retrieve63
retrieve63
DOI: 10.1111/joac.12291
ORIGINAL ARTICLE
KEYWORDS
1 | I N T RO DU CT I O N
Has the food system transitioned from an era of extensive state intervention between around 1930 and 1980 to an
era of increasing coordination through markets in the last 40 years? Has the post‐1945 food regime been followed by
a long, chaotic period of institutional instability and structural incoherence? Have we moved, in short, from state‐
coordinated, “organized” capitalism to market‐oriented, “disorganized” capitalism? These questions are important
J Agrar Change. 2019;19:295–318. wileyonlinelibrary.com/journal/joac © 2018 John Wiley & Sons Ltd 295
296 COLLANTES
for two reasons. First, they are central to the making of a theoretical discourse on the evolution of the modern food
system. Second, they contribute to informing the ongoing political debate on the food economy, especially in relation
to its institutional architecture.
This article uses a case study to explore these questions. The case selected is the dairy chain, which (as we will
see) provides an excellent occasion to examine both the movement towards greater state intervention between
1920/1930 and 1970/1980 and the deregulation that has taken place from 1970/1980 onwards. More specifically,
the case study is about the dairy chain in Spain, where the transition was particularly abrupt due to its coincidence
with major political turning points such as the end of the dictatorship of Francisco Franco in 1975 and the
country's entry to the European Economic Community in 1986. This provides a contrast between an era of exten-
sive state, top‐down intervention in the dairy chain and a later era of democratization, Europeanization, and
deregulation.
The article is organized in six sections. A review of literature comes first. A second section presents the
theoretical framework that will be used throughout the rest of the article. The third section describes the chang-
ing structure of Spain's dairy chain from the 1950s onwards, focusing on the transition from a short chain com-
posed mostly by farmers to a longer chain dominated by processors and, at a later stage, by retailers. The fourth
section presents the evidence that fits the hypothesis that the dairy chain transitioned from organized to disorga-
nized capitalism. A following section brings a set of qualifications and objections to this hypothesis, in relation to
both the first and the second periods. The concluding section summarizes the argument and discusses its
implications.
2 | LITERATURE REVIEW
“corporate food regime” in which the “organizing principle is the market, not the empire or the State” (see also
Pechlaner & Otero, 2008, about a “neoliberal food regime”).
monopolies, in particular, soon became unpopular among national business elites. In this respect, dairy deregulation
cannot be separated from the progress made from the 1980s onwards by the neoliberal agenda in the broader polit-
ical economy of the West (Atkins, 2010; Moser & Brodbeck, 2007).
In those countries belonging to the European Union, the politics of economic integration became a powerful,
additional force against organized national capitalisms. Distinctive national institutions, such as Britain's Milk Market-
ing Boards and Italy's “milk centrals,” were abolished following explicit legislative and judicial action by the European
Union. The main charge on them was that they were incompatible with the protection of competition within a single
European market—the Milk Marketing Boards were monopsonists in the British market for raw milk, whereas milk
centrals were licensed monopolies for the production of pasteurized milk within a given Italian territory (Atkins,
2010; Felice, 2004; Fenton, 1995; Vernon, 2000). Although the European Union went on subsidizing dairy farmers,
the bulk of organized dairy capitalism was discontinued in the late 20th century.
3 | T HE O R E T I C A L F R A M E W O R K
corporations in the United States. In Galbraith's view, published in the midst of the Cold War, U.S. capitalism resem-
bled Soviet communism in that market coordination was not particularly prominent: Although Soviet‐type economies
featured central state planning, in the United States, a vast amount of resources and decisions were coordinated
through plans designed by the managerial elites of large corporations.
Neo‐Schumpeterian economists, finally, incorporate business organization to the discussion in a particularly sys-
tematic way. Inspired by Schumpeter's observations on the connection between innovation and business organiza-
tion, researchers such as Lazonick (1991) and von Tunzelmann (2003) propose a theory of history in which
business organization plays an ever greater role in successive technological revolutions. According to this literature,
the shift from the first to the second industrial revolution in the late 19th century was based on a parallel shift from
decentralized capitalism, in which most coordination took place through impersonal markets, to managerial capital-
ism, in which corporate hierarchies designed and executed plans that were by their very nature attempts to escape
the market (the work by historian Chandler, 1977, has been particularly influential here). This is not very different
from the Marxist and institutional accounts referred to above, but the neo‐Schumpeterian literature also highlights
an additional dimension of business‐led planned coordination. The latter would be not only about vertical decisions
taken within each firm considered in isolation but also about collaboration between firms. The third technological
revolution brought about by information technologies in the late 20th century would have been underpinned by a
shift to collaborative capitalism, in which networks of formally independent companies share plans (often controlled
by the managerial elite of one of said companies) for collaborating in a relatively stable way through time. This is yet
another way in which business organization becomes a distinct mechanism for economic coordination.
conditioned by nonmarket agreements between firms belonging to contiguous nodes of the chain? For instance, do
processors create stable networks of farm suppliers in which prices and standards are different from those prevailing
in the outside‐the‐network market? We may even explore the possibility that business networks operate at the
intranode level (i.e., collusive agreements between oligopolistic firms).
The proposal here implies an empirical approach that is perhaps a bit more disaggregated than usual. As a matter
of fact, we will pay close attention to the impact of changes in the structure of the food chain upon the character of
economic coordination. Most food chains involve a number of subchains with partly distinct coordination systems,
which implies that changes in the relative importance of each subchain may have an influence on the overall structure
of coordination. This will lead us to questions such as does the role played by those subchains featuring strong
planned coordination increase over time? Or, on the contrary, is structural change led by those subchains in which
market coordination is dominant?
It should be noted that this framework does not stand in sharp opposition to the framework that is commonly
used for the study of the political economy of food. The conventional framework tries to identity distinct historical
epochs on the basis of the changing relevance of alternative mechanisms of economic coordination—and so does
the framework depicted here. Our framework simply extends the list of mechanisms under study (transforming the
Smithian market‐versus‐state dichotomy into a triangle the third vortex of which is business organization) and pre-
pares the way for a systematic, piece‐by‐piece empirical analysis.
