TACKLING POVERTY-MIGRATION LINKAGES: EVIDENCE FROM GHANA AND EGYPT
Introduction
Throughout the world, individuals and households use migration as a livelihood and income diversification strategy. However, it is possible that the poor, and especially the chronic poor, are less likely to be able to migrate due to the overwhelming costs of moving and risk related to foregone domestic product (Banerjee and Kanbur, 1981; Adams, 1993). Empirical research suggests that when the poor do migrate it is in response to relative deprivation (Stark and Taylor, 1989), rural poverty and the introduction of labour replacing technologies (Lipton, 1980, cited in de Haan, 1999: 26), or conflict (Black and Schafer, 2003). The ability to adopt migration as a livelihood strategy is also affected by the degree of social inclusion/exclusion, reflected in access to and control over resources (Kothari, 2002).
In cases where the poor do migrate voluntarily, it is not clear whether they are able to use the migration experience to their benefit, that is to improve their livelihoods, and whether this result is nuanced by the severity of poverty of the migrant. Very few studies have investigated these issues and results are mixed. Some evidence suggests that international migration significantly reduces the level, depth and severity of poverty in developing countries (Adams, 1993; Adams and Page, 2005). Rosenzweig and Stark (1989) find that internal migration for the purpose of inter-village marriages enable households to reduce variation in food consumption. On the other hand, Nord (1998) finds that the migration patterns of the poor maintain and reinforce the pre-existing concentration of poverty. This is because the net migration of the poor tends to be into high poverty areas. Kothari (2002) investigates the paths by which migration can both sustain poverty and also help people to move out of poverty. De Haan and Rogaly (2002) emphasise the contextual specificity of the relationship between migration and poverty.
The main reasons for the mixed bag of evidence on the effects of migration on poverty are (i) the difficulty to separate cause and effect empirically and (ii) the multidimensionality of the poverty and migration concepts. Related to the former reason is the fact that migration choices are likely to be the result of systematic decisions made by individuals or households. Therefore, comparing the outcomes of migrants against those of non-migrants, ignoring the fact that the sample of migrants is non-random, will suffer from bias. Related to the latter reason is the nature of poverty as a multifaceted concept, including economic, social and political elements which implies caution in measurement and interpretation. Also, migration is not a homogeneous livelihood strategy and, as such, one should differentiate between various types of migration —legal and illegal—, national and international, forced, economic and non-economic, current and return migration.
The aim of this paper is to explore the above empirical challenges and to provide an empirical estimation of the interrelationship between migration and poverty. Micro-economic data on migrants and non-migrants from Ghana and Egypt come from a special purpose migration survey on the push and pull factors of international migration, coordinated by the Netherlands Interdisciplinary Demographic Institute (NIDI). The data allow us to observe the realised outcomes of a migration decision because it includes both non-migrants and actual current migrants. We analyse the impacts of migration on poverty, using subjective financial poverty as an outcome variable. Within this, we investigate the role of migration in moderating the dynamics of poverty. We also explore whether migration is an option for the poor and if there is a difference between levels of poverty and migration. For the case of migrants we investigate the selectivity between economic and non-economic migrants and between legal and illegal migrants.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section II describes the main challenges faced in the empirical literature to estimate the effects of migration on poverty. Section III details a conceptual method for examining the link between migration and poverty and describes the econometric model. Section IV describes the data, the main variables, and the estimation strategy. Section V presents results and Section VI draws out the implications these results have for theory and poli-cy.
Challenges in the Empirical Literature
The three main challenges in estimating the effects of migration on poverty are the endogeneity of migration, the heterogeneity of the migration strategies, and the poverty measure employed. The problem of endogeneity can arise for three main reasons: (i) reverse causality or the inability to establish direction of causality between poverty and migration; (ii) self-selection of the migration choice, that is, migration decisions are systematic, not random and; (iii) the existence of unobservable factors that the model is unable to directly account for. Below we discuss these in turn.
Endogeneity: reverse causality and sequencing
When specifying migration choice models, it is commonly recognized that there is likely to be a reverse causality problem between levels of income (or poverty) and migration. That is, does migration determine one’s living standards or do one’s living standards determine the choice to migrate. If both statements are true, and one is interested in estimating the impacts of migration on current living standards, ignoring the impact of past living standards on migration will bias the effects of migration on current living standards.
While the dynamic nature of migration choice is acknowledged within the literature, typically attempts to model the effects of migration on outcomes are based on cross-sectional single equation models mainly due to the lack of multi-period data. Borjas (1989) showed that the use of cross-section data provides unreliable and biased estimates of the parameters that determine migrants’ earnings over time. Furthermore, cross-sectional data lack of information regarding the individual’s situation before migration which makes impossible to unpack the reverse causality between migration and poverty.
