JOURNAL
OF ECONOMIC
THEORY
58,
355-376
(1992)
Efficient Equilibrium
Convergence:
Heterogeneity
and Growth
ROBERT TAMURA *
University
Received
of Iowa, Iowa City, Iowa 52242
October
10, 1990; revised
June 11. 1992
An endogenous
growth model arising from task specialization
is used to examine
the effects of differing
initial human
capital distributions.
Two macroeconomic
phenomena
are produced:
income convergence
and leapfrogging
of living standards.
Income
convergence
occurs for all countries
in the same market,
arising from
diminishing
returns to individual
human capital. Leapfrogging
occurs by comparing
countries
in two separate markets.
Income leapfrogging
can occur because the
stationary
growth rate increases with market size, and human capital heterogeneity
reduces growth.
The introduction
of coordination
costs of task assignment
can
produce gains in welfare and growth from human capital heterogeneity.
Journal of
‘!? 1992 Academic Press, Inc.
Economic Literarure
Classification
Numbers:
015. 041.
In this paper I develop an endogenous growth model based upon
specialization of task production. Task specialization is the microfoundation of the CES aggregate production function studied here. I use this model
to examine the macroeconomic effects of differing initial human capital
distributions.’
Two macroeconomic
phenomena are identified: income
convergence and leapfrogging of living standards, i.e., a change in rank
order. Income convergence is predicted for all countries in the same market
and is brought about by the convergence of human capital. Leapfrogging
* I thank
Kevin Murphy,
Sherwin
Rosen, Robert
E. Lucas, Jr., Forrest
Nelson,
Paul
Romer,
Nancy
Stokey,
Steve Trejo, Kei-Mu
Yi, John Kennan,
Narayana
Kocherlakota,
Barbara
McCutcheon,
George
Neumann,
an anonymous
referee, and an associate editor
for helpful
comments.
I am particularly
indebted
to these individuals
for making
this
manuscript
readable! All remaining
errors are mine.
’ This paper concentrates
only on the macroeconomic
implications
of heterogeneous
agents
and will be referenced as heterogeneity.
A market is identified by all agents specializing
in the
production
of different
tasks. In this paper a market
is a collection
of countries
trading the
output of specialized tasks to produce an aggregate consumption
good. Throughout
the paper
individuals
or agents are synonyms
for countries.
Although
important,
this paper ignores the
industrial
organization
implications
of industry
market
structure.
355
0022-0531/92
$5.00
Copyright 0 1992 by Academic Press, Inc.
All rights of reproduction
in any form reserved.
356
ROBERT
TAMURA
occurs by comparing countries in two separate markets. For expository
ease, I refer to effects of a heterogeneous human capital distribution as
arising from heterogeneity.
The aggregate production function contains all three returns to scale.
The aggregate production function exhibits constant returns to scale in the
human capital distribution, diminishing returns in each individual’s human
capital, and it displays increasing returns in the number of agents in the
market. Strict concavity of individual human capital in production and
convex preferences imply that heterogeneity reduces output in any period
and retards growth over time. In the dynamic model the competitive equilibrium produces efficient human capital convergence, and hence, income
convergence. Income convergence. applies to all agents in the same market.
Convergence is monotone; richer agents remain richer. Constant returns in
production and accumulation provide for endogenous growth. Growth is
increasing in market size.
Income convergence is controversial. Some work provides evidence of
income convergence, while other work disputes the existence of income
convergence. Abramowitz [ 1) and Baumol [6, 71 utilize the Maddison
data set to illustrate income convergence for a subset of the OECD countries. Using Summers and Heston [27] data, Dowrick and Nguyen [13],
Mankiw et al. [lS], and Tamura [29] report income convergence for
some countries. Barro and Martin [3] and Mieszkowski [ 193 identify
income convergence for regions in the United States. Becker and Tomes
[9] identify convergence in intergenerational data sets. O’Neill [21] finds
evidence that education convergence predicts income convergence. Some of
these studies are critiqued in DeLong [12] and Quah [22], who show that
convergence may arise from selection bias and Galton’s fallacy. Thus convergence depends on sample selection criteria, time period, and measure of
dispersion.