4 | F A R M E R S , P RO CE S S O R S , A N D R E T A I L E R S I N S P A I N 'S D A I R Y C H A I N
In order to contextualize the analysis of economic coordination, three distinct moments can be identified in the evo-
lution of Spain's dairy chain since the 1950s. At the start of the period, farming was the key link in the chain, and
processing was relatively undeveloped. Second, a major dairy processing industry rose in the period 1950/
1960–1980/1990. Finally, from 1980/1990 onwards, supermarkets have become the key actor.
FIGURE 2 The structure of Spain's dairy chain around 1950. The width of each of the two sections reflects the
relevance of each subchain within the dairy chain as a whole (raw milk has a much larger share of the market than
processed dairy products; see Table 4 below). aExcept in cheese production, where small producers were dominant
Source. Ministerio de Agricultura (1975, 1976) and Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (1986). For 1950 and
1964, the sources give information about milk sales to processing companies for the production of second‐degree processed
products (cheese, butter, condensed milk, etc.) but not for processed liquid milk. This has been estimated through the pro-
duction of processed liquid milk, which is directly available for 1964 (Instituto Nacional de Estadística, 1964) and can be
approximated for 1950 by applying the share of processed milk consumption given by Ovejero (1951, p. 959) to the total
amount of raw milk used for liquid (processed or unprocessed) milk consumption (Ministerio de Agricultura, 1975).
rudimentary: Even though since the late 19th century there had been a move towards more intensive rearing
(through the partial substitution of extensive tendering with natural feeding within the barn) and biological innova-
tion, extensive rearing and autochthonous, multifunctional, low‐yield breeds prevailed. In a way, it is even misleading
to speak about dairy farmers as such—the degree of dairy specialization was very low, and most producers were pur-
suing a diversified strategy that combined several different lines of production (Domínguez & Puente, 1997; Gallego,
2001; Hernández Adell & Pujol‐Andreu, 2016; Simpson, 1995).
This situation was undoubtedly affected by the fact that still by 1950 the Spanish economy was involved in a
major crisis. The Civil War of 1936–1939 had a strong short‐term impact on growth and, in addition, eventually
led to the establishment of a dictatorship whose economic record during the 1940s was very poor. The rise to power
of General Francisco Franco implied, for instance, a reorientation of Spain's international policy towards autarky and
self‐sufficiency, which in turn would make it extremely difficult for firms and farms to upgrade their technologies.
Around 1950, gross domestic product per capita and labour productivity were still below their respective pre‐war
peaks. These problems were particularly severe in agriculture and the broader food system. In the particular case
302 COLLANTES
of the dairy chain, the moves towards milk processing, land use intensification, and biological innovation were all
more important in the decades prior to the war than they were during the post‐war. This does not mean, however,
that prior to the war such moves had ever gained enough momentum to provoke a major transformation of the chain.
In structural terms, the situation described for 1950 was not remarkably different to that of the 1930s (Domínguez,
2003; Langreo, 1995).
FIGURE 3 The structure of Spain's milk chain around 1980. The width of each of the two sections reflects the
relevance of each subchain within the dairy chain as a whole (see Table 4 below). aMostly medium‐sized
processors in processed milk production and large processors in the rest of productions (except cheese)
COLLANTES 303
Source. Farming: Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1984–1985, 1991); processing: Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1975–
1976, 1981–1982, 1991–1992). For dairy processing in 1958, I do not give the figures in the source but a corrected estima-
tion. Because the source was actually a preparatory work for an upcoming manufacturing census, it was probably too
exhaustive: as it is acknowledged in its preface, a very large number of farm‐based and artisan‐type food production units
were misleadingly enumerated as food processing plants. My correction retains the data for those units that employed five
workers or more and assumes that the units employing less than five workers had a share in unit numbers and workers num-
bers that was similar to that in 1970 (which is based on a more reliable source). Considering the trends depicted in the main
text of the article, this may entail some downward bias but one that must be clearly smaller than the upward bias in the orig-
inal source.
a
Labour input, measured in units that equal the number of working hours that a full‐time farm worker would do in the course
of 1 year.
b
1982.
c
1987.
d
1990.
FIGURE 4 Consumption and domestic production of dairy products (butter excluded) in Spain, 1961–1990 (primary
equivalent kilogrammes per capita). Source. Faostat (www.fao.org, Food balance)
Other productivity‐enhancing innovations included milk‐substituting industrial products for the feeding of calves
(with a subsequent rise in cows' net milk yield) and milking machines. Although hard data are not available, it seems
likely that technological change was joined by some farm restructuring. Similarly to other areas of Spanish agriculture,
many small‐scale farmers left the sector and the countryside altogether, whereas many others closed their farms after
retiring and finding that they were unable to secure a successor (Abad & Naredo, 1997; Collantes & Pinilla, 2011).
304 COLLANTES
Even so, by the end of the period, dairy farms remained fairly small in comparison with their Western European coun-
terparts, as well as to the Spanish processors that they were increasingly connected with (Table 2).
Changes in retailing, however, were more modest, especially before the 1980s. Supermarkets and hypermarkets
began to appear in the country's largest cities in the 1970s, but their market share was still not large enough for them
to exert a relevant impact on the decisions of processors or farmers. Moreover, consumers seemed to be strongly
identified with producer brands, which limited the spread of retailer brands. Finally, as late as 1980, almost 40% of
the milk consumed in Spain was still raw milk, most of it commercialized by smaller retailers, itinerant urban middle-
men, or farm populations. All these made retailers dependent on processors, both in the sense that their advance
depended on processors' capacity to expel raw milk from the consumer market and in the sense that their supply
of processed milk had to remain strongly linked to producer brands (Collantes, 2016).
FIGURE 5 The structure of Spain's milk chain today. aThe average business size is largest in the refrigerated
desserts subchain and lowest in the cheese subchain, with liquid milk standing in between
COLLANTES 305
Source. Market shares by retail formats: Collantes (2016); patterns of raw milk use: Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y
Alimentación (1986, 2001) and Ministerio de Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente (2014).
a
Includes all dairy products, computed at market prices; there were no major differences between different types of dairy
products.
b
Restaurants, bars, cafeterias, canteens, and institutions.
c
Door‐to‐door sales, farmgate transactions, self‐consumption, company shops, and small cooperatives.
d
1988.
e
2010.