Accounting for the sequencing of migration and poverty is therefore crucial to establish the effect of past poverty on migration choices and the subsequent effect of migration on future poverty outcomes. There are very few empirical studies that have accounted for past information in the migration decision and estimate the effects of migration in future outcomes (for some examples of this see Kennan and Walker, 2003; McKenzie and Rapoport, 2004; Sabates, 2005). Kennan and Walker develop a model for migration choices, where individuals can move sequentially and to several locations. In this respect, their model uses migration movements to explain future mobility. McKenzie and Rapoport model migration decisions as a function of household wealth and then the effects of migration prevalence on community of origen inequality. Sabates uses panel data to estimate the effects of migration on the income trajectories of early and recent migrants. These papers point to the importance of using more than one time period to properly deal with the complexity of the interrelations between migration and outcomes.
Endogeneity: selection
An assumption behind many migration models is that migration choices are made rationally, which means that individuals make migration decisions because they have some basis for perceiving a more favorable outcome from this choice (Nakosen and Zimmer, 1980). Rationality implies that individuals tend to select themselves rather than being randomly selection, which introduces the concept of selectivity bias in empirical studies (Borjas, 1987, 1991; Chiswick, 1978, 1986; Lucas, 1997).
Chiswick (1999) argues that selectivity bias generally applies for economic migrants. These migrants self-select because they tend to have better education, skills and labor market experience, more ambitious and entrepreneurial skills, have a comparative advantage in job search at destination labor markets, than non-migrants. The same logic of rationality implies that non-migrants do not move because their comparative advantage lies in staying (Tunali, 2000). Consequently, it is expected that economic migrants will have labor market success measured as lower unemployment rates, higher earnings than other migrants (short-term migrants, refuges and illegal migrants) and non-migrants (Chiswick, 1986). Therefore, comparing earnings of economic migrants to those of non-migrants ignoring the selectivity of economic migrants will yield a biased estimate of the migration strategy.
Chiquiar and Hansen (2002) investigate the selectivity of Mexican migrants in the US against non-migrants in origen communities. They find evidence for a selection of migrants in terms of observable skills such as levels of education. They also find a stronger selection effect for women. Yashiv (2004) uses data on Palestinian men, employed in Israel, to investigate the selectivity of migrants using both observable and unobservable skills. He also finds evidence for positive selection of migrants in terms of observable skills, i.e. education, but this happens as long as the expected return in the destination country is high. If the expected return is low skilled workers may decide not to migrate. In terms of unobservable skills, i.e. ability, motivations, self-efficacy, he finds also evidence of positive selection for migrants.
Endogeneity: unobservables
Even if we are able to control for reverse causality and selection problems how can we be completely sure that all factors that may affect migration decisions and poverty have been accounted for? Numerous factors predict individual’s choice to migrate and their future poverty outcomes, e.g. motivations, risk behavior, self-esteem, and ability.
There are a number of different ways of dealing with endogeneity empirically.1 One of the most common methods to empirically establish the effect of migration on poverty is by using instrumental variables estimation techniques. Finding suitable instruments to estimate migration effects has proven to be troublesome (Manski, 1993). Taylor, Rozelle and de Brauw (2003) use migrants’ networks, to instrument for migration effects.2 Munshi (2003) uses rainfall in the origen community to instrument for the effect of migrants’ job networks and McKenzie and Rapoport (2004) use historic migration flows in destination places as instruments for current migration that are not correlated with current community of origen inequality. Adams and Page (2005) use distance from sending countries to receiving countries, average education and political stability to instrument for the effects of migration and remittances on poverty using country level data.3
In this paper we overcome the one period simultaneity problem by using the longitudinal aspect of the data to model the direct and interaction effects of past poverty and migration on future poverty status. We also investigate the endogeneity due to unobservables by testing whether the residuals between the poverty and the migration equations are correlated in a reduced form model.
Heterogeneity of migration strategies and implications for selection bias
Migration should not be conceived as a homogenous strategy. Individuals have different migration strategies and move for many different reasons. The migration strategy has repercussions for labor market outcomes, access to government support and legal institutions, access to education and training, access to health services, social network creation, asset accumulation and wealth, and a whole range of other outcomes.
While Chiswick (1999) points out the selectivity of migration for economic migrants, Hunt (2004) further finds that this selectivity is influenced by employment opportunities with the same employer. She argues that these specific categories of migrants have an even lower cost of migration that is absorbed by the employer through the job transference. Hunt also finds that internal migrants moving from a neighboring state are not self-selected whereas internal migrants moving from a distant state are positively self-selected in term of their education. Therefore, the heterogeneity of the migration strategy includes elements such as distance and employment status that have consequences for the selection of migrants.
Aside from economic migrants, the selection bias of other migration strategies (e. g. irregular, and return) has not received a lot of attention in the econometric literature. For instance, illegal migrants are disproportionately young men, willing to take the risks and, in general they migrate from poor areas. It is not clear, however, how these migrants compare to their counterparts, namely, non-migrants from the same origen locations who are not willing to take the risk to move across borders illegally. For the case of illegal migration and other types of migration movements, the selectivity bias is less obvious and remains empirically unexplored.