Unlike the income convergence controversy, a change in rank order is
undeniable. For example the United States and Germany leapfrogged the
United Kingdom early in the 20th century. Recent work has focused on
differences in technologies, preferences, and public policies to explain both
leapfrogging and convergence. Public policy differences are identified by
Barro [2], Glomm and Ravikumar [14], Jones and Manuelli [ 151, and
Rebel0 * [23]. This paper provides an alternative explanation of convergence and leapfrogging that is based on differing initial human capital
distributions.
A static model of task specialization is developed in Section II. It forms
the microfoundation
for aggregate production. In Section III the dynamic
model is studied, where investment in human capital leads to convergence
in human capital and income. In contrast to Tamura [28,29-J, where an
external effect of human capital in the accumulation technology produced
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
CONVERGENCE
357
convergence, convergence in this model is efficient. Prices are found
to decentralize the efficient solution in Section IV. In Section V I analyze
the balanced growth path and present simulations of the effects of
heterogeneity. Heterogeneity reduces growth and welfare. In Section VI
I modify the model to include a cost of coordinating task assignments.
In contrast to the model without coordination costs, heterogeneity can
increase net output. Furthermore, in a two-period coordination cost model
heterogeneity can increase growth and welfare compared to homogeneity.
II.
MODEL
In this section I provide a microeconomic model of task specialization,
building on the work of Rosen [25], Baumgardner [4,5], and Becker [8].
Task specialization generates a reduced form aggregate production function that I use to analyze the growth process. The model exhibits decreasing returns to individual inputs of human capital, but increasing returns in
the number of market participants. Diminishing returns to an individual’s
human capital makes homogeneity desirable. Because of this, a social
planner chooses dynamics such that the human capital distribution
collapses over time.
There are a continuum of “tasks” involved in the production of final output, and these tasks are indexed by a E [0, 11. There are N agents in the
market. Let m,(a) denote the level of skill of worker i applied to task a,
and let ti(a) be the amount of time worker i spends at task a. I assume that
the amount of output of task a is z(a)=Cy=,
m,(a) t,(a); alternatively,
z(u) can be interpreted as an intermediate good. Let x{ a 1 ti(u) > 0} be
the characteristic function that is 1 if ti(u) > 0, and 0 otherwise; and Hi is
the amount of human capital owned by i. An individual allocates skill
across tasks, but the geometric mean of his or her skill use cannot exceed
his or her human capital. Thus the individual’s
skills constraint
is (J @‘(a)
~{a 1 ti(a) > 0} d~)“~
= Hi, where OE [0, 11. Likewise, an
individual can only spend time on task production up to his or her time
endowment: s t,(a) da = 1. Final output is produced by a Leontief production function :
y = min[z(a)],
a
UE [O, 11.
(1)
I assume that labor is inelastically supplied. With these assumptions the
output maximizing social planner chooses the allocation of workers to
tasks and the optimum quantity of tasks produced in order to
358
ROBERT TAMURA
max y
m(o).1(u)
s.t. J’ = min [~(a)]
u
z(a)= f m,(u) t,(a)
;= I
I/<lJ
my(u)
x{u
1t,(a)
>0)da
1
(2)
=Hi
5t;(u) da = 1.
The solution to this maximum problem involves complete specialization
of tasks; thus, no two individuals work on the same task. It follows that the
level of time and human capital skill devoted is the same for all tasks that
an individual works on: m,(u) = ~,(a’) = m, and ti(u) = t,(u’) = ti for all
a, a’ in [0, 11.’ Only the number of tasks that an agent provides remains
to be solved. Let Ai be the number of tasks that i provides. The efficient
number of tasks for agent i can be determined from the resource constraints.
The skills constraint produces mid f’” = Hi = mj = Hi/A!‘“. From the time
constraint, ti= l/Ai. Therefore, output is y = Hi/AI1 +o)‘o. Since the total
task length is 1, the equilibrium task assignments are
H”“‘+o)
Ai= C”= ’ H+(‘+W)’
!I
iE {1,2, ...) N}.
(3)
J
Hence agents with large amounts of human capital do more tasks than
agents with small amounts of human capital. From (3) output is
If agents are endowed with the same amount of human capital, they do the
same number of tasks, A = l/N, and output is N” +““““H. This shows the
increasing returns to participation.
Kydland and Prescott [ 161 and
Neumann and Topel [20] identify this feature. Holding Cy’, H, constant,
maximum output occurs when all agents are identical.
The constant elasticity of substitution production function contains all
types of returns to scale. Output y is homogeneous of degree 1 in {Hi} ,“=1.
