The Architecture of Globalization:
A Network Approach to International Economic Integration.
Raja Kali and Javier Reyes1
Department of Economics
Sam M. Walton College of Business
University of Arkansas
Fayetteville, AR 72701
Abstract
We combine data on international trade linkages with network methods to examine the global
trading system as an interdependent complex network. We map the topology of the international
trade network and suggest new network based measures of international economic integration, at
both a global system-wide level and a local country-level. We develop network based measures that
incorporate not only the volume of trade but also the influence that a country has on the international
trading system. These measures incorporate the structure and function of the network and may
provide a more meaningful approach to globalization than current measures based on trade volumes.
We find that in terms of participation and influence in the network, global trade is hierarchical with a
core-periphery structure at higher levels of trade, though integration of smaller countries into the
network increased considerably over the 1990’s. The network is strongly “balkanized” according to
geography of trading partners but not as strongly by income or legal origin. Using these new
measures we find that a country’s position in the network has substantial implications for economic
growth. We therefore suggest that a network approach to international economic integration has
potential for useful applications in international business, finance and development.
Keywords: globalization, economic integration, networks, international trade
1
Email: rkali@walton.uark.edu, jreyes@walton.uark.edu
We are grateful to Jon Johnson, Fabio Mendez and Anand Swamy for helpful discussions. We thank seminar participants
at Harvard Business School, the University of Arkansas, Williams College, IGIDR-Mumbai and MWIEG Fall 2005 for
their comments. Viktoria Riiman provided outstanding reseach assistance.
I. Introduction.
While popular usage of the term “globalization” provokes strong and polarizing opinions across the
world, such sentiments are usually associated with the effects, real or perceived, of what economists refer to
as international economic integration.
The increase in international economic integration that has
characterized the last half-century has been associated with the spectacular economic performance and move
out of poverty for large parts of the world (Sachs and Warner, 1995), but also with the increase in the
volatility of country-level performance, reflected in several recent episodes of economic and financial “crises”
(Forbes 2001). There is also a growing perception that the process of globalization has accelerated over the
last decade and that the benefits and costs of increasing economic integration have not been evenly distributed
across the world (Stiglitz, 2002; Bhagwati, 2004).
Despite a sharp increase in interest on these issues, discussions are often handicapped by the dearth of
appropriate measures of international economic integration.
Most studies of international economic
integration or globalization in the economics literature focus on the volume of trade (exports and/or imports
as a fraction of total trade) between countries, or define “trade integration” as the sum of exports and imports
divided by GDP (see for example Rodrik, 2000, IMF World Economic Outlook, 2002).
While these
indicators2 have been useful, the literature recognizes their shortcomings (which we describe in more detail
below). Nevertheless, they are still widely used for studying international economic integration, primarily for
lack of better alternatives.
Recent advances in the study of networks (Albert and Barabasi, 2002; Newman, 2003) have placed
elegant and powerful tools at our disposal, enabling us to suggest alternative measures of international
economic integration (henceforth IEI) that turn from a sole focus on individual country trade levels to a
consideration of the pattern of linkages that tie together countries around the world as a whole. In this paper
we combine a network approach with data on international trade linkages in order to examine the global
trading system as an interdependent complex network3. A network approach enables us to derive statistics
that describe the structure and evolution of global trade in ways that existing measures do not capture, such as
the number of actual and potential trading partners, the structure of regional trading and the influence of
individual countries and groups of countries for the whole network and for specific regions. We use this
change in perspective toward IEI to suggest new measures of integration that provide insights into global
trade that have been overlooked by the literature.
2 Other measures based on volumes such as gross private flows to GDP, and total trade to merchandise value added also
fall into this category.
3
Complex networks are large scale graphs that are composed of so many nodes and links that they cannot be
meaningfully visualized and analyzed using standard graph theory. Recent advances in network research now enable us
to analyze such graphs in terms of their statistical properties. Albert and Barabasi (2002) and Newman (2003) are
excellent surveys of these methods.
2
With this objective, we first map the topology of the international trade network with a view to
understanding its structure and properties. Armed with such an understanding, we then suggest new measures
of IEI, at both a “local”, country-level, and a “global”, system-wide level, that incorporate the structure and
function of the network. We use these measures to parse IEI along a number of different lines: geography,
income and legal origin. This enables an examination of whether global trade has become more integrated or
“balkanized” along these dimensions. We suggest network-based measures that capture not only the volume
of trade but also the “influence” that a country may have on the international trading system. We have data
on the network of international trade linkages at two points in time, 1992 and 1998, and are able to construct
these measures for both years and examine how the network and thus “globalization” has evolved over the
1990’s. Since trade levels vary considerably from country to country and there could be some debate over
what constitutes “consequential” levels of trade, we construct the network for different trade level thresholds4.
We find that at low levels of trade, the global trading network has become much more integrated, while at
higher levels of trade it has not changed much. At low levels of trade, the global trade network is quite
decentralized and homogenous but at higher levels of trade the network looks much more hierarchical and
heterogeneous, with a core-periphery structure. We also find that there is a high level of multilateralism in
global trade and this has not changed much between 1992 and 19985.
As an application, and to demonstrate the potential of the network approach to IEI, we use our
measures of network importance in a cross-country growth regression and find they are all statistically and
economically significant, have the expected signs and raise the explanatory power of the regression above that
obtained using only volume based measures current in the literature. Using one of our measures of local
integration, degree centrality, a measure of how centrally located a country is in the network6, we find that an
improvement in the centrality ranking by 10 units at the two percent trade-link threshold increases the average
growth rate of per capita GDP by 1.1 percentage points.7 A country’s position in the network can thus have
substantial implications for development outcomes.
The paper is organized as follows. Section II describes the data and definitions that we use to
organize the trade-link data. Section III applies concepts from network analysis to understand properties of
4
We describe this procedure in more detail in section II.
While we believe this is the first exercise to explicitly chart the topology of the international trade network and suggest
the use of this topology for the understanding of economic integration, we are by no means the first to use network ideas
in international business and economics. An excellent introduction to this literature is Rauch and Casella (2001) and the
critique by Zuckerman (2003). Systems- or network-based measures of globalization have, to the best of our
knowledge, not been used in economics before, but there is antecedent in the sociology literature. A paper by Smith and
White (1992) uses international trade flow data to consider the change in the structure of the international division of
labor with the goal of understanding patterns and cycles of hegemony in the world-system. The focus of this work is
thus quite different from ours.
6 We describe various network measures in more detail below.
7 This is judged to be a substantial effect by the standards of the literature. For example, Yanikkaya (2003) finds that an
increase of 10% in the total trade to GDP ratio would increase the average growth rate of per capita GDP by 0.18%.
5
3
the network. We first provide an overview of the topology of the network and then delve deeper into the data
and propose measures of local and global economic integration. Section IV is our application to economic
growth. Section V summarizes our findings and suggests further applications of these measures.
II. Definitions and Data.
The first step in our approach is to identify the fundamental building blocks of the network and their
specific properties. A network is a set of points, called nodes or vertices, with connections between them,
called links or edges. In our context, each country is considered to be a node of the network. Since
international trade is usually measured using the monetary value of exports and imports between countries,
trading relationships are analogous to valued links in a network, and these vary from country to country. In
order to chart the structure of the network we wish to take into account the magnitude of these relationships
but not specifically their exact value.
We do this by considering a network link between two countries to be present if the trade level
between them is above a certain threshold. Specifically, we define a trade-link between country i and country
j to be present if the value of exports from country i to country j as a proportion of country i’s total exports is
greater than or equal to a given magnitude. Since exports of country i to country j are in effect imports of j
from i we are able to construct both export and import networks in order to understand IEI from both sides.
Moreover, since trade levels vary considerably from country to country and there could be some debate over
what constitutes “consequential” levels of trade, we construct the network for different trade level thresholds,
which we explain below. Examining how the structure of the network changes as the trade threshold used to
define the presence of links varies also enables us to understand the sensitivity of various topological
characteristics of the network to differing trade magnitudes. Constructing the network for different thresholds
enables us to incorporate both magnitudes and network features into our analysis. Using thresholds enables
us to avoid working directly with valued-directed links even though implicitly these thresholds embody the
values of the trade links in our data.
The data used for our international trade network was extracted from the COMTRADE Database of
the United Nations8. We use the US dollar value of exports and imports of all commodities between 189
countries for 1992 and between 192 countries in 19989. Countries are the nodes of the network and a link
8
United Nations database STIC 1.
A list of countries is included in Table 1A of the Data Appendix. It should be noted that even though our trade network
is extensive, it is not all-inclusive. The United Nations database includes more than 230 countries/areas, plus some NES
(not elsewhere specified) areas. Although we compute the total exports and total imports from the all-inclusive raw
database, in our trade network analysis we only include countries. In other words we ignore regions and NES figures.
Additionally some countries, like Guadeloupe, Martinique, Reunion, and others, are excluded from our analysis because
there are some inconsistencies in the data reported by these countries.
9
4
between them represents trading relationships among these countries. We study import and export relations
separately and therefore we have a directed graph where country A can export to country B without having
country B exporting to country A. Initially we organize the data in matrix form, letting columns represent
exporting countries and rows denote importing countries, and we analyze the flow of payments instead of the
flow of goods. This means that exporting countries will be recipients of payments for their exports, while
importing countries will be sources of payments for their imports. This methodology allows us to analyze the
influence of importing countries on exporting ones as influential buyers. We use the share of exports of
country A to country B out of the total exports of country A and construct binary matrices for different
magnitudes of trade. If country A’s exports to country B, out of the total exports of country A are greater or
equal to a given threshold, then the link B→A is present10. Our primary trade-link definition thus measures
export dependency.
As an illustration, Table 1 is the binary matrix for the first 10 countries in our sample when we use
the exports dependency ratio described and a trade-link threshold of 0% for 1992. For example, the link
between Algeria (source of payments) and Albania (recipient of payments) exists and the cell entry (source =
Algeria, Receiver = Albania) is 1, denoting that imports of Algeria from country Albania are greater than
zero11.
[Insert Table 1 here]
It is also important to note that the number of countries across the two years considered is not
constant. There are a total of 194 countries included in the analysis but only 189 existed in 1992 and 192 in
1998. The 1992 list excludes the Czech Republic, Eritrea, and Ethiopia, while the 1998 excludes
Czechoslovakia and Former Ethiopia. All the network indicators computed take this into consideration.
Alternatively, and as a robustness check, we let the columns of the trade matrix denote importing
countries and rows represent exporting ones and we analyze the flow of goods. In this case, we use the share
of imports of country A from country B out of the total imports of country A, which is a measure of import
dependency of country A on country B, to construct binary matrices for different magnitudes of trade. This
approach allows us to analyze the influence of exporting countries as influential suppliers. We find that the
results for both dependency measures are very similar, and in the following sections focus on the results
obtained using export dependency. We expand on the results obtained with the alternative import dependency
measure to define trade-links in Section IV, which applies the network indicators to economic growth.
10
11
The directed edge goes from B to A because B is the source of payment and A is the recipient of this payment.
Note that this also means that the exports from Albania to Algeria are also greater than zero.
5
III. A Network Approach to Measuring International Economic Integration.
III.I Network Overview
Just as nodes and links are the basic components of any network, node degree is the basic component
of complex network analysis. The degree is the number of links connected to a given node. For directed
networks we have two different measures, in-degree and out-degree. The first one deals with inbound links,
in other words how many times a specific node acts as a receiver. The second one deals with the outbound
links, counting how many times a specific node acts as a source. These two measurements provide an initial
overview of network structure. We can locate highly connected nodes, referred to sometimes as hubs, and by
looking at in- and out- degree measures separately, identify potentially influential receiver and source
countries. It is also possible to obtain an overall idea of how homogeneous the network is. In a homogeneous
network, flows are not dominated by a small group of nodes, implying that there should be no dominant nodes.
Since our data are on the dollar value of exports and imports, and we initially construct the network using
exporting countries as recipients of payments for their exports (in-degree) and importing countries as sources
of payments for their imports (out-degree), henceforth we use the more intuitive terms export-degree and
import-degree instead of in-degree and out-degree respectively. Using our binary matrix representation of the
network [as in Table 1], the export-degree of country i is calculated by summing up the links that are present
in column i, while the import-degree for country j corresponds to the summation of the links present in row j.
We construct the network and associated network measures for several different values of the tradelink threshold12. The zero percent threshold indicates the mere existence of trade among two countries and in
this sense it is the least restrictive threshold. It simply acknowledges the presence of positive trade. We
choose the one and two percent thresholds because eighty three percent of the trade shares in 1992 (eighty
seven percent in 1998) are between zero and one percent, and this number increases to eighty nine percent
when the range between zero and two percent is considered for the 1992 data (and to ninety two in 1998)13.
These thresholds embody higher levels of trade. The export and import degree of country i denote the number
12
The export and import degree results for all countries in the 1992 and 1998 trade networks at the 0, 0.5, 1 and 2
percent thresholds are not reported here for matters of space but are available upon request.
13
The reader should be alerted to the possibility that if trade flows over existing links increase substantially over time the
current approach could be problematic. Consider the case where the number of links is constant across time but the flow
has increased in such a way that the number of links that meet the threshold of two percent remains constant but a large
portion of these move from a range of two percent to a level of four percent. In this case our measures would not capture
these changes in trade flows. The percentages discussed in the text show that this is not the case as the number
(percentage) of links below one and two percent increase between 1992 and 1998. This suggests that in the data, the
number of trade shares above one and two percent are falling even though volume is rising. And this trend holds even
for higher thresholds, like five and ten percent.
6
of trading partners to which i exports to (i.e., i depends on for revenues) and from which i imports from (i.e.,
depend on i for revenues) respectively, that are active in the binary trade matrix for any given threshold14.
As the trade-link threshold is increased, the export and import degree distributions change, providing
insight into the structure of international trade. For relatively low levels of trade the degree distribution for
both imports and exports are similar. Most of the nodes have a relatively high export and import degree
which means that most of the countries have a large number of trade partners for both exports and imports.
But as the trade-link threshold is increased, the distribution of export-degree and import-degree changes
dramatically. The export-degree (number of countries exported to) falls considerably for all the nodes while
the import-degree (number of countries importing from) remains constant only for a very small group of
nodes (the G-7 appear in this group) and falls substantially for the others.