Source. Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1959, 1965–1995), Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (1989–1991,
1992–2006), and Mercasa (2008–2013). See Collantes (2015) for details on source exploitation.
a
Pasteurized and sterilized milk.
b
Condensed, powdered, and evaporated milk.
c
Includes all fermented milks.
d
Mostly other refrigerated desserts, ice creams, and milk shakes.
of technological innovation in processing and farming, this created strong pressure for the restructuring of both sec-
tors (Table 5 and Figure 6). Employment in processing stagnated and eventually decreased. There was much business
concentration in dairy processing: Many small‐ and medium‐sized enterprises disappeared or were absorbed by larger
enterprises. This was particularly clear in the processed milk subchain but took place in the traditionally more atom-
ized cheese subchain as well. Similarly, there was a drastic reduction in the number of farms and in farm labour input.
Most farmers who had been involved in milk production retired or reoriented towards other productions, whereas
the remaining dairy farms became larger and more strongly specialized. Supermarket chains, which were also involved
306 COLLANTES
Source. Farming: Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1989a, 1991, www.ine.es, Censo Agrario, 1999 and 2009); processing:
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1991–1992–1992; www.ine.es, Encuesta Industrial de Empresas, 1999 and 2009).
a
1987.
b
1990.
FIGURE 6 Number of dairy cows, annual work units in dairy farms, and workers in processing companies,
1987 = 100. Source. Dairy cows: Ministerio de Agricultura (1972), Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación
(1986, 2001), and Ministerio de Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente (2011, 2014); annual work units in dairy
farms: Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1989a, 1991; www.ine.es, Censo Agrario, 1999 and 2009); workers in
processing companies: Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1962, 1975–1976, 1981–1982, 1987, 1989b, 1993, 1995;
www.ine.es, Encuesta Industrial de Empresas, 1993–2014)
in frantic internal restructuring, came to play a major part in the coordination of business and farm restructuring
through their very aggressive price policies.
Processors have then tried to maintain their profitability by means of two different manoeuvres. With an eye on
downstream developments, they have shifted from process‐oriented to product‐oriented innovation. By starting a
new cycle of dairy products (refrigerated desserts, in particular), they have aimed at diversifying sales towards niches
that are less mature than that of liquid milk, as well as less exposed to price pressure from supermarkets. Still, output
diversification has progressed less than in other European Union countries. Furthermore, supermarkets since the turn
of the century have been increasingly active (and rather successful) at creating their own brands (and, therefore, at
capturing a substantial share of processing‐related profitability) even for these novel products (Langreo, 2003, 2005).
In the meantime, processors have consistently adopted a second manoeuvre, upstream this time: They have
increased their price pressure on farmers. The remaining dairy farmers have made substantial investments in order
COLLANTES 307
to upgrade their technology (i.e., installation of refrigerated tanks) but still fall short of the productivity results prevail-
ing in North‐western Europe and lack any capacity to respond (even if defensively) to downstream pressure (Cabo,
2004; Calcedo, 2004; Langreo, 2005).
5 | T HE RI S E A N D T H E F A L L OF O RG A N I Z E D D A I R Y C A P I T A L I S M
The evolution of the market‐versus‐state tension in Spain's dairy chain is in line with developments in other Western
countries. In Spain too, we can discern a rise and fall of organized dairy capitalism.
Third, there was commercial protectionism all the way through. Protectionism was initially very extreme and
even included the use of nontariff instruments, such as import quotas and the rationing of foreign currency. During
the late part of the Franco regime and the early post‐Franco years, the State abandoned most nontariff instruments,
and there was even a minor trend towards tariff decrease. However, it became increasingly clear to all stakeholders
that full liberalization (clearly a potential source of tension between state and local agribusiness) would only happen
when Spain became a member of the European Economic Community (henceforth, EEC). The slow pace of Spain‐EEC
membership negotiations implied thus the consolidation of a tariff‐based variety of protectionism until the late 1980s
(Briz, 1977; Langreo, 1995).
And, fourth and last, the State became involved in an active effort to disseminate the message that a complete
and healthy diet required the consumption of large quantities of milk and other dairy products. This effort included
projects developed by sector‐specific agencies such as the National Dairy Committee (Comité Nacional Lechero) and
also by the Ministry of Health. The school milk schemes implemented in the 1950s worked in the same direction
(Collantes, 2017). Although there were differences between Spain's variety of state‐coordinated dairy capitalism
and others in Western Europe (most notably, a much greater role for discretionary, top‐down decision‐making),
the commonalities are remarkable.
up to the early 2000s, it behaved in an overtly passive way in relation to the (widely known) circulation of “black milk”
(milk produced without a quota licence) along the dairy chain (Langreo, 2005).
All in all, the European Union dismantled the quota system in 2015. Although this is not the place to undertake a
full evaluation of its consequences, the end of the quota system may well have exacerbated the drive towards farm
restructuring. More specifically, it seems to have removed obstacles for large farms to expand faster, whereas small
farms (operating under a less favourable cost structure) suffer the most from the downward pressure on farmgate
prices that has consequently appeared. It might be too early to make a definitive assessment in terms of farmers' wel-
fare, but in terms of economic coordination, the end of the quota system has undoubtedly been the latest success of
the pro‐deregulation agenda that dominates the market‐versus‐state tension since the late 20th century.
6 | T HE M A R K E T S TR I K E S BA C K ?
So, was there a transition from organized to disorganized capitalism? Between 1952 and 1986, there was indeed a
system of political economy that comprised price policies, subsidies to producers, commercial protectionism, licensed
monopolies, and demand‐side state initiatives. And after 1986, there was a process of deregulation that was driven
by both internal and external factors and that dismantled almost all of these policy instruments. Yet a closer look at
the evidence reveals not so sharp a discontinuity. The market as a mechanism for economic coordination was not so
absent during the first of our periods nor has it been so present during the second of them.
