BIS 84th Annual Report
BIS 84th Annual Report
BIS 84th Annual Report
= c
is headline inflation,
is the
Hodrick-Prescott trend of core inflation, y
is lagged
import price inflation, and
= c
is wage inflation,
is the
global output gap, and
is lagged headline inflation. Unemployment gap, domestic and global output gaps are estimated with a
Hodrick-Prescott filter.
Sources: C Borio and A Filardo, Globalisation and inflation: new cross-country evidence on the global determinants of domestic inflation,
BIS Working Papers, no 227, May 2007; J Gal, The return of the wage Phillips curve, Journal of the European Economic Association, no 9,
June 2011; IMF, International Financial Statistics; OECD, Economic Outlook and Main Economic Indicators; Datastream; JPMorgan Chase;
national data; BIS calculations.
0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Domestic output gap Global output gap
197185 198698 19992013 197185 198698 19992013
Significant at the 5% level
0.1
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
Domestic unemployment gap Global output gap
1.1972
197185 198698 19992013 197185 198698 19992013
/
/
/
/
/
/
Insignificant at the 5% level
56 BIS 84th Annual Report
the manufacturing sector have increased steadily while labour productivity growth
appears to have slowed somewhat in recent years. If not met by similar gains in
productivity, wage rises will eventually put upward pressure on export prices.
Disinfationary tailwinds, however, do not appear to have run their full course yet.
And there is still scope for further integration into the global economy of low-
income countries with an ample supply of cheap labour.
Investment and productivity: a long-term perspective
Since 2009, investment and labour productivity growth have lagged behind previous
recoveries. Total gross fxed investment in advanced economies is generally lower
than before the crisis (Graph III.9, left-hand panel). The largest investment shortfall
has occurred in countries that experienced the strongest real estate booms:
14 percentage points in Ireland, 9 in Spain, 4 in the United States and 3 in the
United Kingdom. Construction accounts for most of the drop. But spending on
equipment is also below the pre-crisis average in many countries, refecting
weakness of demand and the slow recovery typical of balance sheet recessions.
It is unrealistic to expect investment, as a share of GDP, to return to its pre-
crisis level in advanced economies. The drop in construction spending is a necessary
correction of previous overinvestment and is unlikely to be entirely reversed.
Moreover, the investment share had been on a downward trend long before the
crisis, suggesting that, as output growth recovers, investment may settle below the
pre-crisis average.
This downward trend in advanced economies refects a number of factors. One
is the decline in trend growth over the past few decades. Since the capital-to-output
ratio has generally remained stable or risen slightly in most countries, a smaller
share of GDP needs to be invested to keep the ratio constant over time. A second
factor is a shift in the composition of output from capital-intensive manufacturing
sectors towards less capital-intensive service sectors. Third, to the extent that
the decline in output growth is driven by exogenous factors, such as adverse
demographics, a slower pace of technological innovation or shifting long-run
patterns in consumer demand, the associated fall in the investment-to-GDP ratio
would be a natural consequence of this slowdown, rather than a driving force.
Moreover, the investment weakness may be overstated. Over the past few
decades, the relative prices of investment goods have been trending down: frms
have been able to keep their capital stocks constant by spending less in nominal
terms. In fact, in real terms, investment spending has fuctuated around a mildly
increasing, not decreasing, trend in advanced economies. In addition, offcial statistics
may underestimate intangible investment (spending on research and development,
training, etc), which has been gaining importance in serviced-based economies.
Finally, and most importantly, at the global level investment is not weak. The
secular drop in the investment-to-GDP share in advanced economies has been
offset by a trend increase in EMEs (Graph III.9, centre panel). Part of it refects strong
investment in China, which at close to 45% of GDP looks unsustainably high
(Graph III.9, right-hand panel). But even excluding China, EME investment has
trended up, albeit at a more moderate pace, in particular in emerging Asia.
This broad picture, however, does not mean that investment could not or
should not be higher. Ageing infrastructure is a potential drag on growth in the
United States, the United Kingdom and other advanced economies. In parts of the
euro area, product market and other rigidities hold back business investment. And
supply bottlenecks are having similar effects in several EMEs, including South Africa,
Brazil and various other Latin American countries.
57 BIS 84th Annual Report
Factors that can potentially hold back a cyclical pickup of investment include
a lack of fnance and weak aggregate demand. But in fact fnancial conditions are
extremely favourable. The cost of capital in major economies has generally fallen
below pre-crisis levels, thanks to very low interest rates and buoyant equity
valuations. Large frms generally have no problem borrowing from banks. And bond
fnancing has been readily available on extraordinarily good terms around the
world, including to frms without an investment grade rating (Chapters II and VI).
Thanks to easy fnance and a recovery in proftability, the net fnancial balance
of the non-fnancial corporate sector has continued to improve. It is now back to
surplus in several advanced economies, at similar levels to those prevailing pre-crisis.
In the United States, for example, internal earnings (net of taxes and dividends plus
depreciation charges) have consistently exceeded capital spending since 2009. On
top of this, US frms have also continued to issue long-term debt to exploit record
low yields. And equity is being withdrawn faster than it is raised, as frms pay higher
dividends, buy back shares and engage in mergers and acquisitions.
Access to fnance may still be a problem for small and medium-sized frms in
countries where the banking sector is still impaired, such as parts of Europe.
Improving the supply of fnance for these frms requires that banks recognise their
losses and recapitalise. Monetary stimulus per se is unlikely to have additional
signifcant effects (Chapters I and V).
With fnance not a constraint, the cyclical weakness of investment is better
explained by the slow recovery in aggregate demand that is typical of balance sheet
recessions. As agents repair balance sheets, their spending remains below pre-crisis
norms, depressing the income of other agents and so prolonging the adjustment
phase (Box III.A). The necessary consolidation of public fnances may further slow
Restricted
9/12
Trends in investment diverge Graph III.9
Advanced, by investment type Global
1
Emerging market economies
1
Change between 200307 and 201013;
% pts of GDP
Total fixed investment, % of GDP
Total fixed investment, % of GDP
DE = Germany; ES = Spain; FR = France; GB = United Kingdom; IE = Ireland; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; NL = Netherlands; SE = Sweden;
US = United States.
1
For China and for advanced economy data, the linear trend is calculated from the earliest available data (from 1960). Aggregates are
weighted averages based on GDP at current PPP exchange rates up to 2011. Advanced economies comprise 17 major economies and EMEs
comprise 14 major economies. For China, 2013 values are estimates.
2
India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia and Thailand.
3
Brazil, Chile,
Mexico and Peru.
Sources: European Commission, AMECO database; IMF; CEIC; national data; BIS calculations.
15
10
5
0
IE ES US GB IT NL JP DE FR SE
Residential construction
Non-residential construction
Equipment
Other
16
20
24
28
32
83 88 93 98 03 08 13
Global
Advanced
EMEs
15
20
25
30
35
40
45
83 88 93 98 03 08 13
China
EMEs excluding China
EM Asia excluding China
2
Latin America
3
58 BIS 84th Annual Report
growth in the short term. As the recovery proceeds, investment should pick up.
Indeed, investment growth has already risen in recent quarters, albeit modestly, in
a number of countries, including Germany, the United States and the United
Kingdom.
The current weakness of aggregate demand may suggest the need for further
monetary stimulus or for easing the pace of fscal consolidation. However, these
policies are likely to be either ineffective in current circumstances (Chapter V) or
unsustainable: taking a long-term perspective, they may simply succeed in bringing
forward spending from the future rather than increasing its overall amount over the
long run, while leading to a further rise in public and private debt. Instead, the only
way to boost demand in a sustainable manner is to raise the production capacity of
the economy by removing barriers to productive investment and the reallocation of
resources. This is even more important in the face of declining productivity growth.
Declining productivity growth trends
Since 2010, labour productivity growth has been below pre-crisis averages in most
advanced economies and has so far risen much more slowly than in previous
business cycle recoveries. For instance, it has averaged about 1% in both the United
States and Germany, compared with 2.3% and 1.8%, respectively, over the pre-crisis
decade; and it has been close to zero in the United Kingdom, against a pre-crisis
average of 2%. Spain is an exception: there it has risen above pre-crisis averages
following the large decline in employment.
Part of the weakness of productivity growth since the start of the recovery
refects (as noted earlier) the slow recovery typical of a balance sheet recession. But
it also refects, to some degree, the continuation of a downward trend which began
well before the onset of the fnancial crisis (Graph III.10, left-hand panel). Such a
trend is also evident in estimates of total factor productivity (TFP), which measures
the effciency with which both capital and labour are employed in production
(Graph III.10, centre panel). In the United States and the United Kingdom, both
measures indicate that productivity growth underwent a revival from the mid-1980s
till the early 2000s, but has since subsided. TFP growth in the euro area, by contrast,
has been falling steadily since the early 1970s and is currently negative. TFP growth
in Japan has also clearly lagged behind that of the United States: it frst fell sharply
and then turned negative during the fnancial bust of the early 1990s, recovering
somewhat only in the early 2000s.
The productivity growth slowdown, which may have been partly obscured by
the pre-crisis fnancial boom, is likely to refect deeper factors. The frst is the pace of
technological innovation, which is, however, diffcult to predict. One pessimistic view
is that the information technology revolution led only to a temporary one-off revival
of productivity, which ran its course before the start of the crisis.
5
The second is
patterns of demand: the shift towards low-productivity growth sectors, such as
services (health care, education, leisure, etc) tends to reduce aggregate productivity
growth.
6
The third is the worsening of various structural impediments to the effcient
5
For a pessimistic view, see eg R Gordon, U.S. productivity growth: the slowdown has returned after
a temporary revival, International Productivity Monitor, 2013. For an optimistic view, see M Baily,
J Manyika and S Gupta, U.S. productivity growth: an optimistic perspective, International
Productivity Monitor, 2013.
6
See eg C Echevarra, Changes in sectoral composition associated with economic growth,
International Economic Review, vol 38, 1997; and M Duarte and D Restuccia, The role of structural
transformation in aggregate productivity, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol 125, 2010.
59 BIS 84th Annual Report
allocation of resources, which may prevent the adoption and the effcient use of the
latest technology. High levels of public debt may also weigh negatively (see Box III.B
for details).
The misallocation of resources is likely to have worsened further in the wake of
the fnancial crisis. Existing evidence suggests that in crisis-hit countries low interest
rates and forbearance might be locking up resources in ineffcient companies. For
example, frm-level data indicate that in the United Kingdom around one third of
the productivity slowdown since 2007 is due to slower reallocation of resources
between frms, in terms of both labour movements between frms and frms market
exit and entry.
7
Countries that have been too slow in repairing their balance sheets
may in some respects resemble Japan after its early 1990s fnancial bust (Box III.B).
Unless productivity growth picks up, the prospects for output growth are dim.
In particular, population ageing in many advanced economies, and not only there,
will act as a drag on growth. The share of the working-age population has been
falling in the euro area and, even more rapidly, in Japan. In the United States and
the United Kingdom, it peaked just before the beginning of the fnancial crisis
(Graph III.10, right-hand panel).
All this puts a premium on efforts to improve productivity growth. There is a
need to remove various structural barriers to innovation and investment and to
make economies more fexible in the allocation of capital and labour, especially in
the euro area, Japan and other economies where productivity growth has
signifcantly lagged that of the United States. Examples include distortions in the tax
system, red tape and excessive product and labour market regulation.
8
In addition,
further fscal consolidation is of the essence to prevent high levels of government
7
See A Barnett, A Chiu, J Franklin and M Sebastia-Barriel, The productivity puzzle: a frm-level
investigation into employment behaviour and resource allocation over the crisis, Bank of England
Working Papers, no 495, April 2014.
8
See eg OECD, Economic Policy Reforms 2014: Going for Growth Interim Report, April 2014.
Restricted
10/12
Productivity growth and working-age population are on a declining path Graph III.10
Growth in output per hour worked
1
Growth in TFP
2
Working-age population
3
Per cent
Per cent
Per cent of total population
1
Annualised quarter-on-quarter difference of the Hodrick-Prescott filter (HPF) series of the log-levels of real GDP per hour worked
estimated from Q1 1970 (United States: Q1 1960) up to and including forecasts to Q4 2015.
2
Annual difference in the HPF series of logs
of total factor productivity (TFP) estimated from 1950 (euro area: 1970) to 2011.
3
The shaded area refers to projections.
4
Weighted
average based on GDP at PPP exchange rates (right-hand panel: sum) of France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands and Spain.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; United Nations, World Population Prospects: The 2012 Revision; Penn World Tables 8.0; BIS calculations.
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
70 80 90 00 10
United States Euro area
4
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
70 80 90 00 10
Japan United Kingdom
50
55
60
65
70
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040
60 BIS 84th Annual Report
debt from becoming a persistent drag on trend growth. In this regard, despite some
progress, most advanced economies have yet to set their public fnances on a
sustainable long-term trajectory (Graph III.4 and Annex Table III.3).
9
Several EMEs have until recently displayed stable or even rising productivity
growth. But productivity growth may have turned in some countries. The recent
fnancial booms may partly obscure the fact that improvements in effciency may
become harder to achieve. As an economy reaches middle income levels, the size of
the manufacturing sector peaks and demand for services becomes more important.
This makes it harder to close the productivity gap with the most advanced
economies: quite apart from slower productivity growth in the service sector,
institutional and structural weaknesses tend to be a stronger drag on the service
sector than on manufacturing. Increasing demographic headwinds are also
expected to weigh on growth in a number of EMEs.
These considerations suggest that sustainable long-term growth requires
structural measures that directly tackle the sources of low productivity rather than
policies aimed at stimulating aggregate demand. Relaxing supply constraints may
also have positive spillovers on current demand, as agents could spend more in
anticipation of higher future income. By contrast, debt-fnanced stimulus may be less
effective than hoped and raise long-term sustainability issues (Chapter V).
9
Fiscal adjustment needs are particularly large in Japan, the United States, the United Kingdom,
France and Spain. Most of the required adjustment in the United States and the United Kingdom
is due to age-related spending, which is expected to rise rapidly by the end of the current decade
in the absence of reforms. For a more detailed analysis, see BIS, 83rd Annual Report, June 2013,
Chapter IV.
61 BIS 84th Annual Report
Output growth, infation and current account balances
1
Annex Table III.1
Real GDP Consumer prices
2
Current account balance
3
Annual percentage changes Annual percentage changes Per cent of GDP
2012 2013 2014 1996
2006
2012 2013 2014 1996
2006
2012 2013 2014
World 2.6 2.4 2.8 3.9 3.0 2.7 3.1 4.3
Advanced economies 1.4 1.1 1.9 2.8 1.9 1.3 1.6 1.9 0.6 0.1 0.1
United States 2.8 1.9 2.5 3.4 2.1 1.5 1.8 2.6 2.7 2.3 2.0
Euro area
4
0.6 0.4 1.1 2.4 2.5 1.4 0.8 1.9 1.3 2.4 2.2
France 0.4 0.4 0.8 2.3 2.0 0.9 1.0 1.6 2.2 1.3 1.4
Germany 0.9 0.5 1.9 1.5 2.0 1.5 1.3 1.4 7.4 7.5 7.2
Italy 2.4 1.8 0.6 1.5 3.0 1.2 0.8 2.4 0.4 1.0 1.3
Spain 1.6 1.2 1.0 3.7 2.4 1.4 0.3 3.0 1.1 0.8 1.3
Japan 1.5 1.5 1.3 1.1 0.0 0.4 2.6 0.0 1.0 0.7 0.4
United Kingdom 0.3 1.7 2.9 3.3 2.8 2.6 1.9 1.6 3.7 4.4 3.6
Other western Europe
5
1.3 1.3 2.1 2.6 0.7 0.6 0.7 1.4 9.3 9.6 9.1
Canada 1.7 2.0 2.3 3.2 1.5 0.9 1.7 2.0 3.4 3.2 2.8
Australia 3.6 2.4 2.9 3.6 1.8 2.4 2.7 2.6 4.1 2.9 2.6
EMEs 4.6 4.3 4.2 5.6 4.6 4.7 5.3 5.4 1.9 1.6 1.6
Asia 5.8 5.8 5.8 7.0 3.7 3.4 3.4 2.9 1.9 2.2 2.1
China 7.8 7.7 7.3 9.2 2.7 2.6 2.5 1.4 2.3 2.1 2.1
India
6
4.5 4.7 5.4 6.7 7.4 6.0 5.5 4.8 4.7 2.0 2.4
Korea 2.3 3.0 3.6 5.1 2.2 1.3 1.9 3.2 4.3 6.5 5.1
Other Asia
7
4.6 4.1 4.2 4.0 3.1 3.2 3.5 3.8 3.8 3.6 4.0
Latin America
8
2.9 2.5 2.1 3.1 5.9 8.1 10.9 7.2 1.7 2.5 2.5
Brazil 1.0 2.5 1.7 2.6 5.8 5.9 6.3 7.7 2.4 3.6 3.5
Mexico 3.7 1.3 2.9 3.5 3.6 4.0 3.9 4.4 1.2 1.8 1.9
Central Europe
9
0.7 0.8 2.8 4.0 4.0 1.3 0.9 3.0 2.5 0.6 1.1
Poland 2.1 1.5 3.1 4.5 3.7 1.2 1.1 2.5 3.5 1.3 2.0
Russia 3.5 1.3 0.3 4.3 6.5 6.5 6.4 12.9 3.6 1.5 1.7
Turkey 2.2 4.0 2.4 4.7 8.9 7.5 8.3 24.8 6.2 7.9 6.2
Saudi Arabia 5.8 3.8 4.2 3.6 2.9 3.5 3.4 0.5 22.4 18.0 14.1
South Africa 2.5 1.9 2.5 3.5 5.7 5.8 6.2 4.2 5.2 5.8 5.2
1
Based on May 2014 consensus forecasts. For the aggregates, weighted averages based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange rates. EMEs include
other Middle East economies (not shown here). 19962006 values refer to average annual growth and infation (for EMEs, infation calculated
over 200106).
2
For India, wholesale prices.
3
For the aggregates, sum of the countries and regions shown or cited; world fgures do not
sum to zero because of incomplete country coverage and statistical discrepancies.
4
Current account based on the aggregation of extra-euro
area transactions.
5
Denmark, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland.
6
Fiscal years (starting in April).
7
Chinese Taipei, Hong Kong SAR,
Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand.
8
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru and Venezuela. For Argentina,
consumer price data are based on offcial estimates (methodological break in December 2013).
9
The Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland.
Sources: IMF; Consensus Economics; national data; BIS calculations.
62 BIS 84th Annual Report
Recovery of output, employment and productivity from the recent crisis
In per cent Annex Table III.2
Q1 2014
1
vs pre-crisis peak
(trough for unemployment rate)
Q1 2014
1
vs
pre-crisis trend
Peak-to-trough
fall
2
Memo: Average
annual output
growth
Real
GDP
Employ-
ment
Output
per
worker
Unemp
rate
(%pts)
Real
GDP
Output
per
worker
Real
GDP
Employ-
ment
Pre-
crisis
3
Post-
crisis
4
United States 5.9 0.8 6.6 2.8 12.6 6.8 4.4 5.9 3.4 2.2
Japan 1.2 3.7 2.6 0.4 2.3 3.0 9.7 4.6 1.1 1.8
United Kingdom 0.6 2.5 3.8 2.3 18.6 15.3 7.5 2.5 3.3 1.3
Euro area
Germany 3.8 4.0 0.6 2.2 2.5 5.1 7.0 0.5 1.5 2.1
France 1.1 1.0 2.1 3.0 12.1 4.3 4.1 1.7 2.3 1.1
Italy 9.4 5.2 5.7 6.8 17.7 4.6 9.4 5.2 1.5 0.5
Netherlands 4.5 2.5 2.4 5.0 17.4 8.4 5.1 2.5 2.7 0.1
Spain 7.1 17.8 10.6 17.9 29.0 12.1 7.7 18.3 3.7 0.7
Austria 0.5 4.2 4.2 1.7 11.4 12.0 6.5 1.1 2.5 1.4
Belgium 1.2 1.8 1.0 2.1 10.7 7.6 4.4 0.7 2.2 1.0
Greece 28.3 20.4 6.9 20.6 50.5 18.8 28.3 20.4 3.6 5.6
Ireland 10.1 11.4 1.3 7.9 47.6 12.5 12.2 15.1 7.1 0.2
Portugal 7.5 11.6 4.3 11.5 20.0 1.7 8.8 13.4 2.4 0.9
Poland 15.0 1.4 12.7 3.1 3.9 15.2 1.3 1.4 4.5 3.0
Korea 16.8 7.6 9.3 1.1 11.0 10.9 3.4 0.8 5.1 3.8
1
Q4 2013 for real GDP and output per worker for Ireland; Q4 2013 for unemployment rate for Greece.
2
Trough calculated over 2008 to
latest available data.
3
19962006.
4
2010 to latest available data.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; Datastream; BIS calculations.
63 BIS 84th Annual Report
Fiscal positions
1
Annex Table III.3
Overall balance
2
Underlying government
primary balance
3
Gross debt
2
2009 2014 Change 2009 2014 Change 2007 2014 Change
Advanced economies
Austria 4.1 2.8 1.3 1.4 1.7 3.2 63 90 26.6
Belgium 5.6 2.1 3.5 0.9 1.4 2.3 88 107 19.0
Canada 4.5 2.1 2.4 2.6 1.6 1.0 70 94 23.8
France 7.5 3.8 3.7 4.6 0.1 4.7 73 115 42.1
Germany 3.1 0.2 2.9 0.9 0.8 0.1 66 84 18.3
Greece 15.6 2.5 13.2 10.2 7.5 17.7 119 189 69.4
Ireland 13.7 4.7 9.0 7.7 1.8 9.5 29 133 104.0
Italy 5.4 2.7 2.7 0.4 4.7 4.3 117 147 30.6
Japan 8.8 8.4 0.5 7.0 7.1 0.1 162 230 67.2
Netherlands 5.6 2.7 2.9 3.6 1.2 4.8 51 88 36.1
Portugal 10.2 4.0 6.2 4.9 3.5 8.4 76 141 65.7
Spain 11.1 5.5 5.6 9.4 0.7 8.6 43 108 66.0
Sweden 1.0 1.5 0.6 1.8 0.6 2.4 48 49 0.4
United Kingdom 11.2 5.3 5.9 7.5 2.6 4.9 47 102 54.7
United States 12.8 5.8 7.0 7.5 2.4 5.1 64 106 42.4
Emerging market economies
Brazil 3.3 3.3 0.1 2.7 2.0 0.7 65 67 1.5
China 3.1 2.0 1.1 2.2 0.5 1.7 20 20 0.6
India 9.8 7.2 2.5 5.0 2.4 2.6 74 65 8.7
Indonesia 1.8 2.5 0.8 0.0 1.2 1.2 35 26 9.0
Korea 1.0 0.1 1.1 0.7 0.7 1.4 27 38 11.0
Malaysia 6.7 3.5 3.3 4.3 1.7 2.7 41 56 15.1
Mexico 5.1 4.1 1.0 1.9 1.4 0.5 38 48 10.6
South Africa 4.9 4.4 0.5 0.9 0.8 0.0 28 47 19.0
Thailand 3.2 1.6 1.6 1.4 0.2 1.6 38 47 8.2
1
For the general government.
2
As a percentage of GDP. OECD estimates for advanced economies and Korea, otherwise IMF.
3
As a
percentage of potential GDP; excluding net interest payments. OECD estimates for advanced economies and Korea, otherwise IMF. OECD
estimates are adjusted for the cycle and for one-off transactions, and IMF estimates are adjusted for the cycle.
Sources: IMF; OECD.
65 BIS 84th Annual Report
IV. Debt and the fnancial cycle: domestic and global
A pure business cycle view is not enough to understand the evolution of the global
economy since the fnancial crisis of 200709 (Chapters I and III). This view cannot
fully account for the interaction between debt, asset prices and output that explains
many advanced economies poor growth in recent years. This chapter explores the
role debt, leverage and risk-taking have played in driving economic and fnancial
developments, in particular by assessing where different economies stand in terms
of the fnancial cycle.
Financial cycles differ from business cycles. They encapsulate the self-
reinforcing interactions between perceptions of value and risk, risk-taking and
fnancing constraints which translate into fnancial booms and busts. They tend to
be much longer than business cycles, and are best measured by a combination of
credit aggregates and property prices. Output and fnancial variables can move in
different directions for long periods of time, but the link tends to re-establish itself
with a vengeance when fnancial booms turn into busts. Such episodes often
coincide with banking crises, which in turn tend to go hand in hand with much
deeper recessions balance sheet recessions than those that characterise the
average business cycle.
High private sector debt levels can undermine sustainable economic growth.
In many economies currently experiencing fnancial booms, households and frms
are in a vulnerable position, which poses the risk of serious fnancial distress and
macroeconomic strains. And in the countries hardest hit by the crisis, private debt
levels are still high relative to output, making households and frms sensitive to
increases in interest rates. These countries could fnd themselves in a debt trap:
seeking to stimulate the economy through low interest rates encourages the
taking-on of even more debt, ultimately adding to the problem it is meant to solve.
The growth of new funding sources has changed the character of risks. In the
so-called second phase of global liquidity, corporations in emerging market
economies (EMEs) have tapped international securities markets for much of their
funding. In part, this has been done through their affliates abroad, whose debt is
typically off authorities radar screens. Market fnance tends to have longer
maturities than bank fnance, thus reducing rollover risks. But it is notoriously
procyclical. It is cheap and ample when conditions are good, but can evaporate at
the frst sign of problems. This could also have knock-on effects on domestic
fnancial institutions, which have relied on the domestic corporate sector for an
important part of their funding. Finally, the vast majority of EME private sector
external debt remains in foreign currency, thus exposing borrowers to currency risk.
This chapter begins with a short description of the main characteristics of the
fnancial cycle, followed by a section analysing the stage of the cycle particular
countries fnd themselves in. The third section looks at drivers of the fnancial cycle
in recent years. The fnal section discusses risks and potential adjustment needs.
The fnancial cycle: a short introduction
While there is no consensus defnition of the fnancial cycle, the broad concept
encapsulates joint fuctuations in a wide set of fnancial variables including both
quantities and prices. BIS research suggests that credit aggregates, as a proxy for
66 BIS 84th Annual Report
leverage, and property prices, as a measure of available collateral, play a particularly
important role in this regard. Rapid increases in credit, particularly mortgage credit,
drive up property prices, which in turn increase collateral values and thus the amount
of credit the private sector can obtain. It is this mutually reinforcing interaction
between fnancing constraints and perceptions of value and risks that has historically
caused the most serious macroeconomic dislocations. Other variables, such as credit
spreads, risk premia and default rates, provide useful complementary information
on stress, risk perceptions and risk appetite.
Four features characterise fnancial cycles empirically (Box IV.A describes how
fnancial cycles can be measured). First, they are much longer than business cycles.
As traditionally measured, business cycles tend to last from one to eight years,
and fnancial cycles around 15 to 20 years. The difference in length means that a
fnancial cycle can span several business cycles.
Second, peaks in the fnancial cycle tend to coincide with banking crises or
periods of considerable fnancial stress. Financial booms in which surging asset
prices and rapid credit growth reinforce each other tend to be driven by
prolonged accommodative monetary and fnancial conditions, often in combination
with fnancial innovation. Loose fnancing conditions, in turn, feed into the real
economy, leading to excessive leverage in some sectors and overinvestment in the
industries particularly in vogue, such as real estate. If a shock hits the economy,
overextended households or frms often fnd themselves unable to service their
debt. Sectoral misallocations built up during the boom further aggravate this vicious
cycle (Chapter III).
Third, fnancial cycles are often synchronised across economies. While they do
not necessarily move in lockstep globally, many drivers of the fnancial cycle have
an important global component. For example, liquidity conditions tend to be highly
correlated across markets. Mobile fnancial capital tends to equalise risk premia and
fnancing conditions across currencies and borders and acts as the (price-setting)
marginal source of fnance. External capital thus often plays an outsize role in
unsustainable credit booms, amplifying movements in credit aggregates, and may
also induce overshooting in exchange rates. It does so directly when a currency is used
outside national jurisdictions, as exemplifed by the international role of the US dollar.
Monetary conditions can also spread indirectly through resistance to exchange rate
appreciation, if policymakers keep policy rates lower than suggested by domestic
conditions alone and/or intervene and accumulate foreign currency reserves.
Fourth, fnancial cycles change with the macroeconomic environment and
policy frameworks. For example, they have grown both in length and amplitude
since the early 1980s, probably refecting more liberalised fnancial systems,
seemingly more stable macroeconomic conditions and monetary policy frameworks
that have disregarded developments in credit. The signifcant changes in regulatory
and macroeconomic policy frameworks after the fnancial crisis may also change the
dynamics going forward.
These four features are evident in Graph IV.1, which depicts fnancial cycles in
a large range of countries. In many advanced economies, the fnancial cycle as
measured by aggregating medium-term movements of real credit, the credit-to-
GDP ratio and real house prices peaked in the early 1990s and again around 2008
(Box IV.A). Both turning points coincided with widespread banking crises. The
fnancial cycles in many Asian economies show a markedly different timing, peaking
around the Asian fnancial crisis in the late 1990s. Another boom started in these
economies just after the turn of the millennium and persists today, barely
interrupted by the fnancial crisis. In some cases, for instance the banking distress in
Germany and Switzerland in 200709, strains have developed independently from
the domestic fnancial cycle through banks exposures to fnancial cycles elsewhere.
67 BIS 84th Annual Report
AR84 Chapter 4 June 19 2014 16:00h
Financial cycle peaks tend to coincide with crises
1
Graph IV.1
Euro area
2
Other advanced countries
3
Emerging Asia
4
Germany Japan Korea
Switzerland United Kingdom United States
1
The financial cycle as measured by frequency-based (bandpass) filters capturing medium-term cycles in real credit, the credit-to-GDP
ratio and real house prices (Box IV.A). Vertical lines indicate financial crises emerging from domestic vulnerabilities.
2
Belgium, Finland,
France, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Portugal and Spain.
3
Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway and Sweden.
4
Indonesia,
Hong Kong SAR and Singapore.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
0.30
0.15
0.00
0.15
90 95 00 05 10
The loose link between business and fnancial cycles over prolonged periods
may tempt policymakers to focus on the former without paying much heed to
the latter. But setting policy without regard to the fnancial cycle comes at a peril. It
may result in fnancial imbalances, such as overindebted corporate or household
sectors or bloated fnancial systems, that render certain sectors fragile to even a
small deterioration in macroeconomic or fnancial conditions. This is what happened
in Japan and the Nordic countries in the 1980s and early 1990s and in Ireland,
Spain, the United Kingdom and the United States in the years before the fnancial
crisis.
Diverging fnancial and business cycles can also help to explain the
phenomenon of unfnished recessions. For example, in the wake of the stock
market crashes in 1987 and 2000, monetary policy in the United States was eased
substantially, even though the fnancial cycle was in an upswing (Graph IV.A).
Benefting from lower interest rates, property prices and credit did not contract but
expand, only to collapse several years later.
68 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box IV.A
Measuring fnancial cycles
Policymakers and researchers can build on a wealth of knowledge to measure business cycles, but the same is not
true for fnancial cycles. This box discusses the main ideas and insights in the emerging literature on how to measure
fnancial cycles.
Two methods have been used to identify both business and fnancial cycles. The frst is known as the turning
point method, and goes back to the original work in the 1940s to date business cycles, still used today by the NBER
Business Cycle Dating Committee. This approach identifes cyclical peaks and troughs by looking at growth rates of
a broad range of underlying series. For example, a business cycle peaks when the growth rate of several series,
including output, employment, industrial production and consumption, changes from positive to negative. For
fnancial cycles, BIS research has shown that real credit growth, the credit-to-GDP ratio and real property price
growth represent the smallest set of variables needed to depict adequately the mutually reinforcing interaction
between fnancing constraints and perceptions of value and risks that can cause serious macroeconomic dislocations
and banking crises. That said, other variables, such as credit spreads, equity prices, risk premia and default rates, also
measure risk or risk perceptions and hence fnancial cycles. The second approach is based on statistical flters that
extract cyclical fuctuations with a particular cycle length from a specifc series, for instance output.
The fnancial cycle estimates shown in this chapter follow the second approach and are based on joint
developments in real credit growth, the credit-to-GDP ratio and real property price growth. Cycles in the individual
series are extracted by using a bandpass flter with cycles lasting between eight and 30 years, which are then
combined into a single series by taking a simple average. Bandpass flters are useful for identifying historical fnancial
cycles, yet observations for recent years must be treated more carefully, as trends and thus cyclical fuctuations may
change when more data become available in the future.
The traditional business cycle frequency is around one to eight years. By contrast, the fnancial cycles that matter
most for banking crises and major macroeconomic dislocations last 1020 years. This is evident from Graph IV.A.
Focusing on medium-term frequencies is appropriate for two reasons. First, credit and property prices move much
more closely together at these frequencies than at higher ones. Second, these medium-term cycles are an important
driver of overall fuctuations in these two series, much more so than medium cyclical fuctuations are for real GDP.
Financial cycles identifed in this way are closely associated with systemic banking crises and serious economic
damage. This holds irrespective of whether they are identifed with a turning point approach or a statistical flter.
This box is based on M Drehmann, C Borio and K Tsatsaronis, Characterising the fnancial cycle: dont lose sight of the medium term!,
BIS Working Papers, no 380, June 2012. See also D Aikman, A Haldane and B Nelson, Curbing the credit cycle, prepared for the Columbia
University Center on Capital and Society Annual Conference, New York, November 2010; and S Claessens, M Kose and M Terrones, How do
business and fnancial cycles interact?, IMF Working Papers, no WP/11/88, April 2011. See Drehmann et al, op cit.
The financial and business cycles in the United States Graph IV.A
1
The financial cycle as measured by frequency-based (bandpass) filters capturing medium-term cycles in real credit, the credit-to-GDP
ratio and real house prices.