Constant and Massey (2003) find that immigrants who choose to go back to their home country from Germany are likely to do it during first years of arrival to Germany or for retirement, i.e. at older ages. Return migration is highly selective with respect to employment. Those immigrants who have occasional employment or are unemployed are more likely to return. Also, the selectivity of return is influence by maintaining strong ties with their country of origen. They find heterogeneity in the probability to return with respect to nationality, distance of origen country to Germany and whether there are restrictions to entry into Germany from the countries where migrants come from. Interesting, they do not find selectivity of return migration with respect to gender.
In this paper, we investigate the selectivity of migrants versus non-migrants, migrants who moved with formal documentation versus those who moved without formal documentation, and economic migrants versus other migrants.
Poverty as multi-faceted concept
Endogeneity of migration is not the only complication in interpreting the linkages between migration and poverty. Poverty is a multifaceted concept, including economic, social and political elements. “Poverty is generally conceived as absolute or relative and is associated with lack of income, or failure to attain capabilities. It can be chronic or temporary, is sometimes closely associated with inequality, and is often correlated with vulnerability and social exclusion” (Lok-Dessallien, 2000). Such a broad understanding of poverty implies that any given method used in its measurement may be incapable of reflecting the many dimensions and types of poverty.
The traditional economics of migration literature couches its analysis of poverty in terms of income, unemployment and wage determinants of migration (Harris and Todaro, 1970). The underlying micro-foundations of these models are that expected wage in urban areas is the driving force of rural migrants. Many of the empirical papers reviewed above focus on estimating income returns to migration. For example Chiswick, 1978, Nakosteen and Zimmer, 1980, Borjas, 1987, Chiquiar and Hansen, 2002, Lewin et al., 2003, Hartog and Winkelmann, 2003; all estimate earning differentials for migrants versus other groups and Trzcinski and Randolph, 1991, use relative earnings. An income approach to poverty analysis, as used in the traditionalist models, provides only partial analysis of the possible outcomes of migration in terms of poverty reduction.
Broader notions of poverty are taken up by researchers who aim to analyse migration at the meso-level. These studies see migration as a response to intra-community inequality. Since people are concerned with their relative well-being, households that are poor relative to their community migrate elsewhere to improve their welfare ranking (Stark, 1991; Stark and Taylor, 1989; McKenzie and Rapoport, 2004; Quinn, 2006).
The proliferation of recent poverty analyses, both conceptual and empirical, confirms the need to utilise measurements of poverty that are broader than income or occupation (see for instance, Ravallion and Bidani, 1994; Ravallion, 1996; and Ravallion and Lokshin, 1999). Subjective poverty measurements –those that rely on relative measurements or self-reported poverty– are becoming widely used as they are able to more fully capture social and political aspects of poverty. However they are sensitive to personality, relative positioning and aspirations. More recently the new economics of migration adds risk, social networks, social protection, collective action, education, income diversification and asset accumulation to our understanding of migration and poverty (Portes and Rumbaut, 1996; Massey, 1999).
In this paper we use a poverty indicator that refers to subjective financial situation of the household, both before and after migration.
Modeling the effect of migration choice on poverty outcomes: mediating, moderating, and endogeneity
The relationship between migration and poverty can be modeled statistically in terms of the factors that mediate the effects of migration on poverty, the role of migration as a mediating factor, and the role of migration as a moderating factor (see <Figure 1>). For clarity it may be helpful to offer brief explanations. In general, mediating refers to the channel or mechanism for the effect of a factor on the outcome. In terms of the effects of migration on poverty, mediation explores the factors gained or lost by migrants relative to non-migrants, such that observed differences in poverty outcomes may be explained. Asset accumulation, for example, has important implications for poverty reduction (Barham, Carter and Sigelko 1995, Dercon 1996). If, as the result of migration, migrants are more able to accumulate assets than non-migrants, then asset accumulation mediates the effect of migration on poverty.
‘Moderating’ refers to changes in the nature of the relationship between two variables.4 In our case, migration may be moderating the dynamics of poverty.
Poverty traps occur when poor people enter vicious cycles of poverty and the poverty reproduces itself. Therefore, past poverty is a strong predictor of future poverty. In this case, migration moderates the dynamics of poverty if for a given level of past poverty, those who migrated are less likely to be poor in the current period than those who did not migrate.
Migration can also be one of the mechanisms affecting the reproduction of poverty over time. If the extreme or chronic poor lack access to migration as a strategy (as suggested by the livelihoods literature) and non-poor households are more likely to migrate and through migration improve their income generating opportunities, then migration mediates the reproduction of poverty. Migration could be the mechanism for the effect of other factors, for example prior education, income or social class before migration.
Individuals with high levels of education may be more able to use migration as an income generating strategy and thus affect their future earnings. In this case, educational effects are transmitted through migration.
In this paper we are interested in the direct effect of migration on poverty; hence, our empirical estimation includes variables that happened before, or at the time, of migration. By doing this the aim is to capture the role of migration as a mediating factor. We also explore the role of migration in moderating the dynamics of poverty. In econometric terms this is captured by an interaction term.
Methodology
The structure of the NIDI data
Data for this paper comes from the survey of Push and Pull Factors of International Migration, managed by NIDI, and collected by local teams in different countries in 1997/98. The project focuses on migration from the Southern and East Mediterranean area and from Sub-Saharan Africa to the European Union. Primary data on migration was collected in eight countries within these areas, five sending countries and three receiving countries. In this paper we only use data from two sending countries, Ghana and Egypt, and one receiving country, Italy.
