Contracts and Electricity Pool Prices: J S. G, D P and K W
Contracts and Electricity Pool Prices: J S. G, D P and K W
by
*
University of Melbourne, London Economics and London Economics, respectively. Financial assistance
from London Economics is gratefully acknowledged. In addition, we thank Frank Wolak for helpful
discussions and participants at the 1997 Industry Economics Conference and two anonymous referees for
comments. All views expressed in this papers are those of the authors and do not reflect the views of
London Economics. Please address correspondence to Joshua Gans, Melbourne Business School, 200
Leicester Street, Carlton, Victoria, 3053; Fax: (03) 9349 8133; E-mail: J.Gans@mbs.unimelb.edu.au. The
latest version of this paper will be available at: http://www.mbs.unimelb.edu.au/home/jgans.
2
I. Introduction
In recent years, the electricity sector has been transformed from a vertically
generation and retailing. This change has been well established in England and Wales and
now in Victoria and New South Wales. South Australia and Queensland face similar
The change in the structure of electricity production has come about because of the
establishment of a spot or pool market for electricity generation. This pool is characterised
by generators making half-hourly bids of generation and a price schedule and a pool
operator using these bids as the basis for a dispatch schedule. Generators then receive the
system marginal price (SMP) on all units dispatched. The SMP is the highest price paid for
any unit dispatched. Economists have begun to model this pool market behaviour as either
multi-unit simultaneous auction (von der Fehr and Harbord, 1993). These analyses have
shown that pool markets may not produce competitive outcomes if there are a small number
of dominant generators. Hence, pool prices may be substantially above marginal cost.
Side by side with pool markets are both long and short-term contract markets for
electricity. By writing contracts, generators and retailers can share risks associated with a
fluctuating pool price. But concern has been raised that the imperfect competition of pool
markets will simply translate into market power being exercised in contract markets.
Therefore, the existence of a contract market may allow generators further leverage over
retailers.
The purpose of this paper is to explore the linkages between pool and contract
issues explored by previous researchers. Von der Fehr and Harbord (1992) model the pool
as a multi-unit auction and demonstrate that contracts give generators a strategic advantage
in the pool market by allowing them to commit to supply greater quantities during peak
3
demand periods. However, their model suffers from the disadvantage that the contract
prices are held fixed when in reality they will adjust over time depending on potential pool
market behaviour. Powell (1993) considers the interaction between contract and spot
markets and draws on some of the competitive conclusions below. His model views
contract deals and spot market bidding as simultaneously determined. Our model below
considers the role of pre-emptive contracting before spot market trading occurs. Finally,
Green (1996) appropriately looks at the endogenous formation of both pool and contract
prices in a supply function model. His analysis in many ways mirrors some of the
conclusions below. However, his reliance on the complex, albeit descriptively accurate,
supply function model makes it difficult to analyse how alterations in the cost structure of
In this paper we use a Cournot model of pool market behaviour that lies at one
extreme of the supply function models -- where the ability of generators to influence market
generators and retailers as risk neutral and hence, there are no risk sharing benefits in
signing long-term contracts. Nonetheless, we are able to show that contracts are signed
and, in contrast to the concerns of some, make electricity markets more, not less,
affording more efficient generators a greater market share. We then turn to consider the
effect of the contract market on entry decisions. A final section concludes with remarks
1
Grant and Quiggin (1996) demonstrate that Cournot outcomes naturally result in supply function models
when capital pre-commitments are relatively inflexible, as in electricity generation investment. This is a
commonly used specification to model electricity pools. See also Powell (1993) and Borenstein, Bushnell
and Stoft (1997). In addition, Wolak and Patrick (1997) provide empirical evidence supporting competition
in quantities.
4
While the analysis to follow will eliminate risk sharing aspects of contracting, these
are the concerns that provide a rationale for the existence of contract markets. Therefore, it
To generators and retailers the greatest risk posed by electricity pools is the financial
consequences of fluctuating pool prices. Pool prices will vary each half hour and will be
determined by the balance of supply and demand. Whilst the level of demand can be
Generators themselves will choose how much electricity they will offer to produce. The
power station with the highest marginal bid that is operating at any point in time (and the
anticipated. These uncertainties about availability consequently affect the stability of pool
prices in the short, medium and long term. Therefore, generators and retailers may wish to
cover themselves for this pool price risk by taking out an option contract (which are known
These contracts are purely financial transactions. When these option contracts are
set alongside physical sales or purchases from the pool provide insurance against excessive
fluctuations in the pool price. These contracts are used in the UK, Victoria, NSW and a
similar contract market will operate in the NEM. For example, vesting contracts are simply
a financial hedge with a range of cross-subsidies added into the contract price. The nature
2
A short-term day ahead contract market is also proposed for the NEM. This market is not the focus of
this paper.