2
The business cycle as measured by a frequency-based (bandpass) filter capturing fluctuations in real GDP
over a period from one to eight years.
Source: M Drehmann, C Borio and K Tsatsaronis, Characterising the financial cycle: dont lose sight of the medium term!, BIS Working
Papers, no 380, June 2012.
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
71 74 77 80 83 86 89 92 95 98 01 04 07 10 13
First oil crisis
Second oil crisis
Black Monday
Banking strains
Dotcom crash
Financial crisis
Financial cycle
1
Business cycle
2
69 BIS 84th Annual Report
Where are countries in the fnancial cycle?
In recent years, fnancial cycle downswings in most advanced economies have
coincided with upswings in large EMEs and other countries. Unfortunately, the lack
of long series on credit and property prices precludes the construction of the
fnancial cycle indicator illustrated in Graph IV.1 for several important economies.
But recent credit and property price developments offer a useful picture, if an
incomplete one. These data suggest that countries are at very different stages of
the fnancial cycle (Graph IV.2).
Many euro area countries are in a fnancial downswing. Following a prolonged
boom, the euro area countries that were most affected by the fnancial crisis and
the subsequent European debt crisis, such as Greece and Spain, have seen real
credit and property prices fall by an average of 510% annually in recent years. But
downward pressures appear to be receding somewhat, as the decline in credit and
house prices has slowed in recent quarters.
Financial cycles in other economies that experienced a crisis seem to have
bottomed out. The United States saw a large run-up in credit and asset prices
that ended with the onset of the fnancial crisis. The subsequent downswing in
asset prices and non-fnancial corporate borrowing ended in 2011, and
household borrowing started to pick up in 2013. The picture is less clear-cut
for the United Kingdom and many central and eastern European economies
countries that also experienced boom-bust cycles in the last decade. Deleveraging
in these countries continues, but the pace is slowing and property prices
have started to rise again, suggesting that the downward trend in the fnancial
cycle may have reversed.
Signals are mixed for advanced economies that did not see an outright crisis
in recent years. Australia, Canada and the Nordic countries experienced large
fnancial booms in the mid- to late 2000s. But the global and European debt crises
dented these dynamics; asset prices fuctuated widely and corporate borrowing
fell as global economic activity deteriorated. This pushed the medium-term
fnancial cycle indicator on a downward trend, even though households in all these
economies continued to borrow, albeit at a slower pace. But the strong increase
in commodity prices in recent years prevented a lasting turn of the cycle, and
over the last four quarters real property price and (total) credit growth in Australia
and Canada has picked up to levels close to or in line with developments in
large EMEs.
Booms are clearly evident in several other countries, in particular EMEs. In
many cases, the surge in credit and asset prices slowed in 2008 and 2009
but resumed full force in 2010. Since then, credit to the private sector has
expanded by an average of about 10% per year. In China, this growth was
mainly driven by non-banks, whereas banks fnanced the expansion in Turkey. At
present, there are signs that some of these booms are stalling. For example,
property price growth in Brazil has weakened, which is typical of the later stages
of the fnancial cycle. Rising defaults in the property sector in China also point in
this direction.
What is driving the fnancial cycle in the current context?
To some extent, the current state of the fnancial cycle refects the self-reinforcing
adjustment after the fnancial crisis. The ratios of private sector debt to GDP have
slid by roughly 20 percentage points from their recent peaks in the United States,
the United Kingdom and Spain. While substantial, these reductions still fall well
The financial and business cycles in the United States Graph IV.A
1
The financial cycle as measured by frequency-based (bandpass) filters capturing medium-term cycles in real credit, the credit-to-GDP
ratio and real house prices.
2
The business cycle as measured by a frequency-based (bandpass) filter capturing fluctuations in real GDP
over a period from one to eight years.
Source: M Drehmann, C Borio and K Tsatsaronis, Characterising the financial cycle: dont lose sight of the medium term!, BIS Working
Papers, no 380, June 2012.
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
0.10
0.15
71 74 77 80 83 86 89 92 95 98 01 04 07 10 13
First oil crisis
Second oil crisis
Black Monday
Banking strains
Dotcom crash
Financial crisis
Financial cycle
1
Business cycle
2
70 BIS 84th Annual Report
Where are countries in the financial cycle?
1
Changes in a range of cycle indicators Graph IV.2
Real credit growth
2
Real residential property price growth
3
Medium-term financial indicator
4
AU = Australia; BR = Brazil; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; CN = China; DE = Germany; ES = Spain; FR = France; GB = United Kingdom;
GR = Greece; IN = India; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; KR = Korea; MX = Mexico; NL = the Netherlands; PT = Portugal; TR = Turkey;
US = United States; ZA = South Africa.
Asia = Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand; CEE = central and eastern Europe: Bulgaria, the
Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania and Russia; Nordic = Finland, Norway and Sweden.
* Data not available.
1
A boom (bust) is identified if all three indicators for a country provide clear positive (negative) readings over both horizons. Countries are
not classified if indicators provide marginal or mixed signals over the same periods.
2
Total credit to the private non-financial sector
deflated by GDP deflator (except for Sweden, deflated using consumer prices). Growth rates for 201013 are annualised.
3
Deflated using
consumer price indices. Growth rates for 201013 are annualised.
4
Changes in the financial cycle as measured by frequency-based
(bandpass) filters capturing medium-term cycles in real credit, the credit-to-GDP ratio and real house prices (Box IV.A); Asia excluding
Malaysia, the Philippines and Thailand.
5
Depending on data availability, the last observation is either Q4 2013 or Q1 2014.
Sources: OECD; Datastream; national data; BIS; BIS calculations.
10
5
0
5
10
15
20
ES GR IT PT AU CA CEE DE FR GB JP KR MX NL Nordic US ZA Asia BR CH CN IN TR
Bust Boom
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
10
5
0
5
10
ES GR IT PT AU CA CEE DE FR GB JP KR MX NL Nordic US ZA Asia BR CH CN IN TR
Bust Boom
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
*
0.20
0.15
0.10
0.05
0.00
0.05
ES GR IT PT AU CA CEE DE FR GB JP KR MX NL Nordic US ZA Asia BR CH CN IN TR
Bust Boom
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
_
* * * * * * *
End-2010 to end-2013 Last four quarters
5
71 BIS 84th Annual Report
short of both the size of the prior increases in these countries and the average drop
of 38 percentage points seen after a set of historical crises.
1
These developments could indicate that in at least some cases the ratios
of debt to income still have some way to fall. This could particularly be the case
for Spain, where the decrease in the debt ratio was achieved mainly through
a reduction in the amount of nominal debt outstanding (Graph IV.3). This pattern
is typical of the early stages of deleveraging. In the United States, nominal debt
fell during 2009 and 2010 but has grown since. Instead, the main driver
of deleveraging has been nominal GDP growth. The picture for the United
Kingdom is more mixed: both debt reductions and nominal GDP growth have
played a role.
Accommodative monetary policy has had an ambiguous impact on the
adjustment to lower debt ratios (Chapter V). It has supported adjustment to the
extent that it has succeeded in stimulating output, raising income and hence
providing economic agents with the resources to pay back debt and save. But
record low interest rates have also allowed borrowers to service debt stocks that
would be unsustainable in more normal interest rate conditions, and lenders to
evergreen such debt. This tends to delay necessary debt adjustments and result in a
high outstanding stock of debt, which in turn can slow growth.
Global liquidity and domestic policies fuel credit booms
The strong post-crisis monetary policy easing in the major advanced economies
has spurred a surge in global liquidity. Near zero policy rates and large-scale asset
purchases by the Federal Reserve and other major central banks have boosted asset
1
G Tang and C Upper, Debt reduction after crises, BIS Quarterly Review, September 2010, pp 2538,
show that the ratio of credit to GDP fell after 17 out of a sample of 20 such crises. On average, it
dropped by 38 percentage points, almost the same magnitude as the increase during the preceding
boom (44 percentage points).
Uneven deleveraging after the crisis Graph IV.3
United States United Kingdom Spain
Per cent Percentage points
Per cent Percentage points
Per cent Percentage points
1
Ratio of total credit to the private non-financial sector to nominal GDP.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
Low yields in advanced economies push funds into emerging market economies Graph IV.4
External flows into EME debt
1
International debt securities issuance by EME
non-financial corporations
3
USD bn
Amount outstanding, USD bn
1
Cumulative inflows starting in Q1 2008; excluding Hong Kong SAR and Singapore.
2
Portfolio debt securities (liabilities) plus other debt
instruments (liabilities) minus corresponding BIS reporting banks inflows. For India, the balance of payments data start in Q2 2009 and end
in Q1 2013.
3
Excluding official sector and banks.
Sources: IMF, Balance of Payments Statistics and International Financial Statistics; BIS international banking statistics; BIS calculations.
155
160
165
170
4
2
0
2
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Debt ratio
1
Lhs:
182
189
196
203
6
3
0
3
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Nominal debt
Contribution to changes in debt ratio
by changes in (rhs):
Nominal GDP
198
207
216
225
10
5
0
5
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
500
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
From BIS reporting banks From other investors
2
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Nationality Residence
72 BIS 84th Annual Report
prices around the globe and fuelled investors appetite for risk (the risk-taking
channel).
Large capital infows have amplifed the domestic fnancial expansion in many
EMEs. Since the beginning of 2008, residents in EMEs have borrowed over $2 trillion
abroad (Graph IV.4, left-hand panel).
2
At 2.2% of their annual GDP this may not
look large relative to current account balances, but over the period in question it
represents a signifcant additional stock of external debt.
These residence-based fgures actually underestimate the amount of external
debt incurred by EME nationals because they ignore debt issued by offshore
affliates. Classifying issues by the immediate borrowers nationality (ie where its
parent company is headquartered) rather than residence, as in the balance of
payments, boosts the amount of debt securitities issued by EME corporations by
over one third (Graph IV.4, right-hand panel).
Much of this debt was raised in the bond market from investors other than
banks (red bars in Graph IV.4). This second phase of global liquidity contrasts with
the period before the fnancial crisis, when bank lending played a central role.
3
Two factors explain this shift. First, many globally active banks have been repairing
their balance sheets in the wake of the crisis and have been less willing to lend
outside their core markets (Chapter VI). Second, low interest rates and bond yields
in the large advanced economies have pushed investors into higher-yielding
asset classes such as EME debt (Chapter II). As a result, the average nominal long-
term bond yield in EMEs, based on a sample of those economies with genuine
long-term bond markets and foating exchange rates, fell from about 8% at the
2
In order to avoid double-counting of fows routed through offshore centres, fows to Hong Kong
SAR and Singapore are dropped, but fows from these fnancial centres to other EMEs are included.
3
See H S Shin, The second phase of global liquidity and its impact on emerging economies,
keynote address at the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Asia Economic Policy Conference,
November 2013.
Uneven deleveraging after the crisis Graph IV.3
United States United Kingdom Spain
Per cent Percentage points
Per cent Percentage points
Per cent Percentage points
1
Ratio of total credit to the private non-financial sector to nominal GDP.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
Low yields in advanced economies push funds into emerging market economies Graph IV.4
External flows into EME debt
1
International debt securities issuance by EME
non-financial corporations
3
USD bn
Amount outstanding, USD bn
1
Cumulative inflows starting in Q1 2008; excluding Hong Kong SAR and Singapore.
2
Portfolio debt securities (liabilities) plus other debt
instruments (liabilities) minus corresponding BIS reporting banks inflows. For India, the balance of payments data start in Q2 2009 and end
in Q1 2013.
3
Excluding official sector and banks.
Sources: IMF, Balance of Payments Statistics and International Financial Statistics; BIS international banking statistics; BIS calculations.
155
160
165
170
4
2
0
2
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Debt ratio
1
Lhs:
182
189
196
203
6
3
0
3
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
Nominal debt
Contribution to changes in debt ratio
by changes in (rhs):
Nominal GDP
198
207
216
225
10
5
0
5
2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
500
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
From BIS reporting banks From other investors
2
0
200
400
600
800
1,000
02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Nationality Residence
73 BIS 84th Annual Report
beginning of 2005 to around 5% by May 2013. Using the year-on-year change in
consumer prices in those countries, this amounted to real long-term rates of just
1% in 2013.
4
Offsetting the stimulus from abroad through tighter domestic policy is not
easy. First, a large share of foreign capital infows is denominated in foreign
currency and thus not directly affected by domestic monetary policy. Second,
raising domestic interest rates while rates in the rest of the world remain very
low can trigger even more upward pressure on the exchange rate and capital
infows. Low domestic policy rates may limit debt infows from abroad, but they
also stimulate domestic lending. Indeed, countries with a more accommodative
monetary policy for a given set of domestic economic conditions tend to experience
more rapid credit growth (Graph IV.5).
Risks and adjustment needs
The position in the fnancial cycle identifed above, as well as high levels of private
sector debt, pose challenges for the years to come. There is obviously a risk that
many of the more recent booms will end in a crisis or at least in severe fnancial
stress, just as many have before. But even some countries that are currently in the
down phase of the fnancial cycle or have just bottomed out are vulnerable. Despite
signifcant deleveraging since the fnancial crisis, debt relative to income and asset
prices often remains high, potentially requiring further adjustments to return to
more sustainable levels.
This section frst assesses the risk of fnancial crises using a series of early warning
indicators, and then drills down further to better understand the implications of the
4
See P Turner, The global long-term interest rate, fnancial risks and policy choices in EMEs, BIS
Working Papers, no 441, February 2014.
Low policy rates coincide with credit booms Graph IV.5
AU = Australia; BR = Brazil; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; CL = Chile; CN = China; CZ = Czech Republic;
DK = Denmark; HK = Hong Kong SAR; ID = Indonesia; IN = India; KR = Korea; MX = Mexico; MY = Malaysia;
NO = Norway; PL = Poland; SE = Sweden; SG = Singapore; TH = Thailand; TR = Turkey; ZA = South Africa.
1
Policy rates minus Taylor rule rates, average over the period from end-2008 to end-2013.
2
Growth rates of
total credit to the private non-financial sector as a ratio of GDP over the period from end-2008 to end-2013.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
AU
CA
DK
NO
SE
CH
BR
CL
CN
CZ
HK
IN
ID
KR
MY MX
PL
SG
ZA
TH
TR
15
0
15
30
45
60
75
8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1
y = 9.73 3.64x
t-stat: (1.57) (2.11)
T
o
t
a
l
c
r
e
d
i
t
-
t
o
-
G
D
P
g
r
o
w
t
h
2
Taylor rule deviations
1
R
2
= 0.190
Advanced economies EMEs
74 BIS 84th Annual Report
shift from bank to bond fnance in EMEs. Finally, the degree to which households
and frms need to reduce their debt levels relative to GDP to return to more
sustainable levels is analysed, and a potential debt trap is identifed.
Indicators point to the risk of fnancial distress
Early warning indicators in a number of countries are sending worrying signals. In
line with the fnancial cycle analysis developed in the previous section, several early
warning indicators signal that vulnerabilities have been building up in the fnancial
systems of several countries. Many years of strong credit and, often, property price
growth have left borrowers exposed to increases in interest rates and/or sharp
slowdowns in property prices and economic activity. Early warning indicators cannot
predict the exact timing of fnancial distress, but they have proved fairly reliable in
identifying unsustainable credit and property price developments in the past.
Credit-to-GDP gaps in many EMEs and Switzerland are well above the
threshold that indicates potential trouble (Table IV.1). The historical record shows
that credit-to-GDP gaps (the difference between the credit-to-GDP ratio and its
long-term trend) above 10 percentage points have usually been followed by serious
banking strains within three years.
5
Residential property price gaps (the deviation of
real residential property prices from their long-term trend) also point to risks: they
tend to build up during a credit boom and fall two to three years before a crisis.
Indeed, the Swiss authorities have reacted to the build-up of fnancial vulnerabilities
by increasing countercyclical capital buffer requirements from 1% to 2% of risk-
weighted positions secured by domestic residential property.
Debt service ratios send a less worrying signal. These ratios, which measure the
share of income used to service debt (Box IV.B), remain low in many economies.
Taken at face value, they suggest that borrowers in China are currently especially
vulnerable. But rising rates would push debt service ratios in several other
economies into critical territory (Table IV.1, last column). To illustrate, assume that
money market rates rise by 250 basis points, in line with the 2004 tightening
episode.
6
At constant credit-to-GDP ratios, this would push debt service ratios in
most of the booming economies above critical thresholds. Experience indicates that
debt service ratios tend to remain low for long periods, only to shoot up rapidly one
or two years before a crisis, typically in response to interest rate increases.
7
Low
values therefore do not necessarily mean that the fnancial system is safe.
It would be too easy to dismiss these indicator readings as inappropriate because
this time is different. True, no early warning indicator is fully reliable. The fnancial
system evolves continuously, and the nature of risks shifts over time. But credit gaps
and debt service ratios have proved to be relatively robust. They are based on total
5
The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision chose the credit-to-GDP gap as a starting point
for discussions about countercyclical capital buffer levels because of its reliability as an early
warning indicator. A credit-to-GDP gap above 2 (beige cells in Table IV.1) indicates that authorities
should consider putting in place buffers, which would reach their maximum at readings above 10
(red cells).
6
In the 2004 tightening episode, money market rates in advanced economies increased by around
250 basis points over three years. The thought experiment here assumes that there is a one-to-one
pass-through from money market rates to average lending rates for loans to the private non-
fnancial sector, which, together with current credit-to-GDP ratios and average remaining maturities,
determine the debt service burden (Box IV.B).
7
See M Drehmann and M Juselius, Evaluating early warning indicators of banking crises: satisfying
policy requirements, International Journal of Forecasting, 2014.
75 BIS 84th Annual Report
Early warning indicators for domestic banking crises signal risks ahead
1
Table IV.1
Credit-to-GDP
gap
2
Property price
gap
3
Debt service
ratio (DSR)
4
Debt service ratio if
interest rates rise by
250 bp
4, 5
Boom Asia
6
19.9 16.7 2.4 4.4
Brazil 13.7 3.7 4.0 6.3
China 23.6 2.2 9.4 12.2
India 2.7 3.4 4.4
Switzerland 13.1 13.0 0.6 3.6
Turkey 17.4 4.5 6.2
Mixed signals Australia 6.9 2.0 1.5 4.5
Canada 5.6 5.1 2.0 4.9
Central and eastern
Europe
7
10.5 0.1 1.6 2.9
France 0.9 9.3 2.6 4.9
Germany 8.8 5.4 2.7 0.9
Japan 5.3 2.8 4.4 2.0
Korea 4.1 4.1 0.8 3.5
Mexico 3.7 1.6 0.5 0.9
Nordic countries
8
0.5 2.2 1.5 4.7
Netherlands 13.2 24.2 1.8 5.2
South Africa 3.1 7.5 1.0 0.2
United Kingdom 19.6 11.1 0.9 3.6
United States 12.3 5.7 0.3 2.6
Bust Greece 11.3 2.8
Italy 6.4 16.6 1.0 0.9
Portugal 13.9 7.4 0.3 4.0
Spain 27.8 28.7 2.3 5.4
Legend
Credit/GDP gap>10 Property gap>10 DSR>6 DSR>6
2Credit/GDP gap10 4DSR6 4DSR6
1
Thresholds for red cells are chosen by minimising false alarms conditional on capturing at least two thirds of the crises over a cumulative
three-year horizon. A signal is correct if a crisis occurs in any of the three years ahead. The noise is measured by the wrong predictions outside
this horizon. Beige cells for the credit-to-GDP gap are based on guidelines for countercyclical capital buffers under Basel III. Beige cells for DSRs
are based on critical thresholds if a two-year forecast horizon is used. For a derivation of critical thresholds for credit-to-GDP gaps and property
price gaps, see M Drehmann, C Borio and K Tsatsaronis, Anchoring countercyclical capital buffers: the role of credit aggregates, International
Journal of Central Banking, vol 7, no 4, 2011, pp 189240. For debt service ratios, see M Drehmann and M Juselius, Do debt service costs affect
macroeconomic and fnancial stability?, BIS Quarterly Review, September 2012, pp 2134.
2
Difference of the credit-to-GDP ratio from its
long-run, real-time trend calculated with a one-sided HP flter using a smoothing factor of 400.000, in percentage points.
3
Deviations of real
residential property prices from their long-run trend calculated with a one-sided HP flter using a smoothing factor of 400.000, in per cent.
4
Difference of DSRs from country-specifc long-run averages since 1985 or later depending on data availability and when fve-year average
infation fell below 10% (for Russia and Turkey, the last 10 years are taken).
5
Assuming an increase in the lending rates of 2.50 percentage
points and that all of the other components of the DSRs stay fxed.
6
Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and
Thailand; excluding the Philippines and Singapore for DSRs and their forecasts.
7
Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia,
Lithuania, Poland, Romania and Russia; excluding the Czech Republic and Romania for the real property price gap; excluding Bulgaria, Estonia,
Latvia, Lithuania and Romania for DSRs and their forecasts.
8
Finland, Norway and Sweden.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
76 BIS 84th Annual Report
credit, ie taking account of credit from all sources,
8
and are therefore generally not
affected by the shift from bank to non-bank fnance associated with the second
phase of global liquidity. The quality of the indicators should also be robust to
changes in the equilibrium levels of debt owing to fnancial deepening. Credit-to-
GDP and debt service ratios tend to rise when households and businesses gain access
to fnancial services, with the corresponding welfare benefts. But banks ability to
screen potential borrowers and manage risks puts a natural limit on how fast this
process can take place. Credit extended during a phase of rapid credit growth could
conceal problem loans, leading to fnancial instability when the boom turns to bust.
9
Weaker output growth could also trigger fnancial strains, particularly in
countries where debt has increased above trend for a long time. Many countries
with large credit gaps have been experiencing a prolonged period of rapid growth,
briefy interrupted by the fallout from the fnancial crisis in the advanced economies.
But growth has slowed more recently, and may well remain below the previous
trend in the future (Chapter III).
Commodity exporters could be especially sensitive to a sharp deceleration in
China. This would further increase vulnerabilities of currently booming economies
such as Brazil. But it may also adversely affect some of the advanced economies
that were less affected by the fnancial crisis. As noted above, countries such as
Australia, Canada and Norway were in the upswing of a pronounced fnancial cycle
before the crisis erupted. Since then, the cycle has turned in these economies, but
the fallout was buffered by high commodity prices. Since outstanding debt remains
high, the slowdown of GDP associated with a reduction in commodity exports
could cause repayment diffculties.
Looking beyond total credit, the shift from bank lending to market-based debt
fnancing by non-fnancial corporations in EMEs has changed the nature of risks. On
the one hand, borrowers have used the favourable conditions to lock in long-term
funding, thus reducing rollover risk. For example, of the roughly $1.1 trillion in
international debt securities outstanding of borrowers headquartered in EMEs,
around $100 billion less than one tenth of the total matures in each of the
coming years (Graph IV.6, left-hand panel). In addition, roughly 10% of the debt
securities maturing in 2020 or later are callable, and an unknown proportion have
covenants that allow investors to demand accelerated repayment if the borrowers
conditions deteriorate. Nonetheless, potential annual repayments look relatively
modest relative to the amount of foreign reserves of the main borrower countries.
But the benevolent impact of longer maturities could be offset by fckle market
liquidity. The availability of market funding is notoriously procyclical. It is available in
large quantities and at a cheap price when conditions are good, but this can change
at the frst hint of problems. Capital fows could reverse quickly when interest
rates in the advanced economies eventually go up or when perceived domestic
conditions in the host economies deteriorate. In May and June 2013, the mere
possibility that the Federal Reserve would begin tapering its asset purchases led to
rapid outfows from funds investing in EME securities (Chapter II), although overall
portfolio investment was less volatile.
8
For a discussion of the coverage of total credit series, see C Dembiermont, M Drehmann and
S Muksakunratana, How much does the private sector really borrow? A new database for total
credit to the private non-fnancial sector, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2013, pp 6581.
9
BIS research has shown that the credit-to-GDP gap is a useful indicator for EMEs, where the scope
for further fnancial deepening tends to be larger than in most advanced economies. See
M Drehmann and K Tsatsaronis, The credit-to-GDP gap and countercyclical capital buffers:
questions and answers, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2014, pp 5573.
77 BIS 84th Annual Report
Emerging market economies face new risk patterns Graph IV.6
Scheduled repayments of
international debt securities
1
Bank deposits of non-financial
corporations
3
Net assets of dedicated EME funds
USD bn
USD bn
BG = Bulgaria; CL = Chile; CN = China; CZ = Czech Republic; EE = Estonia; HU = Hungary; ID = Indonesia; KR = Korea; MX = Mexico;
MY = Malaysia; PE = Peru; PL = Poland; RO = Romania; RU = Russia; SI = Slovenia; TH = Thailand; TR = Turkey. ETF = exchange-traded
fund.
1
International debt securities issued by non-bank corporations resident/headquartered (nationality) in Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China,
Colombia, the Czech Republic, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, Iceland, India, Indonesia, Korea, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines,
Poland, Romania, Russia, Singapore, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey and Venezuela.
2
No maturity date available.
3
As a percentage of
banks assets. The line represents the 45 line.
4
Except for Peru (beginning of 2012).
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; Datastream; EPFR; national data; BIS international debt securities statistics; BIS calculations.
Demographic tailwinds for house prices turn into headwinds
Basis points per annum Graph IV.7
AU = Australia; BE = Belgium; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; DE = Germany; DK = Denmark; ES = Spain; FI = Finland; FR = France;
GB = United Kingdom; GR = Greece; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; KR = Korea; NL = Netherlands; NO = Norway; PT = Portugal; SE = Sweden;
US = United States.
Source: E Takts, Aging and house prices, Journal of Housing Economics, vol 21, no 2, 2012, pp 13141.
0
80
160
240
320
14 15 16 17 18 19 20 >20 na
2
Year
Nationality Residence
BG
CL
CN
CZ
EE
HU
ID
KR
MX
MY
PL
RO
RU
SI
TH
TR
PE
0
10
20
30
40
10 20 30 40 50
Beginning 2008
4
E
n
d
-
2
0
1
3
0
300
600
900
1,200
04 06 08 10 12 14
ETFs Non-ETFs
400
300
200
100
0
100
KR JP PT DE IT GR FI ES DK NL FR BE CH GB CA NO SE US AU
Historical (19702009)
Forecasted (201050)
Demographic impact:
Historical
Forecasted
Population-weighted average:
A higher proportion of investors with short-term horizons in EME debt could
amplify shocks when global conditions deteriorate. Highly volatile fund fows to
EMEs indicate that some investors view their investments in these markets as short-
term positions rather than long-term holdings. This is in line with the gradual shift
from traditional open- or closed-end funds to exchange-traded funds (ETFs), which
now account for around a ffth of all net assets of dedicated EME bond and equity
funds, up from around 2% 10 years ago (Graph IV.6, right-hand panel). ETFs can be
bought and sold on exchanges at low cost, at least in normal times, and have been
used by investors to convert illiquid securities into liquid instruments.
Financing problems of non-fnancial corporations in EMEs can also feed into
the banking system. Corporate deposits in many EMEs stand at well above 20% of
the banking systems total assets in countries as diverse as Chile, China, Indonesia,
Malaysia and Peru (Graph IV.6, centre panel), and are on an upward trend in
others. Firms losing access to external debt markets may be forced to withdraw
these deposits, leaving banks with signifcant funding problems. Firms that have
been engaging in a sort of carry trade borrowing at low interest rates abroad and
investing at higher rates at home could be even more sensitive to market
conditions.
Finally, the sheer volume of assets managed by large asset management
companies implies that their asset allocation decisions have signifcant and systemic
implications for EME fnancial markets. For instance, a relatively small (5 percentage
point) reallocation of the $70 trillion in assets managed by large asset management
companies from advanced economies to EMEs would result in additional portfolio
fows of $3.5 trillion. This is equivalent to 13% of the $27 trillion stock of EME bonds
and equities. And the ratio could be signifcantly larger in smaller open economies.
Actions taken by asset managers have particularly strong effects if they are
78 BIS 84th Annual Report
correlated across funds. This could be because of top-down management of
different portfolios, as is the case for some major bond funds, similar benchmarks
or similar risk management systems (Chapter VI).
The shift from bank to securities fnancing has apparently had little impact
on currency risk. Over 90% of international debt securities and well over 80% of
cross-border loans by non-bank corporations resident in EMEs are effectively
denominated in foreign currency. And some of the heaviest borrowers in the
international bond market are property frms and utilities, which are unlikely to have
signifcant foreign currency assets or payment streams that could back up their
debt. There are fnancial instruments that could hedge some of the currency risk.
But in practice many hedges are incomplete, because they cover exposures only
partly, or are based on shorter-term contracts that are regularly rolled over.
Such strategies signifcantly reduce the value of fnancial hedges against large
fuctuations in exchange rates, which often coincide with illiquid markets.
Returning to sustainable debt levels
Regardless of the risk of serious fnancial distress, in the years ahead many
economies will face headwinds as outstanding debt adjusts to more sustainable
long-run levels. Determining the exact level of sustainable debt is diffcult, but
several indicators suggest that current levels of private sector indebtedness are still
too high.
For one, sustainable debt is aligned with wealth. Sharp drops in property and
other asset prices in the wake of the fnancial crisis have pushed down wealth in
many of the countries at the heart of the crisis, although it has been recovering in
some. Wealth effects can be long-lasting. For example, real property prices in Japan
have decreased by more than 3% on average per year since 1991, thus reducing
the collateral available for new borrowing.
Long-run demographic trends could aggravate this problem by putting further
pressure on asset prices (Chapter III). An ageing society implies weaker demand for
assets, in particular housing. Research on the relationship between house prices
and demographic variables suggests that demographic factors could dampen
house prices by reducing property price growth considerably over the coming
decades (blue bars in Graph IV.7).
10
If so, this would partially reverse the effect of
demographic tailwinds that pushed up house prices in previous decades (red bars).
Debt service ratios also point to current debt levels being on the high side.
High debt servicing costs (interest payments plus amortisations) compared with
income effectively limit the amount of debt that borrowers can carry. This is clearly
true for individuals. Lenders, for example, often refuse to provide new loans
to households if future interest payments and amortisations exceed a certain
threshold, often around 3040% of their income. But the relationship also holds in
the aggregate.
Empirically, aggregate debt service ratios fuctuate around stable historical
averages (Graph IV.B), which can be taken as rough approximations for long-term
sustainable (steady state) levels. High private sector debt service costs relative to
income will result in less credit being extended, eventually translating into falling
aggregate debt service costs. Conversely, low debt service ratios give borrowers
ample room to take on more debt. Hence, over time economy-wide debt service
ratios gravitate back to steady state levels.
11
10
See E Takts, Aging and house prices, Journal of Housing Economics, vol 21, no 2, 2012, pp 13141.
11
Box IV.B discusses caveats associated with the choice of long-run averages as benchmarks.
79 BIS 84th Annual Report
In all but a handful of countries, bringing debt service ratios back to historical
norms would require substantial reductions in credit-to-GDP ratios (Graph IV.8).
Even at the current unusually low interest rates, credit-to-GDP ratios would have to
be roughly 15 percentage points lower on average for debt service ratios to be at
their historical norms. And if lending rates were to rise by 250 basis points, in line
with the 2004 tightening episode, the necessary reductions in credit-to-GDP ratios
would swell to over 25 percentage points on average. In China, credit-to-GDP ratios
would have to fall by more than 60 percentage points. Even the United Kingdom
and the United States would need to reduce credit-to-GDP ratios by around
20 percentage points, despite having debt service ratios in line with long-term
averages at current interest rates.
How can economies bring debt back to sustainable levels?
Downward pressures from lower wealth and high debt service burdens suggest that
many economies will have to lower their debt levels in the years to come. This can
happen through several channels. The frst, and least painful, channel is through
output growth, which has the dual effect of reducing credit-to-GDP and debt
service ratios and also supports higher asset prices. The muted growth outlook in
many economies (Chapter III) is not particularly reassuring from this perspective.
Infation can also have an effect. But the extent to which it reduces the real debt
burden depends on how much interest rates on outstanding and new debt adjust to
higher price increases. More importantly, though, even if successful from this narrow
perspective, it also has major side effects. Infation redistributes wealth arbitrarily
between borrowers and savers and risks unanchoring infation expectations, with
unwelcome long-run consequences.
The alternative to growing out of debt is to reduce the outstanding stock of
debt. This happens when the amortisation rate exceeds the take-up of new loans.
This is a natural and important channel of adjustment, but may not be enough. In
some cases, unsustainable debt burdens have to be tackled directly, for instance
Emerging market economies face new risk patterns Graph IV.6
Scheduled repayments of
international debt securities
1
Bank deposits of non-financial
corporations
3
Net assets of dedicated EME funds
USD bn
USD bn
BG = Bulgaria; CL = Chile; CN = China; CZ = Czech Republic; EE = Estonia; HU = Hungary; ID = Indonesia; KR = Korea; MX = Mexico;
MY = Malaysia; PE = Peru; PL = Poland; RO = Romania; RU = Russia; SI = Slovenia; TH = Thailand; TR = Turkey. ETF = exchange-traded
fund.
1
International debt securities issued by non-bank corporations resident/headquartered (nationality) in Brazil, Bulgaria, Chile, China,
Colombia, the Czech Republic, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, Iceland, India, Indonesia, Korea, Lithuania, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines,
Poland, Romania, Russia, Singapore, South Africa, Thailand, Turkey and Venezuela.
2
No maturity date available.
3
As a percentage of
banks assets. The line represents the 45 line.
4
Except for Peru (beginning of 2012).
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; Datastream; EPFR; national data; BIS international debt securities statistics; BIS calculations.