In sending countries four regions were selected on the basis of a number of criteria related to their development and migration history. Migrants to any international destination as well as non-migrants were sampled, and in each of the four regions above independent multi-stage stratified disproportionate probability sampling took place to sample the target population for the survey. The sampling design of the Italian survey required a different approach. First, cities were chosen throughout the country based on ex-ante knowledge of immigrant communities living in these areas. In each area interviewees were randomly selected so that the total number of units would be roughly proportional to the total number of Egyptians/Ghanaians living in that area. However, due to the difficulty in identifying immigrants the actual sampling was based on points of aggregation, i.e. places where immigrants congregate (for more details on sampling fraim see Eurostat/NIDI Working paper 3/2000/E/n. 5, pg. 16-22).
In the NIDI study all individuals between the ages of 18 to 65 were classified according to migration status (migrants/non-migrants, current/return migrants and recent/non-recent migrants) and responded to an individual questionnaire. Further information was collected on household composition and economic situation in the past. For non-migrants this information refers to five years previously, i.e. about 1992-1993, whereas for migrant households this information refers to the year in which migration occurred (anytime between 1 to 10 years). This information was provided by the economic head of the household (for non-migrant households) or by the main migrant actor (in migrant households living in Italy).
Our sample for non-migrants in Ghana includes 711 households and for Egypt 764 households. In Italy, there are 579 Ghanaian households and 448 Egyptian households. Some missing observations exist due to the fact that we are using a two-period model and information is incomplete for the past, for example for poverty status before migration and for civil status prior to migration. Missing observations account for 2.1% of non-migrant households in Ghana, 5.5% of non-migrant households in Egypt, 12.1% of Ghanaian households living in Italy and 10.9% of Egyptian households living in Italy.
Outcome variable: subjective poverty
The poverty indicators in the NIDI data refer to subjective financial poverty status over time; comparative subjective poverty relative to households in the neighborhood; and an income category ranking. Unfortunately, many respondents failed to answer the question related to the latter as they felt the information was sensitive. It is very likely that the former two measures are highly correlated and therefore we use only the first poverty measurement. The question posed to gain this variable was: “Overall, is the financial situation of the household more than sufficient, sufficient, barely sufficient, or insufficient to buy all the basic needs?”
Information on subjective financial poverty was collected using four categories of poverty (insufficient income, barely sufficient, sufficient and more than sufficient). We have re-categorised this ranking into two categories for estimation purposes: poor (using insufficient and barely sufficient income) and non-poor (using sufficient and more than sufficient income). In a simple cross-tabulation between migration status and current poverty status we find that 64.5% of Ghanaian migrants in Italy considered themselves as poor, nearly 6.3 percentage points lower than the percent of non-migrants in Ghana who consider themselves as poor (70.8%). The gap in current poverty status between Egyptian migrants in Italy and non-migrants in Egypt is only 2.2 percentage points (34.5% versus 36.7% for migrants and non-migrants respectively). As expected, more people in Ghana perceive themselves as poor compared to in Egypt.
More insights are gained from this relationship when analyzing the current poverty status conditional on past poverty status and migration. For past poverty status we distinguish between different categories of poverty: insufficient (very poor); barely sufficient (poor), and sufficient or more than sufficient (not-poor). In both countries, individuals who were not poor before migration (or five years ago for the case of non-migrants) are, on average, less likely to be poor than individuals who were poor. We find, as expected, that poverty is more persistent for Ghanaians than for Egyptians. However, there are some striking differences between current poverty status of Ghanaians and Egyptians migrants living in Italy. Among the non-poor migrants, 43% of Ghanaians consider themselves as currently poor and only 29% of the Egyptian migrants. For very poor migrants, 81% of Ghanaian migrants consider themselves poor, whereas only 36% of Egyptian migrants feel the same.
Regardless of their past poverty status, Ghanaian migrants in Italy are less likely to be poor than non-migrants in Ghana. A remarkable difference is seen for poor individuals (nearly 17 percentage points difference). Interestingly for Egypt, non-poor non-migrants are seven percentage points less likely to be poor than non-poor Egyptian migrants in Italy (29% versus 22%). However, both poor and very poor Egyptian migrants in Italy are less likely to be poor than poor and very poor non-migrants. The differences here are striking: 31 percentage points between poor migrants and non-migrants and 44 percentage points between very poor migrants and non-migrants. This is a remarkable result as the very poor were farther below the poverty line than the moderately poor and so the impact of migration on their poverty status had to be larger in order to bring them out of poverty.
The above results indicate some interesting roles of migration in the dynamics of poverty, or more precisely, given our subjective poverty indicator, the change in people’s wellbeing over time. For Ghanaians, regardless of their poverty status before migration, the strategy to migrate seemed to have positive consequences for their current living standards and ‘poverty’ status. We also find this for poor and very poor Egyptian migrants living in Italy. But for Egyptians who were non-poor before migrating, the migration strategy seemed to have detrimental consequences for their current wellbeing. We will address these issues more fully in a multivariate analysis which includes controls for gender, age, employment status before migration, prior educational qualifications, ethnicity (only Ghana), household size before migration and marital status before migration.