In Section V I show that perpetual growth can exist in this model.
Diminishing
returns in H, is the motivation for equalization of human
capital across agents.
‘This is the same result as in Rosen [25] and Baumgardner [4, 51
EFFICIENT EQUILIBRIUM
III.
HETEROGENEITY
CONVERGENCE
359
AND CONVERGENCE
A dynamic version of the static model is introduced and analyzed in this
Section. I characterize the solution to the associated social planner’s
problem and show that there is convergence of the distribution of human
capital levels in the limit. The intuition for convergence is the same as in
the static model: for fixed worker size and fixed total resources, maximum
output occurs when workers are identical. The efficient dynamic growth
path eliminates the differences across individuals.
Assume that agents have identical preferences given by
,zo
P’$3
(5)
where 0 < 1; preferences are logarithmic if CJ= 0.
The law of motion of the stocks of human capital is
Hi,+, = AX;Hf,-P,
(6)
where Xi, is the amount of investment in the stock of the ith individual’s
human capital in period t. Assume that B[AN” + W)p’w]u < 1. Anticipating
the development of the model below, this restriction imposes the transversality condition, and the finiteness of the value function. For CTQ 0, B < 1 is
sufficient.
If {1,}:= i 2 0 are the Pareto weights, then the social planner’s problem
becomes
max { i
i=l
& f
B’ $},
1=0
(P)
Define aggregate consumption, c, - ({Cy= i H$(‘tW’}‘l+W)‘W - Cy=, Xi,).
Efficient allocation of consumption has each agent consuming a fixed
fraction of aggregate consumption:
The last step solves for the efficient allocation
of investment
resources.
360
ROBERTTAMURA
Let {H,) = { Hir}y=, , and [A’,), = { Xir}r=, , t 3 0. The social planner’s
optimization problem is to choose investment resources X, to satisfy
The following theorem shows that the social planner eliminates
heterogeneity. Without loss of generality; order the N agents from lowest
to highest human capital stock, thus agent N has the most human capital.
THEOREM.
Define h, = Hil/HN,, then ‘the ratios of human capital converge
to 1, i.e.,
lim hi,= 1,
t-m
iE { 1, 2, .... N}.
Proof: The proof uses three features of the problem. The value function
is strictly concave and symmetric in each agent’s human capital and is
homogeneous of degree 0 in human capital. Strict concavity and symmetry
of the value function imply that low human capital agents grow faster than
high human capital agents. Homogeneity of the value function implies that
the ratio of agent i’s human capital to agent N’s human capital, hi,,
converges to a stationary solution, h* = 1.
Using (6) to replace (X,1, c”,/ (T is strictly concave in ((Hi,, H, + ,)} f”=I.
Therefore from the theorems of Chapter 4 of Stokey and Lucas [26], the
value function is strictly increasing, strictly concave., and differentiable in
{H,, H, + , }. The first-order condition for agent i is
(1
-PVP
Hit+1
[ Hit1
+@/PpC;--
The derivative of the value function
theorem. This produces
(8)
au:HH”‘).
If+
is calculated
1
from the envelope
(9)
Equation (9) shows that the derivative of the value function is symetric; if
H ,r+,=Hjr+~,
then &,GH, + 1= &/aH,, + 1. Since the value function is
strictly concave and its derivatives are symmetric, (8) shows that H, + 1 is
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
CONVERGENCE
361
strictly increasing in Hi,. Thus if H, < Hi,, then H, + 1 < Hi, + 1, Vt.
Therefore if H, < Hi,, (8) also shows that the growth rate of human capital
for agent i exceeds the growth rate of human capital of agent j. Agents with
lower human capital grow faster than agents with higher human capital,
but never surpass higher human capital agents. The previous arguments
imply that for each agent,
hi,<hi,+l
< 1,
v’t.
Each sequence converges to a limit, say h:. By symmetry h* = hi* = h*, for
all i, j # A?
Homogeneity of the value function allows it to be expressed in terms of
the ratios of human capital, hit, and the growth rate of human capital of
agent N, cN. Define h, = {h,};N_ i. Ignoring H&, the social planner’s
problem is to choose next periods relative human capital distribution and
the growth rate of the largest human capital agent:
([C;=“=,
o(h,)=
max
,+(I+m)
II
1(I+W)/OJ -Cj”‘l
{(hi,+,I,,)IAh~,-P}“P)”
The first-order conditions from this problem produce a system of equations for h,, 1 which only depend on h,. Thus h,, , = 4(h,), where 4 is
continuous. Hence the limit of the sequence is
lim h (+ 1 = h* = ,‘i\
t-m
d(h,) = $li;
h,) =&h*).