Demographic tailwinds for house prices turn into headwinds
Basis points per annum Graph IV.7
AU = Australia; BE = Belgium; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; DE = Germany; DK = Denmark; ES = Spain; FI = Finland; FR = France;
GB = United Kingdom; GR = Greece; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; KR = Korea; NL = Netherlands; NO = Norway; PT = Portugal; SE = Sweden;
US = United States.
Source: E Takts, Aging and house prices, Journal of Housing Economics, vol 21, no 2, 2012, pp 13141.
0
80
160
240
320
14 15 16 17 18 19 20 >20 na
2
Year
Nationality Residence
BG
CL
CN
CZ
EE
HU
ID
KR
MX
MY
PL
RO
RU
SI
TH
TR
PE
0
10
20
30
40
10 20 30 40 50
Beginning 2008
4
E
n
d
-
2
0
1
3
0
300
600
900
1,200
04 06 08 10 12 14
ETFs Non-ETFs
400
300
200
100
0
100
KR JP PT DE IT GR FI ES DK NL FR BE CH GB CA NO SE US AU
Historical (19702009)
Forecasted (201050)
Demographic impact:
Historical
Forecasted
Population-weighted average:
80 BIS 84th Annual Report
through writedowns. Admittedly, this means that somebody has to bear the ensuing
losses, but experience shows that such an approach may be less painful than the
alternatives. For example, the Nordic countries addressed their high and
unsustainable debt levels after the banking crises of the early 1990s by forcing
banks to recognise losses and deal decisively with bad assets, including through
disposals. In addition, authorities reduced excess capacity in the fnancial system
and recapitalised banks subject to tough viability tests. This provided a solid basis
for recovery, which came relatively quickly.
12
Reducing debt levels through writedowns may require important changes in
the regulatory framework in a number of countries. As argued in the 82nd Annual
Report (in the box in Chapter III), reducing household debt requires two main steps.
First, authorities need to induce lenders to recognise losses. Second, they should
create incentives for lenders to restructure loans so that borrowers have a realistic
chance of repaying their debt.
13
The impact of interest rates is ambiguous. In principle, lower interest rates
can reduce debt service burdens. Lower rates may also provide support to asset
prices. In fact, monetary authorities have typically cut interest rates in the wake of
fnancial crises, thus reducing the debt service burden on households and frms.
12
See C Borio, B Vale and G von Peter, Resolving the fnancial crisis: are we heeding the lessons from
the Nordics?, BIS Working Papers, no 311, June 2010.
13
For recent work on this issue, see Y Liu and C Rosenberg, Dealing with private debt distress in the
wake of the European fnancial crisis, IMF Working Papers, no WP/13/44, 2013; and J Garrido, Out-
of-court debt restructuring, World Bank, 2012.
Debt sustainability requires deleveraging across the globe
Change in credit-to-GDP ratios required to return to sustainable debt service ratios
1
Graph IV.8
Percentage points
AU = Australia; BR = Brazil; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; CN = China; DE = Germany; ES = Spain; FR = France; GB = United Kingdom;
IN = India; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; KR = Korea; MX = Mexico; NL = Netherlands; PT = Portugal; TR = Turkey; US = United States;
ZA = South Africa.
Asia = Hong Kong SAR, Indonesia, Malaysia and Thailand; CEE = central and eastern Europe: the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland and
Russia; Nordic = Finland, Norway and Sweden.
1
Debt service ratios are assumed to be sustainable if they return to country-specific long-run averages. Averages are taken since 1985 or
later depending on data availability and when five-year average inflation fell below 10% (for Russia and Turkey, the last 10 years are taken).
The necessary change in the credit-to-GDP ratio is calculated by using equation (1) in Box IV.B and keeping maturities constant.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
75
50
25
0
25
CN FR TR ES NL IN Asia CA BR Nordic AU CEE CH GB KR MX PT US ZA IT DE JP
Current lending rates
Scenarios:
Lending rates increase by 250 bps
81 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box IV.B
Estimating debt service ratios
This box details the construction of debt service ratios (DSRs) and some of the technicalities underlying Graphs IV.8
and IV.9.
Calculating economy-wide DSRs involves estimation and calibration, as detailed loan-level data are generally
not available. We use the methodology outlined in Drehmann and Juselius (2012), who in turn follow an approach
developed by the Federal Reserve Board to construct debt service ratios for the household sector (Dynan et
al (2003)). We start with the basic assumption that, for a given lending rate, debt service costs interest and
repayments on the aggregate debt stock are repaid in equal portions over the maturity of the loan (instalment
loans). By using the standard formula for calculating the fxed debt service costs (DSC) of an instalment loan and
dividing it by GDP, we can calculate the DSR at time t as
(1)
where D
t
denotes the aggregate stock of debt to the private non-fnancial sector as reported by the BIS, Y
t
quarterly GDP, i
t
the average interest rate per quarter, and s
t
the average remaining maturity in quarters (ie for a
fve-year average remaining maturity s
t
= 20).
While credit and GDP are readily observable, this is generally not the case for the average interest rate and
average remaining maturities. For data availability reasons, we proxy the average interest rates on the entire stock of
debt with the average interest rates on loans from monetary and fnancial institutions to the non-fnancial private
sector. This assumes that the evolution of interest rates from bank and non-bank lenders is similar, which seems
reasonable. For a few countries, mainly in central and eastern Europe and emerging Asia, no lending rates are
available. We proxy them with the short-term money market rate plus the average markup between lending rates
and the money market rates across countries. Drawing on the few available sources, we approximate remaining
maturities, but this remains crude. Particularly in the earlier parts of the sample, it may well be the case that
maturities were lower, and DSRs thus higher, given higher infation rates and shorter life expectancy.
The historical averages may be biased downwards and thus the deleveraging needs shown in Graph IV.8
upwards. But the bias is likely to be small, as changes in the maturity parameter have limited effects on the estimated
DSR trends. Furthermore, estimates for the US household sector lead to similar DSRs to those published by the
Federal Reserve, which are based on much more granular data. Levels are also generally comparable across
countries, and the derived DSRs exhibit long-run swings around country-specifc historical averages, indicating that
these are realistic benchmarks.
Comparing the evolution of DSRs with that of lending rates and credit-to-GDP ratios shows that falling interest
rates allowed the private sector to sustain higher debt levels relative to GDP (Graph IV.B). From 1985 onwards, debt-
to-GDP ratios in the United Kingdom and the United States increased substantially, even after taking into account
the fall in the wake of the fnancial crisis. At the same time, lending rates decreased from more than 10% to around
3% now. The combined effect implies that DSRs fuctuate around long-run historical averages.
To construct projections of the DSR for different interest rate scenarios (Graph IV.9), we estimate the joint
dynamics of lending rates and credit-to-GDP ratios using a standard vector autoregression (VAR) process. In
addition to these two variables, we include real residential property prices as an endogenous variable to control
for changes in collateral values, which may allow agents to increase their leverage. The short-term money
market rate enters exogenously. Using the estimated VAR, credit-to-GDP, average lending rates and real property
prices are then projected based on different scenarios for the money market rate. Assuming maturities remain
constant, the resulting credit-to-GDP ratios and lending rates are then transformed into the DSRs shown in
Graph IV.9.
Four interest rate scenarios are considered, all of which start in the second quarter of 2014 and end in the
fourth quarter of 2017. In the frst, money market rates evolve in line with market-implied short rates. In the second
scenario, absolute changes in money market rates follow those observed in each country during the tightening
episode that began in June 2004, and are fxed once the maximum is reached. Third, interest rates are raised to their
country-specifc long-run averages over eight quarters, and remain constant thereafter. In the fourth scenario,
interest rates are kept constant from the second quarter of 2014 onwards.
The results highlight that debt service burdens are likely to increase, or at least not decrease, even taking into
account several caveats. For instance, the confdence intervals of the projections increase with the horizon and
become fairly large by 2017, but even they do not suggest any substantial decrease. Furthermore, the VAR is
*
(1 (1 ) )
t
t t t
t s
t t t
DSC i D
DSR
Y Y i
82 BIS 84th Annual Report
estimated using a sample from the frst quarter of 1985 to the fourth quarter of 2013. Thus, the projections are
based on mostly normal relationships, which may not be accurate during periods of fnancial stress or balance sheet
recessions, when excessive leverage may imply that credit-to-GDP ratios become unresponsive to interest rates. The
VAR framework also assumes that increases or decreases in money market rates are passed on symmetrically to
lending rates. If borrowers have locked in current low rates and rates rise, the increase in the DSRs may be less
pronounced than shown but still more than in the constant rate scenario, as new borrowers have to pay higher rates.
M Drehmann and M Juselius, Do debt service costs affect macroeconomic and fnancial stability?, BIS Quarterly Review, September
2012, pp 2135; and K Dynan, K Johnson and K Pence, Recent changes to a measure of US household debt service, Federal Reserve
Bulletin, vol 89, no 10, October 2003, pp 41726. The justifcation is that the differences between the repayment structures of
individual loans will tend to cancel out in the aggregate. For example, consider 10 loans of equal size for which the entire principal is due at
maturity (bullet loans), each with 10 repayment periods and taken out in successive years over a decade. After 10 periods, when the frst
loan falls due, the fow of repayments on these 10 loans jointly will be indistinguishable from the repayment of a single instalment loan of the
same size. Typically, a large share of private sector loans in most countries will in any case be instalment loans, eg household sector mortgage
credit. See the BIS database on total credit to the private non-fnancial sector (www.bis.org/statistics/credtopriv.htm). These series
are typically only recorded for the past decade or so, but can be extended further back using a weighted average of various household and
business lending interest rates, including the rates on mortgage, consumption and investment loans. We take only long-run averages
as proxies for long-run sustainable levels of DSRs for Graph IV.8, after infation has fallen persistently below 10%. Projected increases in
DSRs are somewhat larger if infation is included in the VAR as an endogenous variable. Infation was not included for the results shown in
Graph IV.9, to base the projections on the most parsimonious system.
Debt service ratios and their main components
1
In per cent Graph IV.B
United States United Kingdom
1
For the total private non-financial sector.
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
80
100
120
140
160
180
0
5
10
15
20
25
86 89 92 95 98 01 04 07 10 13
Credit-to-GDP ratio
Lhs:
30
60
90
120
150
180
0
5
10
15
20
25
86 89 92 95 98 01 04 07 10 13
Debt service ratio
Rhs:
Lending rate
Unfortunately, however, low interest rates can also have the perverse effect of
incentivising borrowers to take on even more debt, making an eventual rise in rates
even more costly if debt continues to grow. Depending on initial conditions, low
rates could therefore lead countries into a debt trap: debt burdens that already seem
unsustainable now may grow even further.
Scenario analysis suggests that a debt trap is not just a remote possibility for
some countries. The analysis is based on a model capturing the joint dynamics of
credit-to-GDP ratios, interest rates and property prices (Box IV.B). Graph IV.9 shows
the estimated future trajectories for debt ratios and property prices for four interest
rate scenarios for the United Kingdom and the United States. The estimated
trajectories look similar for other economies, such as Korea or Brazil.
83 BIS 84th Annual Report
The scenarios highlight that debt service burdens would increase in some
countries irrespective of whether policy rates rose or remained low. At one extreme,
a reversion of money market rates to historical averages would push debt service
burdens to levels close to the historical maxima seen on the eve of the crisis. But
debt service burdens would also grow at the other extreme, if interest rates remained
at the current low levels. Whereas costs on the current stock of debt would remain
constant, further borrowing by households and frms would push up aggregate
debt service costs in this scenario.
To be sure, this scenario analysis is only illustrative. Moreover, it is based on the
assumption that interest rates rise independently of macroeconomic conditions:
presumably, central banks would not raise them unless the outlook for output was
favourable. However, the scenarios examined do point to the tensions embedded
in the current situation.
The conclusion is simple: low interest rates do not solve the problem of high
debt. They may keep service costs low for some time, but by encouraging rather
than discouraging the accumulation of debt they amplify the effect of the eventual
normalisation. Avoiding the debt trap requires policies that encourage the orderly
running-down of debt through balance sheet repair and, above all, raise the long-
run growth prospects of the economy (Chapters I and III).
Debt service burdens are likely to rise
Projected debt service burdens with endogenous debt levels for different interest rate scenarios,
in per cent
1
Graph IV.9
United States United Kingdom
1
Scenarios are: (i) market-implied: interest rates evolve in line with market-implied rates; (ii) 2004 tightening: absolute changes in interest
rates follow the 2004 tightening episode in advanced economies; (iii) rapid tightening: interest rates are tightened to their country-specific
long-run averages over eight quarters; and (iv) constant rates: interest rates are kept constant. Debt service burdens are measured by the
debt service ratio. Historical average since 1985. Projections are based on a simple vector autoregression (VAR) model capturing the joint
dynamics of credit-to-GDP ratios, lending rates, money market rates and real residential property prices (Box IV.B).
Sources: National data; BIS; BIS calculations.
18
20
22
24
26
01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17
Actual debt service ratio Historical average
18
20
22
24
26
01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17
Market-implied
2004 tightening
Scenarios:
Rapid tightening
Constant rates
85 BIS 84th Annual Report
V. Monetary policy struggles to normalise
Monetary policy globally remained very accommodative over the past year as policy
rates stayed low and central bank balance sheets expanded further. Central banks
in the major advanced economies continued to face an unusually sluggish recovery
despite prolonged extraordinary monetary easing. This suggests that monetary policy
has been relatively ineffective in boosting a recovery from a balance sheet recession.
Emerging market economies and small open advanced economies struggled to
deal with spillovers from monetary ease in the major advanced economies. They
have also kept their policy rates very low, which has contributed to the build-up of
fnancial vulnerabilities. This dynamic suggests that monetary policy should play a
greater role as a complement to macroprudential measures when dealing with
fnancial imbalances. It also points to shortcomings in the international monetary
system, as global monetary policy spillovers are not suffciently internalised.
Many central banks faced unexpected disinfationary pressures in the past year,
which represent a negative surprise for those in debt and raise the spectre of defation.
However, risks of widespread defation appear very low: central banks see infation
returning to target over time and longer-term infation expectations remaining well
anchored. Moreover, the supply side nature of the disinfation pressures has
generally been consistent with the pickup in global economic activity. The monetary
policy stance needs to carefully take into account the persistence and supply side
nature of the disinfationary forces as well as the side effects of policy ease.
The prospect is now clearer that central banks in the major advanced
economies are at different distances from normalising policy and hence will exit at
different times from their extraordinary accommodation. Navigating the transition
is likely to be complex and bumpy, regardless of communication efforts; and partly
for those reasons, the risk of normalising too late and too gradually should not be
underestimated.
This chapter reviews the past years developments in monetary policy and then
explores four key challenges that policy faces: low effectiveness; spillovers;
unexpected disinfation; and the risk of falling behind the curve during the exit.
Recent monetary policy developments
Over the past 12 months, nominal and real policy rates remained very low globally,
and central bank balance sheets continued to expand up to year-end 2013
(Graph V.1). On average, the major advanced economies maintained real policy
rates at less than 1.0%. In the rest of the world, real policy rates were not much
higher: in a group of small open advanced economies (which we refer to hereafter
as small advanced economies) Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden
and Switzerland and in the emerging market economies (EMEs) we survey here,
real rates were only marginally above zero. The expansion of central bank assets
slowed somewhat between 2012 and mid-2013 and then accelerated in the second
half of 2013.
This extraordinary policy ease has now been in place for about six years
(Graph V.1). Interest rates fell sharply in early 2009. Central bank assets began to
grow rapidly in 2007, and they have more than doubled since then, to an
unprecedented total of more than $20 trillion (more than 30% of global GDP). The
86 BIS 84th Annual Report
increase has refected large-scale asset purchases and the accumulation of foreign
exchange reserves.
Central banks in major advanced economies kept nominal policy rates near the
zero lower bound and real rates negative (Graph V.2) even as signs of an improvement
in growth accumulated during the past 12 months.
1
In the euro area, where economic
activity has been weak, the ECB halved its main refnancing rate in November, to
25 basis points, and cut it further to 15 basis points in June, given concerns about
low infation and currency appreciation. The ECBs latest move took its deposit rate
to 10 basis points below zero.
The central banks of the euro area, the United Kingdom and the United States
have relied heavily on various forms of forward guidance to convey their intention
to keep policy rates low well into the future (Box V.A). The ECB adopted qualitative
forward guidance in July 2013, saying that it would keep policy rates low for an
extended period. In August 2013, the Bank of England introduced threshold-based
forward guidance, linking the low policy rate environment to criteria about the
unemployment rate, infation projections and expectations, and risks to fnancial
stability. This new type of guidance was similar in many ways to the approach taken
in December 2012 by the Federal Reserve, which also emphasised thresholds for
unemployment and infation. In early 2014, as the forward guidance thresholds for
unemployment were being approached in the United Kingdom and the United
States faster than anticipated, central banks in both those countries made their
guidance more qualitative, featuring a broader notion of economic slack.
1
In April 2013, the Bank of Japan changed its operating target for monetary policy from the
overnight money market rate to the monetary base.
20 June - 14.15h
Monetary policy globally is still very accommodative Graph V.1
Nominal policy rate
1
Real policy rate
1
Total central bank assets
Per cent
Per cent
USD trn
1
For each group, simple average of the economies listed. Real rate is the nominal rate deflated by consumer price inflation.
2
The euro
area, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States.
3
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, Chinese Taipei, Colombia, the Czech Republic,
Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South
Africa, Thailand and Turkey. For Argentina, the consumer price deflator is based on official estimates, which have a methodological break in
December 2013.
4
Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland.
5
Sum of Chinese Taipei, Hong Kong SAR, India,
Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand.
6
Sum of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, the Czech Republic,
Hungary, Mexico, Peru, Poland, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa and Turkey.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; Bloomberg; Datastream; national data.
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
6.0
7.5
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Major advanced economies
2
EMEs
3
4.5
3.0
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Small advanced economies
4
0
4
8
12
16
20
07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Federal Reserve
Bank of England
Peoples Bank of China
Other Asian EMEs
5
Other EMEs
6
Eurosystem
Bank of Japan
87 BIS 84th Annual Report
The trajectories of central bank balance sheets in the major advanced
economies diverged in the past year (Graph V.2, right-hand panel). The Bank of
England and the Federal Reserve gradually shifted away from balance sheet
expansion as the primary means of providing additional stimulus. In August 2013,
the Bank of England announced that it would maintain the stock of its purchased
assets at 375 billion, subject to the same conditions as its forward guidance on
policy rates. In December 2013, the Federal Reserve announced it would gradually
dial back its large-scale asset purchases starting in January. The pace of this tapering
has been smooth since then, but the lead-up to the December announcement
proved to be a communication challenge (Chapter II). At the time of writing,
markets expect the purchase programme to conclude before year-end 2014.
In contrast, in April 2013, the Bank of Japan announced its Quantitative and
Qualitative Easing (QQE) programme as a principal means of overcoming Japans
legacy of protracted defation. Its balance sheet expanded rapidly thereafter, rising
from less than 35% of GDP to more than 50% by early 2014.
Refecting improved euro area fnancial conditions, the ECBs balance sheet
shrank relative to GDP as banks scaled back their use of central bank funding,
including through the ECBs longer-term refnancing operations. And to date, the
ECB has not activated its Outright Monetary Transactions programme (large-scale
purchases of sovereign bonds in secondary markets under strict conditionality).
However, in early June, the ECB announced that it would initiate targeted longer-
term refnancing operations later this year to support bank lending to households
and non-fnancial corporations. In addition, the ECB decided to intensify its
preparatory work related to outright purchases in the asset-backed securities market.
Policy rates in the small advanced economies also remained very low
(Graph V.3, left-hand panel). The Bank of Canada left its policy rate at 1.0% and
adjusted its forward guidance, pushing back the prospective date of a modest
withdrawal of accommodation. With headline infation in Switzerland remaining
around zero or less, the Swiss National Bank kept the range of its policy rate for
three-month Libor unchanged at 025 basis points and maintained its exchange
rate ceiling against the euro. The Central Bank of Norway kept rates at 1.5% as
disinfationary pressures abated over the course of the year. A few central banks in
Policy rates remain low and central bank assets high in major advanced economies Graph V.2
Nominal policy rate Real policy rate
1
Total central bank assets
Per cent
Per cent
Percentage of GDP
1
Nominal policy rate deflated by consumer price inflation.
Sources: Bloomberg; Datastream; national data.
0
1
2
3
4
5
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Euro area
4.5
3.0
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Japan United Kingdom
0
10
20
30
40
50
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
United States
88 BIS 84th Annual Report
Small advanced economies are facing below-target inflation and high debt Graph V.3
Nominal policy rate Deviation of inflation from target
1
Household debt
2
Per cent
Percentage points
Percentage of net disposable income
1
Deviation of inflation from either the central banks inflation target or the midpoint of the central banks target range for all economies
shown in the left-hand panel.
2
Debt and income measures summed across all economies shown in the left-hand panel.
Sources: OECD, Economic Outlook; Bloomberg; Datastream; national data.
0
1
2
3
4
5
2011 2012 2013 2014
Australia
Canada
New Zealand
Norway
Sweden
Switzerland
3
2
1
0
1
2
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Median 25th75th percentile
155
160
165
170
175
180
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
this group changed their policy rates. To support recovery, the Reserve Bank of
Australia twice cut its rate to reach 2.5%. Sveriges Riksbank lowered its policy rate
by 25 basis points, to 75 basis points, against the background of infation that
was persistently below target. In contrast, on evidence of increased economic
momentum and expectations of rising infation pressures, the Reserve Bank of New
Zealand raised its rate three times, for a total of 75 basis points, to reach 3.25%.
Overall, central bank policies in many of the small advanced economies were
strongly infuenced by the evolution of infation rates: on average they had fallen
short of targets by almost 1 percentage point since early 2012 (Graph V.3, centre
panel), and lingering disinfation led many central banks to mark down infation
forecasts.
Moreover, many of these central banks had to balance the short-term
macroeconomic effects of low infation and a lacklustre recovery against the longer-
term risks of building up fnancial imbalances (Chapter IV). Household debt, which
was high and rising, reached an average of roughly 175% of net disposable income
by end-2013 (Graph V.3, right-hand panel). Those elevated levels, and the prospect
of even further debt increases encouraged by accommodative monetary policies,
made these economies vulnerable to a sharp deterioration in economic and
fnancial conditions. In those jurisdictions in which house prices were high, the risk
of a disorderly adjustment of household sector imbalances could not be ruled out.
In EMEs, central banks had to contend with various monetary policy challenges
after a strong post-crisis recovery, which has weakened recently. One such challenge
came from bouts of fnancial market volatility associated with depreciation
pressures during the year (Chapter II). In general, their past strong macroeconomic
performance had helped to insulate many EMEs from the fallout and afforded them
some room for manoeuvre, but only up to a point. Most affected were countries
with weaker economic and fnancial conditions. In many of them, central banks
used the policy rate to defend their currencies (Graph V.4, left-hand panel). Between
April 2013 and early June 2014, several central banks tightened considerably on
net: in Turkey, by 400 basis points, including a 550 basis point hike in one day in
89 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box V.A
Forward guidance at the zero lower bound
The objective of central banks forward guidance at the zero lower bound has been to clarify their intended path for
the policy rate. Such guidance can itself provide stimulus when it reveals that policy rates are likely to remain low for
a period longer than markets had expected. Forward guidance can also reduce uncertainty, thereby dampening
interest rate volatility and, through that channel, lowering risk premia.
Forward guidance must meet three conditions to be effective. First, forward guidance must be clear. In
principle, clarity can be enhanced by spelling out the conditionality of the guidance. However, if the conditionality is
too complex, explicit details may be confusing. Second, forward guidance must be seen as a credible commitment,
ie the public must believe what the central bank says. The stronger the publics belief, the bigger is the likely impact
of the guidance on market expectations and economic decisions, but the greater also is the risk of an undesirable
reduction in central bank fexibility. Finally, even if it is understood and believed, the guidance must be interpreted
by the public as intended. For instance, communicating the intention to keep policy rates at the zero lower bound
for longer than the market expected may be mistakenly seen as signalling a more pessimistic economic outlook, in
which case negative confdence effects could counteract the intended stimulus.
The experience with forward guidance indicates that it has succeeded in infuencing markets over certain
horizons. Forward guidance reduced the fnancial market volatility of expected interest rates at short horizons but
less so at longer horizons (Graph V.A, left-hand panel). This is consistent with the notion that markets see forward
guidance as a conditional commitment, valid only for the near-term future path of policy interest rates. There is also
evidence that forward guidance affects the sensitivity of interest rates to economic news. The responsiveness of
interest rate volatility in the euro area and the United Kingdom to US rate volatility fell considerably after the ECB
and the Bank of England adopted forward guidance in summer 2013 (Graph V.A, centre panel). There is also
Graphs for Box:
Effectiveness of forward guidance at the zero lower bound appears limited Graph V.A
Volatility of futures rates for periods
with forward guidance relative to
periods with little or none
1, 2
One-year futures rate volatility
spillovers
1, 3
Ten-year yield response to US non-
farm payroll surprises
4
Ratio
Percentage points
Basis points
1
Volatility on three-month interbank rate futures contracts; 10-day standard deviation of daily price changes.
2
At less than 1, the values
indicate that periods with enhanced forward guidance reduced the volatility measure, which is average 10-day realised volatility; the lower
the ratio, the greater the reduction. Periods with enhanced forward guidance: Federal Reserve = 9 August 2011current; ECB = 4 July 2013
current; Bank of England (BoE) = 7 August 2013current; Bank of Japan (BoJ) = 5 October 20103 April 2013. Periods with no or less explicit
forward guidance: Federal Reserve = 16 December 20088 August 2011 (qualitative forward guidance); ECB = 8 May 20093 July 2013;
BoE = 6 March 20093 July 2013; BoJ = 22 December 20084 October 2010.
3
Centred 10-day moving averages. The vertical line indicates
4 July 2013, when the ECB provided qualitative forward guidance and the Bank of England commented on the market-expected path of
policy rates.
4
The horizontal axis shows the surprise in the change in non-farm payrolls, calculated as the difference between the actual
value and the survey value, in thousands. The vertical axis shows the one-day change in the 10-year government bond yield, calculated as
the end-of-day value on the release date minus the end-of-day value on the previous day. The t-statistic is shown in brackets.
Sources: Bloomberg; BIS calculations.
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
Eurodollar Euribor Sterling Euroyen
1-year 2-year 5-year
0.00
0.25
0.50
0.75
1.00
Jun 13 Aug 13 Oct 13
Eurodollar Sterling Euribor
20
10
0
10
20
200 100 0 100 200
y = 1.68 + 0.03x
(2.14) (2.88)
y = 0.13 + 0.10x
(0.10) (4.51)
200511 2012current
90 BIS 84th Annual Report
January; and in Russia and Indonesia, by 200 and 175 basis points, respectively.
India and South Africa raised rates by 50 basis points. Brazil boosted rates gradually
by 375 basis points over the period as currency depreciation and other forces
helped keep infation pressures elevated. The EME policy responses to currency
depreciation appeared to refect in part their recent infation experience (Graph V.4,
centre panel). Where infation was above target, depreciation pressures tended to
be stronger and policy rates rose by more. Where infation was at or below target,
no such relationship is visible.
The monetary authorities in the EMEs less affected by capital outfows and
exchange rate pressures had more policy room to respond to other developments.
In Chile and Mexico, the central banks cut policy rates as their economies showed
signs of slowing. In the Czech Republic, the policy rate remained low as infation fell
below target, and the central bank decided to use the exchange rate as an
additional instrument for easing monetary conditions by establishing a ceiling for
the exchange value of the koruna against the euro. Poland cut rates several times
early on as disinfationary pressures took hold. In China, the central bank maintained
its monetary policy stance with some deceleration in monetary and credit growth
as fnancial stability concerns grew, especially in relation to the expanding non-
bank fnancial sector.
A number of EMEs also conducted foreign exchange operations last year to
help absorb unwelcome depreciation pressures. Nonetheless, foreign exchange
reserves for EMEs as a whole continued to increase, especially for China (Annex
Table V.1). However, in a number of EMEs, for example Brazil, Indonesia, Russia and
Thailand, foreign exchange reserves dropped; for several such economies, it was the
frst reported annual decline in many years.
Credit expansion in many EMEs has been raising fnancial stability concerns,
especially against the backdrop of volatile fnancial markets. For the group of EMEs
surveyed here, the credit-to-GDP ratio rose on average by around 40% from 2007
to 2013 (Graph V.4, right-hand panel). For these central banks, questions remain about
the best mix of monetary, macroprudential and capital fow management tools.
Key monetary policy challenges
Central banks are facing a number of signifcant challenges. For the major advanced
economies recovering from balance sheet recessions (that is, a recession induced
evidence that forward guidance made markets more sensitive to indicators emphasised in the guidance. For
instance, US 10-year bond yields became more sensitive to non-farm payroll surprises beginning in 2012 (Graph V.A,
right-hand panel); one interpretation is that news refecting a stronger recovery tended to bring forward the
expected time at which the unemployment threshold would be breached and policy rate lift-off would ensue.
Policy rate forward guidance also raises a number of risks. If the public fails to fully understand the conditionality
of the guidance, the central banks reputation and credibility may be at risk if the rate path is revised frequently and
substantially, even though the changes adhere to the conditionality originally announced. Forward guidance can
also give rise to fnancial risks in two ways. First, if fnancial markets become narrowly focused on it, a recalibration
of the guidance could lead to disruptive market reactions. Second, and more importantly, forward guidance could
lead to a perceived delay in the speed of monetary policy normalisation. This could encourage excessive risk-taking
and foster a build-up of fnancial vulnerabilities.
For a more detailed analysis, see A Filardo and B Hofmann, Forward guidance at the zero lower bound, BIS Quarterly Review, March 2014,
pp 3753.
91 BIS 84th Annual Report
by fnancial crisis and an unsustainable accumulation of debt), the key challenge
has been calibrating the monetary policy stance at a time when policy appears
to have lost some of its ability to stimulate the economy. For many EMEs and small
advanced economies, the main challenge has been the build-up of fnancial
vulnerabilities and the risk of heightened capital fow volatility, problems
complicated by global monetary policy spillovers. Worldwide, many central banks
are struggling with the puzzling disinfationary pressures that materialised in the
past year. And looking ahead, questions arise about the timing and pace of policy
normalisation.
Low monetary policy effectiveness
Central banks played a critical role in containing the fallout from the fnancial crisis.
However, despite the past six years of monetary easing in the major advanced
economies, the recovery has been unusually slow (Chapter III). This raises questions
about the effectiveness of expansionary monetary policy in the wake of the crisis.
Effectiveness has been limited for two broad reasons: the zero lower bound on
the nominal policy rate, and the legacy of balance sheet recessions. First, the zero
lower bound constrains the central banks ability to reduce policy rates and boost
demand. This explains attempts to provide additional stimulus by managing
expectations about the future policy rate path and through large-scale asset
purchases. But those policies also have limitations. For instance, term premia and
credit risk spreads in many countries were already very low (Graph II.2): they cannot
fall much further. In addition, compressed and at times even negative term premia
EMEs respond to market tensions while concerns about stability rise Graph V.4
Change in policy rates since April
2013
1
is linked to exchange rate and
inflation performance
Credit-to-GDP ratio
3
Percentage points
Q1 2007 = 100
BR = Brazil; CL = Chile; CN = China; CO = Colombia; CZ = Czech Republic; HU = Hungary; ID = Indonesia; IN = India; KR = Korea;
MX = Mexico; PE = Peru; PH = Philippines; PL = Poland; RU = Russia; TH = Thailand; TR = Turkey; ZA = South Africa.
1
Nominal policy rate or the closest alternative; for China, seven-day repo rate; changes from 1 April 2013 to 6 June 2014, in percentage
points.
2
Percentage changes in the nominal effective exchange rate from 1 April 2013 to 6 June 2014. A positive (negative) number
indicates depreciation (appreciation).
3
For each group, simple average of the economies listed.
4
China, Hong Kong SAR, India,
Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand.
5
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico and Peru.
6
The Czech
Republic, Hungary, Poland, Russia, Saudi Arabia, South Africa and Turkey.
Sources: Bloomberg; Datastream; national data; BIS.
4
2
0
2
4
TRBRRU ID IN ZACOPHCZ PE KRCNTH PL MXCL HU
Above inflation objective
Below inflation objective
Inflation since 2013 on average:
KR
PH
CN
CL
CO
CZ
PL
HU
ID
TH
IN
PE
BR
MX
ZA
TR
RU
3.0
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
10 5 0 5 10
Depreciation in exchange rate
2
C
h
a
n
g
e
i
n
p
o
l
i
c
y
r
a
t
e
1
Above inflation objective
Below inflation objective
Inflation since 2013 on average:
100
110
120
130
140
07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Emerging Asia
4
Latin America
5
Other EMEs
6
92 BIS 84th Annual Report
reduce the profts from maturity transformation and so may actually reduce banks
incentives to grant credit. Moreover, the scope for negative nominal interest rates is
very limited and their effectiveness uncertain. The impact on lending is doubtful,
and the small room for reductions diminishes the effect on the exchange rate, which
in turn depends also on the reaction of others. In general, at the zero lower bound,
providing additional stimulus becomes increasingly hard.
Second, the legacy of balance sheet recessions numbs policy effectiveness.
Some of this has to do with fnancial factors. When the fnancial sector is impaired,
the supply of credit is less responsive to interest rate cuts. And the demand for
credit from non-fnancial sectors is sluggish they are seeking instead to pay down
debt incurred on the basis of overly optimistic income expectations. This is why
credit-less recoveries are the norm in these situations (Chapter III). But some of
the legacy of balance sheet recessions has to do with non-fnancial factors. The
misallocations of capital and labour that go hand in hand with unsustainable
fnancial booms can sap the traction of demand management policies, as these
address only symptoms rather than underlying problems. For instance, the
residential construction sector would normally be more sensitive than many others
to lower interest rates, but it expanded too much during the boom. In fact, the
historical record indicates that the positive relationship between the degree of
monetary accommodation during recessions and the strength of the subsequent
recovery vanishes when the recession is associated with a fnancial crisis (Box V.B).