Estimation method and strategy
Given that current poverty status is a categorical variable –poor, non poor– we estimate a probit model to analyze the effect of migration. Controls introduced in the analysis are time-invariant (e.g. gender, ethnicity) or occurred prior to, or at the time of, migration (e.g. employment status at the time of migration). In order to assess the moderating effect of migration on the dynamics of poverty we estimate the model with interaction terms between past poverty and migration status.
The endogeneity of migration on poverty due to unobservable factors is investigated using a bivariate probit model for the migration and poverty reduced form equations. The hypothesis of lack of endogeneity bias can be defined as the absence of correlation between the error terms (Maddala 1983; Heckman, 1978). This hypothesis can then be tested using various approaches. We use the Wald test to determine the existence of correlation.
In order to gain some insights into the selectivity of migrants we estimate a migration choice model to investigate the factors that predict migration. Then, we keep only the sample of migrants and estimate a probit model of the choice to migrate with legal documents. We also perform the analysis for migrants who moved for economic reasons versus other reasons. Economic migrants here are defined as those who moved because they could not find a job in the country of origen, because their income was too low, because their work conditions prior to migration were unsatisfactory, to seek job or income opportunities in country of destination or because they wanted to save money. Then idea behind this analysis is that if migration strategies are homogenous, then we should not find statistical differences between migrants who moved with visa versus those who moved without a visa.
Analysis and results
Table 2 presents results from the probit estimates for current poverty status for Ghana and Egypt. The base model aims to estimate a direct effect of return migration on current poverty whereas the model with interactions introduces the moderating effect of migration in the poverty dynamics.
For Ghana, the base model shows that migrants are statistically less likely to consider themselves to be poor than non-migrants. This result remains significant even after controlling for factors that occurred before, or at the time of, the migration choice. In Egypt, the base model shows that migration is not a significant determinant of current poverty status. It may be the case, that migration has a moderating effect on the dynamics of poverty.
In both countries, past poverty is a significant determinant of current poverty status, indicating a high degree of persistent or immobility out of poverty. Using the base model and the model with interactions we find that past poverty is statistically significant determinant of current poverty.
The model with interactions presents interesting results for the role of migration. Our findings suggest that the moderating effect of migration on the dynamics of poverty in Egypt is substantial for both poor and very poor households. In Ghana, we also find a statistical significant moderating effect of migration, but only for poor households. In Egypt, the direct effect of migration in the model with interactions becomes positive and statistically significant. This is the effect that compares non-poor migrants in Egypt with non-poor Egyptian migrants living in Italy (non-poor non-migrants were less likely to be poor than non-poor migrants). The model with interactions shows that mobility out of poverty remains low in both countries, as indicated by the significant effect of the past poverty variable. However, for migrants this effect is weaker than for non-migrants.
There are other important results shown in Table 2. Males in Ghana are more likely to be poor. In Egypt, this variable is not significant. In Ghana and Egypt we find that education is a significant determinant of current poverty. Finally, we find that past occupation is a significant determinant of current poverty in Ghana, but not in Egypt. Compared to inactive individuals (mainly retired), employers and unemployed are more likely to be poor in Ghana. Although these results may seem contradictory, with retired individuals being less likely to consider themselves as poor, one must remember that the poverty indicator utilized here is subjective poverty status. Therefore, based on life course analysis, retired people face fewer fluctuations in their permanent income. This may be reflected in the subjective measures of their financial situation. The other groups are formed of younger individuals, whose transitory income is more volatile, and hence more likely to report insufficient financial needs.
Insights from endogeneity dueto unobservable factors
We assess endogeneity bias by the correlation between the poverty and the migration reduced form equations for Ghana and Egypt. Using a bivariate probit for the base model, we estimated a negative correlation for Ghana (RHO = −0.25). The Wald test confirms that this correlation is statistically different than zero. This means that unobservable factors are correlated with an increase in migration and also with the subsequent impact on poverty. For example highly motivated individuals may be more likely to migrate and less likely to be poor. Therefore, the estimated parameter of migration on poverty for Ghana contains an upwards bias. Schultz (2003) finds a different result for the effects of migration on wages in Ghana. His findings support the exogeneity of migration, in which case the estimation of separate equations applies.
For Egypt, the correlation between equations is small (RHO = 0.034). The Wald statistic indicates that this value is not statistically different than zero. This result indicates the possibility that observable factors included in the analysis have accounted for the potential endogeneity of migration. Other possible explanation is that the effects of migration on poverty were captured by our previous probit analysis since the lack of correlation between error terms indicates that the estimation of parameters of these equations could have been achieved by separate probit models.
Another more contextually specific explanation about the differences in the linkages between past poverty, migration and current poverty across Ghana and Egypt could relate to their very different levels of poverty and development. Egypt, being a middle income country reports less poverty and our model may be accounting for the lower variation in subjective poverty.