Stationarity of h, implies a common growth rate of human capital. From
(8) this only occurs for h* = 1. Therefore the limit of human capital ratios
isl.
1
The theorem shows that human capital converges. Over time, agents
become alike and the number of distinct tasks each agent performs
becomes equal. Rich agents remain richer than their poorer cousins,
although the gap shrinks. No leapfrogging is possible within the market.
Equation (8) shows why individuals care whom their colleagues are.
Having higher human capital colleagues raises welfare, i.e., 2Jv(H,)/iTH, > 0
VH,. Since output is strictly increasing in N, welfare is strictly increasing
in the number of market participants.
ROBERTTAMURA
362
IV. DECENTRALIZATION
In this section I find prices to decentralize the efficient solution to the
planner’s problem in Section III. Assume that complete markets in consumption loans exist. Assume that agents are hired in a competitive labor
market. Human capital is accumulated using one’s human capital and
purchased investment goods, X,,. Since X, can be consumed, the relative
price of Xi, and cir is 1. The individual’s problem, (P,), is to purchase
investment goods and consumption goods, given competitive equilibrium
prices (p,, w,) to
s.t.
Hi,
+,=AX”H!-p
(Pi)
II)
,go
PIICit
+xit)
Gf ‘i*Wit
Hiz.
1=0
Let pi be the Lagrangian multiplier
individual’s Euler equations are
Brczp
’ =
xif
In a competitive
i’s wealth constraint. The
PiPr7
(10)
1
(11)
workers are paid their marginal
product; thus
PI+1
__
-
Hit+1
on individual
p
equilibrium
l-P
Wir+l
Xir+l
+--
P
Pt
Hit+,
’
Equation (12) shows that wages per unit of human capital differ across
agents. High human capital agents are paid less per unit of human capital
than low human capital agents. However, since each agent supplies one
unit of time, earnings are wiHi. These earnings are rising in Hi. This agrees
with what economists observe.
Substituting the equilibrium wage into (11) yields
xi*
Hit+1
Comparing
-p P~+I
1-P J’ir+l
P,
( 13) and (9) requires
PlCl
-=
Pr
4
- Cl
c,+ 1>
I-o
’
t 2 0,
(13)
EFFICIENT EQUILIBRIUM
where p,, = 1. Agent i’s initial
Recall that the consumption
CONVERGENCE
consumption
363
is
of agent i in the efficient solution is
Therefore, in order to support the efficient solution, wealth transfers may
be necessary. Alternatively, the original Pareto weights, li, can be those
arising from the initial distribution of wealth in the market. Prices exist to
decentralize the efficient allocation.
V. DYNAMICS:
GROWTH
AND LEAPFROGGING
In this section I analyze the stationary aggregate growth rate. The most
interesting finding is that the aggregate growth rate is increasing in N:
larger markets grow faster. I provide a finite time approximation
to the
infinite time model. The finite time model is solved numerically, and the
simulations show that heterogeneity lowers growth during the transition
from heterogeneity to homogeneity. However, despite slower growth in the
transitional
phase, an initially heterogeneous economy has the same
asymptotic growth rate as an otherwise identical homogeneous economy.
Solving the Euler equation in the homogeneous agent market implicitly
defines the stationary investment rate, s:
s = [pp + /3(1 - p)s] A”(sN l’w)Op.
Comparative statics reveal that the aggregate growth rate is increasing in
0, A, /I, and N. It is decreasing in o. For log preferences, s = BP/( 1 - /I( 1 - p));
thus the aggregate growth rate is ,4[sN(1+“)‘“]P.
This is a tractable model for analyzing the effect of heterogeneity on the
aggregate growth rate. Consider two markets, identical except for the distribution of the fixed total human capital. Solving each dynamic problem
through numerical simulations allows for calculation of the effects of
heterogeneity on the aggregate growth rate of output. The solutions show
that heterogeneity can dramatically affect the aggregate growth rate.