FIGURE 8 Strong elements of nonmarket coordination (grey areas and arrows) around 1980. The grey arrows apply
mostly to processed milk, which was dominant in relation to cheese and other processed dairy products
perfectly legal in smaller cities and rural areas—a decreasing but still substantial proportion of the population in a late
urbanizing country such as Spain. Even in larger cities, networks for the commercialization of raw milk persisted
throughout the period. Their operations were extra‐legal, but many consumers prized raw milk's lower price and
(Collantes, 2015). In this subchain, there were no price regulations or production licenses nor were there processors
with oligopsonistic powers. Raw milk was produced by farmers in conditions close to perfect competition and sold by
those same farmers or by middlemen in conditions that (except for the lack of perfect information) were also close to
perfect competition.
Moreover, even in the area of processed milk, the design details of organized capitalism favoured a reactivation
of market mechanisms through the back door. Policymakers focused on pasteurized milk, for which they designed the
price and licensing policies presented above. For sterilized milk, however, only price policies (and not territorial
monopolies) were implemented—and these price policies were less rigid than those applied to pasteurized milk. This
asymmetry was to play a key role in the evolution of Spain's dairy capitalism. As soon as the technology of steriliza-
tion and packaging mitigated some of the flavour problems that had originally harmed the reputation of sterilized milk
among consumers, emergent processors began to reallocate resources from the production of pasteurized milk to the
production of sterilized milk. In the domain of sterilized milk, a more flexible price policy allowed for higher profit
rates, whereas the absence of territorial licenses allowed for longer range business strategies for both the collection
of raw milk and the commercialization of processed milk (Langreo, 1995). In other words, although regulation fixed
prices along the two subchains producing processed milk, it did not comprise any mechanism to prevent resource
transfers from one subchain to the other.
In consequence, in the real world, the major policy instrument of Franco's apparently organized dairy capitalism,
the network of licensed local monopolies, never became as extraordinarily important as it was in political discourse or
legislation. At the start of the period, the scheme progressed very slowly because in many cities, there were not many
entrepreneurs who were willing to undertake the required investments under the price conditions fixed by the State.
Only after these conditions were revised upwards in the mid‐1960s was there substantial progress. By then, how-
ever, processors had already found an even more effective way of increasing their profits: reallocating resources
towards a less tightly regulated subchain: that of sterilized milk (Collantes, 2014).
COLLANTES 311
FIGURE 9 Strong elements of nonmarket coordination (grey areas and arrows) today. A wide grey arrow means
very strong nonmarket coordination; a thinner arrow means a more moderate presence of nonmarket coordination
312 COLLANTES
refrigerated desserts. As a matter of fact, the case of Spain's leading retailer (the Spanish‐owned chain of medium‐
sized supermarkets Mercadona) shows that the capacity to create relatively stable networks of processors that
become fully subordinated to retailer demands, specifications, and strategies has become one of the major sources
of competitive advantage within the retailing sector (Collantes, 2016). These retail‐led business networks are cer-
tainly controversial, attracting criticism from both those producers who belong to them (who complain about the
downscaling of their profit rate) and those who do not (who complain about having been excluded from mainstream
contact with the consumer). One thing is clear for the present discussion, though: These networks entail less, rather
than more, market coordination.
The semi‐internalization of upstream providers by large retailers has been replicated by processors in relation to
farmers. To begin with, the persistent relevance of cooperative processors (even if lower than in other parts of
Western Europe) has favoured the consolidation of relatively stable sourcing networks in some parts of the country.
More importantly, both cooperative and private processors have consistently renounced to price warfare against one
another (Langreo, 1997). The Spanish Commission for Markets and Competition now considers it proved that in the
early years of the 21st‐century processors operated as a cartel: They reached agreements over the price that they
would pay farmers for their raw milk and over immobilizing their respective milk collection networks, so that a farmer
who had traditionally belonged to one processor's network would not be accepted into another's (Noceda, 2015).
These voluntary agreements for the restriction of competition can be read as a new (even if illegal) version of one
of the traditional pillars of organized dairy capitalism. The very reaction of Spain's Ministry of Agriculture after
competition authorities imposed a heavy fine on most of the country's leading processors—a reaction that
stressed the Ministry's fear of the consequences that said fine could have on the viability of the dairy chain as a
whole (El País, 2015a)—reflects the actual limits of neoliberalism among Spanish policymakers.
In summary, two of the three main links in the dairy chain are operating under imperfect (mostly monopolistic)
competition, whereas interlink relations are commonly coordinated outside (even if complementarily to) the market.
The contrast between the political economy of the dairy chain before and after 1986 is then not so sharp. In both
cases, we find a combination of markets, on the one hand, and supply management strategies, on the other. In both
cases, such strategies are consciously implemented by hierarchies—political hierarchies in the first case and business
hierarchies in the second. In both cases, supply management is an instrument that elites use in the pursuit of their
objectives—political legitimacy in the first case and profitability in the second. In both cases, finally, the design of sup-
ply management needs to fit with the prevailing technological conditions and (there where they are present) market
signals. The revision of state price policy that took place in the mid‐1960s, for instance, was an attempt to make non-
market coordination more attuned to market signals, but the relentless change in products, standards, and prices that
today's supermarkets promote within the subchains producing retailer brands can be interpreted in a similar way.
Rather than an actual “disorganization” of dairy capitalism, there was a transition towards a different mode of
(partial) “organization.” When, in a recent interview, the president of Spain's largest retailer declares that “We are
learning that milk does not come from a brik, but from a cow” (El País, 2015b), he is adopting a perspective that would
have been perfectly understandable for the policymakers that gave birth to organized dairy capitalism in 1952, with
the qualification that the latter (belonging to a nearly preindustrial era in the dairy chain) would have declared to be
learning that milk does not come from a cow but from a pasteurizing plant. For both the policymakers of the past and
the leading company directors of the present, using power to coordinate the chain seemed and seems more promis-
ing than remaining attached to the textbook idea of a self‐regulating market.