5
Contract components
All contracts types have two common elements; a strike price and a quantity.
However, many are more complex, with multiple strike prices for different times of the day
or periods of the year and contract quantities which may be ‘sculpted’ over the course of
the year. Further, some contracts can only be ‘called’ during certain periods, such as peak
times.
The key components of a contract are listed and briefly described below:
• one-way/two way options; the contract may be called by the holder (retailer) or seller
(generator) of the option, depending upon how the option is defined;
• firm/non-firm capacity; the contract may be firm or related to the availability of
particular generating sets;
• strike price; this will set the price level at which the contract can be called. It can be
varied by time or day. It can also be escalated from year to year;
• maximum capacity; the amount of capacity for which the contract can be called can be
‘sculpted’ by time of day or year to match a purchaser’s load shape;
• maximum and minimum takes; safeguards can be set against the contract being called
too much or too little by constraining the number of takes;
• option constraint; the hours in which the option can be called, whether or not the strike
price is below pool price, can be limited; and
• length of contract; this determines the overall commitment to the contract terms.
There are essentially two forms of these contracts: one-way and two-way. One-
way contracts establish a ceiling pool price (the strike price), as illustrated in Figure 1. If
the price is below the ceiling price retailers pay the pool price, if it is above the ceiling price
retailers still pay the pool price but are compensated by the generator for the difference
Generators sell the contracts to distributors for a fixed option fee. If both
contracting parties are risk neutral, the value of the option fee would be equal to the net
present value of the difference between expected pool purchase costs and purchase costs
6
under the contract (net of the option fee). That is, the net present value of the expected pool
price and the contract price is the same. Since the expected pool price is used to determine
the amount that a buyer would pay for the option fee, it is important to predict the future
Pool price
Strike price
Time
that a two-way contract establishes a firm price for both generator and retailer (see Figure
2). Two-way contracts for differences are like forward contracts - retailers and generators
essentially have agreed to buy/sell electricity for a fixed price over a fixed period in the
future. Therefore, two-way contracts are not normally associated with option fees. Under
a two-way contract, if the pool price rises above the strike price, generators compensate
retailers for the difference. But if pool price falls below the strike price, then retailers
compensate generators for the difference. The net present value of the strike price should
Generally, one-way contracts are the preferred form of cover against infrequent
events, such as pool prices moving above $300/MWh. Thus, the generator bears the risk if
the pool price falls below the strike price; they will not be compensated for downward
shocks.
8
Pool price
Strike price
Time
events the main advantage of the two-way contract is that it reduces generator exposure to
revenue risk when pool prices fall below contract strike price. Under a one-way contract
generators are exposed to this risk. To the extent that generators will be risk adverse they
will prefer two-way to one-way contracts. This has happened in Victoria. Two-way
contracts are generally used to cover base load demand and part of their intermediate
demand. One-way contracts are used for intermediate and peak demand.
While the role of one-way contracts is to hedge against the pool price risk borne by
retailers, two-way contracts involve both retailers and generators sharing risk and, as will
mentioned earlier, our decision to focus on the Cournot case is to demonstrate most clearly
the existence of strategic effects to contracting. This allows us to use a simple framework
to explore the comparative statics associated with such contracting (cf: Green, 1996). The
restrictive assumptions we employ are for ease of exposition and can be generalised quite
easily.
industry demand for electricity is a linear function p = A − b(q1 + q2 ) . This is simply the
inverse load duration curve for a particular time period. It represents the choices of retailers
and customers which are unmodelled in this paper. While industry demand is stochastic in
practice, here we will ignore this possibility -- this is a reasonable restriction given our
assumption the generators and retailers are risk neutral. Generator production costs are
linear with Ci (qi ) = ci qi , where we assume initially that c1 = c2 = c . There are potentially
Finally, we assume that A > ci for all i so that each firm’s output is positive in equilibrium.
demand is perfectly inelastic in any given time period (Patrick and Wolak, 1997).
However, contracts are signed over a longer time horizon. Over those time periods,
demand is more elastic. As this paper considers stable equilibria in both the contract and
spot markets, it is this latter specification that is more appropriate.3 As retailers will come
to expect future spot prices, this will be built into their daily demand for electricity. As
The game between generators proceeds in two stages. In the first stage, generators
can pre-emptively contract with retailers. That is, they each choose, x i, their contracted
3
This has been the approach followed by others (see Green and Newbery, 1992; Powell, 1993).