The export-degree change tells us that at higher levels, all the countries (G-7 included) export to a
relatively small number of partners – which turns out to be by and large the same set of countries, the G-7
plus Spain, Belgium and the Netherlands. These countries account for almost fifty percent of world imports.
The interpretation for the change in import degree is that for higher levels of trade, a small block of influential
countries import from most of the other 179 - 182 countries, while the rest only import from a small number
of countries. The asymmetric change of the import and export degree distributions imply that from the
imports (source of payments) perspective the network is quite skewed, but from the exports (receiver of
payments) perspective it is quite evenly distributed. The mean of the export-degree distribution is 9 countries
at the 2%, for 1992 and 1998, trade-link threshold and 13 and 15 countries at the 1% threshold in 1992 and
1998, respectively.
This pattern of inequality in the degree distribution can be visualized by computing Lorenz curves
and Gini coefficients. Figure 1 presents the Lorenz curves plots for the 1% and 2% thresholds and the Gini
coefficients derived from the deviation of the forty five degree line from each of the Lorenz curves. These
plots and numbers reveal that the 37 most connected countries (20% of the total countries) account for almost
80% of the outbound links in 1992 and 75% in 1998 at the 1% trade-link threshold. These numbers are almost
completely reversed for the inbound links, where the 37 (20% of the total countries) most connected countries
14
From an import degree perspective the maximum degree for all threshold levels is equal to the number of countries
included in the analysis minus one. For the export degree, this still holds for the zero and 0.5 percent threshold. But
given the criteria used to determine the presence of a link, the maximum export degree changes as the threshold
increases. For the 1 percent threshold the maximum export degree is 100 since the percentage of exports to all trading
partners cannot add up to be more than 100. Similarly logic explains why at the 2 percent threshold the upper bound for
export degree is 50. For the 0.5 percent threshold the upper bound is 200, but this is not an issue for the analysis since it
is more than the number of trading partners in our dataset (189 in 1992 and 192 in 1998).
7
account for only 30% of all inbound links, in 1992 and 199815. Similar results are obtained from the analysis
of the 2% trade-link threshold.
The 80/20 finding has special significance in the study of networks as it reflects the existence of a
Pareto distribution, as opposed to a random network where the distribution of node degree is random. This
kind of distribution is also often referred to as a power-law (exponential) distribution as the number of nodes
with degree k, N(k) follows a power law, i.e., N(k)~k-γ where γ is the degree exponent.
Power laws
mathematically formulate the fact that in many networks the majority of nodes have only a few links and that
these nodes coexist with a few big hubs, nodes with an anomalously high number of links. In contrast, for a
random network, the peak of the distribution implies that the majority of nodes have the same number of links.
Therefore a random network has a characteristic scale in its node connectivity, embodied in the average node
and fixed by the peak of the degree distribution. In contrast, the absence of a peak in a power-law distribution
implies that there is no such thing as characteristic node. In other words, there is no intrinsic scale in a powerlaw network. Such networks are therefore referred to as being scale-free16. The international trade network is
thus scale-free at higher levels of trade. This is especially interesting as it implies that it does not make much
sense to speak of a “typical” country in terms of the number of trading partners.
III.2. Measures of Integration
We now introduce more detailed measures of global and local integration.
A. Global Integration Measures
Centrality
Degree analysis suggests that the international trade network has a core-periphery configuration from
an imports perspective with the industrialized countries as the center of gravity. In this type of system the
countries at the core are the most influential nodes since shocks to the core will affect the whole network.
Another way to examine this feature of the network is through the notion of centrality. In many complex
networks, centrality is used as a measure of power and influence. According to Wasserman and Faust (1994),
central actors (nodes) must be the most active because they have the most ties to other actors (nodes). For our
trade network, we can compute node centrality and network centrality.
Node centrality measures how central a given node is with respect to the others while network
centrality measures how centralized the network is with respect to a perfectly centralized network. Here we
present the results on network centrality; we address individual node centrality in the section on local
15 Perfect equality, in this case perfect symmetry, would correspond to 37 countries (around twenty percent) accounting
for twenty percent of the in or outbound links.
16
A startling discovery from recent research on complex networks is that almost all complex networks in nature are
scale-free (see Albert and Barabasi, 2002).
8
measures of integration. We focus here and in the local measures section only on import-degree centrality
indices. There are two reasons for this. First, we already know from the node degree analysis that the exportdegree distribution is very homogenous. Therefore not much information would be added by analyzing the
differences in the export-degree centrality. Second, and more importantly, we are interested in understanding
which countries are influential importing countries in the international trade network.
In order to analyze the centrality of the international trade network from an imports perspective, we
compare it to a perfectly centralized network of the same size. A perfectly centralized network is one in
which only one node sends/receives to/from the other vertices. This is called a star network (the most
unequal possible network)17. Freeman (1979) proposes the following expression as a centralization index:
∑ [C
=
max ∑ [C
g
CI
d
max
i =1
− C D ( ni )
g
i =1
max
]
− C D ( ni ) ]
(2)
d
and Cmax represent the actual maximum degree centrality observed in the data for an
where C max
individual node and the theoretical maximum degree centrality for an individual node in a network with g
countries, and CD(ni) denotes the degree centrality of node i18 . The denominator in expression (2) is the
summation for the star network, and equals (g-1)(g-2) where g denotes the number of nodes in the network.
The degree centrality of an individual node can be simply represented by its degree d (ni ) but a more
standard way is to normalize the individual node centrality in the following fashion,
C D ( ni ) =
d ( ni )
g −1
(2.1)
The Centralization Index, C I , thus measures the degree of variability in the degrees of nodes in the
network as a percentage of that in the star network of the same size.
The way in which the star-like configuration of the import-degree international trade network evolves
between 1992 and 1998 provides information regarding the proportion of countries that have moved toward
or away from the center of gravity. With the increasing volume of international trade observed during the
nineties and the opening of countries like China and former Soviet-bloc countries, it is conceivable that the
international trade network has been becoming less of a star-like network. This would result in a lower level
of influence for the G-7 countries and the emergence of a number of other influential countries that previously
belonged to the periphery.
17
In a star network, all nodes but one have an export/import degree of one except for the central node which has an
export/import degree equal to the number of nodes in the network minus one.
18
A more in depth discussion of degree centrality for an individual node is in the section of Local Measures of
Integration. Note also that there are two other measures of centrality, Betweenness (Freeman 1977) and Closeness
(Sabidussi, 1966). We use the current measure on account of its simplicity as compared to the others and because it
seems better suited to the notion of the “core” of a network in the context of international trade than the others.
9
Table 2 presents the results for the import-degree network centralization index19. This index shows us
that for the lowest trade-link threshold of 0%, the network centralization index for import-degree is around
56% for the period of 1992 and 42% for 1998. In other words, the network is not very centralized. As we
move to higher thresholds, such as 0.5%, 1%, and 2%, we observe dramatic changes that are in line with those
obtained from the node degree distribution analysis. As the threshold increases, the imports network becomes
extremely centralized. That is, a small group of countries are destinations for the bulk of imports which come
from (i.e., are exports from) a large number of countries in the network. We could refer the former group of
countries as the core and the latter group as the periphery. The comparisons of these indices across time
imply that the core-periphery structure did not change noticeably over the nineties and a relatively small
number of countries still constitute the core of the network, a core that is likely to exercise an enormous
amount of influence on the periphery. We provide specific measures of influence later in the section.
Network Density
Node degree and centrality analyses are useful because they allow us to identify the presence or
absence of a center of gravity for the network and give us an overview of the structure and configuration of
the network as a whole. But these indicators do not directly address how integrated the network as a whole
really is. One way to start examining the extent of global integration of the network is to measure the
proportion of all possible links (trading relationships) that are actually present in the network. This ratio is
called network density.
The maximum number of edges for a network is determined by
E max =
E D max
g ( g − 1)
2
= g ( g − 1)
where Emax and E D max denote the maximum number of edges/links for an undirected and a directed
graph, respectively and g is the number of nodes. The density of a directed network, like the international
trade network, is simply the ratio of the links actually present to the maximum possible, E D max .
∆D =
L
g ( g − 1)
(3)
where L stands for the number of links present in the network.
The density calculations for the international trade network are also presented in Table 2. It is
important to keep in mind that as the threshold increases, the maximum number of potential links decreases.
For example, when the threshold used is one percent, the maximum number of countries to which a given
19
Calculated using UCINET software package, specifically Freeman’s degree centrality measures routine.
10
D
country can export is one hundred, therefore the maximum number of possible links, E max
, is determined by
g⋅100 instead of g⋅ (g-1). The results in Table 2 show, as expected given the previous results regarding a
core/periphery structure, that network density drops as the threshold is increased. The results across years
allow us to compare changes in economic integration. For the period of 1992 – 1998, network density
increased by 35% at the 0% threshold and 15% at the 0.5 % threshold. At higher thresholds, density
increased as well but by a smaller margin; 9% and 4% respectively for the 1% and 2% thresholds. Once again,
the implication is that international economic integration measured this way increased much more at lower
levels of trade.
Clustering
The 1990’s have been a booming era for international trade agreements like the NAFTA,
MERCOSUR, and the EU. In light of these preferential trade arrangements, an interesting question is the
extent to which trading partners of a particular country are also linked to each other. This corresponds to the
analysis of the proportion of multilateral trade relationships relative to bilateral ones. In a more globalized
world the share of multilateral relations relative to bilateral ones should be higher than in a more balkanized
world.
In terms of network topology, the extent of multilateralism can been seen through the property of
network transitivity, sometimes also called clustering. In many networks it is found that if node A is
connected to node B and node B to node C, then there is a heightened probability that node A will also be
connected to node C. Clustering thus measures the probability that “the partner of my partner is also my
partner” and provides insight into what is referred to as the neighborhood structure of the network.
Transitivity in network topology means the presence of a heightened number of triangles in the network – sets
of three nodes each of which is connected to each of the others. This can be quantified by defining a
clustering coefficient, C, (Watts and Strogatz, 1998), which is the mean probability that two neighbors of a
given node are also neighbors of each other and can be expressed as the proportion of triples that form a
triangle out of all the triples present in the network20.
3 × Number of triangles
C=
0 ≤ C ≤1
number of connected triples
20
For example a complete triple (triangle) would be A→B, A→C and B→C and/or C→B, and connected triple can be
just A→B, A→C. The factor of 3 accounts for the fact that each triangle contributes to three triples and ensures that
0≤C≤1. See Newman (2003).
11
where a “connected triple” means a single node with links running to an unordered pair of others. In
effect, C measures the fraction of triples that have their third link filled in to complete the triangle. In terms
of the international trade network, C is the mean probability that two countries that are linked to the same
third country are also linked to each other. Note that since our trade-link definition is directional, C is
computed on the basis of these directional links. Thus a triangle with links A to B, B to C, and C to A is
different from a triangle with A to C, B to A and B to C.
The results for the international trade network presented in Table 2 show that the clustering
coefficient is 0.41 at the 2% threshold for the 1998 network and is very high at all thresholds. Moreover, the
clustering coefficient has remained practically constant between 1992 and 1998. The implication of this is that
both the number of complete triangles and triples increased proportionally. This suggests that the extent of
multilateralism has remained fairly high across the time period of our data.
Assortative Mixing
We examine country specific characteristics to investigate the existence of trade patterns driven by
similarities between countries. In network terminology, the presence of such patterns is referred to as
assortative mixing and community structure (Newman, 2003). If countries that share similar characteristics
trade more between themselves than with countries that do not, then it can be concluded that the international
trade network is an assortative network and that there is a definite pattern of preferential attachment. The
specific characteristics that we use to partition the data are income level, region and legal origin21. Such
patterns seem particularly relevant given current globalization debates and allow us to view IEI from a
number of different angles. For example, if high income countries trade with other high income countries
twice as much today relative to previous years, and less with low income countries, we could say that the
network as a whole is becoming more “balkanized” rather than more “globalized” along the income
dimension. If more trade occurs between instead of within groups, then this could be considered evidence of
a more economically integrated system.
While the rationale for examining assortativity in the data along income and geographical region are
fairly obvious, the rationale for using legal origin is the idea, emphasized by Rodrik (2000) and others, that
transaction costs associated with contractual enforcement owing to differences in legal systems can be a major
impediment to trade. Legal origin (La Porta et al. 1998, Shleifer and Glaeser, 2002) has been found to exert
an important impact on many developmental outcomes.
Newman (2003) shows that assortative mixing can be quantified by the following assortativity
coefficient,
21
The countries are grouped according to the World Bank classification of income, the WTO classification for Regions
and Legal Origin.
12
∑ e −∑ a b
r=
1− ∑ a b
i
ii
i
=
i i
i
Tr (e) − e 2
1 − e2
i i
(4)
where e is the matrix containing the elements eij, which is defined to be the fraction of links in a network that
connect a vertex of type i (i.e. region 1) to one of type j (i.e. region 2), e means the sum of all elements of
the matrix e. ai and bi are the fraction of each type of end of a link that is attached to nodes of type i. If r = 0,
then we conclude that there is no assortative mixing. If r =1, the network is said to be perfectly assortative,
and if the network is disassortative then r is negative and its value is determined by,
rmin = −
∑ab
1− ∑ a b
i i
i
i
,
i i
which will generally lie in the range of − 1 ≤ r < 0 .
[Table 3 here]
The results for the assortativity coefficient obtained for the variously partitioned data sets, presented
in Table 3, show evidence of relatively high assortativity in international trade from a regional perspective.
For this partition of the network the assortativity coefficient, r, is positive and has increased over time,
between 1992 and 1998. This implies that over the nineties trading relationships have been predominantly
established or strengthened between countries of the same region. In particular, a closer look at the data
shows that the trading relationships within African countries and within CES countries increased significantly,
as well as the trading activities of these two groups with the rest of the regions22. Additionally, Table 3 also
presents the assortativity coefficients based on income and on legal origin partitions of the network. These
numbers suggest that preferential attachment within countries of the same group, but the degree of
assortativity is not as strong as in the case of regional partitions and the mixing patterns have not changed
significantly during the nineties.