Moreover, deleveraging during the recession, regardless of how it is measured,
eventually ushers in a stronger recovery.
None of this means that monetary accommodation has no role to play in a
recovery from a balance sheet recession. A degree of accommodation was clearly
necessary in the early stages of the fnancial crisis to contain the fallout. But the
relative ineffectiveness of monetary policy does signify that it cannot substitute for
measures that tackle the underlying problems, promoting the necessary balance
sheet repair and structural reforms.
Unless it is recognised, limited effectiveness implies a fruitless effort to apply
the same measures more persistently or forcefully. The consequence is not only
inadequate progress but also amplifcation of unintended side effects, and the
aftermath of the crisis has highlighted several such side effects.
2
In particular,
prolonged and aggressive easing reduces incentives to repair balance sheets and to
implement necessary structural reforms, thereby hindering the needed reallocation
of resources. It may also foster too much risk-taking in fnancial markets (Chapter II).
And it may generate unwelcome spillovers in other economies at different points in
their fnancial and business cycles (see below). Put differently, under limited policy
effectiveness, the balance between benefts and costs of prolonged monetary
accommodation has deteriorated over time.
Monetary policy spillovers
EMEs and small advanced economies have been struggling with spillovers from the
major advanced economies accommodative monetary policies. The spillovers work
through cross-border fnancial fows and asset prices (including the exchange rate)
as well as through policy responses.
3
2
See J Caruana, Hitting the limits of outside the box thinking? Monetary policy in the crisis and
beyond, speech at the OMFIF Golden Series Lecture, London, 16 May 2013.
3
See J Caruana, International monetary policy interactions: challenges and prospects, speech at
the CEMLA-SEACEN conference in Punta del Este, Uruguay, 16 November 2012.
93 BIS 84th Annual Report
Very accommodative monetary policies in major advanced economies infuence
risk-taking and therefore the yields on assets denominated in different currencies. As a
result, extraordinary accommodation can induce major adjustments in asset prices and
fnancial fows elsewhere. As fnancial markets in EMEs have developed and become
more integrated with the rest of the world, the strength of these linkages has grown.
For instance, local currency bond yields have co-moved more tightly in recent years.
4
The US dollar and the other international currencies play a key role here. Since
they are widely used outside the countries of issue, they have a direct infuence on
4
See P Turner, The global long-term interest rate, fnancial risks and policy choices in EMEs, BIS
Working Papers, no 441, February 2014.
Box V.B
Effectiveness of monetary policy following balance sheet recessions
The historical record lends support to the view that accommodative monetary policy during a normal business cycle
downturn helps strengthen the subsequent recovery. But this relationship is not statistically signifcant after
downturns associated with fnancial crises. That is, in business cycles accompanied by crises, the relationship between
the average short-term real interest rate during a downturn and the average growth rate during the subsequent
recovery does not have the sign expected in the case of a non-crisis business cycle (Graph V.B, left-hand panel).
A possible reason is that post-crisis deleveraging pressures make an economy less interest rate-sensitive.
Indeed, the evidence suggests that, in contrast to normal recessions, a key factor that eventually leads to stronger
recoveries from balance sheet recessions is private sector deleveraging (Graph V.B, right-hand panel).
Monetary policy is ineffective and deleveraging is key in recoveries from balance
sheet recessions
1
In per cent Graph V.B
Cyclical recoveries and monetary policy stance Cyclical recoveries and deleveraging
1
The solid (dashed) regression lines indicate that the relationship is statistically significant (insignificant). For a sample of 24 economies
since the mid-1960s. Downturns are defined as periods of declining real GDP and recoveries as periods ending when real GDP exceeds the
previous peak. The data cover 65 cycles, including 28 cycles with a financial crisis just before the peak. Data points for cycles are adjusted
for the depth of the preceding recession and the interest rate at the cyclical peak. See Bech et al (2014) for details.
Sources: M Bech, L Gambacorta and E Kharroubi, Monetary policy in a downturn: are financial crises special?, International Finance, vol 17,
Spring 2014, pp 99119 (also available in BIS Working Papers, no 388, at www.bis.org/publ/work388.pdf); OECD; Datastream; national data;
BIS calculations.
4.5
3.0
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
5.0 2.5 0.0 2.5 5.0
C
y
c
l
i
c
a
l
l
y
a
d
j
u
s
t
e
d
g
r
o
w
t
h
r
a
t
e
d
u
r
i
n
g
r
e
c
o
v
e
r
y
Cyclically adjusted real interest rate during downturn
Cycles with financial crises
4.5
3.0
1.5
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
0.2 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3
C
y
c
l
i
c
a
l
l
y
a
d
j
u
s
t
e
d
g
r
o
w
t
h
r
a
t
e
d
u
r
i
n
g
r
e
c
o
v
e
r
y
Cyclically adjusted private credit by banks to GDP
during downturn
Cycles without financial crises
94 BIS 84th Annual Report
international fnancial conditions. For example, the amount of US dollar credit
outstanding outside the United States was roughly $7 trillion at end-2013
(Graph V.5, left-hand panel). When interest rates expressed in these currencies are
low, EME borrowers fnd it cheaper to borrow in them, and those who have already
borrowed at variable rates enjoy lower fnancing costs. Before the crisis, fows of
dollar credit in particular were driven by cross-border bank lending; since 2008,
activity in global capital markets has surged (Graph V.5, centre panel).
5
Policy responses matter too. Central banks fnd it diffcult to operate with policy
rates that are considerably different from those prevailing in the key currencies,
especially the US dollar. Concerns with exchange rate overshooting and capital
infows make them reluctant to accept large and possibly volatile interest rate
differentials, which contributes to highly correlated short-term interest rate
movements (Graph V.5, right-hand panel). Indeed, the evidence is growing that US
policy rates signifcantly infuence policy rates elsewhere (Box V.C).
Very low interest rates in the major advanced economies thus pose a dilemma
for other central banks. On the one hand, tying domestic policy rates to the very
low rates abroad helps mitigate currency appreciation and capital infows. On the
other hand, it may also fuel domestic fnancial booms and hence encourage the
build-up of vulnerabilities. Indeed, there is evidence that those countries in which
policy rates have been lower relative to traditional benchmarks, which take account
of output and infation developments, have also seen the strongest credit booms
(Chapter IV).
5
See R McCauley, P McGuire and V Sushko, Global dollar credit: links to US monetary policy and
leverage, Economic Policy, forthcoming.
Global borrowing in foreign currencies rises while short-term interest rates co-move Graph V.5
Credit to non-residents, by currency
1
Credit to non-residents, by type
1, 2
Three-month interest rate
Amount outstanding, USD trn
Year-on-year growth, per cent
Per cent Per cent
1
At end-2013 exchange rates. For each currency, credit is to non-financial borrowers outside the respective currency-issuing country or
area. Credit includes loans to non-banks and debt securities of non-financial issuers. In addition, in countries not reporting to the BIS, loans
by local banks to domestic residents in each of the currencies shown are proxied by the respective cross-border loans received by the banks
on the assumption that these funds are then extended to non-banks.
2
Based on the sum of credit in currencies shown in the left-hand
panel.
3
Simple average of Brazil, Chile, China, Chinese Taipei, Colombia, the Czech Republic, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia,
Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Africa, Thailand and Turkey.
4
Simple
average of the euro area, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States.
5
Simple average of Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Norway,
Sweden and Switzerland.
Sources: Bloomberg; Datastream; BIS international debt statistics and locational banking statistics by residence.
0
2
4
6
8
10
03 05 07 09 11 13
US dollar
Euro
Yen
Pound sterling
Swiss franc
20
10
0
10
20
30
03 05 07 09 11 13
Cross-border loans
International debt securities
0
2
4
6
8
10
0
1
2
3
4
5
03 05 07 09 11 13
EMEs (lhs)
3
Major advanced economies (rhs)
4
Small advanced economies (rhs)
5
95 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box V.C
Impact of US monetary policy on EME policy rates: evidence from Taylor rules
One way to assess the impact of US monetary policy on EME policy rates is to estimate augmented Taylor rules for
individual EMEs. The policy rate of each sample economy is modelled as a function of the domestic infation rate,
the domestic output gap and the shadow policy rate of the United States. The shadow rate is designed to
capture the impact of the Federal Reserves unconventional monetary policy measures, such as its large-scale asset
purchase programmes. The sample covers 20 EMEs from Q1 2000 to Q3 2013.
The impact of US monetary policy is found to be statistically signifcant for 16 of 20 EMEs. Since 2012, easier
US monetary policy has been associated with an average reduction of 150 basis points in EME policy rates (Graph V.C,
left-hand panel), although the impact has varied substantially across economies and time. The response of EME
policy rates to infation was often weaker than the prescription of the conventional Taylor rule. These results are
consistent with the fnding that EME policy rates have, over the past decade, run below the level suggested by
domestic macroeconomic conditions as captured in standard Taylor rules (Graph V.C, right-hand panel).
Although the fndings are statistically robust and consistent with the fndings of other studies, they should
be interpreted with caution. Measuring unobservable variables, such as the output gap, is fraught with diffculties.
Even the policy rate might not be an accurate measure of monetary conditions because EME central banks have
increasingly used non-interest rate measures to affect monetary conditions. And even if representative for EME
central banks as a group, the results do not necessarily apply to any given central bank.
For more details on the estimation, see E Takts and A Vela, International monetary policy transmission, BIS Papers, forthcoming. The
shadow policy rate was developed in M Lombardi and F Zhu, A shadow policy rate to calibrate US monetary policy at the zero lower
bound, BIS Working Papers, no 452, June 2014. For example, C Gray, Responding to the monetary superpower: investigating the
behavioural spillovers of US monetary policy, Atlantic Economic Journal, vol 41, no 2, 2013, pp 17384; M Spencer, Updating Asian Taylor
rules, Deutsche Bank, Global Economic Perspectives, 28 March 2013; and J Taylor, International monetary policy coordination: past,
present and future, BIS Working Papers, no 437, December 2013.
US monetary policy has strong spillovers to EME policy rate settings Graph V.C
The impact of US monetary policy
1
Taylor rates in EMEs
Percentage points
Per cent
1
The component of the augmented Taylor equation driven by the shadow US policy rate when it is significant at the 5% level. Data are for
Brazil, China, Colombia, the Czech Republic, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Israel, Korea, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Singapore
(overnight rate), South Africa and Turkey.
2
Weighted average based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange rates for Argentina, Brazil, China,
Chinese Taipei, the Czech Republic, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, Poland, Singapore, South
Africa and Thailand.
3
The range and the mean of the Taylor rates for all inflation-output gap combinations. See B Hofmann and
B Bogdanova, Taylor rules and monetary policy: a global Great Deviation?, BIS Quarterly Review, September 2012, pp 3749.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics and World Economic Outlook; Bloomberg; CEIC; Consensus Economics; Datastream; national
data; BIS calculations.
10
8
6
4
2
0
Q2 12 Q4 12 Q2 13 Q4 13
Average impact Range of impact estimates
for selected EMEs
0
4
8
12
16
20
95 00 05 10
Policy rate
2
Range of Taylor rates
3
Mean Taylor rate
3
96 BIS 84th Annual Report
To address this dilemma, central banks have relied extensively on macroprudential
tools. These tools have proved very helpful in increasing the resilience of the fnancial
system, but they have been only partially effective in restraining the build-up of
fnancial imbalances (Chapter IV and Box VI.D). A key reason is that, as in the case of
capital fow management measures, macroprudential tools are vulnerable to regulatory
arbitrage. The implication is that relying exclusively on macroprudential measures is
not suffcient and monetary policy must generally play a complementary role. In
contrast to macroprudential tools, the policy rate is an economy-wide determinant of
the price of leverage in a given currency, so its impact is more pervasive and less
easily evaded. Countries using monetary policy more forcefully as a complement to
macroprudential policy need to accept a greater degree of exchange rate fexibility.
Failing to rely on monetary policy can raise even more serious challenges down
the road. Allowing the fnancial imbalances to build over time would exacerbate a
countrys vulnerability to an unwinding, thereby imposing greater damage and,
most likely, precipitating an external crisis as well. But if they do not unwind and the
country is hit by an external shock, the central bank will fnd it very hard to raise
interest rates without generating the fnancial stress it was trying to avoid in the frst
place. Full-blown fnancial busts have not as yet occurred in EMEs or small advanced
economies, but countries in which credit growth had been relatively high proved
more vulnerable to the MayJune 2013 period of market tensions (Chapter II). This
indicates that a more gradual but early tightening is superior to a delayed but
abrupt one later on delayed responses cause a more wrenching adjustment.
Disruptive monetary policy spillovers have highlighted shortcomings in the
international monetary system. Ostensibly, it has proved hard for major advanced
economies to fully take these spillovers into account. Should fnancial booms turn
to bust, the costs for the global economy could prove to be quite large, not least
since the economic weight of the countries affected has increased substantially.
Capturing these spillovers remains a major challenge: it calls for analytical frameworks
in which fnancial factors have a much greater role than they are accorded in policy
institutions nowadays and for a better understanding of global linkages.
Unexpected disinfation and the risks of defation
Many central banks faced unexpected disinfationary pressures in the past year; as
a result, infation fell or remained below their objectives. The pressures were
particularly surprising in the advanced economies because the long-awaited
recovery seemed to be gaining traction (Chapter III). A key monetary policy challenge
has been how best to respond to such pressures.
Generally, all else equal, infation unexpectedly below objectives would call for
an easier monetary policy stance. However, the appropriate response depends on a
number of additional factors. Especially important are the perceived costs and
benefts of disinfation. Another factor, as noted above, is the evidence suggesting
that the effectiveness of expansionary monetary policy is limited at the zero lower
bound, especially during the recovery from a balance sheet recession.
Recent developments indicate that the likelihood of persistent disinfationary
pressures is low. Long-term infation expectations (six to 10 years ahead) have been
well anchored up to the time of writing (Graph V.6), which suggests that shortfalls of
infation from objectives could be transitory. Under such conditions, wage infation
and price infation are less likely to reinforce each other ie so-called second-round
effects would not operate. For example, the decline in commodity prices from
recent historical highs has contributed to the disinfationary pressures in the past
few years. Even if these prices stabilise at current levels rather than bounce back, as
appears to be the case at the time of writing, the disinfationary pressures would
97 BIS 84th Annual Report
wane. This is exactly the same reasoning that induced some central banks to accept
infation persistently above policy objectives in previous years. Of course, if infation
expectations become less frmly anchored, disinfationary pressures would become
a more signifcant concern.
Even if the unexpected disinfationary pressures are prolonged, the costs may be
less than commonly thought. The source of the pressures matters. When they arise
from positive supply side developments rather than defcient demand, the associated
costs are known to be lower. Recent disinfationary pressures in part refect such
positive supply side forces, especially the greater cross-border competition that has
been stoked by the ongoing globalisation of the real economy (Chapter III).
The analysis regarding shortfalls in infation also applies to outright and
persistent price declines, and so far, for much the same reasons, central banks have
judged the risk of defation as negligible. In fact, the historical record indicates that
defationary spirals have been exceptional and that defationary periods, especially
mild ones, have been consistent with sustained economic growth (Box V.D). Some
countries in recent decades have indeed experienced growth with disinfation, no
doubt because of the infuence of positive supply side factors.
Nonetheless, given currently high levels of debt, should the possibility of falling
prices be more of a concern? Without question, large debts make generalised price
declines more costly. Unless interest rates in existing contracts adjust by the same
amount, all else equal, falling prices raise the burden of debt relative to income.
Historically, however, the damage caused by falling asset prices has proven much
more costly than general declines in the cost of goods and services: given the range
of fuctuations, falling asset prices simply have had a much larger impact on net
worth and the real economy (Box V.D). For instance, the problems in Japan arose
frst and foremost from the sharp drop in asset prices, especially property prices, as
the fnancial boom turned to bust, not from a broad, gradual disinfation.
Well anchored inflation expectations
1
Year-on-year rate, in per cent Graph V.6
Short-term inflation forecast Long-term inflation forecast
1
Weighted averages based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange rates of the economies listed. Short-term forecast is one-year-ahead mean
forecast of consumer price inflation, derived from current-year and next-year consensus forecasts; for India, wholesale price inflation. Long-
term forecast is six- to 10-year-ahead mean consensus forecast of consumer price inflation; for India, wholesale price inflation after
Q4 2011. Half-yearly observations (March/April and September/October) converted to quarterly using stepwise interpolation.
2
The euro
area, Japan, the United Kingdom and the United States.
3
Brazil, Chile, China, Colombia, the Czech Republic, Hong Kong SAR, Hungary,
India, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Singapore, Thailand and Turkey.
4
Australia, Canada, New
Zealand, Norway, Sweden and Switzerland; for the long-term inflation forecast, aggregate excluding Australia and New Zealand.
Source: Consensus Economics.
0.0
1.5
3.0
4.5
6.0
04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Major advanced economies
2
EMEs
3
0
1
2
3
4
04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Small advanced economies
4
98 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box V.D
The costs of defation: what does the historical record say?
Defations are not all alike. Owing to the prevalence of price declines in the 19th and early 20th centuries as well as
since the 1990s, the historical record can reveal important features of defation dynamics. Four stand out.
First, the record is replete with examples of good, or at least benign, defations in the sense that they
coincided with output either rising along trend or undergoing only a modest and temporary setback. In the pre-
World War I period, defation episodes were generally of the benign type, with real GDP continuing to expand
when prices declined (Graph V.D, left-hand panel). Average real growth in the fve years up to the peak in the
price level was roughly similar to the growth rate in the fve years after the peak (2.3% vs 2.1%). In the early
interwar period (mainly in the 1920s), the number of somewhat more costly (bad) defations increased (Graph V.D,
centre panel): output still rose, but much more slowly the average rates in the pre- and post-peak periods
were 2.3% and 1.2%, respectively. (Perceptions of truly severe defations during the interwar period are
dominated by the exceptional experience of the Great Depression, when prices in the G10 economies fell
cumulatively up to roughly 20% and output contracted by about 10%. That experience is not fully refected in
Graph V.D, centre panel.)
The defation episodes during the past two and a half decades have, on average, been much more akin to the
good types experienced during the pre-World War I period than to those of the early interwar period (although
identifying peaks in the price level during this period is much more diffcult than in the earlier periods because the
recent defations tend to be feeting). For the most recent episodes, the average rates of GDP growth in the pre-
and post-peak periods were 3.6% and 3.1%, respectively, a difference that is not statistically signifcant.
Deflation periods: the good and the bad
CPI peak = 100 Graph V.D
Pre-World War I
1, 2
Early interwar
1, 2
19902013
1, 3
1
A series of consumer price index (CPI) readings five years before and after each peak for each economy, rebased with the peak equal to
100 (denoted as year 0). The simple average of the rebased indices of each economy is calculated.
2
Pre-World War I peaks range from
1860 to 1901; early interwar period peaks range from 1920 to 1930. Simple average of G10 economies. See Borio and Filardo (2004) for
details on identifying the local CPI peaks based on the annual price index. CPI peak years for each G10 economy in the pre-World War I and
early interwar periods are as follows: Belgium, 1862, 1867, 1873, 1891, 1901, 1929; Canada, 1882, 1889, 1920, 1929; France, 1871, 1877,
1884, 1902, 1930; Germany, 1928; Italy, 1874, 1891, 1926; Japan, 1920; the Netherlands, 1892, 1920; Sweden, 1862, 1874, 1891, 1920;
Switzerland, 1892, 1898; the United Kingdom, 1860, 1873, 1891, 1920; the United States, 1866, 1881, 1891, 1920, 1926.
3
Simple average
of 13 economies, quarterly CPI data. A peak occurs when the CPI level exceeds all previous levels and the levels of at least the next four
quarters. CPI peak quarters are as follows: Australia, Q1 1997; Canada, Q4 1993, Q3 2008; China, Q1 1998, Q2 2008; the euro area, Q3 2008;
Hong Kong SAR, Q2 1998; Japan, Q4 1994, Q4 1998; New Zealand, Q3 1998; Norway, Q1 2003; Singapore, Q4 1997, Q1 2001, Q4 2008;
South Africa, Q2 2003; Sweden, Q4 1997, Q3 2008; Switzerland, Q2 2008; the United States, Q3 2008.
Sources: C Borio and A Filardo, Looking back at the international deflation record, North American Journal of Economics and Finance,
vol 15, no 3, December 2004, pp 287311; national data; BIS calculations.
85
90
95
100
105
110
5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Years relative to peak date
60
70
80
90
100
110
5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Years relative to peak date
Consumer price index Real GDP
70
80
90
100
110
120
5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5
Years relative to peak date
99 BIS 84th Annual Report
More generally, fnancial stability concerns call into question the wisdom of
seeking to push infation back towards its objective over the conventional two-year
horizon. Instead, allowing infation to undershoot the target may be appropriate,
especially in those jurisdictions in which fnancial imbalances have been building
up (Chapter IV). All else the same, failing to do so may actually risk unwelcome
disinfationary pressures down the road as the boom turns to bust. This, along with
evidence of diminished policy effectiveness, suggests that although recent
disinfationary pressures deserve close monitoring, the factors limiting their effects
and the costs of further monetary ease should be carefully assessed.
Normalising policy
Looking ahead, the transition from extraordinary monetary ease to more normal
policy settings poses a number of unprecedented challenges. It will require deft
timing and skilful navigation of economic, fnancial and political factors, and hence
it will be diffcult to ensure a smooth normalisation. The prospects for a bumpy exit
together with other factors suggest that the predominant risk is that central banks
will fnd themselves behind the curve, exiting too late or too slowly.
The central banks from the major advanced economies are at different
distances from normalising policy. The Bank of England has maintained its stock of
purchased assets since mid-2012, and in 2014 the Federal Reserve began a steady
reduction of its large-scale asset purchases as a precursor to policy rate lift-off. In
contrast, the Bank of Japan is still in the midst of its aggressive programme of
balance sheet expansion. And the ECB has just announced targeted longer-term
refnancing operations and lowered its key policy rates to unprecedented levels.
Central banks have also indicated that they will calibrate the pace of policy
normalisation on the basis of the strength of the recovery and the evolution
The second important feature of defation dynamics revealed by the historical record is the general absence of
an inherent defation spiral risk only the Great Depression episode featured a defation spiral in the form of a
strong and persistent decline in the price level; the other episodes did not. During the pre-World War I episodes,
price drops were persistent but not large, with an average cumulative decline in the consumer price index of about
7%. More recently, defation episodes have been very short-lived, with the price level falling mildly; the notable
exception is Japan, where price levels fell cumulatively by roughly 4% from the late 1990s until very recently. The
evidence, especially in recent decades, argues against the notion that defations lead to vicious defation spirals. In
addition, the fact that wages are less fexible today than they were in the distant past reduces the likelihood of a
self-reinforcing downward spiral of wages and prices.
Third, it is asset price defations rather than general defations that have consistently and signifcantly harmed
macroeconomic performance. Indeed, both the Great Depression in the United States and the Japanese defation
of the 1990s were preceded by a major collapse in equity prices and, especially, property prices. These observations
suggest that the chain of causality runs primarily from asset price defation to real economic downturn, and then to
defation, rather than from general defation to economic activity. This notion is also supported by the trajectories
of prices and real output during the interwar period (Graph V.D, centre panel), which show that real GDP tended to
contract before defation set in.
Fourth, recent defation episodes have often gone hand in hand with rising asset prices, credit expansion and
strong output performance. Examples include episodes in the 1990s and 2000s in countries as distinct as China and
Norway. There is a risk that easy monetary policy in response to good defations, aiming to bring infation closer to
target, could inadvertently accommodate the build-up of fnancial imbalances. Such resistance to good defations
can, over time, lead to bad defations if the imbalances eventually unwind in a disruptive manner.
For formal evidence on this point, see C Goodhart and B Hofmann, House prices and the macroeconomy, Oxford University Press, 2006,
Chapter 5, Goods and asset price defations.
100 BIS 84th Annual Report
of various crisis-related headwinds. The Federal Reserve expects labour market
headwinds and balance sheet problems to wane over the next few years;
nonetheless, it expects that the real interest rate consistent with macroeconomic
balance (ie the natural rate) will normalise, at about 2%, only over a longer period,
in part because of a persistent surfeit of global saving. The Bank of Englands
Monetary Policy Committee has said that the natural rate is being held down by
continuing strains in the fnancial system and the process of repair in private and
public balance sheets. The ECB sees different headwinds. It expects bank
deleveraging and fnancial fragmentation, among other factors, to hold back the
recovery for several years. Overall, the gap between current market expectations of
policy rates and the trajectory of rates implied by Taylor rules (Graph V.7) may be
shaping the perception of headwinds and their persistence.
A common view today is that central banks should be extra cautious to avoid
endangering the fragile recovery. According to this view, defation would impose
major costs, and even delaying exit would not be a major problem: infation might
rise, but central banks could then quickly catch up. Moreover, according to this
view, careful communication, announcing any exit well in advance and making it
clear that it would be gradual, would help limit the risk of market disruptions.
This view is supported by a number of historical observations. The Federal
Reserves exit decision in 1994 created serious market tensions globally, whereas
the better anticipated and more gradual exit in 2004 had no such large effects.
Moreover, the gradual pace of exit in 2004 did not result in infation increasing
beyond the central banks control. Indeed, this exit was designed to a considerable
extent to avoid some of the shortcomings of the 1994 process.
However, the argument urging central bank restraint focuses on infation
and the business cycle at the expense of the fnancial cycle, ignores the impact
on sovereign fscal positions and may well put too much faith in the powers of
communication. Each issue deserves some elaboration.
The argument loses some of its appeal once attention turns to concerns about
the fnancial cycle. Arguably, it was precisely the slow pace of the policy normalisation
after 2003 that contributed to the strong booms in credit and property prices
leading up to the fnancial crisis. For example, in the United States in the early
2000s, the business cycle turned and equity prices fell, but the rising phase of the
fnancial cycle continued (Chapter IV). Today, several developments deserve close
attention: the signs of a global search for yield (Chapter II); the risk of fnancial
imbalances building up in some regions of the world (Chapter IV); and the high
interest rate sensitivity of private sector debt burdens, as debt levels have failed to
adjust relative to output (Chapter IV).
A very slow pace of normalisation also raises issues about the impacts on fscal
sustainability. One such impact is indirect. Keeping interest rates unusually low for
an unusually long period provides an opportunity to consolidate strained fscal
positions, but more often than not it lulls governments into a false sense of security
that delays the needed consolidation.
Another impact is more direct, but not very visible. Wherever central banks
engage in large purchases of sovereign or quasi-sovereign debt (fnanced naturally
with short-term claims), they shorten the debt maturity profle of the consolidated
public sector balance sheet, which comprises the central bank and the government.
This raises the sensitivity of the debt service burden to changes in short-term
interest rates. It may also lead to political economy pressures on the central bank to
refrain from normalising policy at the appropriate time and pace, ie the risk of fscal
dominance. The government will no doubt dislike seeing its budget position
deteriorate; in that context, the losses that are likely to be incurred by the central
bank could put its room for manoeuvre and even its autonomy at risk. In addition,
101 BIS 84th Annual Report
the liability costs associated with the bloated central bank balance sheets raise
other political economy challenges. For instance, the remuneration on liquidity-
draining facilities may beneft the fnancial sector, which might be perceived by the
public as inappropriate. One option to keep the remuneration costs lower could be
to rely on unremunerated reserve requirements.
Finally, communication has its limitations. Central banks want to communicate
clearly to avoid surprising the markets and generating sharp price reactions. But
efforts to be clear may imply greater assurance than the central bank wishes to
convey and encourage further risk-taking. As risk spreads narrow, increasingly more
leveraged positions are required to squeeze out returns. And even if no leverage is
involved, investors will be lured into increasingly risky and possibly illiquid assets.
The process, therefore, raises the likelihood of a sharp snap-back.
6
Moreover, even
if the central bank becomes aware of such risks, it may nonetheless be very
reluctant to take actions that might precipitate a destabilising adjustment. A vicious
circle can develop. In the end, if the central bank is perceived as being behind the
curve, it may well be the markets that react frst.
All this suggests that the risk of central banks normalising too late and too
gradually should not be underestimated. There are very strong and all too natural
incentives pushing in that direction. Another symptom of this bias concerns central
banks quantitative easing programmes, in which they bought long-term assets on
an unprecedented scale to push term premia down. But now, as the time for policy
normalisation approaches, they appear hesitant to actively sell those assets out of
concerns about disrupting markets.
6
See S Morris and H S Shin, Risk-taking channel of monetary policy: a global game approach,
unpublished paper, Princeton University, 2014.
Taylor rule-implied rates point to lingering headwinds
In per cent Graph V.7
United States United Kingdom Euro area Japan
1
The implied Taylor rule rate, i, is calculated as * + r* + 1.5( *) + 0.5y, where is, for the United States, projected inflation rates of the
personal consumption expenditure price index (excluding food and energy); for the United Kingdom, projected consumer price inflation; for
the euro area, projected inflation in the harmonised index of consumer prices; and for Japan, projected consumer price inflation (all items
less fresh food) excluding the effects of the consumption tax hikes; y is the IMF estimate of the output gap for all economies; * is the
inflation target; and r* is the long-run level of the real interest rate set to the potential growth rate (IMF estimate).
2
Assuming potential
growth 1%.
3
As of 13 June 2014; for the United States, the one-month federal funds futures contract; for the euro area, Japan and the
United Kingdom, the euro, yen and sterling overnight indexed swap curves, respectively.
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; Bloomberg; Datastream; national data; BIS calculations.
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
2014 2015 2016
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
2014 2015 2016
Mean Taylor rate
1
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
2014 2015 2016
Range of Taylor rates
2
2
1
0
1
2
3
4
2014 2015 2016
Market-implied rate
3
102 BIS 84th Annual Report
Annual changes in foreign exchange reserves
In billions of US dollars Annex Table V.1
At current exchange rates Memo:
Amounts outstanding,
December 2013
2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013
World 641 819 1,100 941 747 733 11,686
Advanced economies
1
61 83 194 269 195 55 2,287
United States 4 1 2 0 2 2 48
Euro area 1 8 13 1 12 1 221
Japan 55 7 39 185 28 9 1,203
Switzerland 0 47 126 54 197 21 489
Asia 410 715 651 424 239 529 5,880
China 418 453 448 334 130 510 3,821
Chinese Taipei 21 56 34 4 18 14 417
Hong Kong SAR 30 73 13 17 32 6 311
India 20 12 9 5 1 6 268
Indonesia 5 11 29 14 2 12 93
Korea 61 65 22 11 19 19 336
Malaysia 10 2 9 27 6 4 130
Philippines 3 4 16 12 6 2 74
Singapore 11 12 38 12 21 14 270
Thailand 23 25 32 0 6 12 159
Latin America
2
42 25 81 97 51 6 688
Argentina 0 1 4 7 3 12 25
Brazil 13 39 49 63 19 13 349
Chile 6 1 2 14 0 0 39
Mexico 8 0 21 23 16 15 169
Venezuela 9 15 8 3 0 4 2
CEE
3
6 13 14 3 15 20 294
Middle East
4
150 29 50 88 148 79 893
Russia 56 5 27 8 32 17 456
Memo: Net oil exporters
5
142 52 117 141 209 79 1,818
1
Countries shown plus Australia, Canada, Denmark, Iceland, New Zealand, Sweden and the United Kingdom.
2
Countries shown plus
Colombia and Peru.
3
Central and eastern Europe: Bulgaria, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania,
Slovakia and Slovenia.
4
Kuwait, Libya, Qatar and Saudi Arabia.
5
Algeria, Angola, Kazakhstan, Mexico, Nigeria, Norway, Russia, Venezuela
and the Middle East.
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics; Datastream; national data.
103 BIS 84th Annual Report
VI. The fnancial system at a crossroads
Nearly six years after the apex of the fnancial crisis, the fnancial sector is still coping
with its aftermath. Financial frms fnd themselves at a crossroads. Shifting attitudes
towards risk in the choice of business models will infuence the sectors future
profle. The speed of adjustment will be key to the fnancial sector again becoming
a facilitator of economic growth.
The banking sector has made progress in healing its wounds, but balance sheet
repair is incomplete. Even though the sector has strengthened its aggregate capital
position with retained earnings, progress has not been uniform. Sustainable
proftability will thus be critical to completing the job. Accordingly, many banks
have adopted more conservative business models promising greater earnings
stability and have partly withdrawn from capital market activities.
Looking forward, high indebtedness is the main source of banks vulnerability.
Banks that have failed to adjust post-crisis face lingering balance sheet weaknesses
from direct exposure to overindebted borrowers and the drag of debt overhang on
economic recovery (Chapters III and IV). The situation is most acute in Europe, but
banks there have stepped up efforts in the past year. Banks in economies less
affected by the crisis but at a late fnancial boom phase must prepare for a
slowdown and for dealing with higher non-performing assets.
The role of non-bank fnancial frms has grown as market-based intermediation
has gained in importance following banks retrenchment. Low policy rates and a
continuing search for yield have encouraged private bond issuance, while banks
have faced a persistent cost disadvantage relative to their corporate clients. The
portfolios of asset management companies (AMCs) have soared over the past few
years, and AMCs are now a major source of credit. This, together with high size
concentration in the sector, may infuence bond market dynamics, with implications
for the cost and availability of funding for businesses and households.
The chapter is organised in three sections. The frst section discusses fnancial
sector performance over the past year. The second focuses on structural changes
that have been shaping business models. The third explores the near-term challenges
institutions face, some in dealing with legacy losses, others in strengthening their
defences in view of a possible turn in the fnancial cycle.