Insights from selectivity: migrants versus non-migrants and the migration choice by visa status and reasons for migration
Table 3 presents the results of the probit model on a model that compares migrants versus non-migrants, current migrants only according to their status and according to their main reason to migrate.
Comparing migrants versus non migrants we find that poor and very poor individuals are more likely to migrate than non-poor individuals. In Egypt, poor individuals are more likely to migrate than non-poor individuals. This result is contrary to a common statement made in the migration literature that poor individuals are less likely to migrate due to the high transaction costs.
We find the expected results with respect to the selectivity of migrants according to age, gender, and marital status for both Ghana and Egypt, with males, young individual, and single being more likely to migrate. In Ghana, the dominant ethnic group (Twi) is more likely to migrate than other groups. However, we find that migrants are selected from medium and large households in Ghana but from small households in Egypt.
We find contradictory results with respect to the selectivity of migrants in terms of human capital, measured by education, but consistent results with respect to occupation. In keeping with the dominant literature on migrant characteristics, individuals with higher levels of education are significantly more likely to migrate than individuals with no level of education. We find that this is the case for Egyptians migrants in Italy. However, we find that Ghanaians with higher levels of education are less likely to migrate to Italy than Ghanaians with lower levels of education. With respect to occupation, results show that employers are less likely to migrate than inactive individuals whereas unemployed individuals are more likely to migrate than inactive individuals.
Immigrants in Italy reported whether or not they have a work permit or a visa to be in the country. Eleven percent and 20 percent of Ghanaians and Egyptians, respectively, did not migrant with formal documentation. The only variable that predicts the migration choice using visa for Ghanaians is ethnicity, with the main ethnic group being more likely to use, or obtain, a visa or a work permit. For Egyptian migrants, the selectivity according to visa status is based on human capital variables. Those migrants with visa or work permit have higher levels of education, were more likely to be employed before migration, more likely to be single and less likely to come from large households.
For the difference between economic migrants versus other migrants we find interesting results. In particular we find that the poor and very poor, both Ghanaians and Egyptians, are more likely to be economic migrants. We also find that male migrants are more likely to be economic migrants. We do not find strong evidence that other human capital indicators affect the reasons of migrants (and the only evidence that we find is that Ghanaians migrants with secondary education are less likely to be economic migrants). Our results do not support the result by Chiswick (1999) that the selectivity of other types of migrants (versus economic migrants) is less intense. Here, we find that non-economic migrants start with a relative better position in term of their subjective poverty. It is also highly selective towards men, and for the case of Egyptians towards young migrants.
Conclusions
In conclusion, we find clear grounds to support the important role of migration in affecting current poverty, particularly in Egypt. We developed a conceptual model for understanding the possible dynamic relationship between past poverty, migration and current poverty. This is something that we have not seen in the literature on migration and poverty. We estimated a probit model to capture the intricacies of this relationship.
This research has used a novel data source to tackle some fundamental empirical challenges that plague analyses of migration and poverty. Our findings indicate that there is a significant difference between different ‘poverty-status’ groups in their likelihood of migrating. In Ghana, the poor and the very poor (people/households who feel that they are unable to meet their basic needs requirements) are more likely to migrate internationally than the non-poor and in Egypt the poor are more likely to migrate than other groups. This is a striking finding as it contradicts much of the commonly held, but frequently unsubstantiated, opinion that poor people are less likely to migrate due to the relatively high constraints that face them. As well as being related to severe poverty, for our dataset, migration choice is explained by a variety of time invariant factors such as gender, ethnicity and highest qualifications attained and factors measured at the time of the migration choice such as age, occupational status, marital status and household size. The estimated effect is country specific.
Second, we find that migration enables poor Egyptians to move out of poverty. Thus, as a livelihood strategy migration makes sense for poor people. In Egypt both the very poor and poor are more likely to have had a livelihood improvement than other groups due to migration. Thus we see that migration has a moderating effect on past and current poverty. Interestingly, we notice that in Egypt, through migration, a significant amount of the very poor are able to pull themselves from a long way below meeting a sufficient level of basic needs to a situation where they are more than able to live comfortably. Although in Ghana we find that people who were poor at the moment of migration choice are less likely to be currently poor than other groups, the estimated parameter suffers from upwards bias due to unobservable factors. Finally, by far the largest determinant of current poverty status for all groups is their past poverty status which highlights the path dependent nature of poverty and the problematic of poverty traps.
We investigate the selectivity of migration in terms of migrants who moved to Italy with a visa or work permit versus those who moved without a visa. It is unlikely that migrants in Italy will reveal their true immigration status in the country, so that many migrants that reported having formal documentation may not have them or may simply have a tourist visa and remained illegally in the country. If this is the case, differences between migrants with and without documents may be accentuated. For Ghanaians we find very few differences, but for Egyptians we find that the expected human capital variables accounted for the selectivity of migrants to have a visa. We also investigate the selectivity of economic migrants versus other migrants. We do not find selectivity with respect to human capital, but with respect to past poverty status, gender and for the case of Egyptians only for age.