Degree Correlation
Assortative mixing on the basis of a scalar characteristic such as node degree is known as degree
correlation. This measure determines whether there is preferential attachment between high-degree nodes
and low-degree nodes, or if there is preferential attachment between low and high degree nodes, referred to as
disassortative mixing. Newman (2003) shows that it is possible to compute the degree correlation coefficient
simply by calculating the Pearson correlation coefficient of the degrees at either ends of a link. This
22
Density changes are not presented here for reasons of space, but are available upon request from the authors.
13
calculation should give a positive number for assortatively mixed networks and negative for disassortative
ones.
The results for the degree correlation coefficient, presented in Table 2, show that the international
trade network is a disassortative network. High degree countries trade with low degree countries, and vice
versa. In other words, countries with lots of trading partners trade with countries with few trade partners.
This could be interpreted as yet another manifestation of the core-periphery structure of the global trade
network.
It is worth noting that these results should not be interpreted as a contradiction of our previous
assortative mixing results. In this case there are no groupings of nodes according to some specific attribute.
Degree correlation only records the node degree (number of trading partners) at both ends of each link and
then calculates the correlation between both series. The disassortative mixing result should thus not be
surprising from an economics perspective. International trade relations are not determined by the number of
trading partners that each country has. They are based on structural or natural characteristics like natural
resources and cultural, social, or geographical attributes that lead to comparative advantage.
B. Local Integration Measures
International trade to GDP ratios and individual country shares of international trade out of total
world trade are two indicators that have frequently been used as measures of a country’s degree of openness.
These measures do not take into consideration important features implicit in international trade linkages, like
the number and importance of trading partners and the specific configuration of the international trade
network. By not doing so they over or underestimate a country’s degree of economic integration and cannot
be used to make arguments about the influence that a given country can exercise on others. Recent advances
in complex network analysis offer a variety of tools that can be used to measure the degree of economic
integration at the individual country level.
Node Degree Centrality
The number of in and out-bound links will ultimately determine the connectivity of an individual
node, but there are different ways in which this connectivity can be measured. The simplest of these
measures is Node Degree Centrality. Equation (2.1) shows how it is possible to calculate an index for node
degree centrality. This index can show which countries are at the core or close to the core of the network. If a
country is at the core of the network then its node degree centrality will be close to one. For a periphery
country, this number will be close to zero, given that the number of international trade linkages is relatively
small.
14
In Table A1, included in the data appendix, we report the import-degree centrality indices for the 0, 1
and 2 % thresholds for the years of 1992 and 1998 for all the countries in our sample23. Higher numbers
indicate more central countries.
For the same reasons as explained in the overall network centrality
discussion, we present only import-degree centrality indices.
As expected, the industrialized economies are part of the core of the network from an imports
perspective, ranking in the top 20 for the different thresholds and periods considered. These numbers
corroborate the finding that the centrality of the network has not changed significantly over the nineties since
very few countries have dramatically increased their centrality indices. In essence, when the top twenty five
countries from the 1992 data are compared with the top twenty five of 1998, very few changes are observed.
Countries such as Brazil, South Korea, Indonesia, Malaysia, Mexico, the Russian Federation,
Thailand, and Turkey are among the top thirty (some in the top fifteen) most central countries in the
international trade network. This is especially noteworthy since these countries have been at the epicenter of
several financial, currency and balance of payments crises and contagion episodes of the nineties. This is
suggestive of the importance of international trade linkages for financial contagion (Forbes, 2001;
Abeysinghe and Forbes, 2002).
For comparison across methodologies, Table A1 in the data appendix presents the share of total
international trade (imports plus exports) out of total world trade and the ratio of total trade to GDP for all the
countries considered. In the interests of brevity we do not present country rankings according to these indices,
but there are significant differences when country rankings obtained with these indicators are compared with
those that are obtained when we rank countries according to node degree centrality.
Node Influence or Importance
Node degree centrality provides a preliminary approach to the identification of influential nodes. It is
based on the number of countries that can be reached through direct links by an individual country. But it
misses important features of the international trade network. The number of trading partners is a relevant
statistic, but the specific characteristics of these trading partners may amplify or dampen the influence that a
specific country has on others and on the whole network. One could say that it is not only the quantity of
your partners that matter for influence, but also how influential they are in turn. If country A trades with
country B and B trades with fifty other countries, then A exerts indirect influence on these fifty countries.
In a prominent paper, Salancik (1986) argues that “Accurate assessments of the structural power of
several interdependent parties are hampered by the fact that parties depend on one another indirectly as well
as directly and that any one’s dependencies are not equally important for all parties.” He goes on to propose
an index for dependency networks in which nodes are defined as more important if others nodes depend more
23
Calculated using UCINET software.
15
on them and if the other nodes depending on them are themselves important. Applying his index to our
context, the importance of country i is a function of the dependence of other nodes on i and the importance of
these other nodes.
imp (i ) = ∑ dep (ij ) imp j + iv( i )
for all j ≠ i
(6)
j
where imp ( i ) is the importance of country i , dep ( ij ) is the extent to which country i is depended upon by
country j, and iv(i) denotes the intrinsic value of country i. Equation (6), which represents a system of i
equations, determines that if a country is not depended upon by other countries, then this country will be
unimportant. Also, if a country is depended upon only by unimportant countries, then it would also be
considered unimportant. For the intrinsic value of country i we consider three alternatives, no specific value
(Intrinsic Value, IV=1), the share of total trade of country i (exports plus imports) out of total world trade
(with Intrinsic Value =Trade Share) and the ratio of the GDP per capita of country i with respect to that of the
US (with Intrinsic Value =GDP ratio).24
Equation (6) can be rewritten in matrix form as follows,
IMPi = [D]ij * IMPi + IVi
(7)
where [D]ij denotes the matrix of dependencies of each country j on each country i. For the international trade
network exporting countries depend on the importing ones. Therefore the elements of [D]ij are the share of
exports of country j to country i out of the total exports of country j. This is essentially the same matrix that
has been used in the calculation of all the measures reported so far, but in this case there is no need for the
threshold analysis. By solving the system of equations, denoted by equation (7), it is possible to determine
the importance of an individual country relative to the 194 other countries included in the study 25. The
importance indices thus computed take into consideration volumes of trade and the number and importance of
all trading partners.
[Table 4 here]
Table 4 shows the results for the top thirty countries, according to importance in 1998, but the indices
for all one hundred and ninety four countries are included in Table A1, located in the data appendix.
Importance index measures for the three different approaches to “intrinsic” value of a country described
24
These trade shares were calculated using the same trade data used for the network indicators and for the countries
where the GDP per capita was not available the intrinsic value was set equal to zero.
25
From matrix algebra, the solution to equation (7) requires the existence of [I-D]-1 for which the columns of D should
not all sum to one. This requires that there be at least one member of the network who does not depend only on other
network members for some of the resources transacted through the network. This condition is satisfied for our network
because, as mentioned in footnote 9, our trade network is not all-inclusive but the total exports and total imports are
computed from the all-inclusive database. Therefore we have some countries for which the trade network data does not
capture all international trade (in average we capture 90 to 95% of all trade). The reader is referred to Salancik (1986) for
a detailed discussion of the properties of the importance measure.
16
above are reported. It is worth noticing that country rankings according to importance are starkly different
from those obtained when countries are ranked by the ratio of total trade to GDP. The correlation between
importance index (with Intrinsic Value = GDP ratio) and the ratio of total trade to GDP is 0.14, and between
the same importance index and GDP is 0.79. This suggests that the importance results are not solely driven by
wealth effects; there are consequential network effects26.
IV. Application to Economic Growth
This section illustrates the usefulness of the local integration indicators discussed above by
introducing them in a growth accounting exercise where the objective is to determine the effect of
international economic integration, sometimes referred to as “openness”, on economic growth. Harrison
(1996), Frankel and Romer (1999), Irwin and Trevio (2002), and Yanikkaya (2003), among others, have used
different indicators and methodologies, based on volumes of trade, in order to examine the relationship
between openness and growth.
Most of these studies consider a long-run growth model where a country’s
GDP or income per capita growth rate ( γ y ) is a function of initial GDP conditions (yI), physical capital (k),
human capital (h), and a vector of control variables (Z) that represent country specific characteristics (degree
of openness, geographical, and political characteristics).
γ y = F ( y I , k , h; Z )
(8)
Following Harrison (1996) and Yanikkaya (2003), we use data from the World Development
Indicators of the World Bank to calculate GDP per capita growth rates. Initial GDP per capita levels are
obtained from the Penn Tables Mark 5.6. Life expectancy and telephone lines/1000 data, obtained from
Easterly and Lu’s Global Development Network Growth Database27, are used as proxy variables for human
and physical capital, respectively. Political regime and war deaths data is also obtained from Easterly and Yu.
The geographical control variables included in the study are physical access to international waters and
tropical climate, both obtained from the Sachs and Warner dataset28.
For the degree of openness two types of variables have been considered in the literature. The first
category includes indicators based on volumes of trade, like total trade (imports plus exports), the ratio of
total trade (imports plus exports) to GDP, and total trade with OECD countries and non-OECD countries. The
26
Similar conclusions are reached with the centrality indicators. The correlation of the centrality index, at the one
percent threshold, with the ratio of total trade to GDP is - 0.07 and 0.58 with GDP.
27 http://www.worldbank.org/research/growth/GDNdata.htm
28
Sachs and Warner data set is published on the Center for International Development Web site accessible from
http://www.cid.harvard.edu/
17
other category includes indicators based on trade restrictions, like tariffs, export duties and taxes on
international trade in general.
We use total trade to GDP ratio as the control variable for economic openness and compare these
results to those obtained when we add the local integration measures, namely importance, maximum flow and
degree centrality.
Harrison (1996) and Yanikkaya (2002) estimate the following equation,
γ y = β 0 + β1 y I + β 2 h + β 3 k + β 4Tropical + β 5Water
(9)
+ β 6 Political + β 7War + β 8 Open + ε t
and report a positive and strong relationship between trade shares in GDP and economic growth 29 .
Specifically Yannikkaya (2000), through a panel regression analysis spanning over three decades (70’s, 80’s
and 90’s), concludes that the coefficients (and their signs) for initial GDP conditions (-), human (+) and
physical (+) capital, climate (-), and the total trade to GDP ratio (+) are strongly significant (at the one and
five percent level) and robust, while those for the political regime (-), war deaths (-) and the physical access to
international waters (-) are weakly significant (at the ten percent level).
Due to limited data availability for the international trade network we only have network indicators
for 1992 and 1998. Therefore we cannot follow Yanikkaya’s three period panel regression approach. We
consider the data for 1987 to 1998 and divide the data into the periods 1987 - 1992 and 1993 - 1998. We
average the variables for these two sample periods and perform a panel regression where the 1992 local
integration indicators are used for the 1987 – 1992 sample and the 1998 indicators are used for the 1993 –
1998 sample.
Our results are presented in Table 5. Column (1), which corresponds to the regression that uses the
total trade to GDP ratio as the control variable for openness, shows that changing the panel regression from a
three decade approach to the two sub-samples of 1987 – 1992 and 1993 – 1998 does not affect the results
obtained by Yanikkaya. The coefficient for total trade to GDP ratio (+) is statistically significant while the
other coefficients and their signs are also in line with his findings30. The rest of the columns in Table 5 show
the results obtained when the IEI indicators are included in the analysis. These indicators incorporate network
based measures of IEI for each country that embody more than just trade volumes. They capture a country’s
relevance for the international trade network, whether it is at the center or the periphery of the trade network,
29 Yanikkaya (2002) uses the natural log of GDP as y and the natural log of life expectancy as h. The regressions in this
I
study, discussed below, use these transformations as well.
30
Our results show a positive sign for the control variable for access to international waters, while in Yannikkaya (2000)
the sign is negative. This is explained by the definition of the variable. We use the proportion of land with access to
international waters, while Yannikkaya uses the proportion of landlocked land. We did not include war deaths in our
regression given that there is no data available for the late nineties.
18
and the magnitude of the direct and indirect effects it has on other countries. For the regressions we use the
country rankings for each of the local integration indicators, where a lower number (higher ranking) denotes
higher degree centrality and importance 31 . Therefore we expect negative signs for these variables in the
regression results. As a country drops in the rankings, its relevance or its extent of IEI falls and therefore the
advantages from trade and its positive effects on economic growth diminish accordingly.
[Table 5 here]
Column (2) presents the result for the econometric specification that includes the importance indicator
with constant intrinsic value (i.e. with Intrinsic Value =1) as the IEI variable while excluding the total trade to
GDP ratio. Columns (3) through (8) show the results obtained when other IEI indicators were used in the
analysis while always including the total trade to GDP ratio. Columns (9) and (10) explore the possibility of
the IEI indicators interacting with the level of physical and human capital. As a robustness check, columns
(11) through (14) present the results obtained when we analyze the flow of goods and the import dependency
measure, share of imports of country i from country j out of country i’s imports, is used to compute the
network indicators instead of the export dependency measure, exports of i to country j out of the total exports
of country i.
The results of Table 5 show that the local integration indicators are statistically significant and have
the expected negative sign. They posses explanatory power individually, when they are included as the sole
control variable for economic integration32, and they add information to the economic growth regression when
they are considered in conjunction with the total trade to GDP ratio. Moreover, the effect of higher centrality
in the network is quite striking. For example, column (8) reports that an increase in the centrality ranking of
10 units at the two percent trade-link threshold increases the average growth rate of per capita GDP by 1.11
percentage points. A country’s position in the network can thus have substantial implications for economic
growth.
A more in-depth analysis of the results of Table 5 uncovers a possible relationship between the
position of a country in the network and measures of physical and human capital that are included in the
estimated equation. When the local integration indicators are introduced into the regression analysis, with and
without the trade openness measure, the magnitude and the statistical significance of physical capital
decreases while those for the level of human capital increase. Regarding geographical characteristics, climate
31
In the regression we use country rankings instead of the raw indices computed for two reasons. First the degree of fit
of the regression is better with the ranking data. This leads to the second reason. In many cases the centrality or
importance indices increase for a given country, but its ranking actually decreases. The fact that the ranking data gives a
better degree of fit suggests that network effects are relative and not absolute, i.e. what matters is the relative position in
the network. The general conclusions obtained with the rankings data hold when the regression analysis is carried out
with the raw indices, but for matters of space these are not presented in the paper but are available upon request.