10
quantity, with the strike price, z, a function of their competition in contracting. In the
second, spot market competition in the pool occurs. As will be shown, what occurs in the
latter stage is influenced by the first. This is because both generators and retailers have
rational expectations regarding what price will result in the pool in stage two. Indeed,
given the assumption of risk neutrality, no retailer will sign a contract with a strike price
less than the expected spot price and generators will, in equilibrium, not find it
advantageous to offer lower contract prices than expected spot prices. Therefore, agents
We will analyse the model by working backwards considering stage two pool
market behaviour contingent on any feasible contract set signed and then looking at contract
market behaviour in which all parties expected the predicted stage two behaviour.
Suppose that both generators have signed contracts for amounts ( x1 , x2 ) in stage
Given our Cournot assumption, each generator chooses qi to maximise this function,
holding the quantities of all other generators as given. While marginal cost is always c,
marginal revenue is − b(qi − xi ) + p ; that is, it is linear and intersects the demand curve at at
qi = xi. Contracts alter the intercept of the marginal revenue curve. In particular, when qi <
xi, marginal revenue lies above average revenue because the generator will effectively be a
net buyer into the pool, giving it an incentive to push prices down. Nonetheless, the key
point here is that while marginal incentives are dependent on the quantity of contract cover,
A − bq j + bxi − c
qi = .
2b
The key feature to note about this function is that it is increasing in own level of contract
cover and only depends on the level of contract cover of the other generator through that
generator’s quantity. The intuition for this relationship can be best demonstrated
graphically. Figure 3 depicts the inverse demand curve facing generator 1 for a given q 2 .
It also depicts the marginal revenue curve facing that firm when it has no contract cover.
Note that the marginal revenue curve when it has contract cover of, say, x1units of contract
cover, is higher than the marginal revenue curve without contract cover. For a constant
marginal cost, the quantity at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost is greater when
the generator has signed a forward contract for some quantity. This occurs regardless of
the quantity chosen by the other generator, hence, pushing the reaction curve upwards.
It should be noted that when a generator contracts some output, regardless of the
strike price on that contract, it should bid that contracted amount into the pool at marginal
cost. This ensures that when the pool price is above marginal cost, the generators
act financially as if it had bought the unproduced portion of the contract at pool prices.
Thus, if individual demand facing a generator were relatively low, it may find itself not
producing its full contracted amount. While this is optimal if the pool price is below
marginal (or avoidable) cost, the generator is strictly better producing this quantity if the
pool price is above marginal cost. Note that a firm whose output is entirely contracted,
i.e., with xi = qi , ends up with price equal to marginal cost. This mirrors a result
p
MR (No Contract)
MR (Contract)
MC
c
x1 q1
q2
1’s Reaction
(No Contract)
1’s Reaction
(Contract)
2’s Reaction
q1
Solving out for the unique equilibrium in the stage two subgame, we have:
qi = 1
3 ( 1
b )
( A − c) + 2 xi − x j for all i and p = 1
3 ( A − b( x1 + x2 ) + 2c).
Observe that price is lower when the sum of contract cover is greater. Moreover, whenever
one generator increases its contract cover relative to the other, its quantity sold is greater
while the quantity sold by its rival is lower. As depicted in Figure 3, the assumption of
13
Cournot competition means that each generator’s quantity choice is decreasing in those of
its rivals (i.e., they are strategic substitutes). Greater individual contract cover raises the
returns to having higher quantities in the pool. As such, it raises a given generator’s output
but also results in reduced output by other generators and a lower pool price overall.
Therefore, by encouraging generators to bid a greater quantity into the pool at any
given time, contracts have a strategic effect on the equilibrium in stage two. Note that in
Bertrand competition the pool price equals marginal cost always so that the amount of
contract cover does not have this strategic effect. It is only when generators can make
quantity commitments (even partly), that the strategic implications of contracting are
realised.
Each generator and retailer realises that contracts have effects on pool prices. For
each generator, greater contract cover raises their incentives to bid larger quantities in the
pool and forces others to reduce their quantities, all other things being equal. The lower
pool prices will mean that retailers will demand a lower strike price for any contract signed,
however. The question is, what will happen when each generator competes for these
contracts?
π i = ( p − c)qi = 1
9b ( A − b( x + x ) − c)( A + b(2 x − x ) − c) .
i j i j
Once again, using this payoff, generators choose their level of contract cover, holding the
contract choices (but not the ultimate spot market choices) of the other generator as given.