7 | C O N CL U S I O N
Spain's dairy capitalism apparently conforms to conventional wisdom. Once upon a time (in this case, between 1952
and 1986), the State performed many and varied tasks for the coordination of the dairy economy, but in the last
decades, it has stepped back. Especially after Spain's entry to the European Economic Community, most of the policy
COLLANTES 313
instruments of organized capitalism, including price controls and the licensing of local monopolies for the production
of pasteurized milk, were dismantled.
That this truly entailed a transition from organized to disorganized capitalism is, however, much less evident, and
perhaps misleading. The dairy economy was not really so tightly organized during the era of organized capitalism: As
this article has shown, in some domains, the role played by the market as a coordination device may have been more
prominent in this earlier period than later on. Disorganized capitalism has also been less disorganized than it may
seem, and in some areas, the reach of nonmarket mechanisms of economic coordination has become greater than
in the past.
It is important to clarify what this might mean for broader debates on the historical political economy of food.
The point of this case study has not been to provide a supposedly more precise description of empirical details. In
plain terms, the argument is not that there is a prevailing black‐and‐white narrative, that this is too imprecise, and
that the whole issue should be recast in terms of dark grey and light grey. The main point is that we may be getting
wrong what the nature of the contrast between the post‐1945 period and present time is. According to the analysis
in this article, the contrast does not result simply from the substitution of the state by the market, but also (and in no
small measure) from the substitution of political elites by corporate elites in the control of (the ever present) nonmar-
ket coordination. Rather than “disorganization” or a return to the times when the dairy economy was coordinated
almost exclusively through the market, there was a transition between two different modes of (partially) “organizing”
the dairy economy. In the terms of the evolutionary economics framework adopted by von Tunzelmann (2003), the
transition did affect not only the structure of economic coordination but also (and perhaps more crucially) the control
of such coordination.
Is the case considered in this article representative of more general trends? It does not seem that the argument in
this article is hugely based on elements that are specific to Spain's dairy chain. Other Western countries were of
course ahead of Spain in the process of dairy industrialization, but even so, their share of raw milk in total consump-
tion remained substantial in the two or three decades after the Second World War (de Wilde, 1979). Therefore, it is
likely that here too the visible side of organized dairy capitalism coexisted with a less visible side of decentralized
market coordination. On the other hand, the unfolding of supply chain management strategies by processors and
supermarkets has been common to other Western countries as well (Vorley, 2007). As a result, in the later period,
a highly visible element of deregulation and liberalization seems to have coexisted with a less visible element of non-
market, corporate‐controlled coordination.
It is, however, more difficult to assess the degree up to which the argument presented in this article holds for
other chains in the modern food system. Although state intervention in the food system was far‐reaching during
the short 20th century (Moser & Varley, 2013), not all food chains were as strongly affected as the dairy chain.
And, although retail‐led supply management strategies have been pervasive in the later period (Koning, 2013), not
all food chains were as strongly restructured by them as the dairy chain, particularly in relation to the rise of
retailer‐brand foods. In consequence, we need careful empirical research on other food chains and other countries
in order to perceive the bigger picture beyond political and legal discourse.
An important methodological implication of this case study is that such empirical analysis may allow for a more
precise identification of historical eras in the political economy of food. As Bernstein (2016, pp. 638–639) points out,
much research in food regime analysis has favoured verification over open‐ended investigation. Friedmann (2016,
p. 675) suggests in a similar vein that a more careful empirical analysis may reorient the dominant discourse from
the (somewhat reified) third food regime towards a more nuanced consideration of the different trends, tensions,
and outcomes taking place in different countries and commodity chains. There is in fact a new wave of work going
precisely in that direction (see, for instance, Pritchard, Dixon, Hull, & Choithani, 2016; Winders, Heslin, Ross,
Weksler, & Berry, 2016). The present article suggests that analogous arguments can probably be made, with equally
relevant consequences for longer run interpretations, about the second food regime. Much of the conventional
wisdom on the second food regime or organized capitalism as highly coherent, post‐1945 configurations is based
on a relatively small number of studies, most of them interpreted with an eye on verifying a discourse focused on
314 COLLANTES
the political and the legal rather than on investigating actual practices from below. This is relevant not just as a his-
torical issue but also because of its influence on our understanding of the present time. As McMichael (2016, pp.
154–156) has argued, much of the debate about whether a third regime has emerged or not depends on the terms
of comparison that we choose. A more nuanced, less idealized consideration of the post‐1945 food regime would
probably lead us to be less exigent about the degree of structural coherence that we demand from the present food
regime in order to identify it as such (for a convergent methodological observation, see Bernstein, 2016, p. 643).
A different matter is defining what such food regime or, in the conceptual framework adopted in this article, such
system of economic coordination is about. This article is much closer to McMichael's view of a fully formed corporate
food regime than to alternative views of structural incoherence or an insufficiently crystallized new regime (see
Magnan, 2012, for a review of this debate; see also McMichael, 2016; Friedmann, 2016), but it reaches this conclu-
sion through a different conceptual route. Rather than geopolitical conditions (as is intrinsic to food regime analysis),
the article has highlighted the strategies of supply chain management that processors and supermarkets have
followed in the neoliberal era. Such strategies have been extensively studied within the framework of food regime
analysis (Konefal, Bain, Mascarenhas, & Busch, 2007; Lawrence & Burch, 2007) but not so much so as part of a
broader transition towards network capitalism. In a way, this is what a scholar as influential to political economists
of food as Harvey (1990, p. 159) has in mind when, in a rarely considered part of his work, he suggests that post‐
Fordist capitalism, with its “flexible responses,” becomes more (rather than less) “tightly organized” than its predeces-
sor. This reframing of the analysis is relevant because it highlights the main commonality between present time cap-
italism and the state‐coordinated variety of capitalism that prevailed between 1929/1945 and 1973: the long
distance that separates both of them from the ideal type of an exclusively market‐coordinated capitalism.
This reframing has political implications too, even if they cannot be addressed properly in the remainder of this
article. Mainstream economists have experienced as a victory the fact that CAP's last reform in 2013 did not lead to
increased public intervention in agricultural markets (see, for instance, Swinnen, 2015). At a time of increasing social
unrest in several food chains (including precisely the dairy chain), increasing public intervention was an option
favoured by some farm groups. Mainstream economists, however, favour farm support measures that do not have
an influence on the free workings of markets, for instance, direct payments to farmers. However, if the argument
in this article is correct, the alternative before us today is not really between free markets and state intervention.