Each simulation solves a finite time social planning problem. Each has
48 time periods and 35 agents. The simulations are a finite time approximation to the infinite time horizon model, or an exact solution to a finite time
364
ROBERT
TAMURA
world. The simulations come from solving the Euler equations. These equations form a second-order difference equation system; therefore, two initial
conditions must be specified. These are my specifications of the final period
human capital stocks for all agents, and the zero amount of investment in
the final period. Identical homothetic preferences allows for aggregation,
thus simplifying the problem. Knowing {H,, X,} allows me to solve for
\(X, _ 1} and hence (H,_ , }, for t 6 48. In the simulations aggregate human
capital in the heterogeneous market is equal to aggregate human capital in
the homogeneous market at t = 48.
The top curve in Fig. 1 is the time path of the coefficient of variation of
human capital. The lower curve is the time series of the ratio of the growth
rate with heterogeneity to the growth rate with homogeneity.
The
heterogeneous market growth rate approaches the homogeneous market
growth rate after 24 periods. However, in the first 24 periods, the
heterogeneous market growth rate is small compared to the homogeneous
market growth rate. At t =0 the growth rate in the heterogeneous agent
market is 4% of the growth rate in the homogeneous agent market.
Figure 2 presents the human capital growth rates of some of the agents
in the market. The lowest human capital agent has a growth rate about live
times that of the highest human capital agent in period 24. Figure 3
illustrates the convergence in human capital by each agent to agent 35.
Until the human capital of agent 30 is more than 25 % of the human capital of agent 35, t = 24, the individual growth rates differ from each other
dramatically.
I
16
FIG.
u(c)
= In(c);
p = 0.175;
I
24
Time
w = 0.175;
I
32
A = 1.05;
r
I
I
41B
40
fi = 0.75;
N=
35.
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
I
J
365
CONVERGENCE
I
I
I
I
75
45
15
1
I
24
FIG.
I
32
28
2.
Human
capital
Tim?
growth
I
I
I
40
44
rates of agents.
1
1
.75
75
.5
.5
.25
.25
0
24I
28I
321
36I
40I
Time
FIG.
3.
Human
capital
ratios.
44I
I
48
I
0
366
ROBERT
TAMURA
Figures 4 and 5 contain the individual investment rates of some agents
and the aggregate investment rate in both markets. With log preferences,
the fraction saved is independent of the distribution of human capital in the
market and only depends on the number of periods remaining. Savings and
growth rates, individual and aggregate, converge to zero by period 48,
since this is the final period.
I simulated the model for different values of C. The qualitative results are
similar to the results for log preferences. However, one difference is the
effect of heterogeneity on the aggregate savings rate. For (T= - 1.5 (Fig. 7)
the aggregate savings rate is increasing in the degree of heterogeneity, while
the opposite holds for c = 0.05 (Fig. 6). In all solutions, as the degree of
heterogeneity is reduced, growth accelerates.’
The human capital convergence theorem of Section III applies to all
countries in the same market. No leapfrogging exists within a market.
Leapfrogging
requires comparing
countries
in two separate markets.
Assume that there are two separate markets, one large heterogeneous
market and a small homogeneous market. Further assume that initially the
.03
.0225
,015
.OO?!i
0
-0
I
16
1
20
FIG.
I
24
4.
I
28
I
32
Time
,
36
5
40
I
44
Investment rates of agents.
3 Romer [24] presents evidenceof acceleratinggrowth. Using
five countries reject a nonpositive
trend in growth rates at the
other countries
reject a nonpositive
trend at the 10% level
reject a nonpositive
trend at the 15% level of significance.
nonpositive
trend.
Maddison’s
1 l-country
sample,
5 % level of significances.
Three
of significance.
Two countries
Only Sweden fails to reject a
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
367
CONVERGENCE
.32
.32
.24
.24
.I6
.16
.oa
.08
0
0
FIG. 5. Aggregate investment rate, log utility.
,625
.625
5
.5
.375
,375
.25
.25
,125
.125
I
0
I
6
1
16
I
24
lime
I
32
I
40
FIG. 6. Aggregate investment rate, u = 0.05.
I
48
368
ROBERTTAMURA
.12
.I2
.09
.06
.03
0
0
1
d
i
FIG.
7.
I
Ii5
Aggregate
I
2’4
Time
investment
I
I
32
rate, (r=
4b
I
4i3
-1.5.
large heterogeneous market is richer than the small homogeneous market.
