UNIDO&LMA
UNIDO&LMA
UNIDO&LMA
• Where:Fi = Fraction of foreign exchange, at the margin, spent on importing commodity I Qi = Quantity of
commodity i that can be bought with one unit of foreign exchange (This will be equal to 1 divided by the
CIF value of the good in question).
• Pi = domestic market clearing price of commodity i
• Example Commodities 1,2,3, and 4 are imported at the margin. The proportion of foreign exchange spent
on them, the quantities that can be bought per unit of foreign exchange, and the domestic market clearing
prices are as follows:
• F1 = 0.3, F2 = 0.4, F3 = 0.2, F4 = 0.1
• Q1 = 0.6, Q2 = 1.5, Q3 = 0.25, Q4 = 3.0
• P1 = 16, P2 = 8, P3 = 40, P4 = 5
• The value of a unit of foreign exchange is:
• (.3) (0.6) (16) + (0.4) (1.5) (8) + (02) (0.25) (40) + (0.1) (3.0) (5) = Br. 13.180
The calculation of the shadow price of foreign exchange in
terms of consumer willingness to pay is based on the
assumption that the foreign exchange requirement of a
project is met from the sacrifice of others.
The use of foreign exchange by a project, however, may also
induce the production of foreign exchange through additional
exports or import substitution. In such a case, the shadow
price of foreign exchange would be based on the cost of
producing foreign exchange, not consumer willingness to pay
for foreign exchange.
• Practical Examples using the UNIDO approach
• Imported input
• Table 1 below illustrates how the economic value of a
project's imported textile inputs will be measured using
the UNIDO approach. It has been estimated that the
country has a foreign exchange premium of 30 per cent
and the shadow exchange rate is therefore (1 +0.3) x
OER. All tariffs and taxes are deducted from the
domestic retail price of textiles and their tradable
(foreign exchange) component is inflated by the
shadow exchange rate to obtain the domestic price
equivalent of the cif import price. The economic cost of
domestic transport and handling is then added.
(ii) Exported output
• Table 2 below gives an example of the economic valuation of a project's
exported garment output, using the UNIDO approach. The country again has a
foreign exchange premium of 30 per cent. The foreign exchange earnings are
inflated by the shadow exchange rate and all export subsidies are deducted
from the fob export price to obtain the domestic price equivalent of the
border price.
• Non-traded input
• The domestic price approach to the valuation of a non-traded input such as
electricity is shown in Table 3 below. The financia1 cost of the electricity is its
domestic sales price, Br.2 million, plus Br. 300 000 sales tax. If the non-traded
input's supply can be increased, its economic value will be measured by its
domestic market supply price, after any adjustments have been made for
market imperfections such as taxes, price fixing, subsidies or monopoly
pricing. If the project uses electricity that must be bid away from existing
consumers, then the electricity should be valued at the price that people are
willing to pay for it, its demand price.
•
In the example above, electricity is a private
monopoly and monopoly rents are found to represent
Br. 500000 of the total Br. 2 Million supply price of
electricity.
If the project uses electricity that must be bid away
from existing consumers, then the monopoly rents
should be included when measuring its economic
value, as people are willing to pay this total amount,
including these rents for this electricity.
Monopoly rents are only treated as a transfer and
excluded if the supply of electricity can be expanded
to meet the project's needs. In this case only the cost
to the economy of producing additional electricity is
the relevant economic cost.
• Of the project's total electricity input requirements, 40 per
cent will be met by displacing existing consumers, and 60 per
cent will be met by expanding supply. The economic cost of
this displaced consumption is the total amount that people
were willing to pay for this electricity, including monopoly
rents and sales tax.
• Approximately Br.200 000 (40 per cent of Br. 500 000) of the
monopoly rents should therefore be included in the economic
value of the input, but the remaining Br. 300 000 should not
be included.
• Similarly, approximately 40 per cent of the sales tax (Br.120
000) should be included in the economic value of the input,
the part that is met by displacing existing consumers, but the
remaining Br. 180 000 of sales tax should not be included in
the project's economic costs.
Non-traded output
• If instead the project is producing electricity a non-traded
output, the UNIDO approach to valuing this electricity is as
shown in the Table 4 below. If the entire project's output
meets new demand its economic value is simply its domestic
market demand-price, as long as there is no price fixing or
rationing.
• In this case all new output represents an increment in supply.