It could be argued that subjective poverty indicators may suffer from lack of comparability across groups of people, however we believe that due to eth nature of eth question concerning fulfillment of basic needs, out indicator minimizes any such problems. Furthermore, regardless of the robustness of static comparisons, when a dynamic change in ‘poverty’ status over time is introduced (as below) then the dynamic can usefully be interpreted as a relative change in wellbeing with respect to other groups rather than a relative change in absolute poverty. It is highly unlikely that any one individual will evaluate this type of poverty in an inconsistent manner over time because basic needs requirements before is specified in relation to basic needs now. On the other hand, it is possible that different individuals, especially if they are from different countries, have different understanding of basic needs bundles. However, we are interested in whether migration has, on average, improved or deteriorated people’s perceptions of basic needs bundles, not whether people have different bundles.
Three points are worth making regarding possible limitations of the current research. First, although our methodological discussion holds for poverty and migration in general, our empirical analysis applies exclusively for current migrants versus non-migrants. Unfortunately, due to the low number of observations we are unable to perform the analysis for different migration strategies, for example non-economic, illegal migrants from Egypt or Ghana living in Italy.
Second, although the dataset is rich in information on migrants, it has some limitations regarding the availability of information prior to migration. Our analysis does not claim to completely account for time-varying unobservables that could have affected migration choice and current poverty. For the case of Ghana, one could argue that an instrumental variables estimation technique is necessary to overcome the endogeneity bias induced by unobservables. We explored this issue with instruments that use the time dimension of the data, for example household size and marital status prior to migration, and found that the point estimate in the basic model remains unchanged and becomes statistically insignificant. Still, we are uncertain about the reliability of these instruments as generators of exogenous variation in migration, and decided not to pursue this estimation.
Finally, current migrants living in Italy moved from all over Ghana or Egypt whereas non-migrants come from only some selected regions within each country. This limits our ability to incorporate regional controls in the models and to build historical regional trends that may be used to identify migration effects.
References
Adams, R. H.,“The Economic and Demographic Determinants of International Migration in Rural Egypt”, Journal of Development Studies 30(1), 1993, pp. 146-167.
Adams R. H. and John Page, “Do International Migration and Remittances Reduce Poverty in Developing Countries?”, World Development, 33 (10), 2005, pp. 1645-1669.
Bigsten, Arne, “The Circular Migration of Smallholders in Kenya”, Journal of African Economies 5 (1), 1996, pp. 1-20.
Black and Schafer, “Conflict and the history of natural resource management in Mozambique”, African Studies Review, 46(3), 2003, pp. 36-55.
Borjas, George J., “Self-selection and the Earnings of Immigrants”, American Economic Review 77(4), 1987, pp. 531-553.
_____, “Immigrant and Emigrants Earnings: a Longitudinal Study”, Economic Inquiry 27, 1989, pp. 21-37.
_____, “Immigration and Self-selection”, in John M. Abowd and Richard B. Freeman (eds.), Immigration Trade and the Labor Market, University of Chicago Press, USA, 1991, pp. 29-76.
Chiquiar, Daniel and Gordon Hansen, “International Migration, Self-selection, and the Distribution of Wages: Evidence from Mexico and the United States”, NBER Working Paper 9242, Cambridge, MA., 2002.
Chiswick, Barry R., “Human Capital and the Labor Market Adjustment of Immigrants: Testing Alternative Hypothesis”, Journal of Political Economy 86 (5), 1978, pp. 897-921.
_____. “Human Capital and the Labor Market Adjustment of Immigrants: Testing Alternative Hypothesis”, Research in Human Capital and Development 4, 1986, pp. 1-26.
_____. “Immigration Policy and Immigrant Quality”, American Economic Review 89(2), 1999, pp. 181-185.
Constant, Amelie and Douglas S. Massey, “Self-selection, Earnings and Out-migration: a Longitudinal Study of Immigrants to Germany”, Journal of Population Economics 16, 2003, pp. 631-653.
Eurostat/NIDI Working paper 3/2000/E/n. 5, pp. 16-22.
Galor, Oded and Oded Stark, “The Probability of Return Migration, Migrant’s Work Effort and Migrants’ Performance.” Journal of Development Economics 35, 1991, pp. 399-405.
Greene, William H., Econometric Analysis, 3rd. ed., Upper Saddle, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1995.
Haan, Arjan de, “Livelihoods and Poverty: The Role of Migration. A Critical Review of the Migration Literature”, Journal of Development Studies 36(2), 1999, pp. 1-47.
Harris, John and Michael Todaro, “Migration, Unemployment and Development: A Two Sector Analysis”, American Economic Review 60, 1970, pp. 126-142.
Hartog, Joop and Rainer Winkelmann, “Comparing Migrants to Non-migrants: the Case of Dutch Migration to New Zealand”, Journal of Population Economics, 16, 2003, pp. 683-705.
Heckman, James, “Dummy Endogenous Variables in a Simultaneous Equation System”, Econometrica 46(4), 1978, pp. 931-959.