As shown in the simulations, the poor, small market can have a faster rate
of growth initially. Therefore the small market might leapfrog the richer
market because of the rich, large market’s heterogeneity. Over time the
large market becomes homogeneous, and its growth rate increases. Since
the large market has a faster stationary growth rate, eventually the income
of the large market will leapfrog back over the income of the small market.
VI. COORDINATION
COSTS
This section modifies the model by introducing coordination costs of
task specialization. Coordination costs can prevent all agents from working
in the same market. Holding C;“= 1 Hi constant, if more than one market
exists, then heterogeneity may raise welfare relative to homogeneity. In the
static model this occurs because heterogeneity may support larger markets,
increasing output net of coordination costs. In a two-period model, market
heterogeneity may raise growth and welfare by creating larger markets in
the second period, compared to market homogeneity. In the short run,
therefore, coordination costs can reverse the desirability of homogeneity.
369
EFFICIENT EQUILIBRIUM CONVERGENCE
Assume the costs are incurred to coordinate task specialization. Specialized inputs must be organized to produce the right compatible parts
and avoid task duplication. These costs are modelled in reduced form by
assuming that costs increase with the number of market participants:
costs = c(N),
c’(N) > 0,
c”(N) > 0,
c(l)=O.
(14)
These coordination costs are similar to the coordination costs in Becker
and Murphy [lo].”
Assume that N is the population of the market. In a static homogeneous
agent model the solution to the social planner’s problem, (PC), is to maximize net output:
i=l
The optimal
market size, ni, chosen by a social planner satisfies:
n!‘+“)iwH-c(n,)>(ni+
l)(‘+O)‘V-c(ni+
nl’+O’/~~-c(ni)~(ni-l)(‘+m)‘“H-c(ni-
l),
1).
(15)
When (15) holds for ni = N, the equilibrium
is identical to the static
problem without coordination costs, except that net output replaces gross
output. Under this specification of coordination costs, income growth in a
dynamic model implies that eventually (15) holds as a strict inequality for
ni = N. However, if (15) holds as a strict inequality for n, < N, then there
will be more that one market. Suppose that there exist m markets. Markets
can be ordered in the following manner:
Net output in the homogeneous
agent case is
it1 w+a)‘wH- c(q)}.
(16)
4 Coordination costs are assumed to only depend on the number of market participants. If
coordination costs also depend on the scale of output, {H,}, then the implication of full
market integration in the long run can be overturned. I thank the associate editor for bringing
this to my attention.
642/58/2-17
370
ROBERT
TAMURA
Observe that a redistribution of human capital from the small markets to
the large markets increases output. If human capital were mobile across
agents, then the maximum net output is at least
n1
(1+0)/w N
(17)
-~(i~~)=n:/wlvH-~(t~,).
(7 n1
This is a lower bound on the gains from heterogeneity, because the size of
the largest market may increase. Equation (17) is the maximum net output
possible by only reallocating human capital, i.e., working on the intensive
margin. Net output might rise by increasing market size, the extensive
margin. Therefore introducing coordination costs in the static model can
make heterogeneity more desirable than homogeneity. This gain from
heterogeneity in the static market provides the intuition into possible
benefits of heterogeneity in the dynamic context.
I now extend the static coordination cost model into a dynamic model
by introducing an additional period. Intuitively, a gain from heterogeneity
can arise because there are two margins to use. In a dynamic coordination
cost model, heterogeneity may create larger markets earlier compared to
homogeneity. By increasing market size, it is possible that in the short run
heterogeneity is beneficial to growth and welfare.
In both periods the social planner maximizes net output. Define maximum net output as
(18)
m
s.t. c ni= N.
i=
1
Welfare in the second period is
u2((H2))= y2(‘H2’)u,
0
(19)
The social planner chooses investments given the first period distribution
human capital in order to
(~l({Hl))-CiN,l
~d{Hd)=
max
IXL,
St.
.
ff.
r2
=AXPH!-PI
Xi)“+pV2({H
CT
11
2
1,
of
3
I
(PC)
.