Consequently, all monopoly rents and sales taxes imposed
should be included in measuring the economic benefits of the
project, as this is the amount people are willing to pay for the
electricity. The electricity authority does not receive the sales
tax paid on electricity, so it is not a financial benefit to it.
Impact on Distribution
• Stages three and four of the UNIDO method are concerned
with measuring the value of a project in terms of its
contribution to savings and income redistribution. To facilitate
such assessments, we must first measure the income gained
or lost by individual groups within the society.
• Groups: For income distribution analysis, the society may be
divided into various groups. The UNIDO approach seeks to
identify income gains and losses by the following: Project,
Other private business, Government, Workers, Consumers,
and External Sector There can, however be, other equally
valid groupings.
Measure of Gain or Loss:
• The gain or loss to an individual group within the society as a
result of the project is equal to the difference between the
shadow price and the market price of each input or output in
the case of physical resources or the difference between the
price paid and the value received in the case of financial
transaction.
• Example1: Farmers in a certain area use 1 million units of
electricity generated by a hydro-electric project. The benefit
derived by them, measured in terms of the willingness to pay
is equal to Br. 0.4 million. The tariff paid by them to the
electricity board is Br. 0.25 million. So the impact of the
project on the farmers gain of Br. 0.15 million. (0.4-
0.25million)
• Example2: A mining project requires 1000 laborers. These
laborers are prepared to offer themselves for work at a daily
wage rate of Br. 8.00. (This represents their supply price.) The
wage rate paid to the laborers, however, is Br. 10 per day. So
the redistribution benefit enjoyed by the group of 1000
laborers is Br. 2000 (1000 x (10 – 8) per day.
• Savings impact and its value
• Most of the developing countries face scarcity of capital.
Hence, the governments of these countries are concerned
about the impact of a project on savings and its value thereof.
Stage three of the UNIOO method, concerned with this and
seeks to answer the following questions: Given the income
distribution impact of the project what would be its effects on
savings? What is the value of such savings to the society?
• Impact on Savings: The savings impact of a project is equal to:
• ∆YiMPSi
• where ∆Yi = change in income of group i as a result of the
project.
• MPSi = marginal propensity to save of group i
• Example As a result of a project the change in income
gained/lost by four groups is:
• Group 1 = Br. 100000; Group 2 = Br. 500000; Group 3 = Br. –
200000; and Group 4 = Br. -400000. The marginal propensity to
save of these four groups is as follows:
• MPS1 = 0.05; MPS2 = 0.10; MPS3 = 0.20; and MPS4 = 0.40.
• The impact on savings of the project is thus given by:
• 100,000 X 0.05 + 500,000 X 0.10 - 2 00,000 x 0.20 – 400,000 x
0.40 = -Br. 1 45000.
•
Impact on Income Distribution
• Many governments regard redistribution of income in favor of
economically weaker sections or economically backward
regions as a socially desirable objective.
• Due to practical difficulties in pursuing the objective of
redistribution entirely through the tax, subsidy, and transfer
measures of the government, investment projects are also
considered as investments for income redistribution and their
contribution toward this goal is considered in their evaluation.
• This calls for suitably weighing the net gain or loss by each
group, measured earlier, to reflect the relative value of
income for different groups and summing them.
Adjustment for merit and demerit
•
goods
In same cases, the analysis has to be extended to reflect the
difference between the economic value and social value of
resources. This difference exists in the case of merit goods
and demerit goods.
• A merit good is one for which the social value exceeds the
economic value. For example, a country may place a higher
social value than economic value on production of oil because
it reduces dependence on foreign supplies. The concept of
merit goods can be extended to include a socially desirable
outcome like creation of employment.
• In the case of a demerit good, the social value of the good is
less than its economic value. For example, a country may
regard alcoholic products as having social value less than
economic value.
• The procedure for adjusting for the difference between social
value and economic value is as follows: (i) Estimate the
economic value. (ii) Calculate the adjustment factor as the
difference between the ratio of social value to economic value
minus unity. (iii) Multiply the economic value by the
adjustment factor to obtain the adjustment (iv) Add the
adjustment to the net present value of the project.
• To illustrate, consider a project for which the following
information is available: (i) The present economic value of the
output of the project is Br. 25 million. (ii) The output of the
project has social value, which exceeds its economic value by
20 per cent. Given this information, the adjustment factor
would be 0.2 (120 per cent/100 per cent - 1). Multiplying the
present economic value by 0.2, we get an adjustment of Br. 5
million. This, then, is added to the present economic value of
Br. 25 million.
