gruber_6e_lecture_slides_ch20
gruber_6e_lecture_slides_ch20
CHAPTER 20:
Tax Inefficiencies
and Their
Implications for
Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 1 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
20.5 Conclusion
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 2 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Introduction
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 3 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 4 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Figure 20-1
A tax is imposed, and supply shifts from S1 to S2. Deadweight loss occurs—triangle BAC.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 5 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
• Absent taxes:
price = social marginal benefit = social marginal cost
• The tax drives a wedge between SMB and SMC, preventing
mutually beneficial trades from occurring.
• The units between 90 and 100 would have generated a
consumer and producer surplus.
• The forgone surplus from taxation is called the deadweight loss
(DWL).
• The size of the DWL depends on elasticities.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 6 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
The deadweight loss of a given tax is smaller when the demand curve is less elastic than
when it is more elastic.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 7 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 8 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 9 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 10 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Oates, Wallace E., and Robert M. Schwab. 2015. "The Window Tax:
A Case Study in Excess Burden." Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 29 (1): 163-80.
https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jep.29.1.163
https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2921077
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 11 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
There are obvious spikes at 9, 14, and 19 windows, exactly what we would
predict from the effects of this tax.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 12 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
One could argue that perhaps there was some British custom or
some other reason for having 9, 14, or 19 windows in a house.
• Oates and Schwab address this point by using the fact that in
1761, the government added a provision that houses with 8 or
9 windows would pay 1 shilling per window.
• This means that after 1761, there was suddenly an incentive to
keep the number of windows to 7 or fewer. This is exactly what
happened.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 13 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
In data from 1761 to 1765, the authors find that 27% of houses have 7 windows,
while only 5% have 6 windows, and 3% have 8 windows. This is a ninefold
increase from the 3% of buildings with 7 windows from just a few years earlier.
Clearly, this was a response to the tax.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 14 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Keynes: “The avoidance of taxes is the only pursuit that still carries
any reward.” Some examples of avoidance:
1. The Papal States taxed salt heavily, so Tuscan bakers stopped
using it. Even today, Tuscan bread is saltless.
2. In the early 1980s, Cyprus’s building tax applied to finished
structures. Homeowners put steel bars jutting out from their
roofs to avoid the tax.
3. Thailand taxes business signs on the outside, with higher taxes
for English-only signs. So, many signs have a bit of Thai writing
in the corner or are hung on curtains inside the shop.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 15 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
• DWL rises with the square of the tax, so marginal DWL rises
with the tax rate.
o Marginal deadweight loss: The increase in deadweight loss
per unit increase in the tax.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 16 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
The marginal deadweight loss rises disproportionately with the tax rate.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 17 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 18 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 20 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 21 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Initially the government imposes an equal tax on the low-wage worker and the
high-wage worker, which results in deadweight losses of triangles BAC and EDF.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 22 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
When system is replaced with no tax on low-wage workers, there is no DWL for
this worker, but the DWL for the high-wage worker increases by the trapezoid
GEFI. This results in an increase in deadweight loss because additional taxes
must be collected from high-wage workers in order to collect the same
revenues as before.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 23 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Proportional 20% 20% 894 (H2) $115.71 894 (H2) $231.42 $347.13
tax (area BAC) (area EDF) (BAC + EDF)
Progressive 0% 60% 1,000 (H1) 0 837 (H3) $566.75 $566.75
tax (area GDI) (EDF + GEFI)
The deadweight loss is larger for the higher-wage worker despite the same
reduction in hours worked.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 24 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 25 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
o https://www.nber.org/papers/w7281.pdf
o https://economics.mit.edu/files/1029
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 26 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 27 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 28 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 29 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Imagine that the government had only two goods it could tax:
cereal and caviar:
• Elasticity of demand for caviar is much higher than that for
cereal.
• The inverse elasticity rule would suggest that the government
tax cereal much more highly than caviar.
• This means taxing more heavily the good consumed by poor
people.
• This might hurt vertical equality.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 30 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 31 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
In the market for wheat, demand is fairly inelastic and supply is subsidized,
leading quantity to increase from Q1 to Q2 with a deadweight loss of BAC.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 32 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
In the market for rice, demand is very elastic, so when supply is subsidized, the
quantity rises by much more (from Q1 to Q2), and the deadweight loss is larger (BAC).
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 33 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
In the market for oils and fats, demand is also very elastic, so even a small tax leads
to a large reduction in quantity from Q1 to Q2, with a deadweight loss of BAC.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 34 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 37 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
A Simple Example 1
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 38 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
A Simple Example 2
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 39 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 40 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
As tax rates rise from 0 to τ*, tax revenues rise, but when tax rates rise above τ*
toward 100%, tax revenues fall.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 41 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 42 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
The ratio of marginal utility to marginal revenue rises as tax rates rise for any
taxpayer, but this ratio for Mr. Rich is everywhere below the ratio for Ms. Poor.
Optimal income tax rates are those that equate this ratio across taxpayers.
Here, the optimal rates are 10% for Ms. Poor and 20% for Mr. Rich.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 43 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 44 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
A pure tax on labor would shift the demand curve from D1 to D2 and create the
deadweight loss triangle CAB. If those taxes are tied to benefits provided to
workers, then supply shifts out to S2. Labor supply falls only to L3, and the
deadweight loss triangle shrinks to GAF.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 45 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
When workers value the tax-financed benefit so highly that they are willing to
accept its full cost in lower wages, there is no change in employment when the
tax is imposed.
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 46 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 47 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 48 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 49 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 50 of 49
CHAPTER 20: Tax Inefficiencies and Their Implications for Optimal Taxation
Conclusion
Public Finance and Public Policy Jonathan Gruber Sixth Edition Copyright © 2019 Worth Publishers 51 of 49