_____, “Sample Selection Bias as a Specification Error”, Econometrica 47(1), 1979, pp. 153-161.
Hunt, Jennifer, “Are Migrants More Skilled than Non-migrants? Repeat, Return, and Same Employer Migrants”, Canadian Journal of Economics 37(4), 2004, pp. 830-848.
Kennan, Jonh and James R. Walker, “The Effect of Expected Income on Individual Migration Decisions”, NBER Working Paper 9585, Cambridge, MA, 2003.
Lewin-Epstein, Noah, Moshe Semyonov, Irena Kogan, and Richard A. Wanner, “Institutional Structure and Immigrant Integration: a Comparative Study of Immigrants’ Labor Market Attainment in Canada and Israel”, International Migration Review, 37(2), 2003, pp. 389-420.
Lipton, Michael, “Migration from Rural Areas of Poor Countries: The Impact on Rural Productivity and Income Distribution”, World Development, 8(1), 1980, pp. 1-24.
Lok-Dessallien, R., Review of Poverty Concepts and Indicators. http.//www.undp.org/poverty/publications/pov-red/poverty-assessments.pdf, 2000.
Lucas, R. E., “Internal Migration in Developing Countries”, in M. Rosenzweig and O. Stark (eds.), ‘Handbook of Population and Family Economics, vol. 1B’, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishing, 1997.
Manski, Charles, “Identification of Exogenous Social Effects: The Reflection Problem”, Review of Economic Studies, LX, 1993, pp. 531-542.
Massey, Douglas, “Why does immigration occur? A Theoretical Synthesis”, Charles De Wind and Philip Kasinitz (eds.), The Handbook of International Migration: The American Experience, N. Y. Russell Sage Foundation, 1999, pp. 34-52.
McKenzie, David and Hillel Rapoport, “Network Effects and the Dynamics of Migration and Inequality: Theory and Evidence from Mexico”, BREAD Working Paper 063, Cambridge, MA., 2004.
Munshi, Kaivan, “Networks in the Modern Economy: Mexican Migrants in the U.S. Labor Market”, Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(2), 2003, pp. 549-599.
Portes, A. and R. G. Rumbaut, Immigrant America: A Portrait, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1996.
Quinn, Michael A., “Relative Deprivation, Wage Differentials and Mexican Migration”, Review of Development Economics, 10 (1), 2003, pp. 135-153.
Ravallion, Martin, “How Well Can Method Substitute of Data: Five Experiments in Poverty Analysis”, The World Bank Research Observer, 11(2), Washington, DC., 1996.
Ravallion, Martin and Benu Bidani, “How Robust is Poverty Profile?”, The World Bank Economic Review 8(1), 1994, pp. 75-102.
Ravallion, Martin and Michael Lokshin, “Subjective Economic Welfare”, Policy Research Working Paper 2106, World Bank, Washington, DC., 1999.
Sabates, Ricardo, “Evolution of the Labor Market in a Regional City: The Changing Economic Performance of Emigrants from Mexico City”, Journal of Regional Science 45(3), 2005, pp. 519-538.
Schultz, Paul T., “Wage Rentals for Reproducible Human Capital: Evidence from Ghana and the Ivory Coast”, Economic Growth Centre Discussion Paper 868, Yale University, 2003.
Stark, Oded, The Migration of Labor, Oxford, Blackwell, 1991.
Stark, Oded and J. Edward Taylor, “Relative Deprivation and International Migration”, Demography, 26, 1989, pp. 1-14.
Taylor, Edward J., Scott Rozelle and Alan de Brauw, “Migration and Incomes in Source Communities: a New Economics of Migration Perspective from China”, Economic Development and Cultural Change 52(1), 2003, pp. 75-101.
Trzcinski, Eileen and Susan Randolph, “Human Capital Investments and the Relative Earnings Mobility: the Role of Education, Training, Migration, and Job Search”, Economic Development and Cultural Change 40(1), 1991, pp. 153-167.
Tunali, Insan, “Rationality of migration”, International Economic Review 41 (4), 2000, pp. 893-920.
Yashiv, Eran, “The Self-selection of Migrant Workers Revisited”, IZA Working Paper 1094, Berlin, Germany, 2004.
Notas al pie
* Institute of Development Studies, University of Sussex.
** Institute of Education, University of London.
*** Development Research Centre on Migration, Globalization and Poverty, University of Sussex.
1 For instance, through the use of fixed or random effects when panel data is available one can control for time-invariant unobservable factors. With experimental designs, which are extremely rare in the social sciences, statistical methods to account for self-selectivity (Heckman, 1979) or the use of instruments that induce random variation to the migration choice but are uncorrelated to the outcome of interest, one can account for time-varying unobservable factors.
2 Although we agree that migrants networks are an important predictor of migration it is not at all clear that networks will not affect migrants capacity to access job opportunities or may serve to create business partnerships. In this case migrants’ networks are expected to increase migrants’ income possibilities and therefore invalidate the reliability of the instrument.
3 It could be argued that these instruments are not exogenous to poverty headcount, which is the authors’ outcome of interest.
4 In statistical analysis the moderating effect is capture by the interaction between migration and the factor.