32
The coefficient for importance (IV=1) in column (2) is negative and statistically significant. This result holds for all
the other local integration indicators used in the analysis, but individual results are not presented for matters of space.
19
and access to water, we find that their explanatory power in the regression is also diminished when the local
measures of integration are included.
Specifically, t-tests show that the human capital coefficients for some of the regressions that include
the network measures of IEI are greater (statistically) than the one observed in regression (1). The coefficients
on physical capital and the geographical variables (climate and access to water) are statistically significant in
regression (1) but become statistically insignificant in a number of regressions that include the IEI indicators.
These patterns suggest that a higher ranking in the centrality and importance indices diminishes the effects
that country-specific characteristics (region, climate and technology) have on growth. A more integrated
country is able to make up for the lack of good location and relevant technological improvements by being
better connected in the network, i.e. physical capital and IEI are substitutes. And by being better connected,
the positive effects of human capital on growth are amplified, i.e. human capital and IEI are complements. An
interpretation of this result could be that human capital productivity is enhanced by international economic
integration since a more integrated country offers greater growth opportunities to individuals.
To test these conjectures more carefully we introduce the IEI indicators through an interaction term.
We consider the case for importance (with Intrinsic Value = GDP ratio) and centrality, at the one percent
threshold, and interact them with physical and human capital. However, the results, presented in columns (9)
and (10), are not conclusive since the statistical significance of the coefficients is not consistent across the two
regressions. The coefficient of the interaction term between human capital and the IEI indicators is only
significant when the IEI indicator is the importance indicator, while for the interaction term between physical
capital and IEI the coefficient is only significant when centrality is used as the IEI indicator. This suggests
that the measured effect of international economic integration on economic growth may vary with the kind of
IEI measure used. The importance of a country, which is a measure of how influential the country is, may
interact differently with human and physical capital as compared to the manner in which the centrality of a
country within the network interacts with physical and human capital. These differences in the interaction
affects are intriguing and emphasize that the specific channels through which connectivity affects economic
growth warrant deeper investigation. The overall conclusion that international economic integration matters
for economic growth still continues to hold.
As a robustness check, we compute all the network indicators (global and local) with the alternative
approach of following the flow of goods instead of cash. The results are very similar to those obtained with
the original approach (export dependency) and therefore are not discussed or reported on in detail. In this case
the columns of the trade matrix denote importing countries, while rows correspond to exporting countries33.
33
In this case, from an export degree perspective the maximum degree for all threshold levels is equal to the number of
countries included in the analysis minus one. For the import degree, this still holds for the zero and 0.5 percent
20
The network is again, extremely centralized with a network export degree (i.e out-degree) centrality, at the
one percent threshold, of 87.25% in 1992 and 85.15% in 1998. Implying again a core-periphery structure,
where the core once again includes the G-7 countries as the most influential nodes (suppliers) in the network.
The similarities across the local measures of integration of both dependency measures can be observed in
Table A1. This table reports the indices obtained for the importance indicator (with Intrinsic Value=GDP
ratio) and the centrality indicator at the one percent threshold for both dependency measures. Moreover, the
correlation between the columns is 0.98 and 0.96, respectively34.
The regression results also match fairly well. Columns (11) through (14) present the results for the
case where the network indicators are computed using import dependency. The numbers reported show that
there are no noticeable differences from the results previously discussed. The network indicators increase the
explanatory power of the regression and the complementarities between the network indicators and human
capital still hold.
V.
Discussion
We have attempted to chart the international trading system explicitly as a network and examine its
structure and function from such a perspective. This has enabled us to obtain a clearer understanding of the
structure of the global trading system and construct measures of international economic integration at both the
global, system-wide level and at a local, country-level. While these metrics are implicitly based on the
volume of international trade, they add new dimensions to the analysis of global integration that have not
been previously considered and offer a new approach to describing local, country level integration into the
global network.
As a preliminary application we use our measures of network importance in a cross-country growth
regression. Using these new measures we find evidence consistent with the hypothesis that a country’s
position in the network has substantial implications for economic growth, but the specific channels through
which connectivity affects economic growth requires deeper analysis. We believe that more detailed research
into the relationship between human capital, physical capital, international economic integration and
economic growth is warranted.
The literature on financial contagion (Kaminsky and Reinhart, 2000, 2003; Forbes, 2001, Forbes and
Rigobon, 2002) continues to puzzle over why many of the recent crises that began in relatively small
economies had such global repercussions and why shocks originating in one economy spread to some markets,
while markets in other countries were relatively unaffected.
We find that ranking countries according to
threshold. But given the criteria used to determine the presence of a link, the maximum import degree changes as the
threshold increases. The reasoning for this follows from the arguments discussed in footnote 14.
34
The validity of the 1% and 2% thresholds for the import dependency measure is based on the same criteria used to
justify these thresholds for the export dependency measures.
21
measures of “importance” to the network may provide insight into why and how financial crises are
propagated than simple volume-based measures. For example, using 1992 data to construct the international
trade network, we find that Thailand, a country which was the epicenter of the 1997-98 Asian financial crisis,
ranks 22nd in terms of global trade share but 12th by our measure of network “importance”. In other words,
network based measures identify several of the countries behind the financial crises and contagion of the
1990’s as highly influential countries, with a number of them even ranking above G-7 countries in terms of
influence in the network.
We thus believe that a network approach that is capable of incorporating the cascading of
interdependent ripples that happens when a shock hits a specific part of the network will provide us with a
deeper understanding of economic and financial contagion. It is also possible that such network-based
measures may have real policy relevance in terms of identifying countries that are potentially vulnerable
nodes for the entire network in case of economic and financial collapse. In a separate paper (Kali and Reyes,
2005) we examine this question in more detail by using these network measures of country-level and global
integration as the backbone upon which to explore transmission mechanisms for international financial crises.
In Kali and Reyes (2005) we use network-based measures of connectedness to explain stock market returns
during recent episodes of financial crisis. We find that a crisis is amplified if the crisis epicenter country is
better integrated into the trade network. However, target countries affected by such a shock are in turn better
able to dissipate the impact if they are well integrated into the network. This arguably leads to a better
understanding of why the Mexican, Asian and Russian financial crises were highly contagious, while the
crises that originated in Venezuela and Argentina did not have such a virulent effect.
In conclusion, we believe a network approach to international economic integration may have useful
applications, both academic and policy, in several areas of international business, finance and development.
22
References
Abeysinghe, T. and Forbes, K. (2002), “Trade Linkages and Output-Multiplier Effects: A Structural VAR
Approach with a Focus on Asia.” Forthcoming in the Review of International Economics.
Albert, A. and A. L. Barabasi, (2002), “Statistical Mechanics of Complex Networks”, Reviews of Modern
Physics 74, 47.
Bhagwati, J. (2004), In Defense of Globalization, Oxford University Press.
Borgatti, S.P., Everett, M.G. and Freeman, L.C. 2002. Ucinet 6 for Windows. Harvard: Analytic Technologies.
Feenstra, R. (1998), “Integration of Trade and Disintegration of Production in the Global Economy,” Journal
of Economic Perspectives, 12(4): 31-50.
Feenstra, R., Huang, D-S. and, G. Hamilton (2003), “A Market-Power Based Model of Business Groups,”
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 51, 2003: 459-485.
Forbes, K. (2001), “Are Trade Linkages Important Determinants of Country Vulnerability to Crises,” In
Sebastian Edwards and Jeffrey Frankel, eds., Preventing Currency Crises in Emerging Markets. University of
Chicago Press, Chicago, pgs. 77-124.
Forbes, K. and M. Chinn, (2004), “A Decomposition of Global Linkages in Financial Markets Over
Time,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 86(3): 705-722.
Forbes, K. and R. Rigobon, (2002), “No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market
Comovements,” Journal of Finance, 57(5), pgs. 2223-2261.
Freeman, L. C. (1979), “Centrality in Social Networks: Conceptual clarification.” Social Networks 1, 215239.
Frankel, J. A. (1997), “Regional Trading Blocks in the World Trading System,” Washington DC: Institute of
International Economics.
Frankel, J.A. and D. Romer, (1999) “Does Trade Cause Growth?,” American Economic Review, 89(3) :379 –
399.
Frankel, J. A., E. Stein and S. Wei, (1995), “Trading Blocs and the Americas: the Natural, the Unnatural and
the Supernatural,” Journal of Development Economics, 47(1):61 – 95.
Freeman, L. C. (1977) A set of measures of centrality based on betweenness. Sociometry 40, 35--41.
Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. and B. Sacerdote (2002), “An Economic Approach to Social Capital,” Economic
Journal 112(483): 437-58.
Gomory, R. E. and T. C. Hu, (1964) “Synthesis of a communication network,” Journal of SIAM (Applied
Math), 12, 348
.
Granovetter, M. (1985), "Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness," American
Journal of Sociology, 91 (3): 481-510.
23
Harrison, A. (1996) “Openness and Growth: A Time Series, Cross-Country Analysis for Developing
Countries,” Journal of Development Economics, 48, 419 – 447.
Hanneman, R.A. (2001) “Introduction to Social Network Methods,” Mimeo. University of California,
Riverside.
International Monetary Fund, (2002) “IMF World Economic Outlook: Trade and Financial Integration,”
World Economic and Financial Surveys, September, 2002.
Irwin, D. (1996), “The United States in a New World Economy? A Century’s Perspective,” American
Economic Review, 86: 41-46, May 1996.
Irwin, D. and M. Trevio (2002) “Does Trade Raise Income? Evidence from the Twentieth Century,” Journal
of International Economics, 58, 1 – 18.
Kali, R. and J. Reyes (2005b), “Financial Contagion on the International Trade Network,” Working Paper,
University of Arkansas.
Kaminsky, G. and C. Reinhart (2003), “The Center and the Periphery: The Globalization of Financial
Shocks,” NBER Working Paper 9479.
Kaminsky, G. and C. Reinhart (2000), “On Crisis, Contagion and Confusion,” Journal of International
Economics, Vol. 51 No. 1, June 2000, 145-168.
Krugman, P. (1995) “Growing World Trade: Causes and Consequences,” Brookings Papers on Economic
Activity, No. 1, 327-62.
La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1998), “Law and Finance,” Journal of
Political Economy,” 106: 1113-55.
Newman, M.E.J. (2003), “Mixing Patterns in Networks”, Phys. Rev. E 67, 026126.
Newman, M. E. J. (2003), “The Structure and Function of Complex Networks”, SIAM Review 45, 167-256.
Putnam, R. (2000), Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community, NY. Simon and
Schuster.
Rauch, J.E. and A.Casella (2001) (eds.), Networks and Markets, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 2001.
Rodrik, D. (1998), “Why do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?,” Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 106, No. 5, 1998.
Rodrik, D. (2000), “How Far Will International Economic Integration Go?” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 14(1): 177-186.
Rodrik, D., A. Submranain and F. Trebbi (2002), “Institutions Rule: The Primacy of Institutions Over
Geography and Integration in Economic Development” Mimeo, Harvard.
Sabidussi, G. (1966) The centrality index of a graph. Pyschometrika 31, 581--603.
24
Salancik, G. (1986), "An Index of Subgroup Influence in Dependency Networks,” Administrative Science
Quarterly, vol. 31, 194-211
Sachs, J. and A. Warner, (1995), “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings
Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1995, No. 1. 25th Anniversary Issue: 1-118.
Shleifer, A. and E. Glaeser, (2002), “Legal Origins,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(4): 1193-1191.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2002), Globalization and Its Discontents, W.W. Norton & Company.
Waserman, S. and C. Faust, (1994), Social Network Analysis, Cambridge University Press, 1994.
Watts, D. J. and S. H. Strogatz. (1998) “Collective Dynamics of ‘Small-World’ Networks”, Nature 393:440442.
Watts, D. J. (1999), Small Worlds: The Dynamics of Networks between Order and Randomness, Princeton
University Press.
World Bank (1998), “1998 World Development Indicators” World Bank.
Yanikkaya, H. (2003), “Trade Openness and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Empirical Investigation,”
Journal of Development Economics, 72, 57 – 89.
Zuckerman, E. (2003), “On Networks and Markets by Rauch and Casella, eds.” Journal of Economic
Literature, 41: 545-565.
25
FIGURE 1: LORENZ CURVES AND GINI COEFFICIENTS FOR EXPORT AND IMPORT
DEGREE DISTRIBUTIONS
EXPORT DEGREE
IMPORT DEGREE
Lorent Curves of Imports Degree Distribution at the
1% threshold
1.00
0.90
Gini Coefficient:
0.80
for 1992: 0.22
0.70
for 1998: 0.21
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
0.01 0.12 0.23 0.34
% of links
% of links
Lorenz Curves of Exports - Degree Distribution at the
1% threshold
1992
1998
45 degree
0.45
0.55
0.66
0.77
0.88
0.99
1.00
0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
0.01
Gini Coefficient:
for 1992: 0.79
for 1998: 0.75
1992
1998
45 degree
0.12
0.23
0.34
% of countries
% of links
% of links
1992
1998
45 degree
0.45
0.55
0.55
0.66
0.77
0.88
0.99
Lorenz Curves of Imports Degree Distribution at the
2% threshold
Lorenz Curves of Exports Degree Distribution at the
2% threshold
1.00
0.90
Gini Coefficient:
0.80
for 1992: 0.20
0.70
for 1998: 0.20
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
0.01 0.12 0.23 0.34
0.45
% of countries
0.66
0.77
0.88
0.99
% of countries
1.00
0.90
0.80
0.70
0.60
0.50
0.40
0.30
0.20
0.10
0.00
0.01
Gini Coefficient:
for 1992: 0.83
for 1998: 0.80
1992
1998
45 degree
0.12
0.23
0.34
0.45
0.55
% of countries
26
0.66
0.77
0.88
0.99
TABLE 1.
PARTIAL BINARY MATRIX FOR ZERO PERCENT
THRESHOLD IN 1992
I
M
P
O
R
T
E
R
S
Afghanistan
Albania
Algeria
Andorra
Angola
Barbuda
Argentina
Armenia
Aruba
Australia
.
.
.