The real question is who controls the nonmarket mechanisms that, under one form or another, have been playing
a major part in the coordination of the food chain since the central part of the 20th century. Seen from this angle,
more state intervention in the food chain does not necessarily represent the kind of ideological, anti‐intellectual mis-
trust of free markets that mainstream economists criticize but rather a pragmatic way of consolidating some
countervailing power in the corporate‐led governance of the chain.
ACKNOWLEDGEMEN TS
I gratefully acknowledge the comments made by three anonymous referees and by participants at the EURHO Rural
History 2015 Conference, the 2016 meeting of the Spanish Federation of Sociology, and the agricultural history sem-
inar at Santiago de Compostela, especially Lourenzo Fernández Prieto, Erwin Karel, Daniel Lanero, José Ramón
Mauleón, and Marijn Molema. I also thank Albert Herreria for his careful work on my English. Funding was provided
by the Government of Spain (ECO2015‐65582) and the Regional Government of Aragón (269187).
ORCID
Fernando Collantes http://orcid.org/0000-0001-5450-6312
RE FE R ENC ES
Abad, C., & Naredo, J. M. (1997). Sobre la “modernización” de la agricultura española (1940–1995): de la agricultura
tradicional hacia la capitalización agraria y la dependencia asistencial. In C. Gómez Benito, & J. J. González (Eds.),
Agricultura y sociedad en la España contemporánea (pp. 249–316). Madrid: CIS and MAPA.
COLLANTES 315
Araghi, F. (2009). The invisible hand and the visible foot: Peasants, dispossession and globalization. In A. H. Akram‐Lodhi, &
C. Kay (Eds.), Peasants and globalization: Political economy, rural transformation and the agrarian question (pp. 111–147).
London: Routledge.
Arrighi, G. (1994). The long twentieth century: Money, power, and the origins of our times. London: Verso.
Atkins, P. J. (2010). Liquid materialities: A history of milk, science and the law. Farnham: Ashgate.
Bernstein, H. (2016). Agrarian political economy and modern world capitalism: The contributions of food regime analysis.
Journal of Peasant Studies, 43(3), 611–647.
Biltekoff, C. (2012). Critical nutrition studies. In J. M. Pilcher (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of food history (pp. 172–190). New
York: Oxford University Press.
Boyer, R. (2005). How and why capitalisms differ. Economy and Society, 34(4), 509–557.
Briz, J. (1977). Anotaciones al mercado lácteo en España. Revista de Estudios Agrosociales, 99, 35–79.
Briz, J., Ward, R., & de Felipe, I. (1999). Análisis de la demanda y persistencia de hábitos de consumo de leche en España.
Investigación Agraria: Producción y Sanidad Animales, 14, 129–150.
Cabo, Á. (2004). La ganadería en España. In F. Molinero, R. Majoral, J. M. García Bartolomé, & G. García (Eds.), Atlas de la
España rural (pp. 248–257). Madrid: MAPA.
Calcedo, V. (1997). Crisis, evolución y cambio en la ganadería de vacuno de leche de la España húmeda (1950 al 2000). In
R. Domínguez (Ed.), La vocación ganadera del norte de España: del modelo tradicional a los desafíos del mercado mundial
(pp. 207–286). Madrid: MAPA.
Calcedo, V. (2004). El ganado bovino en España. In F. Molinero, R. Majoral, J. M. García Bartolomé, & G. García (Eds.), Atlas de
la España rural (pp. 258–265). Madrid: MAPA.
Chandler, A. D. Jr. (1977). The visible hand: The managerial revolution in American business. Cambridge: Harvard Belknap.
Chang, H.‐J. (2014). Economics: The user's guide. London: Penguin.
Clar, E. (2008). Farm policy under the Salazar and Franco dictatorships in Portugal and Spain: Towards an authoritarian model
of intervention in agriculture? In N. Vivier (Ed.), The state and rural societies: Policy and education in Europe 1750–2000
(pp. 177–194). Turnhout: Brepols.
Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.
Collantes, F. (2014). La evolución del consumo de productos lácteos en España, 1952–2007. Revista de Historia Industrial, 55,
103–134.
Collantes, F. (2015). Dairy products and shifts in Western models of food consumption since 1950: A Spanish perspective.
Rural History, 26(2), 249–268.
Collantes, F. (2016). Food chains and the retailing revolution: Supermarkets, dairy processors and consumers in Spain
(1960–present). Business History, 58(7), 1055–1076.
Collantes, F. (2017). “Because they just don't want to”: Dairy products, consumer preferences and the nutritional transition in
Spain in the 1950s and early 1960s. Agricultural History, 91(4), 536–553.
Collantes, F. (2018). Why did the industrial diet triumph? The massification of dairy consumption in Spain, 1965–90.
Economic History Review. https://doi.org/10.1111/ehr.12702. forthcoming
Collantes, F., & Pinilla, V. (2011). Peaceful surrender: The depopulation of rural Spain in the twentieth century. Newcastle‐upon‐
Tyne: Cambridge Scholars Publishing.
de Wilde, R. (1979). El mercado de las leches de consumo. Industrias Lácteas Españolas, 9, 19–24.
den Hartog, A. P. (1998). Serving the urban consumer: The development of modern food packaging with special reference to
the milk bottle. In M. R. Schärer, & A. Fenton (Eds.), Food and material culture (pp. 248–267). East Linton: Tuckwell Press.
Domínguez, R. (2001). Las transformaciones del sector ganadero en España (1940–1985). Ager: Journal of Depopulation and
Rural Development Studies, 1, 47–83.
Domínguez, R. (2003). La industria láctea en España, 1830–1985. In C. Barciela, & A. di Vittorio (Eds.), Las industrias
agroalimentarias en Italia y España durante los siglos XIX y XX (pp. 457–495). Alicante: Universidad de Alicante.