∂π i dqi
= dx i ( p − b(qi − xi ) − c) − dx ij bqi .
dq
∂xi 1 4 4 4 2 4 4 4 3 12 3
=0 Strategic
Effect
The first term is zero by the envelope theorem. Under risk neutrality, there is no direct cost
or demand advantage from contracting. Therefore, the effect is purely a strategic one (a
“top dog” strategy in Fudenberg and Tirole’s (1984) terminology). This is positive for, as
noted earlier, increased contracting raises own output in the spot market reducing the
Considering our specific model, the first order condition for the profit maximising
∂π i
∂xi
( ( ) ) ( (
= − 19 A + b 2 xi − x j − c + 29 A − b xi + x j − c = 0 ) )
which, in the unique symmetric subgame perfect equilibrium, yields:
A−c A + 4c
x1 = x2 = and z = .
5b 5
Observe that the resulting level of output (both contracted and spot) for a generator is:
2( A − c )
q1 = q2 = ,
5b
twice the contracted level. So in this specific example, generators contract half of their
output in equilibrium.
A−c A + 2c
q1 = q2 = and p = .
3b 3
Therefore, it is easy to see that by allowing for contracting, price is lower and output is
greater. So while each generator has a strategic benefit from pre-emptive contracting, in
equilibrium this possibility harms their profits. Each would prefer to commit not to
contract, but in a similar vein to the Prisoner’s Dilemma, each chooses to contract a positive
15
amount imposing a negative effect on the other’s profits (see Allaz and Villa, 1993; for
While the strategic role of contracts and its competitive benefits continue to hold with non-
linear demands and costs, one cannot analyse whether more efficient generators use
contracts relatively more or less than less efficient ones in a symmetric environment.
Therefore, in this section, we extend our basic model to consider heterogeneous cost
Consider first a situation in which generators differ in their marginal costs, i.e.,
c1 > c2 . In this case, the equilibrium is no longer symmetric. It is still unique, however,
A + c1 + c2 A + c2 − 2c1 A + c1 − 2c2
p= , q1 = and q2 =
3 3b 3b
Once again, the output of both generators is higher and price lower when contracting is
possible. One can also compare the market shares of generators when contracting is and is
not allowed. Interestingly, with contracting, the market share of the more efficient plant is
These conclusions are not robust to alternative cost specifications. Suppose that
Ci (qi ) = ci 12 qi2 . It is cumbersome but not difficult to show that while the results of Section
III continue to hold for this cost function, generators contract a third of their output in
equilibrium but the market shares in the contracting as compared with the no contracting
case are exactly the same. Nonetheless, as one increases the marginal costs of one
generator, its output falls, the output of its rival rises, total industry output falls, contract
levels fall and each firm continues to contract one third of its output.
electricity generation. In reality, however, the capacity constraints on a generator are such
that marginal cost is relatively flat for most output below a certain level at which it becomes
very step (i.e., the marginal cost curve is an inverted L-shape). Capacity constraints of this
form are difficult to analyse. If both generators are expected to be constrained in a given
period (i.e., in periods of high demand), then neither one gains a strategic advantage from
pre-emptive contracting as this does not reduce the quantity the other bids into the pool. On
the other hand, in periods of low demand, both have strategic incentives similar to those
analysed in this paper. Thus, one would expect the degree of contract cover to vary with
One can also ask whether large versus small generators have a greater incentive to
contract, all other things equal. Assuming equal marginal costs, small generators are likely
to be constrained more often. In a duopoly, this means that a large generator will have a
reduced strategic incentive to contract as they cannot influence the quantity the small
generator bids into the pool. In reality, when there is no duopoly, however, it is difficult to
say whether large or small generators will have a greater incentive to pre-emptively
contract.
17
The previous sections demonstrated that contracts have the effect of diminishing the
overall price for electricity and, hence, the profits of individual generators. In a static
through greater allocative efficiency in electricity. However, lower prices and industry
profits make entry unattractive. While this would not be a concern in industries where
entry can be smooth and entrants have considerable flexibility over the scale of production,
in electricity, this is not a reasonable assumption. Entry will give rise to discrete changes
and potential entrants will have to take account of larger changes in prices received.
Once again, we ask the question: what does the existence of a contract market have
on pool prices? Newbery (1997) has analysed the interaction between contracts and entry
deterrence in electricity markets. In a model in which only incumbent generators were able
committing generators to lower pool prices -- below the level that would allow for entry.