Afghanistan
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
1
Albania
0
0
1
0
0
0
1
0
0
1
E X P O R T E R S
Algeria Andorra Angola Antigua and Barbuda Argentina
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
1
0
1
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
0
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
1
0
0
0
1
Armenia
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
Aruba
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
Australia
1
1
1
0
1
1
1
0
0
0
. . .
TABLE 2. SUMMARY RESULTS: NETWORK OVERVIEW
Threshold
0.00%
1992 1998
Network Centralization (import degree)
Network Density
Clustering Coefficient (overall graph)
Degree Correlation
56.79
41.92
0.78
-0.48
0.50%
1.00%
2.00%
1992 1998 1992 1998 1992 1998
42.55 82.38 84.23 81.70 82.94 77.03 78.25
56.62 9.54 10.97 13.21 14.40 17.89 18.65
0.77 0.54 0.50 0.49 0.46 0.45 0.41
-0.36 -0.21 -0.15 -0.17 -0.13 -0.12 -0.12
TABLE 3. ASSORTATIVE MIXING
1992
1998
0%
1%
2%
Regional
0.067
0.244
0.248
0%
1%
2%
0.075
0.274
0.276
Income Legal Origin
-0.041
0.012
0.057
0.150
0.064
0.169
-0.025
0.074
0.084
0.019
0.153
0.181
Notes: Higher values signify greater assortativity.
Regional classification according to World Trade Organization. (North America, Latin America, Western
Europe, C./E. Europe/Baltic States/CIS, Africa, Middle East, and Asia)
Income classification according to World Bank. (High Income: OECD, High Income: Non-OECD,
Upper middle Income, Lower middle Income, and Low Income)
Legal Origin classification according to La Porta (1998). (British, French, Socialist, German,
Scandinavian, and not classified)
27
TABLE 4. TOP THIRTY COUNTRIES ACCORDING TO THE 1998 IMPORTANCE INDEX (IV=1)
Importance (IV=1)
USA
Germany
Japan
France
United Kingdom
Italy
Belgium-Luxembourg
Spain
Russian Federation
Netherlands
Thailand
India
China
Rep. of Korea
Brazil
Singapore
Canada
Portugal
Australia
Norway
China, Hong Kong SAR
Turkey
Denmark
Switzerland
Saudi Arabia
Austria
Greece
Sweden
So. African Customs Union
Poland
1992
1
2
10
3
4
5
6
7
33
9
12
14
8
11
24
16
18
13
20
31
22
21
15
19
17
25
54
42
28
23
1998
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
Importance (IV=TS)
1992
1
2
3
4
5
6
9
12
24
7
23
31
10
13
25
15
8
29
20
26
11
32
22
14
21
17
39
18
33
34
1998
1
2
3
4
5
6
10
11
20
9
24
27
8
14
21
15
7
34
22
28
13
31
25
16
32
19
41
17
40
30
Importance
(IV=GDP ratio)
1992
1998
1
1
9
14
4
10
16
20
19
17
17
19
10
13
22
24
35
52
14
11
59
57
101
102
92
91
31
32
55
54
18
2
8
8
28
26
13
7
7
3
3
6
57
50
6
5
2
4
135
141
11
12
29
31
15
15
45
48
54
43
Total Trade to GDP
Ratio
1992*
1998*
148
150
104
123
150
153
117
128
100
105
125
122
16
14
127
125
96
115
36
42
61
58
151
149
142
138
75
89
152
151
1
1
95
79
62
88
135
135
64
78
2
2
138
126
72
91
65
84
53
74
56
67
114
134
81
77
144
141
118
114
Notes: Countries ranked according to 1998 Importance index (IV=1).
* For the ranking according to the Total Trade to GDP ratio, the data in the 1992 column is the average
for the 1987 – 1992 period, while for the 1998 column the average is for the 1993 – 1998 time period.
- Importance (IV=1) denotes the importance index was computed using a constant intrinsic value, set
equal to one, for all countries, while Importance (IV=TS) and Importance (IV=GDP ratio) denote the
importance indices computed using the share of total trade of country i (exports plus imports) out of
total world trade and the GDP per capita ratio, respectively as intrinsic values.
28
TABLE 5. PER CAPITA GDP GROWTH RATE REGRESSION (1987 - 1992 and 1993 - 1998)
Network Indicators Based on Export Dependency Ratio
1
Log (IGDP)
-0.7570 **
2
-0.7316 ***
3
-1.0009 **
4
-1.2552 *
5
6
-0.9748 **
-0.9720 **
7
-1.1453 *
Network Indicators Based on Import Dependency
8
-0.9451 **
9
-1.0335 *
10
-1.3743 *
11
12
13
14
-1.2155 **
-1.2309 *
-1.0508 **
-1.4580 *
-2.0592
-1.8171
-2.2941
-2.8034
-2.1294
-2.3448
-2.7069
-2.3332
-2.8070
-3.8767
-2.5630
-2.7966
-2.4236
-3.9397
Human Capital
1.4363 **
1.8231 **
2.1775 **
2.7599 *
2.0968 **
2.1659 **
2.9382 *
2.6308 *
2.1160 *
3.8160 *
2.6785 *
2.6365 *
2.7908 *
3.8138 *
Physical Capital
0.0120 *
2.0475
2.1937
0.0073 ***
2.4511
0.0093 **
3.0119
0.0086 **
2.2023
2.5960
0.0102 *
0.0086 **
3.2410
3.0242
0.0049
0.0034
2.9383
0.0124 **
5.0497
-0.0100
2.6422
0.0085 **
3.4634
0.0094 ***
2.8735
0.0069 ***
4.7979
-0.0071
3.0078
1.9539
2.4225
2.2767
2.7196
2.2075
1.3274
0.8925
2.1560
-1.3246
2.1073
1.7615
1.8243
-0.9680
Regime
-0.0917
-0.2763
-0.1884
-0.1790
-0.1345
-0.1674
-0.1136
-0.0938
-0.0528
0.0540
-0.1539
-0.0662
-0.1151
0.0268
Climate
-0.7500 ***
-0.2642
Access to Water
-0.9530
-0.5854
-0.5518
-0.4081
-0.5104
-0.3504
-0.2917
-0.1445
0.1563
-0.4551
-0.3442
-0.3514
0.0762
-0.6557
-0.4669
-0.4871
-0.4841
-0.4423
-0.4082
-0.4760
-0.0433
-0.1399
-0.4561
-0.1785
-0.5035
-0.3094
-1.6382
-1.4091
-0.9844
-1.0593
-0.9664
-0.9468
-0.9208
-1.0582
-0.0863
-0.2902
-0.8890
-1.0947
-1.1095
-0.6299
1.3522 **
1.3326 *
1.1844 **
0.8438
1.0970 **
1.2331 **
1.1887 **
1.3138 *
0.9006
1.0419 ***
1.0496 **
0.9120 *
1.0182 **
1.1871 **
2.4179
Total Trade to GDP Ratio
2.6605
0.0102 **
0.0095 **
2.4777
Importance (IV=1)
2.3712
2.1378
-0.0084 ***
-1.8324
1.6338
0.0118 *
2.8859
2.1158
2.5517
0.0089 **
2.0268
0.0095 **
2.1779
2.4429
0.0102 **
2.5594
2.6928
0.0088 **
2.2437
1.5541
0.0073 ***
1.6357
1.8883
0.0100 **
2.4006
2.1263
0.0084 **
1.9457
6.6483
0.0071
1.4160
1.9698
0.0091 **
2.2555
2.1026
0.0096 **
2.2447
-0.0133 *
-2.6113
Importance (IV=TS)
-0.0190 *
-3.3306
Importance (IV=GDP ratio)
-0.0115 **
-0.1288 **
-2.3916
-0.0162 **
-2.3744
Centrality 0%
-2.0756
-0.0964 *
-2.7795
-0.0242 *
-3.1289
Centrality 1%
-0.0795 *
-0.2320 ***
-4.5165
Centrality 2%
-0.1413 *
-1.6995
-3.3697
-0.21687 ***
-1.6299
-0.1089 *
-4.4856
Importance (IV=GDP ratio)*Human Capital
0.02947 **
Importance (IV=GDP ratio)*Physical Capital
0.02005 **
2.1057
2.4742
-0.00005
-0.000002
-0.6661
-0.0487
Centrality 1%*Human Capital
0.0223
Centrality 1%*Physical Capital
0.0005 *
0.0242
0.6285
0.6985
0.0005 *
2.3348
R Squared
Adj. R squared
Number of observations
0.162
0.134
183
0.146
0.118
191
0.191
0.156
174
0.222
0.189
174
0.181
0.146
174
0.202
0.168
174
0.246
0.215
174
0.238
0.206
174
0.206
0.162
174
0.296
0.257
174
2.2243
0.173
0.138
174
0.185
0.141
174
0.210
0.177
174
Notes: t-statistics for the coefficients in italics. Rankings data for local IEI indicators was used in these regressions.
*, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level.
Importance (IV=1) denotes the importance index was computed using a constant intrinsic value, set equal to one, for all countries.
Importance (IV=TS) and Importance (IV=GDP ratio) denote the importance indices computed using the world trade shares and the GDP per capita ratios as intrinsic values for the
corresponding years.
29
0.267
0.227
174
DATA APPENDIX
TABLE A1. RESULTS FOR LOCAL MEASURES OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION
World Trade Share Total Trade to GDP
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
Afghanistan
Albania
Algeria
Andorra
Angola
Antigua and Barbuda
Argentina
Armenia
Aruba
Australia
Austria
Azerbaijan
Bahamas
Bahrain
Bangladesh
Barbados
Belarus
Belgium-Luxembourg
Belize
Benin
Bermuda
Bhutan
Bolivia
Bosnia Herzegovina
Br. Virgin Isds
Brazil
Brunei Darussalam
Bulgaria
Burkina Faso
Burundi
Cambodia
Cameroon
Canada
Cape Verde
Cayman Isds
Central African Rep.
Chad
Chile
China
China, Hong Kong SAR
1992
1998
1992*
1998*
0.005
0.008
0.296
0.015
0.086
0.003
0.398
0.001
0.012
1.061
1.399
0.004
0.041
0.049
0.082
0.010
0.019
3.522
0.006
0.009
0.016
0.002
0.024
0.008
0.002
0.854
0.057
0.091
0.005
0.003
0.009
0.037
3.537
0.002
0.011
0.003
0.003
0.278
2.901
2.516
0.005
0.011
0.207
0.011
0.053
0.004
0.560
0.006
0.015
1.047
1.181
0.015
0.024
0.046
0.112
0.012
0.146
2.986
0.006
0.011
0.013
0.001
0.031
0.036
0.016
1.096
0.035
0.092
0.010
0.002
0.019
0.033
4.013
0.003
0.012
0.003
0.002
0.309
3.921
2.167
51.196
40.152
71.097
197.145
15.718
94.418
35.095
76.213
198.540
19.025
96.621
93.043
130.292
125.980
58.920
78.199
45.907
16.081
87.000
37.685
36.379
22.024
36.295
52.884
65.765
40.339
45.615
62.454
27.761
259.622
55.991
52.758
135.817
204.961
17.500
94.028
40.202
78.645
185.350
28.012
97.431
126.471
129.938
104.711
58.838
74.871
47.528
17.705
101.073
39.892
30.542
62.636
44.478
71.659
87.228
43.626
51.138
57.074
38.915
275.828
0% (A)
21.8085
20.2128
64.3617
14.8936
25.0000
26.5957
62.7660
9.5745
14.8936
77.6596
92.5532
8.5106
31.9149
30.3191
58.5106
51.5957
11.7021
93.6170
44.1489
49.4681
52.6596
19.1489
53.1915
9.5745
17.5532
62.7660
52.1277
69.1489
20.2128
22.3404
19.1489
30.8511
81.9149
16.4894
21.2766
19.1489
17.0213
64.8936
86.7021
78.1915
Import - Degree Node Centrality (Index)
1992
1998
1%(A) 1% (B) 2% (A) 0% (A) 1%(A) 1% (B)
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 33.5079 0.0000 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 49.2147 1.0471 0.0000
4.2553 4.7870 1.5957 70.6806 5.2356 2.0940
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 56.5445 0.0000 0.0000
0.5319 0.0000 0.5319 39.2670 0.5236 0.0000
1.0638 0.0000 0.5319 36.6492 1.5707 0.0000
5.8511 10.1060 4.2553 71.2042 4.1885 14.1360
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 31.9372 0.0000 0.0000
0.5319 0.5320 0.0000 24.0838 0.5236 0.5240
16.4894 22.8720 8.5106 90.5759 15.1832 23.5600
26.5957 20.7450 11.7021 97.3822 19.8953 16.7540
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 50.2618 1.5707 1.0470
1.0638 0.0000 0.5319 50.7853 0.5236 0.0000
1.0638 3.1910 0.5319 40.3141 0.5236 3.6650
3.1915 0.0000 1.0638 79.0576 7.8534 1.0470
4.7872 3.7230 1.5957 63.3508 3.1414 3.6650
1.0638 0.5320 0.5319 67.5393 6.8063 5.2360
56.3830 57.9790 35.6383 96.8586 58.6387 56.0210
0.5319 0.0000 0.0000 42.4084 0.0000 0.0000
1.5957 0.0000 1.0638 64.3979 2.0942 0.5240
1.0638 0.0000 0.5319 37.1728 0.0000 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 20.4188 0.0000 0.0000
1.5957 0.5320 0.5319 62.3037 0.5236 0.5240
0.5319 0.5320 0.5319 32.9843 2.0942 1.0470
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 32.4607 0.5236 0.5240
14.8936 32.4470 10.1064 81.6754 16.2304 28.7960
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 47.6440 0.0000 0.0000
10.6383 1.0640 6.3830 73.8220 4.1885 4.7120
0.5319 0.0000 0.0000 59.6859 1.0471 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 41.3613 1.0471 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 30.3665 0.0000 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 60.7330 2.6178 0.5240