Domínguez, R., & de la Puente, L. (1997). Historia de un liderazgo: cambio técnico y trayectorias en la ganadería de Cantabria,
1850–1950. In R. Domínguez (Ed.), La vocación ganadera del norte de España: del modelo tradicional a los desafíos del
mercado mundial (pp. 89–146). Madrid: MAPA.
Domínguez, R., & de la Puente, L. (2009). Ganadería e industrialización láctea. El complejo ganadero‐industrial en Cantabria
en el siglo XX. In L. Germán, R. Hernández, & J. Moreno (Eds.), Economía alimentaria en España durante el siglo XX
(pp. 143–179). Madrid: Ministerio de Medio Ambiente y Medio Rural y Marino.
DuPuis, E. M. (2002). Nature's perfect food: How milk became America's drink. New York: New York University Press.
316 COLLANTES
El País. (2015a). Tejerina teme que la multa de CNMC afecte a la viabilidad del sector lácteo. El País, 4 March 2015.
El País (2015b). Roig: “Para competir no hay que bajar sueldos, sino hacer más con menos”. El País, 5 March 2015.
Felice, E. (2004). Il settore lattiero‐caseario in Italia dal dopoguerra al Duemila. In G. Bertagnoni (Ed.), Una storia di qualità: il
Grupo Granarolo fra valori etici e logiche di mercato (pp. 35–92). Bologna: Il Mulino.
Fenton, A. (1995). Milk and milk products in Scotland: The role of the milk marketing boards. In A. P. den Hartog (Ed.), Food
technology, science and marketing: European diet in the twentieth century (pp. 89–102). East Linton: Tuckwell Press.
Freire, D. (2011). Produzir mais e melhor: Estado, agricultura y consumo alimentario en Portugal (1926–1974). Ayer, 83,
101–126.
Freire, D., & Lanero, D. (2013). The Iberian dictatorships and agricultural modernization after the Second World War. In
P. Moser, & T. Varley (Eds.), Integration through subordination: The politics of agricultural modernization in industrial Europe
(pp. 183–201). Turnhout: Brepols.
Friedmann, H. (2016). Commentary: Food regime analysis and agrarian questions: Widening the conversation. Journal of
Peasant Studies, 43(3), 671–692.
Friedmann, H., & McMichael, P. (1989). Agriculture and the state system: The rise and decline of national agricultures, 1870
to the present. Sociologia Ruralis, 29(2), 93–117.
Galbraith, J. K. (1967). The new industrial state. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.
Gallego, D. (2001). Sociedad, naturaleza y mercado: un análisis regional de los condicionantes de la producción agraria
española (1800–1936). Historia Agraria, 24, 11–57.
García Grande, M. J. (2005). El último decenio: aplicación y consecuencias de las reformas de la PAC. In J. L. y García
Delgado, & M. J. García Grande (Eds.), Política agraria común: balance y perspectivas (pp. 44–69). Barcelona: La Caixa.
Harvey, D. (1990). The condition of postmodernity: An enquiry into the origins of cultural change. Cambridge: Blackwell.
Hernández Adell, I. (2012). La difusión de un nuevo alimento: producción y consumo de leche en España, 1865–1936.
unpublished PhD thesis, Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona.
Hernández Adell, I., & Pujol‐Andreu, J. (2016). Economic growth and biological innovation: The development of the European
dairy sector, 1865–1940. Rural History, 27(2), 187–212.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1959). Encuesta sobre cuentas familiares. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1962). Censo industrial de España 1958: enumeración previa de localización. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1964). Anuario estadístico de España 1964. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1965–1995). Encuesta de presupuestos familiares. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1975–1976). Censo de los locales de España según la inscripción realizada el 31 de diciembre
de 1970. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1981–1982). Censo de locales de España 1980. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1984–1985). Censo agrario de España 1982. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1987). Encuesta industrial. Años 1981 a 1984. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1989a). Encuesta sobre la estructura de las explotaciones agrícolas 1987. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1989b). Encuesta industrial. Años 1983 a 1986. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1991). Censo agrario 1989. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1991–1992). Censo de locales 1990. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1993). Encuesta industrial 1987–1990. Madrid: INE.
Instituto Nacional de Estadística (1995). Encuesta industrial 1989–1992. Madrid: INE.
Just, F. (2009). From crisis to cream. The Scandinavian food system in the interwar period. In Y. Segers, J. Bieleman, &
E. Buyst (Eds.), Exploring the food chain: Food production and food processing in Western Europe, 1850–1990
(pp. 213–228). Turnhout: Brepols.
Kjaernes, U. (1995). Milk: Nutritional science and agricultural development in Norway, 1890–1990. In A. P. den Hartog (Ed.),
Food technology, science and marketing: European diet in the twentieth century (pp. 103–116). East Linton: Tuckwell Press.
Konefal, J., Bain, C., Mascarenhas, M., & Busch, L. (2007). Supermarkets and supply chains in North America. In D. Burch, &
G. Lawrence (Eds.), Supermarkets and agri‐food supply chains: Transformations in the production and consumption of foods
(pp. 268–288). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Koning, N. (2013). The evolution of farm policies: A long‐term global perspective. In P. Moser, & T. Varley (Eds.), Integration
through subordination: The politics of agricultural modernization in industrial Europe (pp. 41–63). Turnhout: Brepols.
Langreo, A. (1995). Historia de la industria láctea en España: una aplicación a Asturias. Madrid: MAPA.
COLLANTES 317
Langreo, A. (1997). Las relaciones contractuales entre ganaderos e industrias dentro del sistema lácteo. In R. Domínguez
(Ed.), La vocación ganadera del norte de España: del modelo tradicional a los desafíos del mercado mundial (pp. 359–394).
Madrid: MAPA.
Langreo, A. (2003). Cambios de fondo en el sistema lácteo español. Distribución y Consumo, 67, 93–104.
Langreo, A. (2005). El sistema alimentario español desde la perspectiva de los sectores productivos (I). Distribución y
Consumo, 81, 5–57.
Lash, S., & Urry, J. (1987). The end of organized capitalism. Gerrards Cross: Polity Press.
Lawrence, G., & Burch, D. (2007). Understanding supermarkets and agri‐food supply chains. In D. Burch, & G. Lawrence
(Eds.), Supermarkets and agri‐food supply chains: Transformations in the production and consumption of foods (pp. 1–26).