Overview of trends
On aggregate, the fnancial sector has made progress in overcoming the crisis and
adjusting to the new economic and regulatory environment. Banks are building
capital faster than planned, and their proftability is improving. In some countries,
however, problems with asset quality and earnings persist. The picture in the
insurance sector is similar, with generally robust premium growth but an uneven
return on equity across jurisdictions.
Banks
Key trends for banks include stronger capital positions and a reduction in risk-
weighted assets (RWA). The sector has made progress in rebuilding its capital base
primarily through retained earnings, supported by a recovery in proftability. This
104 BIS 84th Annual Report
progress has not been uniform, however, as some banks (especially in Europe)
remain under strain. The reduction in RWA refected in some cases outright balance
sheet shrinkage but in many others a decline in the average risk weight of assets.
Given banks track record of overly optimistic risk reporting, the latter driver raises
concerns about hidden vulnerabilities.
Capital ratios
Banks worldwide have continued to boost their capital ratios. Thus far, progress for
the sector as a whole has exceeded the minimum pace implied in the Basel III
phase-in arrangements (Box VI.A). In the year to mid-2013, large internationally
active banks, as a group, increased their average Common Equity Tier 1 (CET1)
capital from 8.5% of risk-weighted assets to 9.5% (Table VI.1). This average ratio
comfortably exceeded the 2019 benchmark of 7% (CET1 plus conservation buffer)
six years ahead of schedule. Smaller, more regionally oriented banks reached the
same average capital ratio, albeit starting from a higher base of 8.8%. Importantly,
these ratios refect the more stringent new defnitions of eligible capital that are
being phased in and will come fully into force only in 2022.
Progress is also evident in the shrinking capital shortfall of those banks that are
lagging. At mid-2013, this shortfall was 85.2 billion, or 59.6 billion lower than at
the beginning of that year. This reduction was primarily due to gains made by large
internationally active banks, which almost halved their shortfall. By contrast, the
shortfall of smaller banks edged slightly higher, but was still less than half the amount
for their larger peers. For comparison, in 2013, the two groups of banks recorded
combined annual profts (after tax and before distributions) of 482 billion, more
than four times the capital shortfall.
Increases in bank capital have provided the main boost to regulatory ratios.
Graph VI.1 (left-hand panel), using data from public fnancial statements, decomposes
changes in the ratios of common equity to risk-weighted assets. Increases in eligible
capital (left-hand panel, yellow bar segments) made the largest contribution overall,
and especially for banks in emerging market economies (EMEs) and for systemically
important institutions (not shown).
Retained earnings played a key role in supplying fresh capital (Graph VI.1, right-
hand panel). In aggregate, they account for 2.8 points out of the 4.1 percentage point
increase in banks capital-to-RWA ratio between 2009 and 2013. Correspondingly, the
ratio of earnings paid out as dividends declined by almost 13 percentage points to
33%. Banks from advanced economies reduced this ratio by more than 12 percentage
points. In the United States, the decline in banks dividend payout ratio contrasted
with the behaviour of government-sponsored enterprises, the main underwriters of
mortgage loans. Under government control, these institutions disbursed their profts
to the US Treasury, keeping their equity cushions slim.
Banks common equity (CET1) has risen relative to risk-weighted assets
Fully phased-in Basel III ratios, in per cent Table VI.1
2009 2011 2012 2013
31 Dec 30 Jun 31 Dec 30 Jun 31 Dec 30 Jun
Large internationally active banks 5.7 7.1 7.7 8.5 9.2 9.5
Other banks 7.8 8.8 8.7 8.8 9.4 9.5
Source: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision.
105 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box VI.A
Regulatory reform new elements and implementation
To minimise transition costs, implementation of the new capital standards is phased over several years (Table VI.A).
The 8% minimum ratio of total capital to risk-weighted assets (RWA) is already in full effect, but the ratios that
involve higher-quality capital Common Equity Tier 1 (CET1) and overall Tier 1 will reach their new, higher levels
in 2015. The new capital conservation buffer and the surcharge for global systemically important banks (G-SIBs),
both defned in terms of CET1/RWA, will be fully binding in 2019.
Schedule of the Basel III capital phase-in
1
Table VI.A
2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019
CET1/RWA
Minimum 4.0 4.5 4.5 4.5 4.5 4.5
Plus buffers:
Capital
conservation
0.625
1.25
1.875
2.5
G-SIBs
2
0.625 1.25 1.875 2.5
Tier 1
Minimum
(ratio to RWA)
5.5 6.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 6.0
Leverage ratio
(to exposure
measure)
Observation Disclosure Migration to Pillar 1
1
Entries in bold denote full strength of each Basel III standard (in terms of the capital ratio). The corresponding defnitions of eligible capital
become fully effective in 2022.
2
Refers to the maximum buffer, as applicable.
In the past year, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) made progress on two key elements of
the post-crisis regulatory reform agenda. The frst comprises the minimum liquidity standards. The liquidity coverage
ratio (LCR) was published in January 2013, and the defnition of high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) was fnalised one
year later. The new defnition makes greater room for central bank committed liquidity facilities (CLFs). Their use has
been allowed for all jurisdictions, subject to a range of conditions and limitations. The restrictions are intended
to limit the use of CLFs in normal times and to encourage banks to self-insure against liquidity shocks, but they may
be relaxed during times of stress, when HQLA might otherwise be in short supply. The Committee also sought
comments on the net stable funding ratio (NSFR), the second liquidity standard.
Another important element fnalised in January 2014 was the defnition of the denominator of the Basel III
leverage ratio, a simple ratio of capital to total bank exposure that complements the risk-based capital requirements.
The exposure measure represents progress in two respects. First, it is universal, as it overcomes discrepancies in the
way different accounting standards capture off-balance sheet exposures, including derivatives. Its defnition adopts
an established regulatory practice that is highly comparable across jurisdictions. Second, the measure is
comprehensive, as it ensures adequate capture of both on- and off-balance sheet sources of leverage. The result is
stricter capital requirements per unit of exposure than those implied by leverage ratios that had already been in
place in some jurisdictions. Early observations suggest that, on average, the exposure measure is about 1520%
higher than the corresponding total assets metric. Starting in 2015, banks are required to disclose the ratio, with a
view to migrating it to a Pillar 1 requirement by 2018 after a fnal calibration.
Given their contribution to higher bank capital so far, stable profts will be key
to the sectors resilience in the near future. On average, profts rebounded further
from the crisis lows, but recovery remained uneven across countries (Table VI.2).
106 BIS 84th Annual Report
Outside the euro area, banks pre-tax profts improved last year but remained
generally below pre-crisis averages. Interest rate margins did not contribute as
much as in previous years. They remained mostly fat globally, and in some cases
even declined (eg in the United States). Instead, lower credit-related costs were the
main factor at work. Loan loss provisions have been declining in most countries,
refecting the economic recovery and progress in loss recognition.
In the euro area, the picture was quite different. Profts remained lacklustre.
Sovereign debt strains continued to affect asset quality, and a stagnating economy
compressed revenues. Banks are stepping up their effort to deal with impaired
balance sheets ahead of the ECBs asset quality review later this year, as witnessed
by the recent spike in the write-off rate.
Recent developments in the Chinese banking sector illustrate the benefts of
retaining earnings as a buffer against losses. As economic growth in China
weakened, borrowers in the country came under fnancial strain and the volume of
impaired loans ballooned. By drawing on their reserves, however, the fve largest
Chinese banks were able in 2013 to absorb credit losses twice as large as a year
earlier, post strong profts and maintain high capital ratios.
Investment banking activity produced mixed results. Revenues from merger
and acquisition advisory business and securities underwriting strengthened, aided
by very robust corporate debt issuance. By contrast, secondary market trading of
fxed income products and commodities weakened, dragging down related revenues
and, alongside a tougher supervisory stance, leading several large capital market
players to trim their trading activity. Legal risk also played a role. Intensifying offcial
probes into market benchmark manipulation have resulted in very large fnes in
recent years.
Chapter 6 - all graphs as of 19 June - 12:00h
Capital accumulation boosts banks regulatory ratios
1
Changes between end-2009 and end-2013 Graph VI.1
Drivers of capital ratios Sources of bank capital
Per cent
Per cent
1
The graph decomposes the change in the ratio of common equity capital to risk-weighted assets (left-hand panel) and the percentage
change in common equity capital (right-hand panel) into additive components. Overall changes are shown by diamonds. The contribution
of a particular component is denoted by the height of the corresponding segment. A negative contribution indicates that the component
had a depressive effect. All figures are weighted averages using end-2013 total assets as weights.
Sources: B Cohen and M Scatigna, Banks and capital requirements: channels of adjustment, BIS Working Papers, no 443, March 2014;
Bankscope; Bloomberg.
9
6
3
0
3
6
9
All US Euro Other EM Latin EM
area Europe Asia America Europe
Capital to risk-weighted assets
Ratio of risk-weighted to total assets
Capital
Total assets
5.0
2.5
0.0
2.5
5.0
7.5
10.0
All US Euro Other EM Latin EM
area Europe Asia America Europe
Capital
Net income
Dividends
Other
107 BIS 84th Annual Report
Risk-weighted assets
The second driver of the improvement in banks capital ratios was the reduction in
the denominator: risk-weighted assets (Graph VI.1, left-hand panel). This may refect
shrinkage in total assets (magenta segments) or a decline in RWA relative to total
assets (blue segments). Most banks grew in size but lowered the average risk weight
of their asset portfolio. In advanced economies, the decline in RWA relative to total
assets contributed 0.7 points to the 3 percentage point average increase in banks
capital ratios. Euro area banks are an exception to this pattern, as shrinking balance
sheets also contributed to the increase in their capital ratios.
In fact, the average risk weight in bank portfolios has been falling since 2007.
Despite the Great Recession and the sluggish recovery, ratios of RWA to total assets
were about 20% lower in 2013 than six years earlier. Market commentary indicates
that more than a genuine reduction in assets riskiness has been at play and suggests
that banks redesigned risk models in order to lower capital requirements by
underestimating risk and providing optimistic asset valuations. This may explain in
part the persistent discount at which bank shares trade on the book value of equity
(Graph VI.8, left-hand panel). This concern has been intensifed by the observation
that risk weights for similar assets vary substantially across banks.
Market observers and supervisory studies point to a dispersion of reported
RWA that is hard to justify given the underlying risk exposures. The dispersion is
generally higher for more complex positions. Focused analysis of banks loan and
Proftability of major banks
As a percentage of total assets
1
Table VI.2
Pre-tax profts Net interest margin Loan loss provisions Operating costs
3
Country
2
2000
07
2008
12
2013 2000
07
2008
12
2013 2000
07
2008
12
2013 2000
07
2008
12
2013
Australia (4) 1.58 1.09 1.28 1.96 1.81 1.79 0.19 0.30 0.17 1.99 1.20 1.11
Canada (6) 1.03 0.85 1.06 1.74 1.58 1.65 0.24 0.25 0.17 2.73 1.85 1.78
France (4) 0.66 0.27 0.32 0.81 0.95 0.92 0.13 0.24 0.21 1.60 1.09 1.16
Germany (4) 0.26 0.06 0.10 0.68 0.81 0.99 0.18 0.16 0.18 1.38 1.15 1.55
Italy (3) 0.83 0.04 1.22 1.69 1.82 1.58 0.40 0.67 1.43 2.27 1.79 1.84
Japan (5) 0.21 0.40 0.68 1.03 0.89 0.77 0.56 0.19 0.02 0.99
4
0.73
4
0.60
4
Spain (3) 1.29 0.77 0.50 2.04 2.32 2.32 0.37 0.94 0.96 2.29 1.61 1.75
Sweden (4) 0.92 0.58 0.77 1.25 0.93 0.98 0.05 0.16 0.08 1.34 0.87 0.84
Switzerland (3) 0.52 0.03 0.36 0.64 0.54 0.61 0.05 0.05 0.01 2.39 1.86 1.90
United Kingdom (6) 1.09 0.19 0.23 1.75 1.12 1.12 0.31 0.54 0.36 2.02 1.27 1.55
United States (9) 1.74 0.53 1.24 2.71 2.49 2.32 0.45 1.06 0.21 3.58 3.01 3.03
Brazil (3) 2.23 1.58 1.62 6.56 4.71 3.55 1.24 1.43 1.07 6.21 3.69 3.28
China (4)
5
1.62 1.61 1.86 2.74 2.34 2.38 0.31 0.29 0.25 1.12 1.02 1.01
India (3)
6
1.26 1.37 1.41 2.67 2.46 2.82 0.88 0.50 0.57 2.48 2.47 2.36
Russia (3) 3.03 1.64 2.04 4.86 4.56 4.15 0.87 1.59 0.80 4.95 2.73 2.68
1
Values for multi-year periods are simple averages.
2
In parentheses, number of banks included in 2013.
3
Personnel and other operating
costs.
4
Excludes personnel costs.
5
Data start in 2007.
6
Data start in 2002.
Sources: Bankscope; BIS calculations.
108 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box VI.B
Regulatory treatment of banks sovereign exposures
Risk sensitivity is at the core of the capital framework. Basel II and III prescribe minimum capital requirements
commensurate with the credit risk of all exposures. This risk sensitivity also applies to sovereign exposures.
The most relevant standard for internationally active banks is the internal ratings-based (IRB) approach. It
requires a meaningful differentiation of risk and asks banks to assess the credit risk of individual sovereigns using a
granular rating scale. The Basel framework is based on the premise that banks use the IRB approach across the
entire banking group and across all asset classes. But it allows national supervisors to permit banks to gradually
phase in the approach across the banking group and, only if the exposures are non-material in terms of both size
and risk, to keep certain exposures in the external ratings-based, standardised approach (SA) indefnitely.
The SA, as a rule, prescribes positive risk weights to all but the highest-quality credits (AAA to AA). For instance,
it assigns a 20% weight to A-rated borrowers and a 100% weight to B-rated ones. National supervisors, however, are
allowed to exercise discretion and set lower risk weights to sovereign exposures that are denominated and funded
in the corresponding national currency. As a result, the risk weights on such exposures have varied considerably
across large international banks, including global systemically important ones. In fact, the variability in sovereign risk
weights across banks is an important driver of the variability of overall risk-weighted assets.
Data on individual bank risk assessments are generally not available outside the supervisory community. A
notable exception is the European Banking Authoritys welcome initiative to disclose the risk weights and total
exposures of large European banks for different asset classes. The information reveals a wide range of practices and
a general tendency to assign a lower weight to exposures to the home sovereign.
In aggregate, banks assign a zero risk weight to more than half of their sovereign debt holdings. This is
particularly true for portfolios under the SA, which cover the majority of banks sovereign exposures, but also for
some IRB portfolios. Interestingly, the tendency to use the potentially more permissive SA is not related to the
capitalisation of the bank but increases with the perceived riskiness of the borrower. In particular, exposures to
sovereigns in the euro area periphery tend to be overwhelmingly under the SA, thus obtaining zero risk weights.
This applies especially to banks with sovereign exposures exceeding 10% of their capital.
Banks assign to their own sovereign a considerably lower risk weight than do banks from other countries. The
home bias is particularly pronounced for Portuguese, Spanish and Irish banks and somewhat less so for French, UK
and Austrian banks.
For further discussion, see Treatment of sovereign risk in the Basel capital framework, BIS Quarterly Review, December 2013, pp 1011.
trading portfolios fnds that both supervisory practices and individual bank choices
are at work.
1
These practices refect a combination of discretion permitted under
the Basel framework and, occasionally, deviations from the framework. Examples
include the implementation of capital foors and the partial use of the standardised
(non-model-based) approach for instance, for credit exposures to sovereigns
(Box VI.B). Internal model risk estimates based on short data samples, and wide
variation in the valuation of trading positions, contribute to the dispersion of RWA.
The combined effect of these varying practices suggests that there is scope for
inconsistency in risk assessments and hence in regulatory ratios.
What is the appropriate policy response to the need to improve the reliability
and comparability of RWA (Chapter V of last years Annual Report)? The internal
ratings-based (IRB) approach should remain a pillar of the regulatory framework. It
provides an essential link to banks own decision-making and it permits a natural
and welcome diversity of risk assessments among banks. What is needed is to
tighten the link to an objective measurement of the underlying risks and to improve
1
See BCBS, Regulatory Consistency Assessment Programme second report on risk-weighted assets
for market risk in the trading book, December 2013; and BCBS, Regulatory Consistency Assessment
Programme analysis of risk-weighted assets for credit risk in the banking book, July 2013.
109 BIS 84th Annual Report
supervisory safeguards. On the one hand, the introduction of the leverage ratio
provides both a backstop to overly optimistic risk assessments and a useful
alternative perspective on a banks solvency. On the other hand, work under way
to understand the drivers of unwanted variation in RWA points to the need to
ensure rigorous supervisory validation of banks models and to improve its cross-
jurisdictional consistency. In addition, other policies, such as imposing tighter
constraints on modelling assumptions and introducing greater disclosure about
these assumptions, can also improve the comparability of RWA. These options
would be superior to requiring a single regulatory model, such as a unique set of
risk weights, which might encourage herding and risk concentration.
Insurance sector
Insurance companies, like banks, are recovering post-crisis. The crisis hit the core
parts of the insurance companies, causing a sharp fall in the value of their investments
and a slowdown in premium growth. Underwriters of credit derivatives also suffered
losses. The recovery in premium growth and capital differs somewhat in the life and
non-life segments and refects frms original asset composition.
Property and casualty insurance frms absorbed the crisis-driven drop in asset
values thanks to their ample capital buffers. At present, these buffers are being
replenished via growing insurance premiums, which rebounded in most markets
during the past couple of years (Table VI.3). Underwriting proftability, as measured
by the combined ratio the sum of underwriting losses, expenses and policyholders
dividends divided by premium income is also improving, despite spikes in policy
payouts due to natural disasters. The reinsurance sector has also strengthened its
capitalisation and tapped alternative sources of capital. The market for catastrophe
bonds, hard hit in the immediate crisis aftermath, recovered after 2010 and issuance
is on the rise. Insurance premiums in EMEs continued to grow strongly, supported
in many countries by an expanding economy, and are narrowing the sizeable gap
in insurance product penetration with mature markets.
The recovery in the life insurance segment has been less strong than in the
property and casualty segment. Life insurers suffered an additional blow during the
Proftability of the insurance sector
As a percentage of total assets Table VI.3
Nonlife Life
Premium growth Investment return Premium growth Investment return
2008 2010 2013 2008 2010 2013 2008 2010 2013 2008 2010 2013
Australia 4.5 5.1 7.1 7.4 6.7 5.0 11.1 2.4 12.1
France 2.0 4.4 2.3 2.7 2.8 2.1 8.5 5.0 5.5
1
1.1 7.4 5.1
Germany 1.0 3.4 3.9 4.0 3.3 2.9 1.0 7.1 1.0
1
1.3 4.6 5.4
Japan 4.1 0.1 2.8 1.3 1.0 1.0 2.8 3.8 2.2
Netherlands 8.4 4.5 1.3
1
4.0 3.4 2.9
1
0.1 11.5 13.4
1
2.0 0.7 6.5
United Kingdom 8.7 0.9 2.0 6.2 3.7 3.1 29.2 4.7 5.2
United States 0.6 0.5 4.4 4.3 3.6 3.2 2.4 13.6 4.3 11.9 13.8 7.6
1
2012 fgures.
Sources: Swiss Re, sigma database; national supervisory authorities.
110 BIS 84th Annual Report
crisis because of the combination of losses from embedded product guarantees and
an increase in the valuation of liabilities driven by a decline in interest rates. While
premium income is recovering from its sharp drop during the crisis, it is still growing
less than beneft payments and surrenders.
Premium growth counteracted weak returns on investment portfolios. The low
yields of high-quality bonds, a key asset class for insurers, remain a drag on
investment revenue. Return on equity has recovered from its crisis trough, but
remains below its historical average. A subdued growth outlook and low returns on
other asset classes have triggered a search for yield by insurance companies,
fuelling demand for riskier securities (Chapter II).
Changes in the regulatory framework tighten insurers capital requirements and
impose stricter constraints on the valuation of long-term assets and liabilities. This
should increase the resilience of the sector. It might also whet insurers appetite for
fxed income securities with regular cash fow streams, including corporate debt.
Looking forward, insurers, and life insurers in particular, are exposed to
interest rate risk. The limited supply of long-term investable assets amplifes this
risk by exacerbating the duration mismatch of assets and liabilities. In this case,
derivatives can provide a good hedge and insurers will beneft from reforms in
over-the-counter market infrastructure that should reduce counterparty risk.
But interest rate risk arises also from guarantees and other option-like elements of
life insurance products with investment features. This risk is complex, more diffcult
to predict and harder to hedge. In this case, capital buffers are a better line of
defence.
Bank versus market-based credit
The crisis and its aftermath halted the trend growth in bank-intermediated fnance.
In the advanced economies most affected by the crisis, bank credit to corporates
has ceded ground to market-based fnancing. In EMEs, both sources have grown,
with market-based fnancing registering the faster pace.
Divergent trends in bank lending
Starting period = 100, nominal values Graph VI.2
United States
Europe
1, 2
Emerging market economies
1, 3
1
Weighted averages based on 2005 GDP and PPP exchange rates.
2
The euro area and the United Kingdom.
3
Argentina, China, Hong
Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Korea, Mexico, Poland and Russia.
Sources: Datastream; national data; BIS estimates.
75
100
125
150
175
200
225
02 04 06 08 10 12 14
Households Corporates
75
100
125
150
175
200
225
02 04 06 08 10 12 14
Households Corporates
50
100
150
200
250
300
350
08 09 10 11 12 13
Households Corporates
111 BIS 84th Annual Report
In the immediate crisis aftermath, banks in the hardest-hit economies pulled
back from credit extension in order to nurse their balance sheets back to strength
(Graph VI.2, left-hand and centre panels). Subsequently, these banks lending to
households remained fat, while that to the corporate sector declined, especially in
Europe. Anaemic demand from overly indebted households and a weak economic
recovery partly explain the stagnation of credit growth. But supply side factors also
played a role. Banks with weak balance sheets were more reluctant to expand their
activities (Graph VI.3, left-hand panel).
By contrast, bank credit has been buoyant in emerging market economies
(Graph VI.2, right-hand panel). Credit to households has grown especially strongly,
refecting low interest rates and capital fows from crisis-hit economies.
In both advanced and emerging market economies, corporate borrowers have
increasingly tapped bond markets. They have found eager investors, as in their search
for yield asset managers have supplied fnancing at very attractive rates, which banks
have been unable to match. In fact, banks are facing higher funding costs than
corporate borrowers themselves (Graph VI.3, right-hand panel). This cost disadvantage
is likely to persist as long as concerns about banks health linger (see discussion below).
Investors search for yield has also dented credit standards. The issuance of
low-credit-quality instruments has surged (Chapter II). Sovereign bonds from the
euro area periphery and hybrid bank debt instruments are cases in point.
Structural adjustments in the fnancial sector
The crisis has had a lasting impact on fnancial intermediaries worldwide. Compelled
by the need to secure proftability, nudged by changes in the regulatory environment
(Box VI.A) and motivated by market signals, many banks have been streamlining
their business mix. In parallel, the asset management sector has grown to become
an established player in the funding of investment. All this has reshaped the
domestic and the international fnancial landscape.
Hurdles to bank lending Graph VI.3
Insufficient capital
1
Expensive funding
3
Per cent
1
Sample of 71 banks in 16 advanced economies. The plotted positive relationship is consistent with the regression analysis in Cohen and
Scatigna (2014).
2
In local currency terms.
3
Option-adjusted spread on a bank sub-index minus that on a non-financial corporate sub-
index, divided by the spread on the non-financial corporate sub-index. Sub-indices comprise local currency assets.
Sources: B Cohen and M Scatigna, Banks and capital requirements: channels of adjustment, BIS Working Papers, no 443, March 2014; Bank
of America Merrill Lynch; Bankscope; national data; BIS calculations.
Efficiency and earnings stability go hand in hand
In per cent Graph VI.4
Retail banks Wholesale-funded banks Trading banks
Sources: Bankscope; BIS estimates.
75
50
25
0
25
50
75
0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30
Capital to RWA, end-2009
T
o
t
a
l
a
s
s
e
t
g
r
o
w
t
h
2
(
2
0
0
9
1
3
)
100
50
0
50
100
150
04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
United States Euro area United Kingdom
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Cost-to-income ratio (lhs)
RoE (rhs)
Emerging market economies (25 banks):
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Cost-to-income ratio (lhs)
RoE (rhs)
Advanced economies (60 banks):
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
112 BIS 84th Annual Report
Changes in business models
Analysis of bank-level balance sheets suggests that three business models provide a
useful characterisation of a worldwide sample of large banks.
2
Two of the models
differ mainly in terms of the sources of banks funding. Banks with a retail model
obtain the bulk of their funding from retail depositors and engage mostly in plain
vanilla intermediation, namely extending loans. Wholesale-funded banks also
hold a large share of their assets in the form of loans, but rely strongly on the
wholesale funding market. Finally, trading banks are particularly active on capital
markets. Loans are a small share of their assets, they engage heavily in trading and
investment banking, and they fund themselves predominantly with debt securities
and interbank borrowing.
Performance and effciency have varied markedly across business models over
the past seven years (Graph VI.4). The onset of the crisis sent return-on-equity (RoE)
plummeting for all bank business models in advanced economies (red lines). But
while RoE stabilised for retail banks after 2009, it underwent drastic swings for
trading and wholesale-funded banks. The story is qualitatively similar in terms of
return-on-assets, an alternative metric that is largely insensitive to leverage. Despite
trading banks sub-par performance, high staff remuneration consistently infated
their cost-to-income ratios above those in the rest of the sector (blue lines). For
their part, banks domiciled in EMEs, which had mainly adopted a retail model and
were largely unscathed by the crisis, achieved stable performance on the back of
greater cost effciency than their advanced economy peers.
Many banks have adjusted their strategies post-crisis, in line with the business
models relative performance (Table VI.4). In the sample under study, one third of
the institutions that entered the crisis in 2007 as wholesale-funded or trading banks
(19 out of 54 institutions) ended up with a retail model in 2012. Meanwhile, few
2
For a description of a method that identifes the number of business models and assigns each bank
in the sample to a model, see R Ayadi, E Arbak and W de Groen, Regulation of European banks and
business models: towards a new paradigm?, Centre for European Policy Studies, 2012.
Hurdles to bank lending Graph VI.3
Insufficient capital
1
Expensive funding
3
Per cent
1
Sample of 71 banks in 16 advanced economies. The plotted positive relationship is consistent with the regression analysis in Cohen and
Scatigna (2014).
2
In local currency terms.
3
Option-adjusted spread on a bank sub-index minus that on a non-financial corporate sub-
index, divided by the spread on the non-financial corporate sub-index. Sub-indices comprise local currency assets.
Sources: B Cohen and M Scatigna, Banks and capital requirements: channels of adjustment, BIS Working Papers, no 443, March 2014; Bank
of America Merrill Lynch; Bankscope; national data; BIS calculations.
Efficiency and earnings stability go hand in hand
In per cent Graph VI.4
Retail banks Wholesale-funded banks Trading banks
Sources: Bankscope; BIS estimates.
75
50
25
0
25
50
75
0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20 0.25 0.30
Capital to RWA, end-2009
T
o
t
a
l
a
s
s
e
t
g
r
o
w
t
h
2
(
2
0
0
9
1
3
)
100
50
0
50
100
150
04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
United States Euro area United Kingdom
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Cost-to-income ratio (lhs)
RoE (rhs)
Emerging market economies (25 banks):
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
Cost-to-income ratio (lhs)
RoE (rhs)
Advanced economies (60 banks):
0
20
40
60
80
0
10
20
30
40
06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13
113 BIS 84th Annual Report
Business models: traditional banking regains popularity
Number of banks
1
Table VI.4
Business model in 2007
Retail Wholesale-funded Trading Total
Business
model in
2005
Retail 34 10 3 47
Wholesale-funded 1 23 0 24
Trading 3 1 17 21
Total 38 34 20 92
Business model in 2013
Retail Wholesale-funded Trading Total
Business
model in
2007
Retail 35 3 0 38
Wholesale-funded 14 18 2 34
Trading 5 2 13 20
Total 54 23 15 92
1
An italicised entry indicates the number of banks that started a period with the business model indicated in the row heading and fnished
that period with the business model indicated in the column heading. Based on a sample of 92 banks from advanced and emerging
economies.
Sources: Bankscope; BIS calculations.
banks switched from retail to another business model post-crisis (three out of 38),
confrming the relative appeal of stable income and funding sources. This recent
trend stands in contrast to developments in the banking sector pre-crisis. From
2005 to 2007, only four of 45 banks switched to a retail model. In parallel, easy
funding and high trading profts led a quarter of the banks with a retail model in
2005 (13 out of 47 institutions) to adopt another model by 2007.
Shifting patterns in international banking
A key aspect of internationally active banks business model relates to the geographical
location of their funding compared with that of their assets (Graph VI.5, left-hand
panel). At one end of the spectrum are German and Japanese banks, whose
international positions are mostly cross-border, largely funded in the home country.
At the other end of the spectrum, Spanish, Canadian and Australian banks use
foreign offces both to obtain funding and to extend credit within the same host
country. Between these two extremes, Belgian and Swiss banks tap geographically
diverse sources of funding and have large cross-border positions mostly booked in
international fnancial centres, such as London, New York, Paris or the Caribbean.
International banking conducted through local offces in foreign countries has
proved to be more resilient than cross-border banking over the past fve years. This
is evident in the positive relationship between the share of locally conducted
intermediation in a banking systems foreign claims and the overall growth in these
claims (Graph VI.5, right-hand panel). As a case in point, the foreign claims of
Australian banks have increased markedly on the back of growing activity by offces
in New Zealand and emerging Asia. Similarly, robust conditions in Latin America
have allowed Spanish banks to increase their foreign claims, despite general
pressure on European banks to reduce foreign lending in order to preserve capital
for their home markets.
114 BIS 84th Annual Report
By contrast, cross-border activities came under strain when liquidity evaporated
during the crisis, subjecting global fnancial markets to stress. Since then, cross-
border bank lending has retreated, driving much of the decline in the foreign claims
of Swiss and German banks over the past fve years. In this context, the sizeable
increase in Japanese banks cross-border claims, mainly to US and emerging Asia
residents, is a notable exception.
The ascent of the asset management sector
As banks reorganise their business lines and retreat from some capital market
activities, market-based fnancial intermediaries have been gaining ground. The
growth in the asset management sector is a case in point. Because asset managers
are responsible for the investment of large securities portfolios, they can have a
substantial impact on market functioning, on asset price dynamics and, ultimately,
on the funding costs of governments, businesses and households.
AMCs manage securities portfolios on behalf of ultimate investors. They cater
to both retail and wholesale customers. They manage the savings of households
and handle the surplus cash balances of small businesses, but also manage large
sums for institutional investors, such as corporate and public pension funds,
insurance companies, corporate treasuries and sovereign wealth funds.
Arrangements vary widely in terms of product design and characteristics, in
line with client funds investment objectives. For example, open- and closed-end
mutual funds pool individual investors funds in larger portfolios that are managed
collectively. By contrast, corporate and public sector pension funds can place money
International banking: the geography of intermediation matters
In per cent Graph VI.5
Foreign assets, by booking location
1
Local intermediation boosts resilience
2
Banks domiciled in: AU = Australia; BE = Belgium; CA = Canada; CH = Switzerland; DE = Germany; ES = Spain; FR = France; GB = United
Kingdom; IT = Italy; JP = Japan; NL = Netherlands; US = United States.
1
At end-Q4 2013. Cross-border, from home office = cross-border positions booked by the lending banks home office plus estimated
cross-border funding of positive net positions vis--vis residents of the home country; cross border, from a third country = cross-border
positions booked outside the lending banks home country; local = positions booked where the borrower resides.
2
Local intermediation
=
i
min{LC
ni
,LL
ni
}/FC
n
, where LC
ni
(LL
ni
) stands for local claims (liabilities) in country i booked by banks headquartered in country n. Foreign
activity is defined as the sum of foreign claims and liabilities. A plotted percentage change in foreign activity occurred between quarter Q
(the quarter between Q2 2008 and Q2 2009 in which the degree of foreign activity in a particular national system attained its maximum
level) and Q4 2013.
Sources: BIS consolidated banking statistics (ultimate risk and immediate borrower basis); BIS locational banking statistics by nationality.
0
20
40
60
80
100
DE JP BE US NL CH FR IT AU GB CA ES
Cross-border,
from home office
Cross-border,
from a third country
Local
JP
DE
US
BE
FR
IT
NL
CH
AU
GB
CA
ES
50
25
0
25
50
75
10 20 30 40 50 60 70
Local intermediation
F
o
r
e
i
g
n
a
c
t
i
v
i
t
y
,
%
c
h
a
n
g
e
115 BIS 84th Annual Report
with AMCs in segregated accounts managed on the basis of mandates tailored to
client needs. In most arrangements, AMCs do not put their balance sheets at risk in
managing those funds. Rather, in exchange for a fee, they offer economies of scale
and scope in the form of expertise in securities selection, transaction execution and
timing, and portfolio administration. There are exceptions, though. For example,
hedge funds actively manage portfolios following investment strategies that
embody a high appetite for risk-taking and involve substantial leverage. The hedge
fund manager has own funds at risk and is rewarded on the basis of performance.
Similarly, a hidden form of leverage relates to the implicit reassurances of capital
preservation made by money market funds. The AMC responsible for those funds
might feel compelled to cover shortfalls due to bad portfolio performance. Explicit
or implicit backing of a segregated funds borrowing by the umbrella organisation
managing the fund may also put the AMC balance sheet at risk.
The asset management sector has grown substantially over the past several
years. While the diversity in the profles of AMCs and products complicates statistical
measurement, estimates put the total assets under management at dozens of
trillions of US dollars (Graph VI.6). Despite a brief decline in the size of the aggregate
portfolio during the crisis, refecting mainly a drop in valuations rather than client
withdrawals, AMCs managed roughly twice as much money in 2012 as they did
10 years before.
The sectors growth has coincided with an increase in the market share of the
largest players. That of the top tier of AMCs accounts for more than one quarter of
the total assets under management (Graph VI.6, red line). Concentration is greatest
at the very top, where a handful of frms dominate the rankings. Many of these top
AMCs are affliated with and/or operate under the same corporate umbrella as
large, systemically important fnancial institutions.
The ascent of the asset management sector presents both opportunities and
challenges for fnancial stability. On the one hand, strengthening market-based
fnancial intermediation can provide a complementary channel to bank-based
funding for businesses and households (see Box VI.C for an example). In fact, the
growth in AMCs portfolios mirrors the rebalancing of funding of the real economy
away from banks and towards markets. Greater diversity in funding channels can be
a strength, to the extent that one might compensate for supply problems in the
other. That said, the nexus of incentives and objectives infuencing the behaviour of
The asset management sector grows and becomes more concentrated Graph VI.6
USD trillions Per cent
Sources: Towers Watson; BIS estimates.
0
20
40
60
10
15
20
25
2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
Aggregate assets, 500 global asset managers
Lhs:
Share of largest 20 asset managers
Rhs:
116 BIS 84th Annual Report
Box VI.C
Financing infrastructure investment
Investment in infrastructure, if properly targeted and designed, can boost potential growth. Both emerging and
advanced economies need to create, or upgrade, crucial transport and energy-related infrastructure. Overstretched
fscal positions set clear limits to the availability of public sector funding in many countries and put a premium on
promoting private sector funding for such projects. Unlocking this potential requires a degree of certainty about
project design and operation as well as diversity in fnancing instruments.
A key impediment to greater private sector funding is uncertainty about the pipeline of projects. The suitability
of a project for private investors often hinges on the design of legal contracts that govern the distribution of risks
and cash fows. Ill-structured contracts can lead to cost overruns and even failure. Political risks also loom large. For
instance, a history of politically motivated changes to the prices that infrastructure operators can charge greatly
increases the perception of such risks. Private fnanciers will bear the fxed costs of building up expertise if they can
invest in well planned projects that are not subject to cancellation, or major revisions, during the long period of
gestation and construction. Otherwise, less complex asset classes will be preferred.
Another factor that can attract long-term portfolio investors is greater diversity in fnancing instruments.
Infrastructure bonds, for instance, are potentially attractive to pension funds and insurance companies. Over the
long life cycle of infrastructure projects, these bonds credit risk tends to subside more rapidly than that of
comparable corporate bonds (Graph VI.C, left-hand panel). The bonds also tend to exhibit greater ratings stability
and higher recoveries in the event of default. Specialised investment vehicles, such as infrastructure funds, can also
attract new investors by offering diversifcation possibilities across projects in different sectors and countries.
Nevertheless, bank loans remain the main form of debt fnancing for infrastructure (Graph VI.C, right-hand panel).
While loans have some advantages in the construction and early operational phases, bonds could be used more
widely for seasoned projects or the privatisation of existing infrastructure. In EMEs, their issuance is tied to the
development of onshore local currency markets.
Hence, longer-term infrastructure debt is not necessarily riskier than its shorter-term counterpart. See M Sorge, The nature of credit risk
in project fnance, BIS Quarterly Review, December 2004, pp 91101. For more detail, see T Ehlers, F Packer and E Remolona,
Infrastructure and corporate bond markets in Asia, in A Heath and M Read (eds), Financial Flows and Infrastructure Financing, proceedings
of the Reserve Bank of Australia annual conference, March 2014.
Infrastructure finance: default profiles, volumes and composition Graph VI.C
Lower risk at long horizons
1
Post-crisis pickup in volumes
2
Per cent
USD bn
1
Cumulative default rates of investment grade bonds.
2
Aggregate issuance for the periods 200408 and 200913. Local currency issues
are converted into US dollars at the prevailing exchange rate at issue date.
3
Australia, Canada, western Europe, Japan and the United
States.
4
Other emerging market economies: Africa, emerging Asia excluding China, central and eastern Europe, the Middle East and Latin
America.
Sources: Moodys Investors Service, Infrastructure default and recovery rates 19832012 H1, Special Comment, 18 December 2012;
Bloomberg; Dealogic; BIS calculations.
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
2.0
Y1 Y2 Y3 Y4 Y5 Y6 Y7 Y8 Y9 Y10
Corporate bonds Infrastructure bonds
0
100
200
300
400
Advanced China Other EMEs
4
economies
3
200408
200913
Syndicated loans Project bonds
117 BIS 84th Annual Report
AMCs can adversely affect market dynamics and funding costs for the real economy.
Portfolio managers are evaluated on the basis of short-term performance, and
revenues are linked to fuctuations in customer fund fows. These arrangements can
exacerbate the procyclicality of asset prices, feeding the markets momentum in
booms and leading to abrupt withdrawals from asset classes in times of stress.
Greater concentration in the sector can strengthen this effect. Single frms in
charge of large asset portfolios may at times exert disproportionate infuence on
market dynamics. This is especially true when different managers within the same
organisation share research and investment ideas, and are subject to top-down risk
assessments. Reduced diversity in the marketplace weakens the systems ability to
deal with stress. Another concern arising from concentration is that operational or
legal problems at a large AMC may have disproportionate systemic effects.
How strong are banks, really?
Banks still need to take important steps to buttress their resilience and ensure the
long-term sustainability of their business models. In order to regain markets
confdence, institutions from a number of crisis-hit countries must further repair
their balance sheets by recognising losses and recapitalising. This would reduce
their funding costs and strengthen their intermediation capacity. At the same time,
banks operating in, or exposed to, countries with recent fnancial booms should
avoid excessive expansion and ensure that they have enough loss-absorbing
capacity to face a turning fnancial cycle (Chapter IV).
Banks in post-crisis recovery
Banks directly affected by the fnancial crisis have not yet fully recovered. Even
though their capital positions have improved (see above), analysts and markets
remain sceptical. Downbeat perceptions drive banks stand-alone ratings, which
capture inherent fnancial strength and factor out explicit and implicit guarantees
from an institutions parent or sovereign, as well as all-in ratings, which gauge
overall creditworthiness. Scepticism is also evident in the valuation of certain banks
equity and in the spreads markets charge for bank debt.
In April 2014, the stand-alone ratings of banks on both sides of the Atlantic
stood several notches below their pre-crisis levels (Graph VI.7, left-hand and centre
panels, green bar segments). The crisis exposed these banks 2007 ratings as overly
optimistic, triggering a wave of large downgrades. The major rating agencies
assessments of banks inherent health continued to deteriorate even past 2010,
showing only marginal signs of improvement more recently.
Low and deteriorating stand-alone ratings can undermine confdence in the
banking sector. For one, they cast doubt on banks own assessments that their
fnancial strength has been improving. They also imply that banks need to rely more
than in the past on external support to improve their creditworthiness. But, facing
fnancial problems of their own or trying to reduce taxpayers exposure to fnancial
sector risks, sovereigns have had less capacity and have expressed a reduced
willingness to provide such support. As a result, banks all-in ratings have
deteriorated in step with, or by more than, stand-alone ratings (Graph VI.7, left-
hand and centre panels, combined height of green and red bar segments).
Price-based indicators from credit and equity markets also reveal scepticism,
especially about euro area and UK banks. Given credit ratings in the non-fnancial
corporate sector (Graph VI.7, right-hand panel), this scepticism has resulted in
a positive wedge between the banks funding costs and what their potential
118 BIS 84th Annual Report
customers can obtain on the market (Graph VI.3, right-hand panel). Coupled with a
slow recovery of the interbank and repo markets, this has weakened banks cost
advantage, thus causing them to lose ground to market-based intermediation.
Likewise, euro area and UK banks price-to-book ratios have remained persistently
below one, in contrast to those of US banks, which seem to have regained market
confdence (Graph VI.8, left-hand panel).
Banks ratings remain depressed
Asset-weighted averages Graph VI.7
Bank ratings, Fitch
1
Bank ratings, Moodys
1
Non-financial corporate ratings
2
1
Numbers of banks in parentheses.
2
From Moodys.
Sources: Fitch Ratings; Moodys; BIS calculations.
BB
BBB
BBB+
A
AA
Euro Other United EMEs
area Europe States (64)
(44) (20) (17)
e
n
d
2
0
0
7
e
n
d
2
0
1
0
A
p
r
2
0
1
4
Stand-alone
BB
BBB
BBB+
A
AA
Euro Other United EMEs
area Europe States (72)
(50) (21) (13)
External support
BB
BBB
BBB+
A
AA
Euro Other United EMEs
area Europe States
e
n
d
2
0
0
7
e
n
d
2
0
1
0
A
p
r
2
0
1
4
Markets scepticism differs across banking systems Graph VI.8
Price-to-book ratios
1
Capitalisation ratios
2
Ratio
Per cent Per cent
1
Based on 200 large banks. Aggregates are calculated as the total market capitalisation across institutions domiciled in a particular region,
divided by the corresponding total book value of equity.
2
Region-wide market capitalisation divided by the sum of region-wide market
capitalisation and region-wide book value of liabilities; averages over the previous three months; based on the Moodys KMV sample of
listed entities.
3
Nordic countries = Denmark, Norway and Sweden.
Sources: Datastream; Moodys; BIS calculations.
0.50
0.25
1.00
1.75
2.50
05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Euro area
United States
EMEs
United Kingdom
Switzerland and
Nordic countries
3
40
50
60
70
0
10
20
07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14
Advanced economies
Emerging markets
Non-financial corporates (lhs): Banks (rhs):
119 BIS 84th Annual Report
Despite post-crisis capital-raising efforts, doubts remain about the quality of
certain banks balance sheets. More fresh capital has supported an upward trend in
banks market capitalisation, both in absolute terms and relative to the book value
of liabilities (Graph VI.8, right-hand panel, red lines). However, the capacity of capital
to absorb future losses is severely undermined by unrecognised losses on legacy
assets. Unrecognised losses distort banks incentives, diverting resources towards
keeping troubled borrowers afoat and away from new projects. And as these losses
gradually come to the surface, they raise banks non-performing loan (NPL) ratios. In
the euro area periphery countries, NPL ratios have continued to rise, almost six years
after the apex of the crisis (Graph VI.9, left-hand panel), while new lending has remained
subdued. Similarly, banks in central Europe have reported stubbornly high and, in
some cases, rapidly increasing NPL ratios since 2008 (Graph VI.9, right-hand panel).
In the United States, non-performing loans tell a different story. After 2009, the
countrys banking sector posted steady declines in the aggregate NPL ratio, which
fell below 4% at end-2013. Coupled with robust asset growth, this suggests that
the sector has made substantial progress in putting the crisis behind it. Persistent
strains on mortgage borrowers, however, kept the NPL ratios of the two largest
government-sponsored enterprises above 7% in 2013.
Enforcing balance sheet repair is an important policy challenge in the euro area.
The challenge has been complicated by a prolonged period of ultra-low interest
rates. To the extent that low rates support wide interest margins, they provide
useful respite for poorly performing banks. However, low rates also reduce the cost
of and thus encourage forbearance, ie keeping effectively insolvent borrowers
afoat in order to postpone the recognition of losses. The experience of Japan in the
1990s showed that protracted forbearance not only destabilises the banking sector
directly but also acts as a drag on the supply of credit and leads to its misallocation
(Chapter III). This underscores the value of the ECBs asset quality review, which aims
to expedite balance sheet repair, thus forming the basis of credible stress tests.
The goal of stress tests is to restore and buttress market confdence in the
banking sector. Ultimately, though, it is banks capacity to assess their own risks that
Non-performing loans take divergent paths
As a percentage of total loans Graph VI.9
Advanced economies Emerging Asia Latin America Other emerging economies
Definitions differ across countries.
Sources: IMF, Financial Soundness Indicators; national data; BIS calculations.
0.0
2.5
5.0
7.5
10.0
12.5
02 05 08 11 14
United States
Spain
Italy
0
3
6
9
12
15
02 05 08 11 14
Korea
Thailand
Indonesia
India
China
1
2
3
4
02 05 08 11 14
Mexico
Brazil
0
3
6
9
12
15
02 05 08 11 14
Czech Republic
Hungary
Poland
Turkey
Russia
120 BIS 84th Annual Report
would support this confdence on a continuous basis. Hence the importance of
policy initiatives to promote transparent, reliable and internationally harmonised
risk measurement systems and enhanced disclosure.
Banks in a late fnancial boom phase
In countries with recent fnancial booms, banks may be weaker than they appear.
This concern applies mainly to institutions exposed to those emerging market
economies where perceptions of a benign credit outlook and strong earnings
potential have ridden on an unstable leverage-based expansion. A similar concern
applies to bank operations in certain advanced economies, such as Switzerland and
the Nordic countries, where strong valuations (Graph VI.8, left-hand panel) may be
refecting fast credit growth and frothy property prices (Chapter IV).
Several indicators deliver an upbeat message about EME banks. For one, the
NPL ratios of banks domiciled in parts of emerging Asia and Latin America have
been low and declining, standing at around 3% or lower at end-2013 (Graph VI.9,
second and third panels). In this context, Indian banks rising NPL ratios are an
exception. In addition, the credit ratings that both Fitch and Moodys assign to large
EME banks have remained stable and even improved slightly on aggregate since
2007 (Graph VI.7). And the corresponding price-to-book ratios have been high,
hovering around 2 over the past fve years (Graph VI.8, left-hand panel).
That said, such indicators failed to signal vulnerabilities in the past. Because of
their backward-looking nature, NPL ratios did not pick up in advanced economies
until 2008, when the crisis was already under way (Graph VI.9, left-hand panel).
Similarly, pre-crisis credit ratings and market valuations did not warn about the
imminent fnancial distress.
In contrast, measures of credit expansion and the speed of property price
infation, which have been reliable early warning indicators, are fashing red lights
about a number of emerging market economies at the current juncture (Chapter IV).
These warnings are echoed by capitalisation ratios, which equal the market value of
equity divided by the book value of liabilities (Graph VI.8, right-hand panel, blue
lines). On the back of leverage-based balance sheet growth, these ratios have
declined steadily on aggregate for both banks and non-fnancial corporates (NFCs)
in EMEs. Thus, any event that triggers investor scepticism would depress
capitalisation ratios from a low starting point, potentially endangering fnancial
stability. The EME NFC sector is an important part of the picture not only because it
is the main source of credit risk to domestic banks but also because it has recently
entered the intermediation chain (Chapter IV).
In a sign of growing investor scepticism, Chinese banks price-to-book ratios
have diverged from those of EME peers and have been declining over the past fve
years. Explicit and implicit links between regulated and shadow banks have
contributed to this scepticism. National data indicate that non-bank credit to private
NFCs grew sevenfold between mid-2008 and end-2013, thus increasing its share in
the countrys total credit from 10% to 25%. The fragilities accompanying this rapid
rise surfaced in a number of near and outright defaults among Chinas shadow
banks and contributed to a drastic reduction in the countrys credit supply in
the frst quarter of 2014. Industry analysts expect such strains to have repercussions
on banks, not least because they have acted as issuers and distributors of shadow
banking products.
Authorities in EMEs need to alert banks to the scale of current risks, enforce
sound risk management and strengthen macroprudential measures. For one, the
deteriorating growth outlook in these economies calls for a downward revision of
earnings forecasts. In addition, EME authorities will need to cope with the fallout
121 BIS 84th Annual Report
from the phasing-out of monetary accommodation in advanced economies. The
resulting market tensions (Chapters II and IV) have highlighted the importance of
proper management of interest and exchange rate risk. More generally, the build-
up of fnancial vulnerabilities underscores the importance of not being lulled into a
false sense of security and of reassessing previously used macroprudential tools
(Box VI.D). Emerging market economies have been early adopters of such tools and
have gained extensive experience regarding their operation and effectiveness. This
experience can be the basis for further refnements and improvements to the
macroprudential policy framework.
Box VI.D
The effectiveness of countercyclical policy instruments
Policies that address macro-fnancial vulnerabilities require effective instruments that take a system-wide perspective.
In recent years, several jurisdictions have strengthened the systemic orientation of their prudential framework by
redesigning existing, and introducing new, macroprudential policy tools to mitigate the risks arising from the
fnancial cycle. Similar tools have been incorporated in international standards. Even though it is premature to seek
frm conclusions about the effectiveness of newly introduced tools, such as countercyclical capital buffers, the
historical experience of some jurisdictions with similar tools provides a useful context.
The yardstick for the assessment of instrument effectiveness is tied to the objective of the policy. In the case of
countercyclical tools, there are two complementary objectives. The frst, narrower, one is to protect fnancial
institutions from the effects of the cycle. The second, broader, objective is to tame the fnancial cycle. Success in the
narrow objective does not guarantee success in the broader one, as policymakers experience so far with the most
prominent countercyclical instruments confrms.
Capital buffers and dynamic provisions
A number of jurisdictions have introduced a countercyclical capital requirement in order to increase banks resilience
in the face of risk built up during credit booms. Switzerland activated the tool in 2013 with a focus on the domestic
mortgage market. The early signs are that the tool is more effective in strengthening banks balance sheets than in
slowing down mortgage credit growth or affecting its cost. This mirrors Spains experience with dynamic provisioning.
More ample provisions helped Spanish banks to partially buffer the impact of the bust in the property market, but
did not prevent the bubble from infating in the frst place.
Loan-to-value (LTV) and debt service-to-income (DSTI) ratios
These tools have a longer track record in a number of jurisdictions. The evidence indicates that they help to improve
banks resilience by increasing that of borrowers. A number of studies fnd that tighter LTV caps reduce the sensitivity
of households to income and property price shocks. The impact on the credit cycle is less well documented, but
experience suggests that tightening LTV and DSTI caps during booms slows real credit growth and house price
appreciation to some extent. In particular, a typical tightening of the maximum DSTI ratio generates a 47 percentage
point deceleration in credit growth over the following year. But relaxing the constraint has a more ambiguous effect.
Time-varying liquidity requirements / reserve requirements
Similarly to capital, the impact of higher liquidity buffers on the resilience of banks is self-evident. There is also
evidence that liquidity-based macroprudential tools can effectively enhance the systems resilience. The evidence
on the impact of liquidity-based tools in curbing the credit cycle is not as strong. Studies assessing the impact of
higher reserve requirements fnd that lending spreads increase and lending shrinks, but that the effects do not last.
See S Claessens, S Ghosh and R Mihet, Macro-prudential policies to mitigate fnancial system vulnerabilities, Journal of International
Money and Finance, vol 39, December 2013, pp 15385; and K Kuttner and I Shim, Can non-interest rate policies stabilise housing markets?
Evidence from a panel of 57 economies, BIS Working Papers, no 433, November 2013. For a study of the net stable funding ratio, see
BCBS, An assessment of the long-term economic impact of stronger capital and liquidity requirements, August 2010.
123 BIS 84th Annual Report
Organisation of the BIS as at 31 March 2014 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128
The BIS: mission, activities, governance and financial results . . . . . 129
The meetings programmes and the Basel Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129
Bimonthly meetings and other regular consultations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129
Global Economy Meeting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
All Governors Meeting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
Other regular consultations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130
The Basel Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131
Synergies of co-location . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
Flexibility and openness in the exchange of information . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
Support from the economic expertise and banking experience of the BIS . . 132
Activities of BIS-hosted committees and the FSI in 2013/14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132
Key initiatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
Policy reform . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133
Policy implementation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136
Simplicity, comparability and risk sensitivity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138
Improving the effectiveness of supervision . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 139
Committee on the Global Financial System . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141
Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
Monitoring implementation of standards for financial market
infrastructures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
Recovery of financial market infrastructures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142
Authorities access to trade repository data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Non-banks in retail payments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Payment aspects of financial inclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Cyber-security in FMIs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Red Book statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Markets Committee . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143
Central Bank Governance Group . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144
Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 144
Financial Stability Institute . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
Meetings, seminars and conferences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 145
FSI Connect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
Activities of BIS-hosted associations in 2013/14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
Financial Stability Board . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 146
Reducing the moral hazard posed by systemically important financial
institutions (SIFIs) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 147
Strengthening the oversight and regulation of shadow banking . . . . . . . . . . . 149
Credit ratings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
Financial benchmarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
Addressing data gaps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150
Advancing transparency through the legal entity identifier (LEI) . . . . . . . . . . . 150
Strengthening accounting standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
Enhanced Disclosure Task Force (EDTF) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
Contents
124 BIS 84th Annual Report
Monitoring implementation and strengthening adherence to international
standards . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
Impact of regulatory reforms on emerging market and developing
economies (EMDEs) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151
Financial regulatory factors affecting the availability of long-term finance . . 152
International Association of Deposit Insurers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
Enhance IADI standards and evaluations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152
Conduct research and develop guidance on insurance and resolution . . . . . 152
Strengthen deposit insurance systems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
Expand membership and strengthen its support . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
International Association of Insurance Supervisors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
Financial stability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153
Insurance core principles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
ComFrame . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
Global insurance capital standard . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
Multilateral Memorandum of Understanding . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
Coordinated Implementation Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 154
Self-assessment and peer reviews . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
Joint Forum publications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
Economic analysis, research and statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
Analysis and research in the Basel Process . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155
Research topics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156
International statistical initiatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 156
Cooperation with other central bank initiatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
Representative Offices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 157
The Asian Office . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
The Asian Consultative Council . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 158
The Special Governors Meeting and other high-level meetings . . . . . . . . . . . 158
The Americas Office . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 159
Financial services of the Bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160
Scope of services . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160
Financial operations in 2013/14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 161
Liabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 161
Graph: Balance sheet total and customer placements by product . . . . . 161
Assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
Governance and management of the BIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
The General Meeting of BIS member central banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 162
BIS member central banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 163
The BIS Board of Directors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
Board of Directors . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 164
Alternates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
In memoriam . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
BIS Management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 165
BIS budget policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
BIS remuneration policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 166
Net profit and its distribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
Financial results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167
Proposed dividend . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
Proposed allocation of net profit for 2013/14 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
Independent auditor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
Election of the auditor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
Report of the auditor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 168
125 BIS 84th Annual Report
Financial statements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171
Balance sheet . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173
Profit and loss account . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 174
Statement of comprehensive income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175
Statement of cash flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176
Movements in the Banks equity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 178
Accounting policies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
1. Scope of the financial statements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
2. Functional and presentation currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
3. Currency translation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
4. Designation of financial instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
5. Asset and liability structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179
6. Cash and sight accounts with banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
7. Notice accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
8. Sight and notice deposit account liabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
9. Use of fair values in the currency banking portfolios . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
10. Securities purchased under resale agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 180
11. Currency assets held at fair value through profit and loss . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
12. Currency deposit liabilities held at fair value through profit and loss . . . . . . . . . . 181
13. Currency investment assets available for sale . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
14. Short positions in currency assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
15. Gold . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
16. Gold loans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
17. Gold deposits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 181
18. Realised and unrealised gains or losses on gold . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182
19. Securities sold under repurchase agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182
20. Derivatives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182
21. Valuation policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
22. Impairment of financial assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
23. Accounts receivable and accounts payable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
24. Land, buildings and equipment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
25. Provisions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183
26. Post-employment benefit obligations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
27. Cash flow statement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 184
Notes to the financial statements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185
1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185
2. Use of estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 185
3. Change in accounting policy for post-employment benefit obligations . . . . . . . . 186
4. Cash and sight accounts with banks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
5. Gold and gold loans . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 189
6. Currency assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 190
7. Loans and advances . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191
8. Derivative financial instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 191
9. Accounts receivable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 192
10. Land, buildings and equipment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193
11. Currency deposits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194
12. Gold deposits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
13. Securities sold under repurchase agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195
14. Accounts payable . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 196
15. Other liabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 196
16. Share capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 196
126 BIS 84th Annual Report
17. Statutory reserves . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 197
18. Shares held in treasury . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198
19. Other equity accounts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198
20. Post-employment benefit obligations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200
21. Interest income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205
22. Interest expense . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 205
23. Net valuation movement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
24. Net fee and commission income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
25. Net foreign exchange gain / (loss) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 206
26. Operating expense . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 207
27. Net gain on sales of securities available for sale . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 208
28. Net gain on sales of gold investment assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 208
29. Earnings and dividends per share . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 208
30. Cash and cash equivalents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
31. Taxes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
32. Exchange rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 209
33. Off-balance sheet items . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210
34. Commitments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 210
35. The fair value hierarchy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 211
36. Effective interest rates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 213
37. Geographical analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214
38. Related parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215
39. Contingent liabilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217
Capital adequacy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
1. Capital adequacy frameworks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
2. Economic capital . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 218
3. Financial leverage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220
4. Risk-weighted assets and minimum capital requirements under the
Basel II Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221
5. Tier 1 capital ratio . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 222
Risk management . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
1. Risks faced by the Bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
2. Risk management approach and organisation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223
3. Credit risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225
4. Market risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 234
5. Operational risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 239
6. Liquidity risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 240
Independent auditors report . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 245
Five-year graphical summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 246
Finance
General Manager
Deputy General Manager
Board of Directors
Chairman of the Board
Internal
Audit
Committee on
Payment and
Settlement
Systems
Markets
Committee
Central Bank
Governance
Group
Representative
Office for Asia
and the Pacific
Financial Stability
Board
Secretariat
International
Association of
Insurance
Supervisors
International
Association
of Deposit
Insurers
Administrative
Committee
Financial
Stability Institute
Legal
Service
Banking
Department
Treasury
Asset
Management
Banking
Operational
Services
Financial Analysis
General
Secretariat
Building, Security
and Logistics
Communications
Human Resources
Information
Management
Services
Meeting Services
Monetary and
Economic
Department
Policy,
Coordination &
Administration
Research &
Statistics
Representative
Office for the
Americas
Committee on
the
Global Financial
System
Basel Committee
on Banking
Supervision
Banking
and Risk
Management
Committee
Audit
Committee
Nomination
Committee
Risk Control
Board
Secretariat
Irving Fisher
Committee
Compliance
&
Operational
Risk*
Organisation of the BIS as at 31 March 2014
* Direct access to the Audit Committee on compliance matters.
129 BIS 84th Annual Report
The BIS: mission, activities, governance and
fnancial results
The mission of the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) is to serve central banks
in their pursuit of monetary and fnancial stability, to foster international
cooperation in those areas and to act as a bank for central banks.
In the light of the Banks mission, this chapter reviews the activities of the BIS,
and of the groups it hosts, for the fnancial year 2013/14; describes the institutional
framework that supports the work of those groups; and presents the years fnancial
results.
In broad outline, the BIS pursues its mission by:
promoting discussion and facilitating collaboration among central banks;
supporting dialogue with other authorities that are responsible for promoting
fnancial stability;
conducting research on policy issues confronting central banks and fnancial
supervisory authorities;
acting as a prime counterparty for central banks in their fnancial transactions; and
serving as an agent or trustee in connection with international fnancial operations.
The BIS promotes international cooperation among monetary authorities and
fnancial supervisory offcials through its meetings programmes and through the
Basel Process hosting international groups pursuing global fnancial stability (such
as the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision and the Financial Stability Board)
and facilitating their interaction in an effcient and cost-effective way (see below).
The BIS economic analysis, research and statistics function helps meet the
needs of monetary and supervisory authorities for policy insight and data.
The BIS banking function provides prime counterparty, agent and trustee
services appropriate to the BIS mission.
The BIS has its head offce in Basel, Switzerland, and representative offces in
the Hong Kong Special Administrative Region of the Peoples Republic of China
(Hong Kong SAR) and in Mexico City.
The meetings programmes and the Basel Process
The BIS promotes international cooperation among fnancial and monetary offcials
in two major ways:
hosting and preparing background material for meetings of central bank
offcials; and
the Basel Process, which facilitates cooperation among the international groups
hosted by the BIS.
Bimonthly meetings and other regular consultations
At bimonthly meetings, normally held in Basel, Governors and other senior offcials
of BIS member central banks discuss current developments and the outlook for the
world economy and fnancial markets. They also exchange views and experiences
on issues of special and topical interest to central banks. In addition to the
bimonthly meetings, the Bank regularly hosts gatherings that variously include
public and private sector representatives and the academic community.
130 BIS 84th Annual Report
The two principal bimonthly meetings are the Global Economy Meeting and
the All Governors Meeting.
Global Economy Meeting
The Global Economy Meeting (GEM) comprises the Governors of 30 BIS member
central banks in major advanced and emerging market economies that account
for about four ffths of global GDP. The Governors of another 19 central banks
attend the GEM as observers.
1
The GEM has two main roles: (i) monitoring and
assessing developments, risks and opportunities in the world economy and the
global fnancial system; and (ii) providing guidance to three BIS-based central bank
committees the Committee on the Global Financial System, the Committee on
Payment and Settlement Systems and the Markets Committee. The GEM also
receives reports from the Chairs of those committees and decides on publication.
As the Global Economy Meeting is quite large, it is supported by an informal
group called the Economic Consultative Committee (ECC). Limited to 18 participants,
the ECC includes all BIS Board Governors and the BIS General Manager. The ECC
assembles proposals for consideration by the GEM. In addition, the ECC Chairman
initiates recommendations to the GEM on the appointment of Chairs of the
three central bank committees mentioned above and on the composition and
organisation of those committees.
All Governors Meeting
The All Governors Meeting comprises the Governors of the 60 BIS member central
banks and is chaired by the BIS Chairman. It convenes to discuss selected topics of
general interest to its members. In 2013/14, the topics discussed were:
New challenges for the institutional design of central banks
Central bank challenges from forward guidance
Financial structure determinants and implications
Meeting higher capital requirements: progress and challenges
Domestic and global drivers of infation: has the balance changed?
By agreement with the GEM and the BIS Board, the All Governors Meeting
is responsible for overseeing the work of two other groups: the Central Bank
Governance Group, which also meets during the bimonthly meetings, and the
Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics.
Other regular consultations
During the bimonthly meetings, Governors of central banks in (i) major emerging
market economies and (ii) small open economies gather to discuss themes of
special relevance to their economies.
In addition, the Bank hosts regular meetings of the Group of Central Bank
Governors and Heads of Supervision (GHOS), which oversees the work of the Basel
1
The members of the GEM are the central bank Governors of Argentina, Australia, Belgium, Brazil,
Canada, China, France, Germany, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Italy, Japan, Korea, Malaysia,
Mexico, the Netherlands, Poland, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, South Africa, Spain, Sweden,
Switzerland, Thailand, Turkey, the United Kingdom and the United States and also the President of
the European Central Bank and the President of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. The
Governors attending as observers are from Algeria, Austria, Chile, Colombia, the Czech Republic,
Denmark, Finland, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Israel, Luxembourg, New Zealand, Norway, Peru, the
Philippines, Portugal, Romania and the United Arab Emirates.
131 BIS 84th Annual Report
Committee on Banking Supervision. In its January 2014 meeting, the GHOS
endorsed several proposals from the Basel Committee (as discussed below in more
detail in the report of the Committee): a common defnition of the Basel III
leverage ratio and related disclosure requirements; changes to the Basel III net
stable funding ratio; minimum requirements for liquidity-related disclosures; and
modifcations of the defnition of high-quality liquid assets for purposes of Basel IIIs
liquidity coverage ratio. Finally, the GHOS also reviewed and endorsed the
Committees strategic priorities in its work programme for the next two years, with
the highest priority accorded to completion of the crisis-related policy reform
agenda.
The Bank regularly arranges informal discussions among public and private
sector representatives that focus on their shared interests in promoting a sound
and well functioning international fnancial system. In addition, for senior central
bank offcials, the Bank organises various meetings to which other fnancial
authorities, the private fnancial sector and the academic community are invited to
contribute. These meetings include:
the annual meetings of the working parties on monetary policy, held in Basel
but also hosted at a regional level by a number of central banks in Asia, central
and eastern Europe, and Latin America;
the meeting of Deputy Governors of emerging market economies; and
the high-level meetings organised by the Financial Stability Institute in various
regions of the world for Governors and Deputy Governors and heads of
supervisory authorities.
Other meetings in the past year included:
a roundtable meeting of Governors from Africa, in May 2013;
a meeting of Governors from Latin American and Caribbean central banks, in
June 2013;
a Central Bank of Russia BIS Seminar, Challenges for monetary and fnancial
policy, in July 2013; and
a roundtable meeting of Governors from Central Asia, jointly hosted by the
Swiss National Bank and the BIS, in November 2013.
The Basel Process
The Basel Process refers to the facilitative role of the BIS in hosting and supporting
the work of international groups six committees and three associations engaged
in standard setting and the pursuit of fnancial stability.
The hosted committees, whose agendas are guided by various sets of central
banks and supervisory authorities, are as follows:
the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS): develops global
regulatory standards for banks and addresses supervision at the level of
individual institutions and as it relates to macroprudential supervision;
the Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS): monitors and analyses
the broad issues relating to fnancial markets and systems;
the Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems (CPSS): analyses and sets
standards for payment, clearing and settlement infrastructures;
the Markets Committee: monitors developments in fnancial markets and their
implications for central bank operations;
the Central Bank Governance Group: examines issues related to the design and
operation of central banks; and
the Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics (IFC): addresses statistical
issues of concern to central banks, including those relating to economic,
monetary and fnancial stability.
132 BIS 84th Annual Report
The hosted associations are as follows:
the Financial Stability Board (FSB): an association including fnance ministries,
central banks and other fnancial authorities in 24 countries; coordinates at the
international level the work of national authorities and international standard
setters and develops policies to enhance fnancial stability;
the International Association of Deposit Insurers (IADI): sets global standards
for deposit insurance systems and promotes cooperation on deposit insurance
and bank resolution arrangements; and
the International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS): sets standards for
the insurance sector to promote globally consistent supervision.