32.9787 32.4470 12.7660 94.7644 36.1257 31.9370
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 25.1309 0.0000 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 27.2251 0.5236 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 32.4607 0.0000 0.0000
0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 29.3194 0.0000 0.0000
6.3830 5.3190 4.2553 63.3508 6.8063 5.2360
31.3830 55.3190 23.9362 87.4346 32.4607 71.2040
21.2766 39.8940 13.8298 87.4346 21.9895 29.8430
30
2% (A)
0.0000
0.5236
3.1414
0.0000
0.0000
1.0471
2.6178
0.0000
0.0000
6.2827
12.0419
1.5707
0.0000
0.0000
5.7592
2.6178
2.6178
41.8848
0.0000
1.5707
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
1.5707
0.0000
9.9476
0.0000
1.5707
1.0471
0.5236
0.0000
1.5707
14.1361
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
5.2356
21.4660
12.0419
Importance (Indices)
1992
1998
IV=1 (A) IV= Trade Share (A) IV= GDP ratio (A) IV= GDP ratio (B) IV=1 (A) IV= Trade Share (A) IV= GDP ratio (A) IV= GDP ratio (B)
1.000009
0.000051
0.000229
0.000056
1.000023
0.000050
0.000307
0.000101
1.000008
0.000076
6.391498
6.391366
1.000061
0.000110
9.519243
9.517703
1.000356
0.002961
18.339408
18.338620
1.000391
0.002069
14.094820
14.093288
1.000011
0.000147
0.000605
0.000013
1.000012
0.000108
0.000434
0.000035
1.000080
0.000859
6.616348
6.614312
1.000044
0.000533
0.001587
0.000773
1.000051
0.000027
51.981323
51.979640
1.000100
0.000041
46.270562
46.267650
1.000947
0.003980
33.301830
33.307900
1.001010
0.005604
37.007575
37.012529
1.000004
0.000009
10.686923
10.686900
1.000021
0.000063
8.119077
8.118839
1.000030
0.000121
0.000566
0.000331
1.000031
0.000147
0.000577
0.000429
1.002347
0.010623
76.285661
76.300752
1.002176
0.010478
77.610933
77.629868
1.001577
0.014006
77.363925
77.363254
1.001603
0.011822
71.452152
71.450111
1.000018
0.000039
0.000226
0.000059
1.000308
0.000153
7.699721
7.699017
1.000069
0.000406
0.001961
0.000761
1.000048
0.000238
0.000971
0.000453
1.000352
0.000488
0.010866
0.006434
1.000055
0.000464
0.001203
0.001498
1.000916
0.000824
4.951931
4.950241
1.000745
0.001126
5.060631
5.058723
1.000231
0.000100
51.105952
51.107429
1.000231
0.000123
49.828717
49.830107
1.000130
0.000186
28.507949
28.507852
1.000490
0.001464
22.290609
22.288741
1.007874
0.035258
77.467568
77.458359
1.007374
0.029891
71.332601
71.316856
1.000031
0.000065
22.577584
22.577016
1.000042
0.000056
20.464405
20.464032
1.000213
0.000086
3.887956
3.887689
1.000327
0.000108
3.657450
3.656828
1.000067
0.000163
0.000980
0.000739
1.000020
0.000126
0.000652
0.000194
1.000004
0.000019
0.000071
0.000005
1.000006
0.000015
0.000069
0.000007
1.000117
0.000239
9.231486
9.230795
1.000075
0.000312
8.565582
8.564637
1.000063
0.000082
0.000244
0.000212
1.000475
0.000360
0.006992
0.000963
1.000008
0.000017
0.000316
0.000035
1.000034
0.000158
0.000850
0.000180
1.001677
0.008551
23.087249
23.110156
1.002553
0.010975
21.834634
21.827948
1.000026
0.000566
0.000998
0.001503
1.000024
0.000353
0.000897
0.000724
1.000979
0.000910
24.484019
24.473479
1.000283
0.000923
17.360599
17.360930
1.000015
0.000048
3.432496
3.432433
1.000111
0.000100
3.040029
3.039718
1.000007
0.000029
2.948036
2.947979
1.000053
0.000023
1.961360
1.961179
1.000011
0.000094
0.000577
0.000088
1.000016
0.000188
3.987437
3.986910
1.000014
0.000373
6.854501
6.854724
1.000150
0.000332
6.263795
6.263479
1.002507
0.035403
80.221615
80.219546
1.002350
0.040172
77.460183
77.448693
1.000015
0.000020
10.835566
10.835339
1.000011
0.000026
10.778145
10.777845
1.000018
0.000111
0.000764
0.000201
1.000030
0.000122
0.000705
0.000235
1.000001
0.000027
4.907603
4.907634
1.000003
0.000032
3.038041
3.038108
1.000001
0.000026
4.273180
4.273191
1.000014
0.000025
2.911908
2.911907
1.000529
0.002786
26.539030
26.536249
1.000628
0.003094
30.850239
30.847741
1.005212
0.029028
8.376523
8.405595
1.003421
0.039231
10.361804
10.443086
1.002065
0.025185
90.094537
90.115207
1.002043
0.021698
79.453587
79.449250
TABLE A1. RESULTS FOR LOCAL MEASURES OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION (…continues)
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
China, Macao SAR
Colombia
Comoros
Congo
Costa Rica
Cote d'lvoire
Croatia
Cuba
Cyprus
Czech Rep.
Czechoslovakia
Dem. People's Rep. of Korea
Dem. Rep. of the Congo
Denmark
Djibouti
Dominica
Dominican Rep.
Ecuador
Egypt
El Salvador
Equatorial Guinea
Eritrea
Estonia
Ethiopia
Faeroe Isds
Fiji
Finland
Fmr Ethiopia
France
French Polynesia
Gabon
Gambia
Georgia
Germany
Ghana
Greece
Greenland
Grenada
Guatemala
Guinea
Guinea-Bissau
Guyana
Haiti
Honduras
Hungary
Iceland
India
Indonesia
Iran
Iraq
0.053
0.199
0.002
0.029
0.078
0.058
0.111
0.031
0.061
n.a.
0.323
0.022
0.027
1.005
0.005
0.004
0.086
0.086
0.206
0.029
0.001
n.a.
0.006
n.a.
0.012
0.015
0.651
0.012
6.538
0.009
0.043
0.006
0.003
11.460
0.047
0.378
0.011
0.002
0.056
0.016
0.001
0.010
0.007
0.036
0.300
0.047
0.592
0.847
0.401
0.014
0.039
0.255
0.001
0.021
0.116
0.078
0.122
0.039
0.045
0.531
n.a.
0.019
0.018
0.836
0.004
0.003
0.113
0.105
0.194
0.055
0.007
0.003
0.076
0.020
0.008
0.011
0.693
n.a.
5.547
0.013
0.032
0.004
0.013
9.254
0.043
0.382
0.008
0.002
0.087
0.014
0.001
0.008
0.012
0.061
0.475
0.045
0.751
0.798
0.261
0.062
141.237
32.657
56.864
86.538
74.714
59.724
147.228
105.810
n.a.
75.980
49.319
65.788
128.603
122.847
70.156
59.056
52.547
44.360
110.265
n.a.
114.612
n.a.
111.199
49.426
21.234
43.927
81.789
124.449
84.161
49.322
43.398
44.585
105.304
41.119
54.979
53.128
159.240
37.022
63.078
67.541
65.629
16.592
48.947
30.245
-
117.359
35.152
62.036
136.199
87.684
76.911
95.244
97.655
95.900
n.a.
42.244
65.956
106.906
111.196
94.461
54.652
49.029
56.907
177.558
157.232
32.770
116.299
66.184
n.a.
43.828
95.477
114.676
67.538
46.788
58.353
40.370
107.831
42.204
43.800
48.721
192.789
31.549
84.614
74.276
68.393
24.792
52.654
47.506
-
32.9787
71.2766
19.1489
26.5957
47.8723
31.3830
65.4255
27.1277
64.8936
n.a.
34.0426
23.4043
22.3404
90.4255
26.0638
24.4681
29.2553
47.8723
37.2340
37.2340
15.9574
n.a.
13.2979
n.a.
51.0638
52.6596
80.3191
53.1915
97.8723
18.6170
23.4043
25.0000
11.7021
98.4043
73.4043
38.2979
46.2766
24.4681
31.9149
27.6596
18.0851
50.5319
26.5957
34.0426
73.9362
54.7872
69.1489
66.4894
30.8511
17.5532
0.0000
6.9149
0.0000
0.0000
1.5957
1.5957
3.7234
0.0000
1.5957
n.a.
2.6596
0.0000
0.0000
15.9574
0.5319
1.5957
1.0638
2.1277
2.6596
2.1277
0.0000
n.a.
0.5319
n.a.
0.0000
1.5957
10.1064
2.1277
81.3830
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
87.7660
2.6596
4.2553
0.0000
1.0638
0.5319
0.0000
0.0000
2.6596
0.0000
1.5957
6.3830
0.5319
18.0851
13.2979
7.4468
1.0638
0.0000 0.0000 42.9319 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000022
6.9150 3.7234 83.7696 6.2827 7.3300 3.1414 1.000987
0.0000 0.0000 30.3665 0.0000 0.5240 0.0000 1.000010
0.0000 0.0000 41.8848 1.0471 0.0000 0.0000 1.000013
2.6600 1.5957 65.4450 2.6178 3.6650 2.0942 1.000393
1.0640 0.5319 72.7749 4.7120 9.9480 3.1414 1.000115
2.1280 2.1277 76.4398 4.7120 3.1410 3.6649 1.000759
0.0000 0.0000 39.2670 0.5236 1.0470 0.5236 1.000047
0.5320 1.5957 74.8691 1.0471 0.5240 0.5236 1.000159
n.a.
n.a.
86.9110 7.3298 10.4710 4.1885
n.a.
4.2550 1.5957
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
1.000201
0.0000 0.0000 38.2199 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000021
0.0000 0.0000 31.9372 1.5707 0.0000 0.5236 1.000020
25.0000 8.5106 91.6230 12.5654 14.1360 6.2827 1.002766
0.5320 0.5319 34.0314 0.5236 0.0000 0.5236 1.000078
0.0000 1.0638 35.6021 2.0942 0.0000 1.0471 1.000070
0.5320 0.5319 39.2670 1.0471 0.0000 0.5236 1.000132
2.6600 0.5319 71.2042 4.7120 2.6180 1.5707 1.000126
1.0640 1.0638 77.4869 8.3770 4.1880 4.1885 1.000261
1.5960 2.1277 61.2565 4.7120 2.6180 3.1414 1.000137
0.0000 0.0000 23.5602 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000001
n.a.
n.a.
21.9895 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000
n.a.
0.0000 0.0000 73.2984 4.1885 2.0940 2.6178 1.000013
n.a.
n.a.
65.9686 1.5707 1.0470 1.5707
n.a.
0.5320 0.0000 53.4031 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000012
2.6600 1.0638 28.7958 0.0000 0.5240 0.0000 1.000093
13.2980 5.3191 87.9581 8.3770 10.9950 4.7120 1.000983
0.5320 1.5957
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
n.a.
1.000889
85.6380 70.2128 98.9529 80.1047 84.8170 63.8743 1.013698
0.0000 0.0000 64.3979 0.0000 0.5240 0.0000 1.000014
0.5320 0.0000 35.6021 1.0471 0.0000 0.0000 1.000007
0.0000 0.0000 48.1675 0.5236 0.5240 0.0000 1.000006
0.5320 0.0000 35.0785 1.0471 0.5240 0.5236 1.000003
92.0210 78.7234 98.9529 82.1990 90.5760 70.1571 1.019359
1.0640 1.5957 46.5969 2.6178 1.5710 2.0942 1.000201
1.5960 0.5319 84.2932 14.6597 6.2830 7.8534 1.000357
0.0000 0.0000 50.2618 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000013
0.0000 0.5319 51.3089 1.5707 0.0000 0.5236 1.000053
1.0640 0.5319 54.4503 3.1414 4.1880 2.6178 1.000075
0.0000 0.0000 57.5916 0.0000 1.0470 0.0000 1.000010
0.0000 0.0000 25.1309 0.5236 0.0000 0.0000 1.000003
0.5320 0.5319 35.6021 1.5707 1.0470 1.0471 1.000136
0.0000 0.0000 36.6492 0.0000 0.0000 0.0000 1.000004
0.5320 0.5319 55.4974 2.6178 2.0940 1.5707 1.000095
6.3830 1.5957 82.7225 10.4712 8.9010 4.7120 1.000419
1.0640 0.5319 64.9215 1.0471 0.5240 0.5236 1.000068
22.3400 14.3617 83.7696 20.4188 34.0310 14.1361 1.002892
12.2340 6.3830 89.0052 13.0890 25.1310 5.7592 1.000902
6.9150 3.1915 56.0209 7.3298 8.3770 3.6649 1.000401
0.5320 0.5319 32.9843 0.5236 2.0940 0.5236 1.000132
31
0.000532
0.001990
0.000019
0.000295
0.000778
0.000580
0.001112
0.000309
0.000613
n.a.
0.003237
0.000221
0.000266
0.010055
0.000054
0.000038
0.000862
0.000856
0.002063
0.000290
0.000014
n.a.
0.000063
n.a.
0.000118
0.000147
0.006512
0.000118
0.065446
0.000086
0.000430
0.000063
0.000027
0.114713
0.000467
0.003787
0.000114
0.000015
0.000562
0.000161
0.000014
0.000103
0.000068
0.000365
0.003006
0.000468
0.005924
0.008482
0.004019
0.000135
84.266554
18.725478
8.100254
7.371080
19.138250
7.527817
0.012796
20.162670
51.771525
n.a.
43.834048
0.000499
2.029670
82.970932
0.000237
24.279924
12.419053
14.440028
13.175909
13.381317
4.507980
n.a.
26.525010
n.a.
0.001143
18.196769
66.954891
1.879307
75.369818
0.000323
31.191388
4.515771
0.000123
78.175352
4.681447
45.358450
0.000858
18.564411
13.472651
9.862295
2.301102
8.383903
3.355387
7.970074
31.153068
77.136290
6.524222
12.014279
18.234856
0.002043
84.266090
18.705536
8.100119
7.371379
19.137486
7.527781
0.007945
20.162237
51.768941
n.a.
43.834930
0.000450
2.029734
82.976124
0.000161
24.279494
12.418306
14.440323
13.173511
13.381113
4.507975
n.a.
