokes DE. 1963. Spatial models of party competition. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 57:368–77
Sundquist JL. 1983. Dynamics of the Party System: Alignment and Realignment of Political Parties in the United
States. Washington, DC: Brookings Inst.
Teles SM. 2008. The Rise of the Conservative Legal Movement: The Battle for Control of the Law. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton Univ. Press
Theriault SM. 2008. Party Polarization in Congress. New York: Cambridge Univ. Press
Theriault SM. 2013. The Gingrich Senators. Oxford, UK: Oxford Univ. Press
Theriault SM, Rohde DW. 2011. The Gingrich senators and party polarization in the U.S. Senate. J. Polit.
73:1011–24
Van Houweling RP. 2003. Legislators’ personal policy preferences and partisan legislative organization. PhD thesis,
Harvard Univ.
Wawro GJ, Schickler E. 2006. Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton
Univ. Press
Weyl B. 2014. 2013 vote studies: party unity. CQ Weekly, Feb. 3, pp. 183–88

www.annualreviews.org • Party Polarization and Governance 281


PL18CH15-Lee ARI 17 April 2015 20:0

Wood BD, Waterman RW. 1991. The dynamics of political control of the bureaucracy. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev.
85:801–28
Woodward CV. 1951. Origins of the New South 1877–1913. Baton Rouge: La. State Univ. Press
Yalof DA. 1999. Pursuit of Justices: Presidential Politics and the Selection of Supreme Court Nominees. Chicago:
Univ. Chicago Press
Zelizer JE. 2004. On Capitol Hill: The Struggle to Reform Congress and Its Consequences, 1948–2000. New York:
Cambridge Univ. Press
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

282 Lee
PL18-FrontMatter ARI 6 April 2015 13:4

Annual Review of
Political Science
Contents Volume 18, 2015

A Conversation with Hanna Pitkin


Hanna Pitkin and Nancy Rosenblum p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 1
Income Inequality and Policy Responsiveness
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Robert S. Erikson p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p11


How Do Campaigns Matter?
Gary C. Jacobson p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p31
Electoral Rules, Mobilization, and Turnout
Gary W. Cox p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p49
The Rise and Spread of Suicide Bombing
Michael C. Horowitz p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p69
The Dysfunctional Congress
Sarah Binder p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p85
Political Islam: Theory
Andrew F. March p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 103
Borders, Conflict, and Trade
Kenneth A. Schultz p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 125
From Mass Preferences to Policy
Brandice Canes-Wrone p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 147
Constitutional Courts in Comparative Perspective:
A Theoretical Assessment
Georg Vanberg p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 167
Epistemic Democracy and Its Challenges
Melissa Schwartzberg p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 187
The New Look in Political Ideology Research
Edward G. Carmines and Nicholas J. D’Amico p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 205
The Politics of Central Bank Independence
José Fernández-Albertos p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 217
What Have We Learned about the Resource Curse?
Michael L. Ross p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 239

v
PL18-FrontMatter ARI 6 April 2015 13:4

How Party Polarization Affects Governance


Frances E. Lee p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 261
Migration, Labor, and the International Political Economy
Layna Mosley and David A. Singer p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 283
Law and Politics in Transitional Justice
Leslie Vinjamuri and Jack Snyder p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 303
Campaign Finance and American Democracy
Yasmin Dawood p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 329
Female Candidates and Legislators
Jennifer L. Lawless p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 349
Access provided by University of California - Davis on 09/15/15. For personal use only.
Annu. Rev. Polit. Sci. 2015.18:261-282. Downloaded from www.annualreviews.org

Power Tool or Dull Blade? Selectorate Theory for Autocracies


Mary E. Gallagher and Jonathan K. Hanson p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 367
Realism About Political Corruption
Mark Philp and Elizabeth Dávid-Barrett p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 387
Experiments in International Relations: Lab, Survey, and Field
Susan D. Hyde p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 403
Political Theory as Both Philosophy and History: A Defense Against
Methodological Militancy
Jeffrey Edward Green p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 425
The Empiricists’ Insurgency
Eli Berman and Aila M. Matanock p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 443
The Scope of Comparative Political Theory
Diego von Vacano p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 465
Should We Leave Behind the Subfield of International Relations?
Dan Reiter p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 481

Indexes

Cumulative Index of Contributing Authors, Volumes 14–18 p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 501


Cumulative Index of Article Titles, Volumes 14–18 p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p p 503

Errata

An online log of corrections to Annual Review of Political Science articles may be found
at http://www.annualreviews.org/errata/polisci

vi Contents

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy