Untitled
Untitled
Untitled
Kuznet’s Puzzle
Consumption is the sole end and purpose of all production —Adam Smith
Classical economist concern about the consumption but with respect to production and
growth
3 – conjectures
1. MPC
2. APC and MPC (APS & MPS)
3. MPC and Income and Interest rate
Consumption
1. MPC
Keynes conjectured that the marginal propensity to consume—the amount consumed out of an
additional dollar of income—is between zero and one
“Fundamental psychological law, upon which we are entitled to depend with great
confidence, . . . is that men are disposed, as a rule and on the average, to increase their
consumption as their income increases, but not by as much as the increase in their income.”
Consumption
Application of MPC
The reason is that, according to the consumption function C = C(Y - T), higher income causes higher consumption. When an
increase in government purchases raises income, it also raises consumption, which further raises income, which further raises
consumption, and so on
In this case, a $1.00 increase in government purchases raises equilibrium income by $2.50.
Consumption
Now consider how changes in taxes affect equilibrium income. A decrease in taxes of DT
immediately raises disposable income Y - T by DT and
therefore, increases consumption by MPC * DT
This expression is the tax multiplier, the amount income changes in response to a $1 change in
taxes. (The negative sign indicates that income moves in the opposite direction from taxes.)
For example, if the marginal propensity to consume is 0.6, then the tax multiplier is
DY/DT = -0.6/(1 - 0.6)
= (-1.5)
In this example, a $1.00 cut in taxes raises equilibrium income by $1.50
Consumption
1. MPC
Consumption
Average propensity to consume falls as income rises became a central part of early Keynesian
economics
3. Income is the primary determinant of consumption and that the interest rate does not have an
important role
The average propensity to save (APS) or the savings rate is the ratio of savings to disposable
income
Researchers found that higher-income households saved a larger fraction of their income
Consumption and income for the period between the two world wars-These data also
supported the Keynesian consumption function.
during the Great Depression, both consumption and saving were low, indicating that the marginal propensity to consume is between zero and one
In addition, during those years of low income, the ratio of consumption to income was high, confirming Keynes’s second conjecture.
Finally, because the correlation between income and consumption was so strong, no other variable appeared to be important for explaining
consumption
Consumption
Consumption Puzzle
Keynesian consumption function met with early successes: two anomalies soon arose
1. SECULAR STAGNATION: during World War II - low consumption would lead to an inadequate demand for goods and
services, resulting in a depression -World War II did not throw the country into another depression
Although incomes were much higher after the war than before, these higher incomes did not lead to large increases in the rate of
saving
Keynes’s conjecture that the average propensity to consume would fall as income rose appeared not to hold
2. KUZNETS PUZZLE: Kuznets constructed new aggregate data on consumption and income - Kuznets assembled these data in
the 1940s - the ratio of consumption to income was remarkably stable from decade to decade
Consumption
Secular-stagnation hypothesis and the findings of Kuznets both indicated that the average
propensity to consume is fairly constant over long periods of time
Economists wanted to know why some studies confirmed Keynes’s conjectures and others
refuted them
The short-run:
consumption function has a falling APC
The long-run:
consumption function has a constant APC
Consumption
Consumption Puzzle
Consumption
slope of a line and a “c" for its vertical intercept: y = C + cY We are given the coordinates of two points on this line, and so
To find the vertical intercept (autonomous Consumption), we simply write the equation of the line, substituting the
coordinates of either point for the x and y and substituting 0.6 for the slope, m.
C = C + cY
14 = C + 0.6 (20)
14 = 12 + C
C= 2
C = C + cY
26 = C + 0.6 (40)
26 = 24 + C
C= 2
Consumption
Consumption
6B. How much would people spend on consumption goods (C) even if their incomes (Y) fell temporarily to zero?
To find the vertical intercept, we simply write the equation, substituting the coordinates of either point for Y and C and
substituting 0.6 for the slope, b.
C = a + bY
21 = a + 0.6(20)
21 = a + 12
This is the level of consumer spending we would expect to see
a = 21 - 12
even if income has (temporarily) fallen to zero.
a=9
Equivalently: C = a + bY
33 = a + 0.6(40)
33 = a + 24
a = 33 - 24
Consumption
Consumption
A. Find the MPC for this economy and write the equation that describes consumption behavior.
The MPC is the Marginal Propensity to Consume, which is simply the slope of the consumption equation. To get the slope, we
need to find two points on the equation whose coordinates are known.
The intercept is one such point: Y = 0; C = 6.
The other point is the intersection of the consumption line with the 45-degree line: Y = 15; C = 15 (Remember that the 45-degree
line has a slope of 1.0, which means that, starting from the origin, the Y-distance and the C-distance to any point on that line are
are the same).
So, now we visualize a right triangle with one acute vertex touching the C-intercept and the other touching the intersection with
the 45-degree line. The vertical leg of the triangle, the RISE, is 15-6, or 9; The horizontal leg of the triangle, the RUN, is 15. The
SLOPE is the RISE over the RUN: 9/15 = 0.6.
Now we know both the vertical intercept (a = 6) and the slope (b = 0.6) and can write the equation describing consumption
behavior:
C = a + bY
C = 6 + 0.6Y
Consumption
7B. How much do people spend on consumption goods (C) when total income (Y) is 35?
This question calls your bluff: Show me you can actually make use of this equation relating C to Y. You can simply substitute 35 for
Y and solve for C:
C = 6 + 0.6Y
C = 6 + 0.6(35)
C = 6 + 21
C = 27
7C. How much do they save?
There are two ways to calculate the level of saving. The easiest is simply to recognize that saving is what's left of your income
after you're through spending. That is, S = Y - C; S = 35 - 27 = 8
Alternatively, you could write the saving equation by observing the general form: S = -a + (1 - b)Y, and then evaluating for an
income of Y = 35:
S = -a + (1 - b)Y
S = -6 + 0.4Y
S = -6 + 0.4(35)
S = -6 + 14
S= 8
Consumption
7D. How much would the investment community have to spend for the economy to be in equilibrium with Y = 35?
An income-expenditure equilibrium requires that income be equal to expenditures. For this wholly private economy, we can write
the equilibrium condition as Y = C + I. We know that for an income of 35, consumption spending is 27. So we can write: 35 = 27 +
I. Therefore I = 35 - 27 = 8.
Alternatively, we can recognize that for a wholly private economy, it is always true that Y = C + S. That is, your income has to be
equal to the part of it that you spend plus the part of it that you don't spend. We can now write the equilibrium condition as C + S
= C + I. Subtracting consumption spending from both sides gives us the alternative equilibrium condition for a wholly private
economy: S = I. This means that if S = 8, then that amount needs to be borrowed and spent by the investment community for the
economy to be in macroeconomic equilibrium.
(By the way, if we were dealing with a mixed economy, we would write as our accounting identity: Y = C + S + T. That is, your
income has to be equal to the part of it that you spend plus the part of it that you don't spend plus the part that you don't even
see--because the government took it as taxes before you were given your (after-tax) income. In this case, the alternative
equilibrium would be S + T = I + G.)
Consumption
when disposable incomes increase (decrease), this is accompanied by an increase (decrease) in consumption
1986–1987: increase in the percentage change in disposable incomes- the percentage change in consumption declined.
1993–1994 and 1995–1996, despite a drop in disposable income -Consumption actually increased
Consumption they enjoy today- the less they will be able to enjoy tomorrow: tradeoff
Irving Fisher: analyze how rational, forward-looking consumers make intertemporal choices,
Fisher’s model illuminates the constraints consumers face, the preferences they have, and
how these constraints and preferences together determine their choices about consumption
and saving
Consumption
Consumption smoothing theory is not a behavioral theory but a preference maximization theory
where individuals are forward looking
Intertemporal analysis is about the trade-offs when the present choices affect the alternatives
available in the future
Consumption
1. Intertemporal Constraints
Intertemporal approach focus on how do rational consumer distribute their consumption over
time
Assumes: there are only two time period current and future
• It’s downward sloping. Its slope is −(1 + r1), because if you sacrifice one unit of consumption today and put it in the
bank for one period, you get 1+r1 units next period.
• The set of feasible consumption paths (C1,C2) are those inside or at the borders of the triangle formed by the
vertical axis, the horizontal axis, and the intertemporal budget constraint. Points D, E, and F are all feasible
consumption paths.
• What feasible point the household will choose depends on its preferences
If Consumer spend part of his income, and save some amount for future consumption,
When, C1 < Y1 and saving is Y1 – C1 then earning on that saving would be (1 + r) (Y1 – C1)
= Y1 – C1 +
C1 +
If there are only two time period then present value of life-cycle consumption = present value of life income
If money is spend rather than to save then opportunity cost of interest will forgone
Given the intertemporal Budget Constrain, consumer needs to maximize consumption utility
Utility function is used to know the preferences over current and future prefaces, which can be represent by
Indifference Curve
Consumption
Consumer Preference
C2
Indifference Curve depicts preferences of an individual for consumption
today versus consumption tomorrows
The indifference cure that are more to north east represent higher utility Satisfaction
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=iOmDo5jLFw8
Consumption
δ = Discount rate at which an individual values future consumption relative to current consumption , Assumed δ > 0
For an individual on same indifference curve, value of the gain in utility from the increased future consumption must exactly
offset the loss in the utility from reduction in present consumption: MU C2 = MUc1 (
-= (1 + δ ) =MRTP
Marginal rate of time preference measures rate of time preference for present consumption versus future consumption
If | / | > 1 at point B – Positive time Preference – more unit of consumption in future ( son of business tycoon)
If | / | < 1 at point B –Negative time Preference –Less unit of consumption in future (farmer having bumper crop this year)
If | / | = 1 at point B – Neutral time Preference – Trade off between present and future consumption (ratio is 1:1)
Consumption
Optimization
MRS = 1 + r
Consumption
increase in the real interest rate rotates the consumer’s budget line around the point (Y1, Y2) alters
the amount of consumption he chooses in both periods
impact of an increase in the real interest rate on consumption into two effects:
1. Income effect
2. Substitution effect
Consumption
Constraints on Borrowing
Fisher’s model assumes that the consumer can borrow as well as save
The ability to borrow allows current consumption to exceed current income: consumes some of
his future income today
In a series of papers written in the 1950s, Franco Modigliani, Albert Ando and Richard Brumberg
Modigliani emphasized that income varies systematically over people’s lives and that saving
allows consumers to move income from those times in life when income is high to those times
when it is low.
This interpretation of consumer behavior formed the basis for his life-cycle hypothesis
Consumption
The Hypothesis
What level of consumption will the consumer choose if he wishes to maintain a smooth level of
consumption over the course of his life?
Consumption
C = (W + RY)/T
if the consumer expects to live for 50 more years and work for 30 of them, then
T = 50 and R = 30, so his consumption function is
C = 0.02W + 0.6Y
consumption depends on both income and wealth. An extra $1 of income per year raises
consumption by $0.60 per year, and an extra $1 of wealth raises consumption by $0.02 per year
C = aW + bY, where the parameter a is the marginal propensity to consume out of wealth, and
the parameter b is the marginal propensity to consume out of income.
Consumption
Implications
C/Y = a(W/Y) + b.
Consumption
In the long run, as wealth increases, the consumption function shifts upward, This upward shift
prevents the average propensity to consume from falling as income increases. In this way,
Modigliani resolved the consumption puzzle posed by Simon Kuznets’s data
Consumption
the permanent-income hypothesis emphasizes that people experience random and temporary
changes in their incomes from year to year
Consumption
The Hypothesis
Implications
According to the permanent-income hypothesis, consumption depends on permanent income YP
Many studies of the consumption function try to relate consumption to current income Y
what Friedman’s hypothesis implies for the average propensity to consume. Divide both sides of
Consumption function by Y to obtain APC = C/Y = aYP /Y
When current income temporarily rises above permanent income, the average propensity to
consume temporarily falls; when current income temporarily falls below permanent income, the
average propensity to consume temporarily rises
Consumption
3 Case Studies
The permanent-income hypothesis can help us interpret how the economy responds to
changes in fiscal policy
The tax surcharge did not seem to have the desired effect of reducing aggregate demand.