This two-period, three-agent model is solved numerically. The homogeneous market has period-one aggregate human capital equal to the period-
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
371
CONVERGENCE
one aggregate human capital of the heterogeneous market. Figures 8-12
present simulation
results of the effect of heterogeneity on welfare,
individual growth rates, the aggregate growth rates of output, consumption, and mean human capital. They show that binding coordination costs
can reverse the results obtained in Section V. In Fig. 8 there are ranges of
mean human capital, where heterogeneity increases welfare relative to
homogeneity. I interpret these differences as capturing the distinction
between the short run and the long run. As wealth rises over time full
integration of market participants is possible. In the short run, however,
coordination costs can inhibit the formation of markets.
As the size of the market rises, so does the growth rate of output. Therefore changes in the extensive margin can explain increasing growth rates.
This captures the dynamic gains from trade: the larger the market, the
larger the gains from specialization, and the greater the specialization, the
larger the growth rate.
Introducing
coordination
costs to the model provides an alternative
explanation of leapfrogging. Heterogeneous countries grow at unequal
rates when the market structure moves from three small markets to two
markets. In this case the two countries integrating into the intermediate
market grow much faster than the left out country. Since the higher human
capital countries expand the market, they diverge from the smaller country.
This is shown in the growth rates of the individual countries in Fig. 9.
I
J
I
2.25
Mean
FIG.
8.
Value
function,
I
4.5
Human Capital
u(c) = In(c);
6.75
o = 0.5; p = 0.5.
1
9
ROBERT TAMURA
312
5
4
3
2
1
I
2.25
I
4.5
Mean Human
Capital
I
6.75
I
9
FIG. 9. Human capital growth rates of agents.
17.5
15
mogeneou
12.5
10
7.5
5
fi
2.5
-r
0
I
2.25
I
4.5
Mean Human
I
Caoital
6.75
FIG. 10. Growth rate of aggregate output.
I
9
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
373
CONVERGENCE
- 32
28
z
2
-24
- 16
-8
4
FIG.
11.
I
5.5
Growth
rate of aggregate
I
I
2.25I
4.5I
consumption
I
I
/
6.75
I
9
-
2.5 0I
Mean
FIG.
642/58/2-18
12.
Growth
Human
rate of mean
Caoital
human
capital
374
ROBERTTAMURA
From Fig. 9, in the intermediate range, the smallest human capital country
loses not only relative to the other two players, but absolutely as well!
Thus growth need not make all countries richer, although with complete
markets in consumption loans, all countries are better off, since consumption rises for all.
In the fully integrated outcome, the two smaller countries gain relative
to the biggest country, i.e., gl > g2 > 83. The interior range characterizes
leapfrogging of countries 2 and 3 relative to country 1, and convergence
between 2 and 3. In Figs. 11 and 12 there exist ranges where consumption
growth and mean human capital growth is higher under heterogeneity than
homogeneity.
CONCLUSIONS
This paper provides an endogenous growth model with efficient equilibrium convergence in human capital and income. This arises from the
decreasing returns to individual human capital. The CES production
function implies that agents have an incentive to equalize the human
capital in society. Since there are increasing returns to participation,
all
agents desire to participate in the same market. In Tamura [28,29] an
external effect of human capital in the accumulation technology produces
convergence; therefore high human capital agents have an incentive to
segregate themselves from low human capital agents. In the model of this
paper, absent coordination costs, high human capital agents prefer high
human capital coworkers, but are happy to have anybody participate in
the market.
In this model I compute the effect of heterogeneity on growth. Without
coordination
costs, the simulations indicate that heterogeneity reduces
growth. Introducing
coordination
costs can reverse this negative relationship. If heterogeneity creates larger markets faster than homogeneity,
then growth and welfate increase.
Finally, the model provides an explanation of reversal of income
rankings, or leapfrogging. Suppose there are two markets, a large rich,
heterogeneous market, and a small, poor, homogeneous market. The large
heterogeneous market may grow slower than the small homogeneous
market, allowing the small market to leapfrog the large market. As
heterogeneity is eliminated in the large market, growth accelerates. Since
the large market has a higher stationary growth rate, the large market will
leapfrog back over the small market.
EFFICIENT
EQUILIBRIUM
CONVERGENCE
375
REFERENCES
ABRAMOWITZ,
Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind, J. &on. Hist. 46 (1986),
385406.
R. BARRO, Government
spending in a simple model of endogenous
growth,
J. Polk Econ.
98 (1990), S103-S125.