We analyse this case as follows. Suppose that there are two incumbent generators,
1 and 2, as in Section III who have symmetric marginal costs, c. In addition, suppose
there are no capacity constraints. There is a potential entrant, 3, who has marginal cost of c
≤ c, but must incur a sunk entry cost of F > 0. It will, therefore, enter if its expected post-
entry profits π3 ≥ F.
It is quite easy to demonstrate that entry profits are lower when there is a contract
market compared with a situation in which such a market does not exist. Therefore, there
exists a range of sunk costs, F, such that the entrant would choose to enter if there was no
contract market but would not enter otherwise. If this is the case, then the price that
18
However, when there is a contract market, entry does not occur so the price remains at its
duopoly level, 15 ( A + 4c) . In this case, a contract market serves to lower electricity prices
if and only if A − c ≥ 5(c − c), i.e., if the cost differential is small. For a large entrant cost
advantage, if F is such that entry might be deterred by having a contract market, then the
In addition, it can shown quite easily that there exist parameter values under which
efficient entry is deterred by a contract market. That is, taking into account the sunk costs,
it can be shown that a potential entrant will find entry unprofitable, yet such entry would
have reduced industry-wide average costs.5 The possibility that efficient entry is deterred
becomes more likely at intermediate ranges of sunk entry costs. In reality, when entry can
occur on many different scales, the possibility that the contract market has a negative
V I . Conclusions
This paper has demonstrated that contract markets can serve to make oligopolistic
spot markets more competitive. Generators have a purely strategic incentive to sign
forward contracts so as to raise their share of the overall electricity market. However, this
option has a negative effect on the profits of other generators. Each is caught in the
mutual interest to refrain from so doing. The result is an electricity market with prices
Our conclusion, however, was qualified by the possibility that the contract market
might deter entry that might otherwise occur and hence, could lead to higher electricity
4
Of course, as the cost advantage grows large the range of sunk costs that might deter otherwise possible
entry grows smaller.
19
prices in the long-run. This analysis of the possible dynamic consequences of contracts is
only a beginning. In particular, signing a contract can make current generators less flexible
the interaction between pool and contract markets in a dynamic setting where each sends
signals and provides incentives for entry and investment (as in Aghion and Bolton, 1987;
5
For instance, this occurs when A = 10, b = 1, c = 6, c = 0 and F = 38. In this case, post entry profits are
36 while the average cost reduction in entry occurred would be 1.
20
References
Allaz, B. and J-L. Vila (1993), “Cournot Competition, Futures Markets and Efficiency,”
Journal of Economic Theory, 59 (1), pp.1-16.
Borenstein, S., J. Bushnell and S. Stoft (1997), “The Competitive Effects of Transmission
Capacity in a Deregulated Electricity Industry,” Working Paper No.6293, NBER.
von der Fehr, N-H. M., and D. Harbord (1992), “Long-Term Contracts and Imperfectly
Competitive Spot Markets: A Study of the UK Electricity Industry,” Memorandum
No. 14, Dept of Economics, University of Oslo.
von der Fehr, N-H. M., and D. Harbord (1993), “Spot Market Competition in the UK
Electricity Industry,” Economic Journal, 103 (2), pp.531-546.
Gans, J.S. and S.P. King (1998), “Exclusionary Contracts, Competition and Efficiency,”
mimeo., University of Melbourne.
Green, R.J. (1996), “The Electricity Contract Market,” Working Paper, No.9616, DAE,
Cambridge University.
Green, R.J. and D.M. Newbery (1992), “Competition in the British Electricity Spot
Market,” Journal of Political Economy, 100, pp.929-953.
Fudenberg, D. and J. Tirole (1984), “The Fat Cat Effect, the Puppy Dog Ploy and the Lean
and Hungry Look,” American Economic Review, 74 (2), pp.361-368.
Innes, R. and R.J. Sexton (1994), “Strategic Buyers and Exclusionary Contracts,”
American Economic Review, 84 (3), pp.566-584.
Newbery, D.M. (1997), “Competition, Contracts and Entry in the Electricity Spot Market,”
Working Paper, No.9707, DAE, Cambridge.
Patrick, R.H. and F.A. Wolak (1997), “Estimating the Customer-Level Demand for
Electricity Under Real-Time Pricing,” mimeo., Stanford.
Wolak, F.A. and R.H. Patrick (1997), “The Impact of Market Rules and Market Structure
on the Price Determination Process in the England and Wales Electricity Market,”
mimeo., Stanford.