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Lazonick, W. (1991). Business organization and the myth of the market economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Magnan, A. (2012). Food regimes. In J. M. Pilcher (Ed.), The Oxford handbook of food history (pp. 370–388). New York: Oxford
University Press.
Maluquer de Motes, J. (2014). La economía española en perspectiva histórica. Barcelona: Pasado y Presente.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (1986). Anuario de estadística agraria 1986. Madrid: MAPA.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (1989–1991). Consumo alimentario en España. Madrid: MAPA.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (1992–2006). La alimentación en España. Madrid: MAPA.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Pesca y Alimentación (2001). Anuario de estadística agraria 2001. Madrid: MAPA.
Martiin, C. (2010). Swedish milk, a Swedish duty: Dairy marketing in the 1920s and 1930s. Rural History, 21(2), 213–232.
McMichael, P. (2009). A food regime analysis of the world food crisis. Agriculture and Human Values, 26(4), 281–295.
McMichael, P. (2016). Commentary: Food regime for thought. Journal of Peasant Studies, 43(3), 648–670.
Mercasa (2008–2013). Alimentación en España. Madrid: Mercasa.
Ministerio de Agricultura (1972). Anuario de estadística agraria 1972. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura.
Ministerio de Agricultura (1975). Anuario de estadística agraria 1975. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura.
Ministerio de Agricultura (1976). Anuario de estadística agraria 1976. Madrid: Ministerio de Agricultura.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente (2011). Anuario de estadística agraria 2011. Madrid: Ministerio de
Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente.
Ministerio de Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente (2014). Anuario de estadística agraria 2014. Madrid: Ministerio de
Agricultura, Alimentación y Medio Ambiente.
Moser, P., & Brodbeck, B. (2007). Du lait pour tous: portrait en images, documents et analyses de l'économie et de la politique
laitières en Suisse au 20e siècle. Baden: Hier+Jetzt.
Moser, P., & Varley, T. (2013). The state and agricultural modernization in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries in Europe.
In P. Moser, & T. Varley (Eds.), Integration through subordination: The politics of agricultural modernization in industrial
Europe (pp. 13–39). Turnhout: Brepols.
Nicolau, R., Pujol, J., & Hernández, I. (2010). Milk, social acceptance of a new food in Europe: Catalona, 19th–20th centuries.
Dynamis, 30, 119–140.
Noceda, M. A. (2015). Competencia multa con 88 millones a nueve empresas lácteas. El País, 3 March 2015.
Orland, B. (2005). Milky ways. Dairy, landscape and nation building until 1930. In C. Sarasúa, P. Scholliers, & L. Van Molle
(Eds.), Land, shops and kitchens: Technology and the food chain in twentieth‐century Europe (pp. 212–254). Turnhout:
Brepols.
Ovejero, S. (1951). El problema zootécnico en la producción de leche. Anuario General de Veterinaria y Zootécnica, 2,
953–963.
Pechlaner, G., & Otero, G. (2008). The third food regime: Neoliberal globalism and agricultural biotechnology in North
America. Sociologia Ruralis, 48(4), 351–371.
Pritchard, B. (2009). The long hangover from the second food regime: A world‐historical interpretation of the collapse of the
WTO Doha Round. Agriculture and Human Values, 26(4), 297–307.
Pritchard, B., Dixon, J., Hull, E., & Choithani, C. (2016). “Stepping back and moving in”: The role of the state in the contem-
porary food regime. Journal of Peasant Studies, 43(3), 693–710.
Ríos‐Núñez, S. M., & Coq‐Huelva, D. (2015). The transformation of the Spanish livestock system in the second and third food
regimes. Journal of Agrarian Change, 15(4), 519–540.
318 COLLANTES
Schuurman, A. (2013). Agricultural policy and the Dutch agricultural institutional matrix during the transition from organized
to disorganized capitalism. In P. Moser, & T. Varley (Eds.), Integration through subordination: The politics of agricultural mod-
ernisation in industrial Europe (pp. 65–84). Turnhout: Brepols.
Segers, Y., & Lefebvre, W. (2009). Industrialising the countryside. The cooperative dairy industry in Belgium during the inter-
war period. In Y. Segers, J. Bieleman, & E. Buyst (Eds.), Exploring the food chain: Food production and food processing in
western Europe, 1850–1990 (pp. 49–75). Turnhout: Brepols.
Simpson, J. (1995). Spanish agriculture, 1765–1965: The long siesta. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Smith, A. [1776](1961). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: Methuen.
Swinnen, J. F. M. (2015). An imperfect storm in the political economy of the Common Agricultural Policy. In J. F. M. Swinnen
(Ed.), The political economy of the 2014–2020 Common Agricultural Policy: An imperfect storm (pp. 443–484). Brussels:
Centre for European Policy Studies.
Valenze, D. (2011). Milk: A local and global history. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Vatin, F. (1990). L'industrie du lait. Paris: L'Harmattan.
Vernon, K. (2000). Milk and dairy products. In K. F. Kiple, & K. C. Ornelas (Eds.), The Cambridge world history of food
(pp. 692–702). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
von Tunzelmann, N. (2003). Historical coevolution of governance and technology in the industrial revolutions. Structural
Change and Economic Dynamics, 14, 365–384.
Vorley, B. (2007). Supermarkets and agri‐food supply chains in Europe: Partnership and protest. In D. Burch, & G. Lawrence
(Eds.), Supermarkets and agri‐food supply chains: Transformations in the production and consumption of foods (pp. 243–267).
Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Williamson, O. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.
Winders, B., Heslin, A., Ross, G., Weksler, H., & Berry, S. (2016). Life after the regime: Market instability with the fall of the
US food regime. Agriculture and Human Values, 33(1), 73–88.
How to cite this article: Collantes F. From organized to disorganized capitalism? Market versus nonmarket
coordination in Spain's dairy chain. J Agrar Change. 2019;19:295–318. https://doi.org/10.1111/joac.12291
Copyright of Journal of Agrarian Change is the property of Wiley-Blackwell and its content
may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright
holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for
individual use.