26.525017
n.a
0.001468
18.196334
66.959255
1.879147
75.370332
0.000010
31.191907
4.515733
0.000201
78.168246
4.680999
45.354995
0.000780
18.563843
13.472739
9.862378
2.301062
8.383381
3.355330
7.969794
31.152232
77.136019
6.524502
12.017141
18.233998
0.001906
1.000021
1.000663
1.000005
1.000065
1.000270
1.000425
1.000669
1.000068
1.000121
1.000728
n.a.
1.000019
1.000125
1.001847
1.000094
1.000089
1.000117
1.000313
1.000566
1.000384
1.000003
1.000009
1.000289
1.000562
1.000013
1.000011
1.000903
n.a.
1.011009
1.000024
1.000041
1.000030
1.000205
1.014137
1.000254
1.001479
1.000009
1.000080
1.000426
1.000048
1.000021
1.000090
1.000020
1.000201
1.000644
1.000094
1.003470
1.000873
1.000759
1.000151
0.000389
0.002551
0.000006
0.000207
0.001163
0.000783
0.001224
0.000387
0.000448
0.005315
n.a.
0.000194
0.000184
0.008367
0.000044
0.000028
0.001136
0.001049
0.001939
0.000553
0.000065
0.000034
0.000762
0.000205
0.000078
0.000108
0.006934
n.a.
0.055524
0.000126
0.000318
0.000041
0.000135
0.092627
0.000432
0.003826
0.000076
0.000024
0.000866
0.000137
0.000014
0.000082
0.000119
0.000612
0.004756
0.000448
0.007520
0.007986
0.002618
0.000623
67.703848
17.516604
5.320368
4.688901
17.545786
6.384617
27.011545
0.001800
0.003470
44.120983
n.a.
0.000651
0.000597
81.305629
0.000164
0.001028
14.889685
11.039027
12.396435
13.915658
9.634090
0.000082
28.620795
1.909343
0.000800
16.454331
68.959225
n.a.
68.127625
0.000431
23.583104
3.472129
15.043293
69.996274
4.298029
43.749310
0.000721
16.886398
12.786251
8.991573
2.011349
11.083694
7.339439
6.981768
30.621892
76.684430
7.311329
12.153833
16.910491
0.002591
67.703425
17.516803
5.320331
4.688767
17.546037
6.387173
27.005988
0.001925
0.001063
44.120556
n.a.
0.000688
0.000548
81.307929
0.000018
0.000634
14.888716
11.038490
12.393346
13.915102
9.634139
0.000012
28.620568
1.909060
0.000778
16.454199
68.964426
n.a.
68.132996
0.000075
23.583185
3.472138
15.042653
70.000616
4.297655
43.744003
0.000728
16.885904
12.786220
8.991812
2.011409
11.083283
7.339247
6.981299
30.621389
76.684017
7.312936
12.160376
16.909027
0.003176
TABLE A1. RESULTS FOR LOCAL MEASURES OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION (…continues)
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
Ireland
Israel
Italy
Jamaica
Japan
Jordan
Kazakhstan
Kenya
Kiribati
Kuwait
Kyrgyzstan
Lao People's Dem. Rep.
Latvia
Lebanon
Liberia
Libya
Lithuania
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Maldives
Mali
Malta
Marshall Isds
Mauritania
Mauritius
Mexico
Micronesia
Mongolia
Morocco
Mozambique
Myanmar
Nepal
Neth. Antilles
Netherlands
New Caledonia
New Zealand
Nicaragua
Niger
Nigeria
Norway
Oman
Pakistan
Palau
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Poland
0.708
0.408
5.099
0.045
6.952
0.059
0.012
0.038
0.001
0.119
0.001
0.004
0.013
0.047
0.065
0.193
0.049
0.011
0.012
1.135
0.003
0.008
0.054
0.001
0.010
0.043
1.534
0.001
0.004
0.168
0.017
0.020
0.011
0.052
3.873
0.014
0.267
0.013
0.006
0.282
0.851
0.122
0.224
0.001
0.133
0.029
0.030
0.105
0.359
0.428
0.982
0.468
4.255
0.046
6.423
0.049
0.094
0.052
0.001
0.175
0.012
0.007
0.059
0.071
0.065
0.114
0.088
0.012
0.010
1.325
0.004
0.011
0.044
0.002
0.011
0.037
2.325
0.001
0.008
0.176
0.010
0.033
0.015
0.039
3.169
0.011
0.226
0.023
0.007
0.169
0.747
0.109
0.170
0.001
0.052
0.027
0.040
0.129
0.592
0.690
112.447
82.065
38.980
110.347
18.733
128.946
149.337
52.981
102.375
78.126
38.048
103.494
103.128
93.540
40.939
57.611
140.611
50.323
177.891
105.392
131.269
36.481
85.339
54.334
47.447
34.394
101.836
54.824
67.688
38.687
63.302
70.882
83.145
34.792
69.915
93.312
62.612
24.541
58.850
43.689
130.501
79.234
47.448
122.601
16.692
127.796
77.828
68.533
93.563
79.814
62.011
107.387
71.152
126.110
49.203
64.933
189.409
56.834
194.689
99.741
125.468
52.920
119.317
58.292
52.689
56.627
99.291
58.597
85.110
39.769
78.713
71.779
90.117
36.653
76.166
101.263
100.573
27.236
91.258
50.939
82.9787
53.1915
98.4043
59.0426
45.7447
52.6596
11.7021
54.7872
21.2766
39.3617
9.0426
19.1489
13.2979
34.5745
26.5957
30.3191
29.2553
50.0000
24.4681
79.7872
18.6170
25.5319
61.7021
9.0426
22.3404
64.8936
72.8723
6.9149
16.4894
36.7021
23.9362
53.7234
23.9362
46.8085
95.7447
19.1489
68.0851
26.0638
23.4043
38.8298
78.1915
47.3404
72.3404
6.3830
36.7021
22.8723
38.2979
61.1702
55.8511
78.7234
5.8511
4.2553
79.2553
4.2553
30.8511
4.2553
0.5319
1.5957
0.0000
2.1277
0.0000
0.0000
0.5319
1.0638
1.5957
2.6596
7.4468
1.0638
1.0638
14.3617
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
3.7234
12.2340
0.0000
0.0000
2.6596
1.0638
0.5319
0.0000
3.1915
62.2340
0.0000
4.2553
1.0638
0.0000
1.0638
10.1064
1.0638
10.6383
0.0000
2.6596
0.5319
0.5319
4.7872
11.1702
17.0213
4.7870
1.5960
82.4470
5.8510
45.2130
2.1280
0.5320
6.3830
0.0000
1.0640
0.0000
0.0000
0.5320
0.5320
0.0000
2.1280
7.4470
0.5320
0.0000
18.0850
0.0000
0.0000
0.5320
0.0000
0.0000
1.5960
13.2980
0.0000
0.0000
1.5960
0.0000
0.5320
0.0000
6.9150
70.2130
0.0000
9.0430
1.0640
0.0000
3.7230
14.3620
2.6600
10.6380
0.0000
3.7230
0.5320
1.0640
1.5960
1.5960
13.8300
2.6596
1.0638
63.8298
2.6596
21.2766
1.5957
0.0000
1.5957
0.0000
1.5957
0.0000
0.0000
0.5319
0.5319
0.0000
1.0638
7.4468
0.0000
0.5319
7.9787
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
1.0638
7.9787
0.0000
0.0000
0.5319
0.5319
0.5319
0.0000
2.1277
44.6809
0.0000
2.1277
1.0638
0.0000
1.0638
6.3830
1.0638
7.4468
0.0000
1.0638
0.0000
0.0000
2.1277
6.3830
10.6383
90.5759
72.2513
97.3822
64.3979
96.8586
58.6387
35.6021
60.7330
22.5131
71.7277
46.5969
27.2251
56.5445
87.9581
38.2199
35.6021
49.2147
58.1152
45.5497
80.6283
31.9372
38.7435
62.8272
20.4188
35.0785
69.1099
89.0052
11.5183
34.5550
73.2984
31.9372
32.9843
40.8377
36.6492
98.9529
24.0838
49.7382
55.4974
52.8796
72.2513
84.2932
61.7801
79.5812
12.0419
53.4031
60.7330
43.4555
67.5393
75.9162
82.7225
7.8534
6.8063
67.0157
4.7120
60.2094
2.0942
2.6178
2.0942
0.5236
4.1885
2.6178
0.0000
1.0471
3.6649
1.5707
3.6649
2.6178
0.5236
1.5707
13.0890
0.0000
2.6178
0.5236
0.0000
0.5236
3.1414
13.6126
0.0000
0.0000
3.1414
0.5236
0.0000
0.5236
1.0471
59.1623
0.5236
0.5236
2.6178
2.0942
1.5707
12.5654
1.0471
8.9005
0.0000
3.1414
1.5707
1.5707
4.7120
10.9948
18.8482
10.9950
1.5710
80.6280
1.5710
88.4820
1.0470
2.0940
6.2830
0.0000
3.1410
1.5710
0.0000
1.5710
1.0470
0.0000
2.0940
2.6180
1.0470
0.0000
25.6540
0.0000
0.0000
0.5240
0.0000
1.0470
1.5710
16.7540
0.0000
0.0000
3.1410
0.5240
0.0000
0.0000
1.5710
69.6340
0.0000
3.6650
0.5240
0.5240
4.7120
8.9010
2.6180
8.3770
0.0000
3.6650
1.0470
1.0470
1.5710
3.6650
11.5180
32
3.6649
1.5707
53.4031
2.6178
46.5969
1.5707
1.5707
0.5236
0.0000
2.6178
1.5707
0.0000
1.0471
1.5707
0.5236
1.5707
1.5707
0.0000
1.0471
6.8063
0.0000
2.6178
0.0000
0.0000
0.5236
1.5707
2.0942
0.0000
0.0000
2.0942
0.0000
0.0000
0.5236
0.5236
37.1728
0.5236
0.5236
2.0942
0.5236
1.5707
8.9005
1.0471
5.2356
0.0000
1.5707
1.0471
0.5236
2.0942
5.7592
7.8534
1.000686
1.000291
1.011094
1.000318
1.004673
1.001289
1.000021
1.000159
1.000013
1.000286
1.000003
1.000005
1.000039
1.000177
1.000081
1.000173
1.001448
1.000054
1.000045
1.001132
1.000010
1.000007
1.000053
1.000006
1.000006
1.000216
1.001456
1.000000
1.000003
1.000208
1.000057
1.000055
1.000022
1.000209
1.005041
1.000015
1.000513
1.000115
1.000008
1.000184
1.001142
1.000191
1.001318
1.000001
1.000193
1.000032
1.000056
1.000313
1.001001
1.001839
0.007088
0.004082
0.051045
0.000446
0.069567
0.000588
0.000122
0.000384
0.000006
0.001195
0.000009
0.000037
0.000130
0.000468
0.000649
0.001931
0.000487
0.000112
0.000125
0.011360
0.000035
0.000077
0.000536
0.000009
0.000104
0.000431
0.015363
0.000008
0.000041
0.001682
0.000166
0.000201
0.000106
0.000521
0.038768
0.000144
0.002673
0.000126
0.000059
0.002819
0.008521
0.001224
0.002241
0.000008
0.001331
0.000288
0.000303
0.001049
0.003590
0.004282
56.001632
54.545777
75.100863
14.053449
87.378619
13.952203
0.000197
4.444755
0.000104
0.002355
0.000006
0.000092
25.450657
13.273144
0.002226
0.004225
0.017305
3.150096
2.200073
26.395285
0.000124
3.116485
0.001104
0.000015
4.852306
38.850725
28.830682
0.000011
0.000042
13.296199
3.567050
0.000612
4.271000
0.007739
75.920383
0.000453
57.477683
6.911151
3.328483
3.367481
80.964717
0.002294
6.830991
0.000015
20.652176
12.259805
19.056968
13.773895
10.878976
23.522992
56.003128
54.543460
75.093075
14.053281
87.427675
13.950818
0.000212
4.445427
0.000006
0.001714
0.000006
0.000048
25.450634
13.270984
0.000766
0.004869
0.020783
3.150029
2.199817
26.396912
0.000063
3.116484
0.000818
0.000002
4.852259
38.850174
28.828730
0.000003
0.000020
13.295626
3.566615
0.000640
4.270869
0.009677
75.922577
0.000149
57.480036
6.910525
3.328459
3.368128
80.972330
0.003054
6.830405
0.000011
20.651017
12.259273
19.056722
13.772718
10.876700
23.521093
1.000759
1.000411
1.009812
1.000545
1.011265
1.000275
1.000360
1.000178
1.000014
1.000351
1.000171
1.000011
1.000207
1.000359
1.000143
1.000186
1.000263
1.000044
1.000116
1.000953
1.000016
1.000207
1.000048
1.000004
1.000047
1.000221
1.000955
1.000000
1.000013
1.000417
1.000026
1.000033
1.000048
1.000123
1.004893
1.000053
1.000155
1.000171
1.000091
1.000665
1.002060
1.000290
1.000930
1.000000
1.000190
1.000157
1.000083
1.000397
1.000875
1.001129
0.009827
0.004683
0.042595
0.000465
0.064285
0.000493
0.000937
0.000520
0.000006
0.001749
0.000120
0.000068
0.000586
0.000714
0.000653
0.001144
0.000882
0.000124
0.000104
0.013264
0.000044
0.000106
0.000440
0.000016
0.000114
0.000373
0.023278
0.000011
0.000081
0.001765
0.000103
0.000333
0.000151
0.000386
0.031718
0.000112
0.002264
0.000229
0.000069
0.001687
0.007475
0.001089
0.001698
0.000007
0.000521
0.000275
0.000396
0.001287
0.005924
0.006905
69.629486
54.373270
68.166548
10.683938
76.691880
12.608815
18.629835
4.122530
0.000117
0.003751
8.264857
0.000157
21.855285
16.467114
0.002491
0.004208
24.595319
2.596810
2.438134
31.657577
0.000169
2.820555
46.471870
0.000060
4.211827
41.704624
25.294002
0.000017
0.000194
13.374015
3.183892
0.000729
4.392844
0.002139
73.479269
0.000266
56.122345
5.170872
2.610686
2.537720
81.688101
0.001889
6.360905
0.000010
19.294675
10.275025
14.790340
14.367943
10.608268
27.102359
69.632859
54.371724
68.172402
10.681875
76.720227
12.608154
18.629789
4.122799
0.000018
0.003700
8.264768
0.000087
21.854388
16.465323
0.001352
0.004119
24.594139
2.596943
2.437878
31.663962
0.000056
2.820262
46.471784
0.000058
4.211849
41.704240
25.294615
0.000013
0.000136
13.373186
3.183693
0.000448
4.392629
0.001570
73.483132
0.000176
56.122902
5.169903
2.610602
2.538467
81.688260
0.002214
6.361473
0.000009
19.295511
10.274614
14.789701
14.366063
10.606973
27.098062
TABLE A1. RESULTS FOR LOCAL MEASURES OF ECONOMIC INTEGRATION (…continues)
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
Portugal
Qatar
Rep. of Korea
Rep. of Moldova
Romania
Russian Federation
Rwanda
Saint Kitts and Nevis
Saint Lucia
Saint Vincent and the Grenadines
Samoa
Sao Tome and Principe
Saudi Arabia
Senegal
Serbia and Montenegro
Seychelles
Sierra Leone
Singapore
Slovakia
Slovenia
So. African Customs Union
Solomon Isds
Somalia
Spain
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Suriname
Sweden
Switzerland
Syria
Tajikistan
TFYR of Macedonia
Thailand
Timor-Leste
Togo
Tonga
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Turkmenistan
Uganda
Ukraine
United Arab Emirates
United Kingdom
United Rep. of Tanzania
Uruguay
USA
Uzbekistan
Vanuatu
Venezuela
Viet Nam
Yemen
Zambia
Zimbabwe
0.692
0.054
2.137
0.002
0.100
0.933
0.003
0.002
0.006
0.003
0.003
0.000
1.045
0.021
0.167
0.004
0.008
1.766
n.a.
