L ExchangeEconomy
L ExchangeEconomy
X = x0R + x0F
0
Y = yR + yF0
Starting with the initial endowments, after trade the consumers end up at an allocation (xR ; yR ) and
(xF ; yF ): Note that, at every feasible allocation in the exchange economy, the consumers consume non-
negative quantities and the supply of each good must equate the demand of that good, i.e., the allocation
(xR ; yR ) and (xF ; yF ) are feasible if:
xR ; yR ; xF ; yF 0
and
X = xR + xF
Y = y R + yF
f or R : uR (xR ; yR )
f or F : uF (xF ; yF )
Note that every agent’s utility depends on his own consumption and not what the other person consumes.
The fact that the consumers are inherently di¤erent and their preferences are di¤erent makes mutually
bene…cial trade possible.
Edgeworth Box:
To depict the allocations in this exchange economy, Edgeworth and Bowley devised a diagram, called an
Edgeworth box, to show all possible allocations of the available quantities of goods x and y between the two
consumers.
The dimensions of the Edgeworth Box are the total quantities of x and y:
There are two origins: the lower left corner of the box is for R; the upper right corner of the box is for
F:
1
Every point inside the box (a; b) depicts a "feasible" allocation in the economy where R consumes:
xR = a; yR = b and F consumes: xF = X a:yF = Y b:
Thus, Edgeworth box shows four quantities: (xR ; yR ) and (xF ; yF ) in two-dimensional space.
In this Edgeworth box, now let us draw representative indi¤erence curves for the two agents. Under the
standard assumptions of continuity, monotonicity and convexity, the rational preferences are represented by
indi¤erence curves in Figure . Notice that while R0 s indi¤erence curve, convex to the lower left origin OR
looks familiar, F 0 s ICs, convex to OF look upside down. In this Figure , The endowment point is denoted
as W: At initial endowment, R0 s utility level is associated with IR and F 0 s utility is the level of IC IF :
Pareto E¢ ciency
So far, in partial equilibrium analysis, we focussed on one good and de…ned the "social surplus" (the sum
of consumers’surplus and producers’surplus) as the total net bene…t created in the market for that good.
Now we need to extend the same notion in general equilibrium analysis. To do so, we use the concept of
"Pareto E¢ ciency," following the work of Vilfredo Pareto.
If A and B are two feasible allocations (i.e. each contains non-negative quantities of both the goods and
the total consumption of each good sum up to the total amount of that good available in the economy), we
say A Pareto-dominates B if both the consumers R and F like A at least as well as B: In that case, A is
Pareto-improving compared to B:
Pareto E¢ ciency: A feasible allocation is Pareto optimal or Pareto E¢ cient if there is no other feasible
allocation that both consumers like at least as well, and that is preferred by at least one of them. In other
words, an allocation is Pareto optimal if there is no Pareto-improving allocation compared to that, i.e. no
other feasible allocation makes at least one of the consumers better o¤, without making any of them worse
o¤.
Now let us see how we can …nd out Pareto optimal allocations. In Figure 1, the initial endowment point is
not Pareto optimal, because any of the points in the area enclosed by the two ICs IR and IF pareto dominates
this point. At any of these points, both R and F are better o¤ (at a higher indi¤erence curve). In the same
logic, any point in the Edgeworth box where the indi¤erence curves of the two consumers intersect can never
2
be Pareto optimal, because a move to the interior of the lens-shaped area between those two indi¤erence
curves will make both the consumers better o¤. So, assuming that the indi¤erence curves are smooth and
convex, the Pareto optimal points must be the ones where the indi¤erence curves of the consumers touch
each other, that is, tangent to each other. At this tangency point, moving towards any direction will make
one of the consumers worse o¤, and no other feasible allocation will be Pareto-improving compared to this
point.
So, at the Pareto optimal points, the slopes of the ICs are same, i.e.:
M RS R = M RS F
i.e.,
M Ux R M Ux F
=
M Uy M Uy
max uR (xR ; yR )
s:t: uF (xF ; yF ) = u0
X = xR + xF
Y = yR + y F
M RS R = M RS F
Contract Curve
The contract curve is the set of all Pareto-optimal allocations in the Edgeworth Box. In the Figure , the
curve joining all the yellow-dotted points is the contract curve.
3
But there remains a question: to which of the many allocations on the contract curve will consumers end
up after trade?
In a perfectly competitive market, each consumer will only agree to trade if it is bene…cial to him. So,
the …nal equilibrium will be on the part of the contract curve where neither of the consumers is worse o¤
compared to the initial endowment point. This is called the Core. In Figure , the allocations on the contract
curve which can not be sustained as an equilibrium are marked.
Core: The core is the set of all Pareto-optimal allocations that are welfare-improving for both consumers
relative to their own endowments (as illustrated in Figure 2).
Rational trade should achieve a core allocation.
Figure 2: Core
ai 2 (0; 1)
M RS 1 = M RS 2
Now,
M U1i ai yi
M RS i = =
M U2i 1 ai xi
So, Pareto e¢ ciency requires:
a1 y1 a2 y2
=
1 a1 x1 1 a2 x2
Using Feasibility condition:
x1 + x2 = 1
y1 + y2 = 1
4
We have,
y1 a2 (1 a1 ) 1 y1
= (1)
x1 a1 (1 a2 ) 1 x1
This is the equation of the contract curve, i.e., the set of all Pareto optimal points.
If a1 = a2 = 21 ; this equation will simplify to:
x1 = y1
u1 (x1 ; y1 ) = minfx1 ; y1 g
u1 (x1 ; y1 ) = x1 + y1
Now, let us turn to the de…nition of Competitive Equilibrium in an Exchange Economy, also known as the
Walrasian Equilibrium.
A Walrasian Equilibrium is a vector of allocation and price ((xR ; yR ),(xF ; yF );(px ; py )) such that:
max uR (xR ; yR )
Such that px xR + py yR = px x0R + py yR
0
max uF (xF ; yF )
Such that px xF + py yF = px x0F + py yF0
5
2. (xR ; yR ),(xF ; yF ) is a feasible allocation, i.e.
xR + xF = X
yR + y F = Y