Unemployment continued to fall, and inflation continued to rise
Consumption
3. The Tax Rebates of 2008
Severe financial crisis in 2008, the economy was heading into a recession
To counteract the recessionary forces, Congress passed the Economic Stimulus Act, which provided
$100 billion of one-time tax rebates to households
Single individuals received $300 to $600, couples received $600 to $1,200, and families with children
received an additional $300 per child
Most important, because sending out many millions of checks was a long process, consumers received
their tax rebates at different times
The timing of receipt was based on the last two digits of the individual’s Social Security number,
which is essentially random.
By comparing the spending behavior of consumers who received early payments to the behavior of
those who received later payments, researchers could use this random variation to estimate the effect
of a transitory tax cut
Consumption
The Tax Rebates of 2008
Therefore, transitory changes in taxes should have only a negligible effect on consumption
and aggregate demand
Consumption
The permanent-income hypothesis highlights the idea that consumption depends on people’s
expectations
The rational-expectations assumption states that people use all available information to make
optimal forecasts about the future
Consumption
Random-Walk Hypothesis
The economist Robert Hall was the first to derive the implications of rational expectations for
consumption
When changes in a variable are unpredictable, the variable is said to follow a random walk.
Implications
If consumers obey the permanent-income hypothesis and have rational expectations, then only
unexpected policy changes influence consumption. These policy changes take effect when they
change expectations
Consumption
David Laibson: the Pull of Instant Gratification
Harvard professor David Laibson: behavioral economics, real human beings whose behavior can
be far from rational
Raises the possibility that consumers’ preferences may be time-inconsistent: they may alter their
decisions simply because time passes, gratification may induce him to change his mind
Consumption
Question
Gabe and Gita both obey the two-period Fisher model of consumption. Gabe earns $100 in the
first period and $100 in the second period. Gita earns nothing in the first period and $210 in the
second period. Both of them can borrow or lend at the interest rate r.
You observe both Gabe and Gita consuming $100 in the first period and $100 in the second
period. What is the interest rate r
Consumption
Questions
Consumption
Questions
Suppose the interest rate increases. What will happen to Gabe’s consumption in the first
period?
Is Gabe better off or worse off than before the interest rate rise? (show it diagrammatically)
Consumption
Questions
Consumption
Questions
What will happen to Gita’s consumption in the first period when the interest rate increases?
Is Gita better off or worse off than before the interest rate increase?
Consumption
Consumption
Questions
The chapter uses the Fisher model to discuss a change in the interest rate for a consumer who
saves some of his first-period income. Suppose, instead, that the consumer is a borrower. How
does that alter the analysis? Discuss the income and substitution effects on consumption in both
periods
Consumption
Questions
The increase in the real interest rate causes the budget line to
rotate around the point (Y1, Y2)
Questions
The chapter analyzes Fisher’s model for the case in which the consumer can save or borrow at an
interest rate of r and for the case in which the consumer can save at this rate but cannot borrow
at all.
Consider now the intermediate case in which the consumer can save at rate rs and borrow at rate
rb, where rs < rb
On a single graph, show the two budget constraints from parts (a) and (b). Shade the area that
represents the combination of first period and second-period consumption the consumer can
choose
Consumption
Questions
Consumption
Questions
Now add to your graph the consumer’s indifference curves. Show three possible outcomes:
1. one in which the consumer saves
2. one in which he borrows
3. one in which he neither saves nor borrows
Consumption
Questions
Consumption
Questions
Explain whether borrowing constraints increase or decrease the potency of fiscal policy to
influence aggregate demand in each of the following cases.
a. A temporary tax cut
b. An announced future tax cut
Consumption
Questions
The potency of fiscal policy to influence aggregate demand depends on the effect on
consumption:
If consumption changes a lot, then fiscal policy will have a large multiplier.
If consumption changes only a little, then fiscal policy will have a small multiplier.
That is, the fiscal-policy multipliers are higher if the marginal propensity to consume is higher
Consumption
Questions
Consider a two-period Fisher diagram. A temporary tax cut means an increase in first-period disposable income Y1
. Figure 16–8(A) shows the effect of this tax cut on a consumer who does not face a binding borrowing constraint, whereas Figure
16–8(B) shows the effect of this tax cut on a consumer who is constrained
Consumption
Questions
Questions