0.156
0.439
0.003
0.003
2.298
0.081
0.013
0.014
1.324
1.871
0.070
0.001
n.a.
0.997
0.000
0.013
0.001
0.045
0.150
0.538
0.004
0.007
0.054
0.212
5.415
0.020
0.053
13.744
0.008
0.001
0.392
0.060
0.041
0.027
0.050
0.591
0.083
1.970
0.020
0.202
1.148
0.003
0.002
0.004
0.003
0.001
0.001
0.684
0.022
0.067
0.004
0.003
1.779
0.226
0.183
0.453
0.003
0.002
2.326
0.087
0.027
0.010
1.456
1.570
0.072
0.006
0.028
0.935
0.000
0.010
0.000
0.054
0.139
0.686
0.010
0.016
0.271
0.484
5.300
0.023
0.066
15.589
0.043
0.002
0.323
0.179
0.035
0.019
0.034
71.323
63.644
116.370
45.109
52.823
23.855
140.507
163.290
140.178
97.932
95.195
80.617
55.373
121.023
36.635
375.556
n.a.
138.556
24.190
38.297
66.074
49.377
59.544
70.834
52.695
n.a.
71.543
82.292
73.030
85.362
32.766
27.789
54.155
106.450
50.376
44.069
43.543
20.696
72.690
53.222
47.742
44.834
70.610
49.147
67.480
66.375
122.062
58.545
50.701
36.704
127.539
137.100
112.562
115.388
115.775
74.158
69.226
128.891
46.370
352.436
117.998
113.324
35.560
45.453
79.420
10.947
71.957
68.547
71.553
85.776
69.722
94.107
89.068
44.592
31.179
80.383
127.932
56.488
55.821
43.079
23.750
85.778
49.683
84.208
73.319
72.583
76.482
85.6383
53.1915
79.7872
10.6383
34.0426
37.7660
20.7447
18.6170
47.8723
22.8723
15.9574
16.4894
75.5319
30.3191
60.6383
35.6383
23.9362
63.8298
n.a.
80.8511
80.8511
14.8936
22.8723
96.2766
55.8511
27.1277
23.9362
43.0851
93.0851
32.9787
9.0426
n.a.
79.7872
4.2553
24.4681
14.8936
59.0426
62.2340
79.2553
10.6383
26.0638
17.5532
59.0426
91.4894
29.2553
29.7872
96.8085
10.6383
18.6170
54.2553
27.1277
29.7872
28.1915
59.0426
23.4043
2.1277
28.7234
0.5319
2.1277
10.1064
0.0000
0.5319
3.7234
0.5319
0.5319
0.0000
18.6170
0.5319
6.9149
0.5319
0.0000
26.5957
n.a.
6.9149
7.9787
0.0000
0.5319
58.5106
3.7234
0.5319
1.0638
11.7021
25.5319
1.5957
0.0000
n.a.
25.0000
0.0000
1.0638
0.5319
4.2553
3.7234
19.1489
0.0000
0.5319
1.0638
3.1915
74.4681
0.5319
1.5957
88.2979
0.5319
0.0000
8.5106
0.5319
1.5957
1.0638
2.1277
8.5110
0.5320
40.9570
0.0000
2.1280
12.2340
0.0000
0.0000
2.1280
0.5320
0.0000
0.0000
17.5530
0.5320
4.2550
0.5320
0.0000
30.3190
n.a.
2.6600
12.2340
0.0000
0.0000
38.8300
0.5320
0.0000
0.0000
19.1490
47.3400
1.5960
0.0000
n.a.
27.1280
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
7.9790
2.1280
15.4260
0.0000
0.0000
1.5960
6.9150
85.1060
0.0000
1.0640
94.1490
0.5320
0.0000
15.4260
0.5320
0.5320
0.0000
3.7230
12.7660
1.5957
23.9362
0.0000
0.5319
5.8511
0.0000
0.0000
2.6596
0.5319
0.0000
0.0000
10.6383
0.0000
3.1915
0.5319
0.0000
18.0851
n.a.
2.6596
4.7872
0.0000
0.5319
40.4255
1.5957
0.0000
0.5319
4.7872
13.2979
0.5319
0.0000
n.a.
15.4255
0.0000
0.5319
0.5319
2.6596
0.0000
11.1702
0.0000
0.5319
0.5319
1.5957
63.2979
0.5319
0.5319
81.3830
0.0000
0.0000
3.7234
0.0000
0.5319
1.0638
0.5319
88.4817
57.5916
89.0052
51.8325
79.5812
82.7225
56.5445
22.5131
47.1204
43.4555
17.8010
21.9895
80.1047
61.7801
79.5812
30.8901
35.0785
76.9633
75.9162
85.8639
91.0995
18.8482
26.7016
97.3822
44.5026
72.2513
42.4084
89.5288
94.7644
45.5497
27.2251
62.8272
92.6702
3.1414
59.1623
17.8010
64.3979
74.8691
84.2932
30.3665
73.8220
81.1518
53.9267
98.4293
72.7749
63.8743
97.9058
33.5079
21.4660
65.9686
43.4555
38.7435
59.1623
40.8377
21.4660
1.0471
27.7487
1.0471
6.8063
24.0838
2.0942
1.0471
3.1414
2.0942
0.0000
0.0000
12.0419
1.0471
4.7120
0.0000
0.0000
22.5131
3.1414
4.7120
6.2827
0.0000
0.5236
63.8743
1.5707
4.7120
1.5707
16.7539
24.6073
2.6178
0.5236
3.1414
24.6073
0.0000
1.5707
0.0000
4.7120
2.0942
22.5131
0.5236
2.6178
11.5183
7.8534
73.2984
1.5707
2.0942
90.0524
1.0471
0.0000
8.9005
1.5707
1.5707
2.0942
1.0471
5.2360
1.0470
55.4970
0.5240
5.7590
33.5080
0.0000
0.0000
0.0000
1.5710
0.0000
0.0000
18.3250
4.7120
1.0470
0.0000
0.0000
30.8900
2.6180
2.6180
16.2300
0.0000
0.0000
51.3090
0.5240
1.0470
1.0470
35.0790
37.1730
1.5710
0.0000
0.5240
30.8900
0.0000
2.0940
0.0000
6.2830
1.0470
17.8010
0.5240
2.0940
14.6600
12.0420
85.8640
3.6650
1.5710
93.1940
1.0470
0.0000
13.0890
3.6650
0.5240
2.0940
1.0470
12.0419
0.0000
17.2775
0.0000
2.6178
17.2775
1.0471
0.5236
2.0942
0.5236
0.0000
0.0000
8.3770
0.5236
1.5707
0.0000
0.0000
15.7068
0.5236
2.6178
4.7120
0.0000
0.0000
43.9791
0.5236
1.5707
1.5707
5.7592
8.3770
1.0471
0.5236
0.5236
16.2304
0.0000
0.5236
0.0000
3.1414
0.5236
9.9476
0.5236
2.6178
6.8063
4.7120
59.6859
0.5236
1.0471
82.7225
0.5236
0.0000
3.6649
0.0000
1.0471
0.5236
1.0471
1.002935
1.000139
1.004080
1.000011
1.000124
1.001037
1.000014
1.000032
1.000344
1.000055
1.000027
1.000001
1.002576
1.000030
1.000632
1.000034
1.000002
1.002712
n.a.
1.000720
1.001412
1.000006
1.000024
1.005749
1.000336
1.000041
1.000052
1.000871
1.002429
1.000108
1.000003
n.a.
1.003648
1.000000
1.000105
1.000035
1.000399
1.000232
1.002224
1.000009
1.000063
1.000167
1.000339
1.011954
1.000071
1.000077
1.030205
1.000026
1.000011
1.000704
1.000054
1.000130
1.000071
1.000130
0.006927
0.000545
0.021391
0.000016
0.001003
0.009339
0.000033
0.000015
0.000065
0.000032
0.000031
0.000005
0.010455
0.000211
0.001667
0.000040
0.000075
0.017678
n.a.
0.001563
0.004389
0.000028
0.000032
0.023012
0.000815
0.000132
0.000141
0.013249
0.018729
0.000701
0.000012
n.a.
0.009980
0.000000
0.000127
0.000009
0.000446
0.001501
0.005389
0.000035
0.000072
0.000536
0.002125
0.054205
0.000201
0.000534
0.137579
0.000085
0.000014
0.003923
0.000603
0.000411
0.000269
0.000505
Notes: (A) Denotes network indicators computed with the Export Dependency Ratio (i.e. exports of i to j out of total exports of i).
(B) Denotes network indicators computed with the Import Dependency Ratio (i.e. imports of i from j out of total imports of i).
(-) data is not available. (n.a.) country is not applicable.
33
48.958924
0.001283
43.296530
0.000088
15.709880
34.591843
4.135726
32.415887
23.042458
24.845484
0.000384
5.662109
0.023868
5.809950
0.010419
32.119525
3.708233
70.374220
n.a.
40.260357
27.567363
0.000131
0.000091
56.057349
10.060867
0.000373
0.001005
75.394605
91.597355
13.738387
0.000030
n.a.
20.740801
0.000002
4.685590
0.000315
36.229550
19.666077
22.635384
0.000111
2.505207
31.258953
0.005415
68.633975
1.609739
30.500886
100.589834
0.000197
0.000127
26.985461
4.401174
3.742668
3.612574
10.032842
48.953445
0.001163
43.297885
0.000111
15.709628
34.597808
4.135655
32.415513
23.039809
24.845195
0.000077
5.662093
0.026355
5.809829
0.008673
32.119442
3.708302
70.376369
n.a.
40.259710
27.574227
0.000055
0.000018
56.041207
10.060141
0.000149
0.000545
75.403369
91.602777
13.738080
0.000026
n.a.
20.736510
0.000002
4.685344
0.000020
36.234577
19.665117
22.631722
0.000146
2.505065
31.259233
0.006727
68.594516
1.609492
30.500887
100.570956
0.000170
0.000011
26.988201
4.400749
3.742230
3.612199
10.032801
1.002177
1.000114
1.002952
1.000063
1.000457
1.005329
1.000111
1.000052
1.000217
1.000101
1.000002
1.000005
1.001837
1.000234
1.000594
1.000009
1.000009
1.002547
1.000301
1.000459
1.001291
1.000004
1.000031
1.006225
1.000218
1.000342
1.000092
1.001422
1.001843
1.000210
1.000044
1.000162
1.003496
1.000004
1.000102
1.000000
1.000400
1.000261
1.001967
1.000061
1.000532
1.000936
1.000784
1.010674
1.000164
1.000500
1.030747
1.000177
1.000002
1.000887
1.000119
1.000113
1.000172
1.000086
0.005922
0.000835
0.019716
0.000198
0.002023
0.011488
0.000034
0.000016
0.000042
0.000034
0.000013
0.000006
0.006845
0.000225
0.000669
0.000037
0.000026
0.017814
0.002265
0.001834
0.004535
0.000030
0.000020
0.023281
0.000875
0.000266
0.000104
0.014578
0.015712
0.000716
0.000059
0.000277
0.009357
0.000000
0.000098
0.000005
0.000538
0.001391
0.006873
0.000099
0.000160
0.002712
0.004850
0.053059
0.000233
0.000661
0.156061
0.000433
0.000018
0.003235
0.001794
0.000350
0.000191
0.000342
47.079143
0.001645
42.316816
7.120538
15.052632
22.068008
2.836722
40.179348
19.851502
20.882870
0.000061
3.984000
0.017393
4.991881
0.002705
38.270087
2.422815
81.719478
36.731237
46.757611
23.644578
0.000106
0.000049
53.851243
10.642130
0.001851
0.001020
69.801958
81.614385
13.231600
3.830060
14.945334
19.915362
0.000005
3.052881
0.000013
26.166296
19.713282
22.397474
0.000595
2.897545
14.077592
0.011292
69.508126
1.396282
32.803976
100.579422
0.002554
0.000061
19.340935
0.004792
3.604136
2.485421
8.688628
47.073592
0.002145
42.325537
7.120406
15.051980
22.077258
2.836568
40.178903
19.850265
20.882634
0.000054
3.983981
0.020386
4.991998
0.001766
38.269988
2.422806
81.721306
36.730354
46.757087
23.651177
0.000094
0.000011
53.840964
10.641773
0.000496
0.000852
69.809061
81.617213
13.230974
3.829951
14.944494
19.919083
0.000001
3.052868
0.000005
26.171609
19.712447
22.392069
0.000430
2.897287
14.078641
0.010076
69.482232
1.395869
32.803445
100.535228
0.002526
0.000058
19.341968
0.004734
3.604019
2.484929
8.688653