The Banks own Financial Stability Institute (FSI) facilitates the dissemination of
the standard-setting bodies work to central banks and fnancial sector supervisory
and regulatory agencies through its extensive programme of meetings, seminars
and online tutorials.
The Basel Process is based on three key features: synergies of co-location,
fexibility and openness in the exchange of information, and support from the
economic expertise and banking experience of the BIS.
Synergies of co-location
The physical proximity of the nine committees and associations at the BIS creates
synergies that produce a broad and fruitful exchange of ideas. In addition, by
reducing each groups costs of operation through economies of scale, the Basel
Process supports a more effcient use of public funds.
Flexibility and openness in the exchange of information
The limited size of these groups leads to fexibility and openness in the exchange of
information, thereby enhancing the coordination of their work on fnancial stability
issues and preventing overlaps and gaps in their work programmes. At the same time,
their output is much larger than their limited size would suggest, as they are able to
leverage the expertise of the international community of central bankers, fnancial
regulators and supervisors, and other international and national public authorities.
Support from the economic expertise and banking experience of the BIS
The work of the nine groups is informed by the BISs economic research and by the
practical experience it gains from the implementation of regulatory standards and
fnancial controls in its banking activities.
Activities of BIS-hosted committees and the FSI in 2013/14
This section reviews the years principal activities of the six committees hosted by
the BIS and of the Financial Stability Institute.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) seeks to enhance supervisory
cooperation and improve the quality of banking supervision worldwide. It supports
supervisors by providing a forum for exchanging information on national
supervisory arrangements, improving the effectiveness of techniques for supervising
international banks and setting minimum supervisory and regulatory standards.
133 BIS 84th Annual Report
The Committee, which generally meets four times a year, consists of senior
representatives of bank supervisory authorities and central banks responsible for
banking supervision or fnancial stability issues in the Committees member
countries. The Group of Governors and Heads of Supervision (GHOS) is the Basel
Committees governing body and consists of central bank Governors and non-
central bank heads of supervision from member countries.
Key initiatives
The Committees current work programme has four goals:
policy reform, with the primary task of completing the crisis-induced reforms;
implementation of the Basel regulatory framework;
further examining the balance between simplicity, comparability and risk
sensitivity in the regulatory framework; and
improving the effectiveness of supervision.
Policy reform
The Basel III framework, a set of global regulatory standards on bank capital
adequacy and liquidity that promote a more resilient banking sector, began taking
effect in many jurisdictions at the start of 2013. All Basel Committee member
countries have introduced the capital adequacy requirements. The Committee
continues to develop global regulatory and supervisory standards and to monitor
its members implementation of the Basel framework.
Basel III leverage ratio. On 12 January 2014, after endorsement by the GHOS, the
Committee issued the full text of the framework and disclosure requirements for
the Basel III leverage ratio. The document included modifcations to the consultative
proposal the Committee issued in June 2013. The leverage ratio complements the
risk-based capital framework to better limit the build-up of excessive leverage in
the banking sector.
The numerator of the leverage ratio is a measure of equity (the capital
measure), and the denominator is a measure of assets (the exposure measure).
The capital measure is currently defned as Tier 1 capital, and a minimum leverage
ratio of 3% has been tentatively proposed. The Committee is checking the ratio at
banks twice per year to assess its appropriateness over a full credit cycle and for
different types of business models. It is also collecting data to assess the impact
of using Common Equity Tier 1 (CET1) or total regulatory capital as the capital
measure.
Banks have begun reporting on the ratio to national supervisors, and public
disclosure starts on 1 January 2015. The Committee will make any fnal adjustments
to the defnition and calibration of the leverage ratio by 2017, with a view to
migrating to a Pillar 1 (minimum capital requirements) treatment on 1 January 2018.
Basel III net stable funding ratio. The Committee frst published its proposals on the
net stable funding ratio (NSFR) in 2009 and included the measure in the December
2010 Basel III agreement. Since that time, the Committee has been reviewing the
standard and its implications for fnancial market functioning and the economy.
The NSFR limits over-reliance on short-term wholesale funding, encourages
better assessment of funding risk across all on- and off-balance sheet items, and
promotes funding stability. A robust funding structure increases the likelihood that,
if a banks regular sources of funding are disrupted, it will maintain liquidity
suffcient to sustain its operations.
134 BIS 84th Annual Report
On 12 January 2014, after endorsement by the GHOS, the Committee issued
proposed revisions to the NSFR. The revisions include reducing cliff effects within
the measurement of funding stability, improving the alignment of the NSFR with
the liquidity coverage ratio, and altering the calibration of the NSFR to focus
greater attention on short-term, potentially volatile funding sources.
Refnements to the liquidity coverage ratio. Also in January 2014, the GHOS endorsed
the Committees proposal to modify the defnition of high-quality liquid assets
(HQLA) within the liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) framework to provide greater use
of committed liquidity facilities (CLFs) provided by central banks. The use of CLFs
within the LCR had been limited to those jurisdictions with insuffcient HQLA to
meet the needs of the banking system. Subject to a range of conditions, a restricted
version of a CLF (an RCLF) may be used by any jurisdiction in times of stress. The
conditions are intended to limit the use of RCLFs in normal times, thereby
maintaining the principle that banks should self-insure against liquidity shocks and
that central banks should remain the lenders of last resort. Whether jurisdictions
choose to make use of RCLFs is a matter for national discretion; central banks are
under no obligation to offer them.
Margin requirements for non-centrally cleared derivatives. In September 2013,
the Committee and the International Organization of Securities Commissions
(IOSCO) released the fnal framework for margin requirements for non-centrally
cleared derivatives. Under these globally agreed standards, all fnancial frms and
systemically important non-fnancial entities that transact non-centrally cleared
derivatives will have to exchange initial and variation margin commensurate with
the counterparty risks arising from such transactions. The framework has been
designed to reduce systemic risks related to OTC (over-the-counter) derivatives
markets as well as to provide frms with appropriate incentives for central clearing
while managing the overall liquidity impact of the requirements.
The requirements will be phased in over a four-year period, which begins in
December 2015 with the largest, most active and most systemically important
participants in the derivatives market.
Standardised approach for capitalising counterparty credit risk exposures. Following
a public consultation on a non-internal model method proposed in June 2013,
the Committee published a fnal standard in March 2014 to improve the
methodology for assessing the counterparty credit risk associated with derivatives
transactions. The standardised approach, which will come into effect on 1 January
2017, will replace the capital frameworks existing methods the Current Exposure
Method and the Standardised Method. It improves on the risk sensitivity of the
Current Exposure Method by differentiating between margined and unmargined
trades. The standardised approach updates supervisory factors to refect the
level of volatilities observed over the recent stress period and provides a more
meaningful recognition of netting benefts. At the same time, the method is
suitable for a wide variety of derivatives transactions, reduces the scope for
discretion by banks as it does not rely on internal models, and avoids undue
complexity.
Updated assessment methodology and additional loss absorbency requirement
for global systemically important banks. In July 2013, the Committee published
an updated framework that sets out its assessment methodology for identifying
global systemically important banks (G-SIBs). The framework also describes the
requirements for additional loss absorbency that will apply to G-SIBs, the phase-in
135 BIS 84th Annual Report
arrangements for these requirements and the disclosures that banks above a certain
size are required to make to enable the framework to operate on the basis of
publicly available information.
The measures will enhance the going-concern loss absorbency of G-SIBs and
reduce the probability of their failure. The rationale for the measures is that current
regulatory policies do not fully address the cross-border negative externalities
created by G-SIBs.
The assessment methodology takes an indicator-based approach comprising
fve broad categories: size, interconnectedness, lack of readily available substitutes
or fnancial institution infrastructure, global (cross-jurisdictional) activity and
complexity.
The amount of additional loss absorbency will consist of buckets of CET1,
with the buckets ranging in size from 1% to 3.5% of CET1, depending on a banks
systemic importance. Initially, no G-SIBs were assigned to the highest requirement
3.5% (the so-called empty bucket) which was established to discourage banks
from becoming even more systemically important.
In December 2013, in accordance with the timeline it set out in July, the
Committee published (i) the denominators that were used to calculate bank scores
and (ii) the cutoff score and bucket thresholds that were used to identify the
updated list of G-SIBs and to allocate them to buckets. That information will enable
banks to calculate their own scores and their higher loss absorbency requirement.
The requirement will be introduced, in parallel with the Basel III capital conservation
and countercyclical buffers, between 1 January 2016 and year-end 2018, becoming
fully effective on 1 January 2019.
Measuring and controlling large exposures. Concentrated exposures to individual
counterparties have been a major source of bank failures and were signifcant
during the global fnancial crisis. In April 2014, with the results of public consultation
and a quantitative impact study in hand, the Committee fnalised a supervisory
framework for measuring and controlling large exposures to contain the maximum
loss a bank could face in the event of a sudden counterparty failure. The framework
can be used to mitigate the risk of contagion between G-SIBs, thus underpinning
fnancial stability. It also offers policy measures designed to capture large exposures
to shadow banks that are of concern to supervisors.
Capital requirements for investments in funds. Following a public consultation in
mid-2013, the Committee revised its policy framework for the prudential treatment
of banks investments in the equity of all types of funds (eg hedge funds, managed
funds, investment funds) that are held in the banking book. The revised framework
will take effect from 1 January 2017 and will apply to all banks regardless of the
method they use for assigning risk weights for credit risk.
In general, investing in funds should involve identifying their underlying assets,
but this look-through approach may not always be feasible. Therefore, the revised
framework provides incentives for improved risk management practices. It also
helps address risks associated with banks interactions with shadow banks and thus
contributes to the broader effort by the Financial Stability Board to strengthen the
oversight and regulation of shadow banking.
Fundamental review of the trading book. In October 2013, the Committee issued a
follow-up to its May 2012 consultative paper on its fundamental review of capital
requirements for the trading book. The October consultative paper comprises
detailed proposals for a comprehensive revision of the market risk framework. Key
features include:
136 BIS 84th Annual Report
a revised boundary between the trading book and banking book that is less
permeable and more objective; it reduces the incentives for regulatory
arbitrage and remains aligned with banks risk management practices;
a shift in the measure of risk, from value-at-risk to expected shortfall, to better
capture tail risk; calibration would be based on a period of signifcant fnancial
stress;
incorporation of market illiquidity risk and an additional risk assessment tool
for trading desks with exposure to illiquid, complex products;
a revised standardised approach that is suffciently risk-sensitive to act as a
credible fallback to internal models, and is still appropriate for banks that do
not require sophisticated measurement of market risk;
a revised internal models-based approach that includes a more rigorous
approval process for the models and more consistent identifcation and
capitalisation of material risk factors;
a strengthened relationship between the standardised and the models-based
approaches that requires all banks to conduct a standardised calculation and
publicly disclose the resulting standardised capital charges; and
a closer alignment of the regulatory treatment of credit risk in the trading
book and the banking book by differentiating securitisation and non-
securitisation exposures.
The Committee is also considering making the standardised approach a foor
or a surcharge to the models-based approach. The Committee expects to fnalise
the trading book framework in 2015 following a comprehensive quantitative impact
study.
Revisions to the securitisation framework. In December 2013, the Committee published
a second consultative paper on revisions to the securitisation framework following
a comment period and a quantitative impact study. In revising the framework, the
Committee aimed to strike an appropriate balance between risk sensitivity,
simplicity and comparability. The major changes in the December document apply
to the hierarchy of approaches and the calibration of capital requirements.
For the hierarchy, the Committee has proposed a simple framework akin to
that used for credit risk: if they have the capacity and supervisory approval, banks
may use (i) an internal ratings-based approach in setting their capital requirement;
if that is not possible for a given exposure, they may use (ii) an external ratings-
based approach (if permitted by their jurisdiction) or, failing that, (iii) a standardised
approach.
Capital requirements remain more stringent than under the existing framework.
The Committee also proposes to set a 15% risk-weight foor for all approaches
instead of the 20% foor originally proposed. The Committee intends to fnalise the
securitisation framework around year-end 2014.
Policy implementation
Implementation of the Basel III framework is a key priority of global regulatory
reform. To facilitate implementation, the Basel Committee adopted a Regulatory
Consistency Assessment Programme (RCAP). The RCAP (i) monitors the progress on
implementation and (ii) assesses the consistency and completeness of the adopted
standards. The RCAP also facilitates dialogue among Committee members and aids
the Committee in developing standards.
The assessments are carried out by jurisdiction and by theme. The thematic
focus, currently on risk-based capital, will expand from 2015 to cover Basel III
standards on liquidity, leverage and systemically important banks.
137 BIS 84th Annual Report
In October 2013, the Committee published updated procedures for conducting
jurisdictional assessments. The document will be updated as the scope of the RCAP
expands to include all aspects of the Basel III framework.
An important part of the jurisdictional assessments is to ensure that the
internationally active segment of the domestic banking system conforms to the
letter and spirit of the relevant Basel standards; the assessment does so by
highlighting the current and potential impact of that segment on the overall
regulatory environment. This helps reveal differences within and across jurisdictions
and allows member jurisdictions to initiate corrective measures, as appropriate, to
strengthen and improve the functioning of their regulatory regimes.
This year the RCAP conducted jurisdictional assessments for Switzerland
(published in June 2013), China (September), Brazil (December) and Australia
(March 2014). By end-2014, the RCAP will have completed assessments for all
countries that are home to G-SIBs. By end-2015, it will have completed or initiated
detailed peer reviews of the capital regulations of all 27 member jurisdictions of the
Basel Committee, which together account for more than 90% of global banking
assets.
Progress reports. In April and October 2013, the Committee issued reports providing
a high-level view of Committee members progress in adopting Basel II, Basel 2.5
and Basel III. The reports focus on the status of domestic rule-making processes to
ensure that the Committees capital standards are transformed into national law or
regulation according to the internationally agreed time frames. The Committee
believes that disclosure will provide an additional incentive for members to fully
comply with the international agreements.
Reports to the G20. In April 2013, the Committee gave updates to the G20 Finance
Ministers and Central Bank Governors on progress in adopting the Basel III
regulatory reforms. The report covered capital and other regulatory standards as
well as banks progress in bolstering their capital. It also highlighted specifc
shortcomings in implementation that will require continued policy and operational
attention.
In August 2013, the Committee reported to the G20 Leaders on implementation
of Basel III, the further harmonisation of capital regulations across member
jurisdictions and the fnalisation of the Basel frameworks remaining post-crisis
reforms. The report also included Committee fndings regarding bank calculations
of risk-weighted assets.
Basel III monitoring. Published twice a year, the Committees Basel III monitoring
report covers the implications of Basel III for fnancial markets. The results of the
monitoring exercise assume that the fnal Basel III package has been fully
implemented. Thus, they do not take account of the transitional arrangements set
out in the Basel III framework, such as the gradual phase-in of deductions from
regulatory capital. The latest report was released in March 2014. It shows that, as of
30 June 2013, the sampled banks average CET1 capital ratio under the Basel III
framework was 9.5% for Group 1 (representative of internationally active banks with
Tier 1 capital of more than 3 billion) and 9.1% for Group 2 (representative of all
other banks). The fully phased-in CET1 minimum requirement is 4.5%, and the CET1
target level is 7.0%. The report indicates that shortfalls in the risk-based capital of
large internationally active banks generally continue to shrink.
Liquidity coverage ratio. In January 2014, following a mid-2013 public consultation,
the Committee issued fnal requirements for banks LCR-related disclosures.
138 BIS 84th Annual Report
Internationally active banks in all Committee member jurisdictions will have to
publish their LCR according to a common template to help market participants
consistently assess banks liquidity risk position. National authorities will implement
these disclosure standards, and compliance will be required from the date of the
frst reporting period after 1 January 2015.
Risk data aggregation and risk reporting. In December 2013, the Committee
published a report that assessed the overall progress of G-SIBs in adopting the
Committees Principles for effective risk data aggregation and risk reporting. The
principles, issued in January 2013, are designed to help improve risk management,
decision-making and resolvability.
The assessment found that many banks are having diffculties with the initial
stage of implementation, which covers the governance, architecture and processes
for strong data aggregation. Of the 30 banks identifed as G-SIBs during 2011 and
2012, 10 reported that they will not be able to comply with the principles by the
1 January 2016 deadline for full implementation, the main reason being the
resources devoted to large multi-year computer and data-related projects.
The Committee will continue to monitor the status of G-SIBs as regards
meeting the deadline. In addition, the Committee urges national supervisors to
apply these principles to institutions identifed as domestic SIBs three years after
their designation as such. The Committee believes that the principles can be
applied to a wider range of banks in a way that is appropriate to their size, nature
and complexity.
Simplicity, comparability and risk sensitivity
Having substantially strengthened the banking systems regulatory framework, the
Committee has now turned to the matter of its complexity and the comparability of
capital adequacy ratios across banks and jurisdictions. The Committee considers it
essential to the ongoing effectiveness of the Basel capital standards to simplify
them where possible and to improve the comparability of their outcomes
(eg regulatory capital, risk-weighted assets and capital ratios).
In 2012, the Committee commissioned a small group of its members to review
the Basel capital framework, aware that, over time, the framework has steadily grown
and that more sophisticated risk measurement methodologies have been introduced.
The goal of the task force was to point to areas of undue complexity within the
framework and opportunities to improve the comparability of its outcomes.
In July 2013, the Committee released a discussion paper on the trade-offs
between the risk sensitivity of the Basel capital standards and their simplicity and
comparability. The goal of the paper was to seek views to help shape the
Committees thinking on this question.
Related developments in the analysis of comparability were the Committees
release of two studies on the risk-weighting of assets, the frst regarding credit risk
in the banking book, and the second regarding market risk in the trading book.
Banking book risk-weighting of assets for credit risk. In July 2013, the Committee
published its frst report on the consistency of weighting for credit risk in the
banking book. Part of the RCAP, the study draws on supervisory data from more
than 100 major banks plus data on sovereign, bank and corporate exposures
collected from 32 major international banks as part of a portfolio benchmarking
exercise.
Risk-weighted assets (RWA) for credit risk in the banking book vary considerably
across banks, mostly because the differences in the riskiness of assets across banks
139 BIS 84th Annual Report
are real. The study found, however, that a material portion of the variation is driven
by differences in bank and supervisory practices regarding the weighting process.
These differences could result in the reported capital ratios of identical portfolios
for some outlier banks varying by as much as 2 percentage points in either direction
from a 10% capital ratio benchmark potentially a 4 percentage point difference
although the capital ratios for most banks fall within a narrower range.
The report discusses policy options for minimising such excessive practice-
based variations. The Committee considers it critical to improve the comparability
of regulatory capital calculations by banks while maintaining good risk sensitivity.
Trading book risk-weighting of assets for market risk. The Committees December
2013 report on market risk in the trading book follows up on a January 2013 study,
which found that internal models produced a signifcant variation in market risk
weights and that modelling choices were a signifcant driver of the variation. The
December study extended that analysis to more representative and complex
trading positions. It confrmed the earlier fndings and in addition showed that the
variability in market risk weights typically increases for more complex trading
positions.
Policy recommendations in the December study support reforms identifed in
the earlier report, which are being addressed by the Committees ongoing reviews
of the trading book framework and Pillar 3 (market discipline) requirements for
disclosure. These reform areas are:
improving public disclosure and the collection of regulatory data to aid the
understanding of weighting for market risk;
narrowing the range of modelling choices for banks; and
further harmonising supervisory practices with regard to model approvals.
Improving the effectiveness of supervision
The global fnancial crisis underscored the crucial importance of supervision for
fnancial stability and for the effective functioning of the policy framework.
Sound capital planning. In January 2014, the Committee issued A sound capital
planning process: fundamental elements, which brings together recent supervisory
thinking on important lessons from the fnancial crisis concerning weak capital
planning.
During and after the crisis, certain jurisdictions conducted ad hoc stress tests to
assess capital adequacy at banks. Because of the pressing need to determine
whether banks were appropriately capitalised, those frst rounds of offcial stress
tests often did not include an assessment of the processes banks employ to project
potential capital needs and to manage capital sources and uses. More recently,
supervisors have begun to codify their expectations for what constitutes sound
processes for capital planning. Those processes help banks judge the appropriate
amount and composition of capital needed to support their business strategies
across a range of potential scenarios and outcomes.
Supervisory colleges. A consultative document published by the Committee in
January 2014, Revised good practice principles for supervisory colleges, updates the
original document, published in October 2010, which included a commitment to
take stock of any key lessons learned from their use. The January consultative
report follows a review of the challenges encountered in implementation and
possible areas of additional best practice. The review took into account the
perspectives of home and host supervisors and internationally active banks.
140 BIS 84th Annual Report
Money laundering and fnancing of terrorism. In January 2014, following a mid-
2013 consultative period, the Committee issued Sound management of risks
related to money laundering and fnancing of terrorism, a set of guidelines
describing how banks should include such risks within their overall risk
management framework. The guidelines are consistent with those in International
standards on combating money laundering and the fnancing of terrorism and
proliferation, issued by the Financial Action Task Force (FATF) in 2012, and
supplement their goals and objectives. The Committees guidelines include cross-
references to FATF standards to help banks comply with national requirements
based on those standards.
Market-based indicators of liquidity. Also in January 2014, the Committee
published information to assist supervisors in their evaluation of the liquidity
profle of assets held by banks. The document, Guidance for supervisors on
market-based indicators of liquidity, also helps promote greater consistency in the
classifcation of so-called high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) across jurisdictions in
the context of the Basel III LCR. The guidance does not change the defnition of
HQLA within the LCR; rather, it helps supervisors assess whether assets are suitably
liquid for LCR purposes.
Intraday liquidity management. In April 2013, the Committee issued the fnal
version of its Monitoring tools for intraday liquidity management. The seven
quantitative tools were developed in consultation with the CPSS to help banking
supervisors better monitor a banks management of intraday liquidity risk and its
ability to meet its payment and settlement obligations. They complement the
qualitative guidance in the Committees 2008 Principles for sound liquidity risk
management and supervision.
Introduced for monitoring purposes only, the tools will also help supervisors
gain a better understanding of banks payment and settlement behaviour.
Internationally active banks will be required to apply them; national supervisors will
determine the extent to which the tools apply to non-internationally active banks
within their jurisdictions. Monthly reporting of the monitoring tools will commence
from 1 January 2015 to coincide with the implementation of the LCR reporting
requirements.
External audits. The fnancial crisis revealed the need to improve the quality of
external audits of banks. Following a public consultation in 2013, the Committee
published External audits of banks in March 2014. Its 16 principles and
accompanying explanatory guidance describe supervisory expectations regarding
audit quality and how they relate to the external auditors work in a bank.
Joint Forum publications. During the past year, the Joint Forum
2
issued publications
on mortgage insurance, longevity risk and point of sale disclosures.
Mortgage insurance: market structure, underwriting cycle and policy implications
Published in August 2013 after a comment period, this report examines the
interaction of mortgage insurers with mortgage originators and underwriters. It
makes a series of recommendations for policymakers and supervisors that aim to
reduce the likelihood of mortgage insurance stress and failure in times of crisis.
2
The Joint Forum was established in 1996 under the aegis of the Basel Committee, IOSCO and the
IAIS to deal with issues common to the banking, securities and insurance sectors, including the
regulation of fnancial conglomerates. Its membership consists of senior supervisors from the three
sectors (www.bis.org/bcbs/jointforum.htm).
141 BIS 84th Annual Report
Longevity risk transfer market: market structure, growth drivers and impediments,
and potential risks
Longevity risk is the possibility of paying out on pensions and annuities for
longer than anticipated because of rising longevity. Published in December
2013 following a comment period, the guidance considers risk transfer markets
and makes recommendations for supervisors and policymakers.
Point of sale disclosure in the insurance, banking and securities sectors
Published for consultation in August 2013, the report assesses differences and
gaps in regulatory approaches to point of sale (POS) disclosure for investment
and savings products across the insurance, banking and securities sectors. The
report considers whether POS disclosures need to be further aligned across
sectors, and it includes recommendations to assist policymakers and
supervisors in addressing that question.
BCBS: www.bis.org/bcbs
Committee on the Global Financial System
The Committee on the Global Financial System (CGFS) monitors fnancial market
developments for the Governors of the BIS Global Economy Meeting and analyses
the implications of these developments for fnancial stability and central bank
policy. The CGFS is chaired by William C Dudley, President of the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York. Committee members are Deputy Governors and other senior
offcials from 23 central banks of major advanced and emerging market economies
and the Economic Adviser of the BIS.
Among the focal points of the Committees discussions during the past year
were the challenges posed by the eventual exit of major central banks from their
current accommodative policies and the resulting implications for fnancial markets.
Cross-market spillovers from exit, including reversals in capital fows, were a key
aspect of this topic. Committee members also examined risks posed by fnancial
imbalances that may have built up during the recent period of monetary
accommodation and the possibility of addressing them through macroprudential
policy. Also discussed were sovereign and banking sector risks in the euro area, the
budgetary stand-off in the United States, and the risks posed by macroeconomic
and fnancial developments in China and other key emerging market economies.
A number of in-depth analyses and longer-term projects have been
commissioned by the Committee from groups of central bank experts. Three of
these groups produced public reports during the year.
The rising demand for collateral assets. The frst report, issued in May 2013, explored
the increasing demand for collateral assets arising from regulatory reform and other
developments. It found that endogenous market adjustments are likely to prevent any
lasting system-wide scarcity of collateral assets. The report argued that policy
responses therefore need to focus primarily on those market adjustments and their
implications, rather than on supply-demand conditions for the assets. Later in the
year, key market responses, including collateral transformation and optimisation
activities, were investigated further in an informal workshop with industry participants.
Trade fnance. The second report, published in January, examined the interplay
between changes in trade fnance and international trade. It found that trade
fnance has historically posed little fnancial stability risk. It noted, however, that
when banks run down their trade fnance assets in response to strains, the trade
fnance market can transmit stress from the fnancial system to the real economy.
142 BIS 84th Annual Report
Therefore, policies that broadly address weaknesses in bank capital and liquidity
and encourage competition aspects of current regulatory efforts were found to
generally provide an effective means for avoiding or containing disruptions to
trade fnance fows.
Banking systems in emerging market economies (EMEs). In March, a report provided
indications that banking groups headquartered in EMEs are starting to play a
greater role in regional fnancial systems. That process, however, has not yet
reached a point where it would signifcantly change the risk profle of EME banking
systems. Yet over time there may be broader effects that warrant strengthening the
regulatory environment and market infrastructures and providing crisis prevention
and resolution measures.
CGFS: www.bis.org/cgfs
Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems
The Committee on Payment and Settlement Systems (CPSS) promotes the safety
and effciency of payment, clearing, settlement and reporting systems and
arrangements, thereby supporting fnancial stability and the wider economy.
Comprising senior offcials from 25 central banks, the CPSS is a recognised global
standard setter in its feld. It also serves as a forum for central banks to monitor and
analyse developments concerning payment, clearing and settlement within and
across jurisdictions and to cooperate in related policy and oversight matters. The
Committee Chair is Benot Cur, a member of the Executive Board of the
European Central Bank.
Monitoring implementation of standards for fnancial market infrastructures
The CPSS-IOSCO Principles for fnancial market infrastructures (PFMIs report),
published in April 2012, sets out international standards for systemically important
FMIs payment systems, central securities depositories, securities settlement systems,
central counterparties (CCPs) and trade repositories. The PFMIs report also specifes
fve responsibilities for the authorities that oversee or regulate the FMIs, including
effective cooperation between authorities where more than one is involved.
Monitoring the consistent, complete and timely implementation of the PFMIs
is a high priority for the CPSS and involves three phases: (i) Have the legislation and
related rules to enable implementation been adopted? (ii) Are the legislation and
related rules complete and consistent with the PFMIs? (iii) Has implementation of
the new standards produced consistent outcomes?
In August 2013, the CPSS and IOSCO published the results of the frst phase of
monitoring. The report showed that most jurisdictions had begun enactment of the
necessary laws and rules. Although few had completed the process for all types of
FMIs, the results represented substantial progress during the relatively brief period
since the PFMIs report was issued.
Continued monitoring and regular updates for the frst phase are planned until
all jurisdictions have completed the legal and regulatory framework. In February
2014, the CPSS and IOSCO also started the second phase of the monitoring process.
Recovery of fnancial market infrastructures
In August 2013, the CPSS and IOSCO released a consultative report, Recovery of
fnancial market infrastructures. The report gives guidance to fnancial market
143 BIS 84th Annual Report
infrastructures such as CCPs on developing plans to enable them to recover from
threats to their viability and fnancial strength that might prevent them from
continuing to provide critical services. It was produced in response to comments
received on an earlier CPSS-IOSCO report, Recovery and resolution of fnancial
market infrastructures, that requested more guidance on what recovery tools would
be appropriate for FMIs.
Authorities access to trade repository data
A report issued by the CPSS and IOSCO in August 2013 outlines the framework to
guide authorities regular and ad hoc access to data held in trade repositories. The
guidance expands on issues of access addressed in the January 2012 CPSS-IOSCO
publication on aggregation and reporting of data on OTC derivatives.
Non-banks in retail payments
The CPSS is studying the role of non-banks in retail payments. It is analysing the
factors that explain the growing importance of non-banks in this area, the possible
risks and the differing regulatory approaches of the various CPSS jurisdictions.
Payment aspects of fnancial inclusion
The CPSS, in cooperation with the World Bank, has recently started to explore the
links between payment systems and fnancial inclusion.
Cyber-security in FMIs
The CPSS has begun analysing cyber-security issues and their implications for FMIs
in view of the operational risk principle set out in the PFMIs report.
Red Book statistics
In December 2013, the CPSS published its annual update of Statistics on payment,
clearing and settlement systems in the CPSS countries.
CPSS: www.bis.org/cpss
Markets Committee
The Markets Committee is a forum for senior central bank offcials to jointly monitor
developments in fnancial markets and assess their implications for the operations
of central banks. The Committees membership comprises 21 central banks.
In June 2013, the BIS Global Economy Meeting appointed Guy Debelle,
Assistant Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia, as Chair of the Committee. He
succeeded Hiroshi Nakaso, Deputy Governor of the Bank of Japan, who had served
as Chair since June 2006.
The timing of the Federal Reserves decision to scale back its pace of asset
purchases and the Bank of Japans new monetary policy framework (quantitative
and qualitative easing) shaped the Committees discussion during the year. The
Committee monitored the impact of these developments in emerging market
economies especially closely.
Moreover, the Committee discussed the greater emphasis on forward policy
guidance in some advanced economies; money market developments in China; and
144 BIS 84th Annual Report
the emerging contours of the ECBs comprehensive assessment of credit institutions.
Uncertainties surrounding the debt limit and government shutdown in the United
States in late 2013 prompted a close dialogue among Committee members to
discuss potential market implications.
In addition to monitoring near-term market developments, the Committee also
devoted time to the potential longer-term market effects of new and evolving
fnancial regulations. The Committees deliberations included discussions on swap
execution facilities and European Commission proposals for a fnancial transaction
tax and the regulation of fnancial benchmarks. The Committee also discussed the
design of foreign exchange benchmarks.
Under the auspices of the Markets Committee, the BIS and 53 participating
central banks conducted the 2013 Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign
Exchange Market Activity. Trading in foreign exchange markets averaged
$5.3 trillion per day in April 2013, up from $4.0 trillion in April 2010. The Committee
reviewed the usefulness of the surveys expanded coverage of currency pairs and of
the refnements introduced in the survey categories for counterparty and execution
methods. To aid the design of future Triennial Surveys, the Committee organised a
January 2014 workshop with private sector participants regarding execution
methods for foreign exchange transactions.
Markets Committee: www.bis.org/markets
Central Bank Governance Group
The Central Bank Governance Group comprises nine central bank Governors and is
chaired by Zeti Akhtar Aziz, Governor of the Central Bank of Malaysia. It serves as a
venue for information exchange on the design and operation of central banks as
public policy institutions. The Group also suggests priorities for BIS work carried out
on these topics through the almost 50 central banks that make up the Central Bank
Governance Network. Central bank offcials have access to the results of numerous
surveys on governance topics conducted among Network central banks as well as
other governance research, and selected material is published.
The Governance Group convened during several BIS bimonthly meetings to
study the evolving circumstances of central banks. The Group discussed the post-
crisis organisational issues faced by central banks that have a major responsibility
for banking supervision, surveyed the organisation of fnancial risk management
within central banks, and discussed the challenges faced in communicating policy
actions and intentions in uncertain times. The information and insights provided
help central banks assess the effectiveness of their own arrangements as well as the
alternatives available.
Central Bank Governance Group: www.bis.org/cbgov
Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics
The Irving Fisher Committee on Central Bank Statistics (IFC) addresses statistical
topics related to monetary and fnancial stability. The IFC comprises more
than 80 central banks worldwide, including almost all BIS members, and is
currently chaired by Muhammad Ibrahim, Deputy Governor of the Central Bank
of Malaysia.
The Committee and various central banks co-sponsored workshops and
meetings on the following topics: balance of payments issues (Bank of France); the
integrated management of micro-databases (Bank of Portugal); and measuring
145 BIS 84th Annual Report
structural change in the fnancial system, especially regarding shadow banking
(Peoples Bank of China). It also organised six sessions at the 59th biennial World
Statistics Congress of the International Statistical Institute (ISI), held in Hong Kong
SAR. The IFCs sessions covered data methodologies and compilation exercises
related to fve sets of fnancial and economic variables: bank interest rates, real
effective exchange rates, infation measures, external debt and capital fows. At the
Congress, the IFC became an affliated member of the ISI.
The Committee has set up a task force to analyse data sharing between
central bank statistical departments and bank supervisors so as to support
research and policy analysis relating to fnancial stability. The group has made an
inventory of approaches taken in different countries, and it is identifying good
practices that will allow central banks and supervisors to benchmark their national
arrangements.
The IFCs 2013 annual report was endorsed by the BIS All Governors Meeting
in January and was published in February.