Where the socially valuable output of the project does not appear as an
output in the economic analysis - as is the case where the project
generates employment - the procedure is somewhat different.
In such a case the output is treated like an externality and its valuation in
social terms is the adjustment. While the adjustment for the difference
between the social value and economic value is seemingly a step in the
fight direction, it is amenable to abuse.
Once the analyst begins to make adjustment for social reasons, projects
which are undesirable economically maybe made to appear attractive
after such adjustment. Since the dividing line between 'political' and
'social' is rather nebulous, it becomes somewhat easy to push politically
expedient projects, irrespective of their economic merit by investing them
with social desirability. While there is no way to prevent such a
manipulation, the stage-by-stage UNIDO approach mitigates its
occurrence by throwing it in sharp relief.
Little and MIRRLEES APPROACH
The Little and Mirrlees approach (sometimes known as the
border price approach), also values traded goods at their
border prices, in the same way as the UNIDO (domestic price)
approach.
However, these border prices are then converted into local
currency at the official exchange rate rather than at a shadow
exchange rate. The project's traded good inputs and outputs
are effectively kept in their border prices.
However, if there is a foreign exchange premium in the
country concerned the prices of non-traded goods will have
risen to match the tariff inclusive prices of tradable. The price
of non-tradable will therefore overstate the goods' true value
to consumers, relative to the border prices of traded goods.
• The border price approach therefore revalues these non-
traded goods in border price equivalents using commodity
specific Conversion Factors.
• These conversion factors are the ratio of the border price
equivalent of each non-traded good to its domestic price.
Multiplying the domestic price value of a non-traded good by
its conversion factor has the effect of converting the good's
domestic price into its border price equivalent
• Both traded and non-traded goods are then valued in the
same numeraire, i.e., border prices, so it will be possible to
include them together in the project's cash flow. This is the
reason why this method can also be called the border price
approach.
• The Little-Mirrlees approach makes traded and non-traded
goods prices comparable by precisely the inverse method to
that used by the UNIDO approach, which values both traded
and non-traded goods in comparable, domestic prices.
• T In summary this approach values:
• Traded Goods Non-Traded goods
• @ Border price x OER @ Domestic price i X Cfi
•
• Border price equivalent
• Numeraire: border prices
• CFi = conversion factor of good i = border price equivalent i
• Domestic price i
• Practical Examples of the Little-Mirrless Approach
Imported input
• For purposes of comparison, we shall use similar examples to
the ones used under the UNIDO approach. If the analyst
decides to use the border price approach to incorporating the
foreign exchange premium, a project's imported textile inputs
would be valued as shown in Table 5 below.
• All tariffs and taxes are deducted from the domestic retail
price but the foreign exchange component of the input is
valued at the official exchange rate, so that it is expressed in
border prices.
• Non-traded components such as transport and internal
handling and distribution, on the other hand, are valued in
border price equivalents using individual conversion factors.
Exported output
• As shown in Table 6 below, to value the exported garment
output of a project using the border price approach the
foreign exchange component is converted into local currency
using the official exchange rate and any export taxes and
subsidies are treated as transfers and are deducted.
• Once again, non-traded components will be valued in their
border price equivalents using their own conversion factors.
(iii) Non-traded input
• The valuation of non-traded electricity inputs using the L-M
approach is shown in Table 7 below. As in the example in
Table3, 60 per cent of the project's electricity requirements
will be met by new production and 40 per cent by displacing
existing consumers.
• The electricity is valued at its border price equivalent by
multiplying its corrected domestic prices, as calculated in
Table 3, by its commodity specific demand and supply price
conversion factors, CFdpi and CFspi.
• These conversion factors are the ratio of the economic price
(border price equivalent) to the financial (market price) of
electricity.
Non-traded output
• The method of valuing non-traded electricity output using
the border price approach is shown in Table 8.
• If all of the project's electricity output meets new demand, its
economic value is its domestic market demand price,
including any monopoly rents and sales taxes, multiplied by
the demand price conversion factor relevant to electricity
output.
• This CFdp for electricity has already been assumed to be 0.8.
CONCLUSIONS: Usage, Advantages and Disadvantages of the Two Approaches