R. BARRO AND X. SALA I MARTIN, Convergence,
J. Polit. Econ. 100 (1992), 223-251.
J. R. BAUMGARDNER,
The division
of labor, local markets,
and worker
organization,
J. Polir. Econ. 96 (1988). 509-527.
J. R. BAUMGARDNER,
Physicians’
services and the division of labor across local markets,
J. Polk Econ. 96 (1988), 948-982.
W. J. BAUMOL, Productivity
growth,
convergence,
and welfare: What the long-run
data
show, Amer. Econ. Rev. 76 (1986), 1072-1085.
W. J. BAUMOL AND E. N. WOLFF, Productivity
growth,
convergence,
and welfare: Reply,
Amer. Econ. Rev. 78 (1988), 1155-1159.
G. S. BECKER, “A Treatise on the Family,”
Harvard
Univ. Press, Cambridge,
MA, 1981.
G. S. BECKER AND N. TOMES, Human
capital and the rise and fall of families, J. Labor
Econ. 4 (1986), Sl-S39.
G. S. BECKER AND K. M. MURPHY, Human capital, the division of labor. and economic
progress, unpublished
University
of Chicago manuscript,
1990.
G. S. BECKER, K. M. MURPHY.
AND R. TAMURA. Human capital, fertility
and economic
growth,
J. Polit. Econ. 98 (1990). S12-S37.
B. J. DELONG,
Productivity
growth,
convergence,
and welfare:
Comment,
Amer. Econ.
Rev. 78 (1988), 1138-1149.
S. DOWRICK
AND D.-T.
NGUYEN,
OECD
comparative
economic
growth
1950-85:
Catchup
and convergence,
Amer. Econ. Reu. 79 (1989), 101&1030.
G. GLOMM
AND B. RAVIKUMAR,
Public
vs. private
investment
in human
capital:
Endogenous
growth
and income
inequality,
unpublished
University
of Virginia
manuscript,
1991.
L. E. JONES AND R. MANUELLI,
A convex model of equilibrium
growth: Theory and policy
implications.
J. Polit. Econ. 98 (1990), 1008-1038.
F. KYDLAND
AND E. PRESCOTT, The workweek
of capital and its cyclical implications,
J. Monef. Econ. 21 (1988), 343-360.
R. E. LUCAS, JR., On the mechanics
of economic development,
J. Monel. Econ. 22 (1988),
342.
N. G. MANKIW,
D. ROMER, AND D. N. WEIL, A contribution
to the empirics of economic
growth,
unpublished
Harvard
University
manuscript,
1990.
P. MIESZKOWSKI,
Recent trends in urban and regional development,
in “Current
Issues in
Urban
Economics”
(P. Mieszkowski
and M. Straszheim,
Eds.). Johns Hopkins
Univ.
Press, Baltimore,
1979.
G. NEUMANN AND R. TOPEL, Employment
risk, diversification,
and unemployment,
Quart.
J. Econ. 106 (1991), 1341-1365.
D. O’NEILL,
Human
capital
accumulation
and growth:
An empirical
investigation,
unpublished
University
of Iowa manuscript,
1991.
D. QUAH, Galton’s
fallacy and tests of the convergence
hypothesis,
unpublished
M.I.T.
manuscript,
1990.
S. REBELO, Long-run
policy analysis and long-run
growth,
J. Polif. Econ. 99 (1991).
50@521.
P. ROMER, Increasing
returns and long-run
growth,
J. Polit. Econ. 94 (1986), 1002-1037,
S. ROSEN, The division of labor and the extent of the market,
unpublished
University
of
Chicago manuscript,
1982.
1. M.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
14.
15.
16.
17.
18.
19.
20.
21.
22.
23.
24.
25.
376
26. N. STOKEY
Dynamics,”
ROBERT
R. E. LLICAS,
Harvard
University
E. Prescott),
“Recursive
Methods
in Economic
Press. Cambridge.
MA, 1989.
27. R. SUMMERS
AND A. HESTON, A new set of international
comparisons
of real product and
price levels estimates for 130 countries,
195G1985,
Ret). lncame Wealth 34 (1988), l-25.
28. R. TAMURA.
income convergence
in an endogenous
growth
model. J. Polif. Econ. 99
( 1990). 522-540.
29. R. TAMURA,
From decay to growth: A dynamic equilibrium
model of income distribution,
unpublished
University
of Iowa manuscript.
1991.
AND
JR. (with
TAMURA