IFC: www.bis.org/ifc
Financial Stability Institute
The Financial Stability Institute (FSI) assists supervisory authorities worldwide in
their oversight of fnancial systems by fostering a solid understanding of prudential
standards and good supervisory practice.
The FSI helps supervisors to implement reforms developed by international
standard-setting bodies by explaining the concepts and detail of the reforms and
their implications for supervision. It carries out these tasks through a range of
channels, including high-level meetings, seminars and the internet. Its online
information resource and learning tool, FSI Connect, is used by fnancial sector
supervisors at all levels of experience and expertise.
The FSI annually surveys selected countries implementation of the Basel
framework and publishes the results on the BIS website. The 2013 survey results,
combined with work by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, show that
100 countries have implemented or are in the process of implementing Basel II, and
72 countries are implementing Basel III.
Meetings, seminars and conferences
The FSIs extensive programme of high-level meetings, seminars and conferences is
targeted at banking and insurance supervisors and central bank fnancial stability
experts. Over the past year, approximately 1,700 participants attended 41 banking
events and nine insurance seminars.
The annual high-level regional meetings for Deputy Governors of central banks
and heads of supervisory authorities, organised jointly with the BCBS, took place in
Africa, Asia, central and eastern Europe, Latin America and the Middle East. Topics
included fnancial stability, macroprudential tools and policies, regulatory priorities
and other key supervisory issues.
The FSI held banking seminars in Basel and collaborated with the following
supervisory groups for seminars elsewhere:
Africa Committee of Bank Supervisors of West and Central Africa (BSWCA);
Southern African Development Community (SADC)
Americas Association of Supervisors of Banks of the Americas (ASBA); Center
for Latin American Monetary Studies (CEMLA); Caribbean Group of Banking
Supervisors (CGBS)
146 BIS 84th Annual Report
Asia and the Pacifc Executives Meeting of East Asia-Pacifc Central Banks
(EMEAP) Working Group on Banking Supervision; South East Asian Central
Banks (SEACEN); Central Banks of South East Asia, New Zealand and Australia
(SEANZA) Forum of Banking Supervisors
Europe European Banking Authority (EBA); Group of Banking Supervisors
from Central and Eastern Europe (BSCEE)
Middle East Arab Monetary Fund (AMF); Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC)
Committee of Banking Supervisors
Other Group of French-Speaking Banking Supervisors (GSBF); Group of
International Finance Centre Supervisors (GIFCS)
In collaboration with the International Association of Insurance Supervisors
(IAIS) and the IAISs regional network, the FSI held insurance seminars in Switzerland
as well as in Africa, Asia, central and eastern Europe, Latin America and the Middle
East.
The seminars last year focused on the revised BCBS and IAIS core principles,
risk-based supervision, macroprudential policies and systemic risk assessment, and
Basel III capital and risk-based solvency.
FSI Connect
FSI Connect is used by more than 9,800 subscribers from 250 central banks and
banking and insurance supervisory authorities. It offers more than 230 tutorials
covering a wide range of regulatory policy and supervisory topics. Recently released
tutorials cover supervisory intensity and effectiveness, public awareness of deposit
insurance systems, macroprudential supervision, group-wide supervision and on-
site inspection processes for insurance supervisors, and pricing of life insurance
products.
FSI: www.bis.org/fsi
Activities of BIS-hosted associations in 2013/14
This section reviews the years principal activities of the three associations hosted
by the BIS in Basel.
Financial Stability Board
The Financial Stability Board (FSB) coordinates at the international level the fnancial
stability work of national authorities and international standard-setting bodies; and
it develops and promotes fnancial sector policies to enhance global fnancial
stability.
3
Its membership consists of fnance ministries, central banks,
4
and fnancial
supervisory and regulatory authorities in 24 countries and territories;
5
the European
3
The FSB is a notfor-proft association under Swiss law and is hosted by the BIS under a fve-year
renewable service agreement. The BIS provides fnancial and other resources for the FSB Secretariat,
which currently comprises 29 staff members.
4
Including a central bank group, the CGFS.
5
The country members of the G20 plus Hong Kong SAR, the Netherlands, Singapore, Spain and
Switzerland.
147 BIS 84th Annual Report
Central Bank (ECB) and the European Commission; and international fnancial
institutions and standard-setting bodies.
6
The FSB, chaired by Mark Carney,
7
operates through Plenary meetings of its
membership; the Plenary appoints the Chair of the FSB and a Steering Committee.
The FSB also has four Standing Committees:
Assessment of Vulnerabilities chaired by Agustn Carstens, Governor of the
Bank of Mexico;
Supervisory and Regulatory Cooperation chaired by Daniel Tarullo, member
of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System;
Standards Implementation chaired by Ravi Menon, Managing Director of the
Monetary Authority of Singapore; and
Budget and Resources chaired by Jens Weidmann, President of the Deutsche
Bundesbank.
To facilitate its interaction with a wider group of countries, the Plenary
has established six regional consultative groups (for the Americas, Asia, the
Commonwealth of Independent States, Europe, the Middle East and North Africa,
and sub-Saharan Africa). These groups bring FSB members together with institutions
from about 65 non-member jurisdictions to discuss vulnerabilities affecting regional
and global fnancial systems and the current and potential fnancial stability
initiatives of the FSB and member jurisdictions.
The Plenary has also established various working groups, which cover a number
of technical areas.
Plenary meetings were held in June and November 2013 and in March 2014.
As detailed below, the FSB was active in a wide range of areas during the year, and
several policy initiatives were endorsed at the September 2013 St Petersburg
Summit of the G20 Leaders.
Reducing the moral hazard posed by systemically important fnancial
institutions (SIFIs)
Endorsed by the G20 Leaders at their 2010 Seoul Summit, the FSBs framework to
address the systemic risks and moral hazard associated with SIFIs contains three key
elements:
a resolution framework to ensure that all fnancial institutions can be quickly
resolved without destabilising the fnancial system and exposing the taxpayer
to risk of loss;
higher loss absorbency for SIFIs to refect the greater risks they pose for the
global fnancial system; and
more intense supervisory oversight for SIFIs.
Resolution of SIFIs. In July, the FSB published Guidance on recovery triggers and
stress scenarios covering three key aspects of recovery and resolution planning:
(i) developing the scenarios and triggers that should be used in recovery plans for
global SIFIs (G-SIFIs); (ii) developing resolution strategies and associated operational
resolution plans tailored to different group structures; and (iii) identifying the
6
The international fnancial institutions are the BIS, IMF, OECD and World Bank; the international
standard-setting bodies are the BCBS, the International Accounting Standards Board (IASB), the
IAIS and IOSCO.
7
Was Governor of the Bank of Canada until 1 June 2013 and became Governor of the Bank of
England on 1 July 2013.
148 BIS 84th Annual Report
functions that should remain in operation during resolution to maintain systemic
stability.
In August, the FSB published three consultative papers regarding its October
2011 document Key attributes of effective resolution regimes for fnancial institutions
(hereafter in text and titles, Key attributes).
On 12 August, it released Application of the Key attributes to non-bank fnancial
institutions. When fnal, the guidance is intended to form additional annexes to the
Key attributes on the following topics:
the resolution of fnancial market infrastructures (FMIs) and of systemically
important FMI participants;
the resolution of insurers; and
client asset protection in resolution.
Also on 12 August, the FSB released Information sharing for resolution purposes,
which covers standards for confdentiality and statutory safeguards for information
sharing within cross-border crisis management groups and for institution-specifc
cross-border cooperation agreements.
On 28 August, the FSB published Assessment methodology for the Key attributes,
which proposes criteria for assessing jurisdictions compliance with the Key
attributes and offers guidance on related legislative reforms. The FSB developed the
draft methodology in conjunction with the IMF, World Bank and standard-setting
bodies.
Higher loss absorbency. In November 2013, the FSB released the annual update to
its list of global systemically important banks (G-SIBs) using end-2012 data; it was
based on a revised methodology that was published by the BCBS in July 2013. One
bank was added to the list, increasing the overall number from 28 to 29.
The list distributes the banks across the lower four of the fve levels of required
additional loss absorbency (additional common equity) for G-SIBs. The fve levels
range from 1% to 3.5% of risk-weighted assets, according to the level of systemic
risk posed by the bank. The highest level (3.5%) is currently kept empty as a
disincentive for G-SIBs to increase their systemic importance. Starting from 2016,
the additional loss absorbency will be phased in over three years, initially for those
banks in the November 2014 list.
8
In July 2013, the FSB published an initial list of nine global systemically
important insurers (G-SIIs), using the IAIS assessment methodology and end-2011
data. Starting from November 2014, the list of G-SIIs will be updated and published
annually by the FSB. In July 2014, in consultation with the IAIS and national
authorities, the FSB will determine the systemic status of, and appropriate risk
mitigating measures for, major reinsurers. The IAIS also published policy measures
for G-SIIs and an overall framework for macroprudential policy and surveillance in
insurance, which were endorsed by the FSB.
More intense supervisory oversight. In November 2013, the FSB published Principles
for an effective risk appetite framework and the consultation paper Guidance on
supervisory interaction with fnancial institutions on risk culture. These papers form
part of the FSBs initiative to increase the intensity and effectiveness of supervision,
which is a key component of the policy response to the problem of frms that are
too big to fail. Supervisory expectations for frms risk management functions and
overall risk governance frameworks are increasing, as these were areas that
exhibited signifcant weaknesses during the global fnancial crisis.
8
The current list is at www.fnancialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_121031ac.pdf.
149 BIS 84th Annual Report
In April 2014, the FSB will publish its fnal version of the guidance regarding
risk culture, which will incorporate the feedback from the public consultation and
report on efforts to enhance supervisory effectiveness.
Extending the framework. The FSB and standard-setting bodies continue to extend
the SIFI framework to additional types of fnancial institutions. In January 2014,
the FSB and IOSCO published for public consultation Assessment methodologies
for identifying non-bank non-insurer global systemically important fnancial
institutions (NBNI G-SIFIs). The document proposes methodologies for the
identifcation of NBNI G-SIFIs, but it does not identify specifc institutions, nor
does it propose any policy measures. Policies will be developed once the
methodologies are fnalised.
Improving the OTC derivatives markets. The G20 has made commitments to improve
the functioning, transparency and oversight of the OTC derivatives markets through
increased standardisation, central clearing, organised platform trading and
reporting of all trades to trade repositories (TRs). The FSB published progress
updates on the reforms in April and September 2013, and it continues to work with
member jurisdictions to complete the reforms, settle remaining cross-border issues
and ensure the consistency of implementation across jurisdictions.
The FSB has set up a study group to consider how the data reported to TRs can
be effectively used by authorities, in particular by aggregating the data. In February
2014, the FSB published a consultation paper that analyses the options for
aggregating TR data on OTC derivatives.
Strengthening the oversight and regulation of shadow banking
The shadow banking system credit intermediation involving entities and activities
outside the regulated banking system can be a source of systemic risk both
directly and through its interconnections with the regular banking system. Shadow
banking can also create opportunities for arbitrage that might undermine stricter
bank regulation and lead to a build-up of additional leverage and risks in the
fnancial system as a whole.
In August 2013, after a comment period, the FSB published revised policy
recommendations to strengthen the oversight and regulation of the shadow
banking system and mitigate its potential systemic risks. The recommendations
focus on fve areas:
spillovers between the regular banking system and the shadow banking system;
the susceptibility of money market funds (MMFs) to runs;
the incentives associated with securitisation;
the risks and procyclical incentives associated with securities fnancing
transactions that may exacerbate funding strains in times of market stress; and
systemic risks posed by other shadow banking entities and activities.
The recommendations are now largely fnalised with the exception of the
proposals for securities fnancing transactions, which will be further refned.
In November 2013, the FSB released its third annual monitoring report on
global trends and risks of the shadow banking system, including innovations and
changes that could lead to growing systemic risks and regulatory arbitrage. The
report includes data from 25 jurisdictions and the euro area as a whole, which
represent about 80% of global GDP and 90% of global fnancial system assets. For
the frst time, the report also incorporates estimates from a hedge fund survey by
IOSCO.
150 BIS 84th Annual Report
Credit ratings
In August 2013, the FSB released a progress report and an interim peer review
report on the work by standard setters and national authorities to accelerate their
implementation of the FSBs October 2010 guidance on reducing reliance on credit
rating agency ratings. The goal of the guidance is twofold: to eliminate mechanistic
market reliance on ratings, which is a cause of herding and cliff effects that can amplify
procyclicality and cause systemic disruption; and to create incentives for market
participants to improve their independent credit risk assessments and due diligence.
The second stage of the peer review will analyse planned actions to reduce
reliance on the ratings; and it will report on progress with alternative measures of
credit risk and the strengthening of banks internal credit risk assessment processes.
The FSB intends to issue the fnal peer review report in 2014.
Financial benchmarks
The G20 has tasked the FSB with promoting consistency in the various efforts to
improve the reliability and robustness of interbank benchmark interest rates. The
FSB has established a high-level Offcial Sector Steering Group (OSSG) of regulators
and central banks to coordinate reviews of existing interest rate benchmarks. The
OSSG will also guide a Market Participants Group, which will examine the feasibility
of adopting additional reference rates and potential transition issues. The OSSG will
report to the FSB by June 2014.
Addressing data gaps
The global fnancial crisis highlighted major gaps in information on globally active
fnancial institutions. The FSB is developing a common data template with which
G-SIBs can analyse their exposures and funding dependencies by counterparty, and
their concentration by country, market, currency, sector and instrument. The
international data hub that is collecting these data is hosted by the BIS and became
fully operational in the second quarter of 2013 with the assembly of harmonised
data on credit exposures of G-SIBS. In October 2013, the FSB and IMF published
their Fourth progress report on the implementation of the G-20 data gaps initiative,
which reported considerable progress.
Advancing transparency through the legal entity identifer (LEI)
The objective of the global LEI system is to provide unique identifcation of parties
to fnancial transactions across the globe. The G20 endorsed the June 2012 FSB
report A global legal entity identifer for fnancial markets, and an interim system
has been launched. A key building block of an improved fnancial data infrastructure,
the LEI will facilitate the achievement of many fnancial stability and risk
management objectives as well as reduce operational risk within frms.
The Regulatory Oversight Committee (ROC) was established in January 2013 as
a standalone body responsible for governance of the global LEI system and to
ensure that it serves the public interest. It has asked the FSB to act as the founder
of the Global LEI Foundation (GLEIF), and the FSB is undertaking a due diligence
review of the possibility. The GLEIF will be established as a not-for-proft foundation
under Swiss law to act as the operational arm of the LEI system. It will support the
worldwide application of uniform operational standards and protocols set by the
ROC and support the maintenance of a centralised database of identifers and
corresponding reference data.
151 BIS 84th Annual Report
Strengthening accounting standards
The G20 and FSB support the development of a single set of high-quality global
accounting standards. The FSB continues to encourage the IASB and the Financial
Accounting Standards Board to complete their convergence project, and it is
monitoring their progress in implementing specifc G20 and FSB accounting
recommendations. The two boards made further progress in 2013. Work in the key
areas of accounting for the impairment of loans and for insurance contracts is
scheduled to be completed in 2014.
Enhanced Disclosure Task Force (EDTF)
The EDTF is a private sector initiative to enhance the risk disclosure practices of
major banks. It issued principles and recommendations for such disclosures in
October 2012. In August 2013, it published a survey on the level and quality of
implementation as it appeared in the major banks 2012 annual reports. The FSB
has asked the EDTF to undertake another survey in 2014.
Monitoring implementation and strengthening adherence to international
standards
The FSBs Coordination Framework for Implementation Monitoring (CFIM)
mandates that implementation of reforms in priority areas (those deemed by the
FSB to be particularly important for global fnancial stability) should be subject to
more intensive monitoring and detailed reporting. Current priority areas are the
Basel II, Basel 2.5 and Basel III frameworks; the OTC derivatives market reforms;
compensation practices; policy measures for G-SIFIs; resolution frameworks; and
shadow banking. Detailed reporting of progress in implementation, conducted in
cooperation with relevant standard-setting bodies, has begun in several of these
areas, and the FSB will extend and deepen monitoring in 2014.
In August, the FSB published the second progress report on member
jurisdictions adoption of the FSBs principles for sound compensation practices,
issued in September 2009.
The FSBs most intensive monitoring mechanism is the peer review
programme. It is conducted through its Standing Committee on Standards
Implementation to evaluate member jurisdictions adoption of international
fnancial standards and FSB policies. In 2013, the FSB completed country peer
reviews of South Africa, the United Kingdom and the United States. Three other
peer reviews began in 2013 and will be completed in 2014: the thematic review of
reducing reliance on ratings issued by credit rating agencies and country reviews
of Indonesia and Germany.
In December 2013, the FSB published an update on its initiative to promote
jurisdictions adherence to standards for international supervisory and regulatory
cooperation and information exchange. This annual update provides information
on all jurisdictions evaluated under the initiative, including those identifed as non-
cooperative.
Impact of regulatory reforms on emerging market and developing
economies (EMDEs)
As requested by the G20, and in consultation with standard-setting bodies and
international fnancial institutions, the FSB reports on signifcant unintended
consequences of internationally agreed reforms and of measures taken to address
152 BIS 84th Annual Report
them. In September 2013, the FSB published an update of monitoring developments,
which draws in part on the fndings of a workshop organised in May 2013 on
experiences among EMDEs. It also draws on discussions in FSB regional consultative
groups and input from FSB members. The FSB will continue to report on the effects
of reforms on EMDEs as part of its overall implementation monitoring framework.
Financial regulatory factors affecting the availability of long-term fnance
In August 2013, the FSB updated the G20 Finance Ministers and Central Bank
Governors on fnancial regulatory factors affecting the supply of long-term investment
fnance. The FSBs monitoring of this issue will continue as part of a broader study of
long-term fnance being undertaken for the G20 by international organisations.
FSB: www.fnancialstabilityboard.org
International Association of Deposit Insurers
The International Association of Deposit Insurers (IADI) is the global standard-
setting body for deposit insurance systems. It contributes to the stability of fnancial
systems by enhancing the effectiveness of deposit insurance and, in active
partnership with other international organisations, by promoting international
cooperation on deposit insurance and bank resolution arrangements. IADI also
provides guidance on establishing and enhancing deposit insurance systems.
Jerzy Pruski, President of the Management Board of Polands Bank Guarantee
Fund, serves as the President of IADI and the Chair of its Executive Council.
The theme of IADIs 13th Annual General Meeting and Conference, held in
Buenos Aires, was Navigating through the fnancial reform landscape. Topics
included changes in the global fnancial landscape; the response of deposit
insurance and the banking sector to the fnancial crisis; fnancial safety net design;
deposit insurance funding arrangements and reforms in bank resolution regimes;
and contingency planning for bank failures.
IADI took action to advance the four strategic priorities it adopted in 2013, as
follows.
Enhance IADI standards and evaluations
To enhance its standards and the evaluations based on them, IADI established a
steering committee in February 2013 to propose a revision of its Core principles for
effective deposit insurance systems.
9
In January 2014, IADI provided the committees
revisions for discussion by a Joint Working Group consisting of the BCBS, FSB, IMF,
World Bank, European Commission and European Forum of Deposit Insurers. In
June, the IADI Executive Council will consider the fnal version, which will later be
presented to the FSB as an update to the FSBs key standards.
Conduct research and develop guidance on insurance and resolution
As a member of the FSBs Resolution Steering Group, IADI is contributing to the
design of an international standard for the resolution of failed fnancial institutions.
9
IADIs core principles are part of the FSBs key standards for sound fnancial systems and are used
in the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP) conducted by the IMF and World Bank. IADI
experts participate in FSAP evaluations and in IMF and World Bank technical assistance
programmes.
153 BIS 84th Annual Report
A key issue for deposit insurers and resolution regimes is the use of bail-in for a
bank resolution. IADI initiated a research project to identify strategies and guidance
for the application of bail-in for deposit insurance systems.
IADI continued to advance its research on ex ante funding for deposit insurance
funds and multiple deposit insurance systems within one jurisdiction. It also
published guidance on mitigating moral hazard through early detection and timely
intervention; and it issued a research paper on fnancial inclusion.
IADI is enhancing its database of global deposit insurance systems through
updates from research surveys, including its own annual survey of deposit insurers.
IADI posted on its public website a selection of results from its third annual survey;
full results are available to IADI members, the FSB and the BIS.
More than 200 participants attended IADIs Second Bi-Annual Research
Conference, which presented current research related to the conference theme,
Evolution of the deposit insurance framework: design features and resolution
regimes.
Strengthen deposit insurance systems
IADI introduced a Self-Assessment Technical Assistance Program (SATAP). Under the
SATAP, IADI experts assist deposit insurer members in evaluating their insurance
systems and, as needed, in developing a reform programme.
In August 2013, IADI and the FSI held their third annual joint seminar on bank
resolution and deposit insurance. Since 2008, IADI has collaborated with the FSI to
produce eight online tutorials on deposit insurance systems.
IADI hosted global and regional seminars on various topics including
reimbursement of deposit insurance, Islamic deposit insurance issues, integrated
protection schemes and contingency planning for effective resolutions.
Expand membership and strengthen its support
This year, nine deposit insurers joined IADI, bringing its coverage of all explicit
deposit insurance systems to 65% and the total number of organisations affliated
with IADI to 96. To address IADIs growth and strengthen its support of the
membership, the Executive Council approved the establishment of a Research Unit
in the Secretariat to enhance IADIs participation in research on current policy
issues.
IADI: www.iadi.org
International Association of Insurance Supervisors
The International Association of Insurance Supervisors (IAIS) is the global standard-
setting body for the insurance sector. Its purpose is to promote effective and
globally consistent supervision and contribute to global fnancial stability so that
policyholders may beneft from fair, safe and stable insurance markets.
Peter Braumller, a director in Austrias Financial Market Authority, chairs the IAIS
Executive Committee.
Financial stability
In July 2013, the IAIS released its assessment methodology and policy measures
for G-SIIs, which were endorsed by the FSB. It also released a framework for
implementing macroprudential policy and surveillance (MPS) in the insurance
154 BIS 84th Annual Report
sector. The focus of the MPS framework is on enhancing the supervisory capacity
to identify, assess and mitigate macro-fnancial vulnerabilities that could lead to
severe and widespread fnancial risk. The MPS framework is being refned by
developing guidance on related IAIS insurance core principles and by developing
a toolkit and data template of early warning risk measures for stress testing.
Insurance core principles
At its October general meeting, the IAIS revised Insurance Core Principle (ICP) 22,
which covers anti-money laundering and combating the fnancing of terrorism, and
adopted an applications paper on the same subject. This revision is an update to
the October 2011 Insurance core principles, standards, guidance and assessment
methodology. In October, the IAIS also adopted issues papers on policyholder
protection schemes and the supervision of cross-border operations through
branches.
ComFrame
In October, the IAIS issued the fnal consultation draft of the Common Framework
for the Supervision of Internationally Active Insurance Groups (ComFrame), which
builds on the IAIS insurance core principles. In 2014, after any modifcations arising
from the comment period, feld testing of ComFrame will begin so that it can be
further modifed as necessary before formal adoption in 2018. Members are to
begin implementation of ComFrame in 2019.
Global insurance capital standard
In October, the IAIS announced its plan to develop the frst-ever risk-based global
insurance capital standard (ICS), which will be a part of ComFrame. Full
implementation of the ICS will thus begin in 2019 after two years of testing and
refnement with supervisors and internationally active insurance groups.
The IAIS also began developing basic capital requirements (BCRs), which
are scheduled to be fnalised and ready for implementation by G-SIIs in late
2014. BCRs will undergird the higher loss absorbency requirements for GSIIs,
and their development and testing is expected to also support development of
the ICS.
Multilateral Memorandum of Understanding
Insurance supervisors that are signatories to the IAIS Multilateral Memorandum of
Understanding (MMoU) participate in a global framework for cooperation and
information exchange. The memorandum sets minimum standards to which
signatories must adhere, and all applicants are subject to review and approval by
an independent team of IAIS members. By participating in the MMoU, supervisors
are better able to promote the fnancial stability of cross-border insurance
operations for the beneft of consumers. The MMoU currently has 39 signatories
representing more than 54% of worldwide premium volume.
Coordinated Implementation Framework
The Coordinated Implementation Framework (CIF), adopted in October 2013, sets
forth key principles and strategies to guide the IAISs extensive work in monitoring
its members implementation of IAIS supervisory material. The CIF establishes a
155 BIS 84th Annual Report
programme of working with associations of supervisors around the world on
regional implementation.
Central to the CIF is leveraging the work of partners. One of these partners,
the Access to Insurance Initiative (A2ii), advances capacity building in inclusive
insurance markets. Such markets are a critical area of attention for standard-setting
bodies under the G20s Global Partnership for Financial Inclusion.
Self-assessment and peer reviews
In October, the IAIS released an aggregate report containing the fndings from two
self-assessment and peer reviews (SAPRs) conducted on ICP 1 (Objectives, Powers
and Responsibilities of the Supervisor), ICP 2 (Supervisor) and ICP 23 (Group-Wide
Supervision). The IAIS is committed to reviewing all ICPs through the SAPR process
by the end of 2016. The outcome of these assessments will help identify areas
in which the ICPs may need to be revised, which was the case with the SAPR for
ICP 23; the results will also feed into IAIS education activities.
Joint Forum publications
The Joint Forum, which the IAIS co-established in 1996, issued publications during
the past year on mortgage insurance, longevity risk and point of sale disclosures
(more details are given above, at the end of the section on the Basel Committee on
Banking Supervision).
IAIS: www.iaisweb.org
Economic analysis, research and statistics
The BIS provides in-depth economic analysis and research on policy issues
regarding macroeconomic, monetary and fnancial stability. These activities are
carried out by the Monetary and Economic Department (MED) at the head offce in
Basel and at the BIS Representative Offces in Hong Kong SAR and Mexico City. The
BIS also compiles and disseminates international statistics on fnancial institutions
and markets.
Analysis and research in the Basel Process
BIS economists produce analytical background documents and research papers on
issues of importance to central banks and fnancial supervisory authorities. In
particular, such work is prepared for the regular meetings of Governors and other
senior central bank offcials. MED also provides analytical and statistical support to
the BIS-hosted committees and associations.
BIS researchers collaborate with central bank and academic economists and
participate in research conferences and networks. Such engagements foster
international cooperation in policy research and analysis, stimulate the exchange of
ideas and enhance the quality of the Banks work.
The BIS itself organises conferences and workshops designed to bring
together participants from the worlds of policy, research and business. Of
these gatherings, the fagship event for central bank Governors is the BIS
Annual Conference. In June 2013, the 12th BIS Annual Conference Navigating
the Great Recession: what role for monetary policy? focused on the nature
of the Great Recession and its aftermath. Papers considered the appropriate
156 BIS 84th Annual Report
policy mix, the risk of overburdening monetary policy, the relevance of global
spillovers and the advancement of monetary policy cooperation in this evolving
environment.
Most BIS analysis and research is published through the principal outlets on
the Banks website (www.bis.org) the Annual Report, the BIS Quarterly Review, BIS
Papers and BIS Working Papers. BIS economists also publish in professional journals
and other external publications.
BIS research: www.bis.org/forum/research.htm
Research topics
Refecting the Banks mission, the focus of BIS research is on monetary and fnancial
stability. In recent years, the principal themes of the work have been the challenges
posed by the global fnancial crisis and its longer-term policy implications. During
the past year, BIS research devoted special attention to three areas: fnancial
intermediation; new frameworks for monetary and fnancial stability policies; and
the global economy and spillovers.
The research on fnancial intermediation focused on conditions in emerging
market economies, the measurement of banks systemic importance and
adjustments surrounding higher capital requirements. Analyses covered specifc
fnancial market segments (long-term fnance, longevity risk transfer markets,
collateral asset markets), instruments (non-deliverable forwards, contingent
convertible bonds) and practices (liquidity stress testing, portfolio allocation). More
general issues included the link between the fnancial system and growth, and the
interplay between the fnancial health of the sovereign and that of the banking sector.
The research on new policy frameworks consisted of two lines of inquiry. The
frst explored various aspects of monetary policy and the macroeconomy, including
collateral frameworks and practices; forward guidance policies; and the use of
specifc instruments such as committed liquidity facilities. It also considered foreign
exchange intervention, interest rate pass-through processes, the sustainability and
implications of extraordinarily low interest rates, and the link between the
macroeconomy and the fnancial cycle (eg the usefulness of credit as an early
indicator of crisis). The second line of enquiry addressed prudential policy, including
the identifcation of systemically important institutions and the impact of structural
regulation, which aims at distinguishing types of banking activity. Research also
examined the macroeconomic impact of reforms in the regulation of OTC derivatives.
The third area of research, the global economy and spillovers, explored the
nexus between the international monetary and fnancial system and the
performance of the global economy. Among the issues studied were global
imbalances; the concept, measurement and policy implications of global liquidity;
and monetary policy spillovers.
International statistical initiatives
The BISs unique international fnancial statistics facilitated detailed studies on
transnational banking activity. Studies also focused on developments revealed by
the 2013 BIS Triennial Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives
Market Activity.
The BIS is pursuing further enhancements to its international banking statistics.
Together with central banks, it is improving the collection and dissemination of
data on cross-border claims and liabilities of internationally active banks, a
multistage process endorsed by the CGFS. In the current phase, central banks have
157 BIS 84th Annual Report
started reporting a more detailed sectoral breakdown in both the locational and
consolidated banking statistics; the latter are being extended to cover the liability
positions of banks, including capital.
The BIS International Data Hub completed its frst year of operations. It
accomplished phase 1 of its goal, which was to assemble micro data covering global
systemically important banks. This work has helped to strengthen the supervisory
dialogue by providing authorities with a more complete picture of balance sheet
interlinkages in derivatives markets. The Data Hub has been coordinating with the
FSB Data Gaps Implementation Group in preparing for phase 2, which is the
collection of additional data.
On its website, the BIS has begun releasing its Data Bank statistics regarding
global liquidity indicators.
10
This initiative forms part of the BISs support for G20
activities and extends earlier work by the BIS and CGFS.
The BIS also participates in the Inter-Agency Group on Economic and Financial
Statistics (IAG), which follows up on the FSB and IMF recommendations to the G20
to close data gaps revealed by the fnancial crisis.
11
BIS statistics: www.bis.org/statistics
Cooperation with other central bank initiatives
The BIS contributes to the activities of central banks and regional central bank
organisations. During the past year, it cooperated with the following groups on the
following topics:
CEMLA (Center for Latin American Monetary Studies) foreign exchange
intervention, payment and settlement systems;
FLAR (Latin American Reserve Fund) reserves management;
MEFMI (Macroeconomic and Financial Management Institute of Eastern and
Southern Africa) payment and settlement systems, reserves management;
SEACEN (South East Asian Central Banks) Research and Training Centre
central bank governance, fnancial stability, macroeconomic and monetary
policy challenges, payment and settlement systems; and
World Bank governance and oversight of central bank reserves management.
BIS experts also contributed to events organised by the International Banking
and Finance Institute of the Bank of France.
Representative Offces
The BIS has a Representative Offce for Asia and the Pacifc (the Asian Offce),
located in Hong Kong SAR; and a Representative Offce for the Americas (the
Americas Offce), located in Mexico City. The Representative Offces promote
10
The Data Bank contains key economic indicators reported by almost all BIS member central banks,
additional detailed macroeconomic series from major advanced and emerging market economies
and data collected by BIS-hosted groups. The BIS is making a substantial effort to facilitate use of
the Data Bank for calculating and disseminating long series of important economic variables, such
as credit.
11
The IAG comprises the BIS, the ECB, Eurostat, the IMF, the OECD, the United Nations and the World
Bank (www.principalglobalindicators.org). These organisations also sponsor the Statistical Data and
Metadata Exchange (SDMX), whose standards the BIS uses for its collection, processing and
dissemination of statistics (www.sdmx.org).
158 BIS 84th Annual Report
cooperation and the BIS mission within each region by organising meetings,
supporting regional institutions and Basel-based committees, conducting policy
research and fostering the exchange of information and data. The Asian Offce also
provides banking services to the regions monetary authorities.
12
The Asian Offce
The Asian Offce undertakes economic research, organises high-level regional
meetings and, through its Regional Treasury, offers specialised banking services and
explores new investment outlets in regional fnancial markets. The economists of
the Asian Offce focus their research on the regions policy issues. The Asian Offces
activities are guided by the Asian Consultative Council (ACC), comprising the
Governors of the 12 BIS member central banks in the Asia-Pacifc region.
13
Governor
Amando Tetangco, of the Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas, succeeded Governor
Choongsoo Kim, of the Bank of Korea, as Chair of the Council in April 2014.
The Asian Consultative Council
At its June 2013 semiannual meeting, in Basel, the ACC endorsed a secondment
programme in Hong Kong as a mechanism for research collaboration among
member central banks in the region. At its February 2014 meeting, in Sydney, the
Council endorsed a two-year research programme on Expanding the boundaries
of monetary policy.
Research
Economists in the Asian Offce produced research on the two themes previously
endorsed by the ACC. On the fnancial stability side, the theme was cross-border
fnancial linkages in Asia and the Pacifc; outlines for proposed papers and specifc
policy issues were discussed at a July research workshop in Hong Kong. On the
monetary policy side, the theme was infation dynamics and globalisation; in
September, a conference in Beijing co-hosted with the Peoples Bank of China
showcased the results of that research.
In carrying out their research, Asian Offce economists collaborated with
academics from around the world and economists at BIS member central banks in
the region. The resulting papers have informed policy discussions in various central
bank meetings and have appeared in the BIS Quarterly Review and refereed
journals.
The Special Governors Meeting and other high-level meetings
The Asian Offce organised 10 high-level BIS policy meetings. Most were held jointly
with a central bank or with either EMEAP or SEACEN.
The ACC Governors meet with others from around the world in the annual
Special Governors Meeting. Normally held in Asia in February, it was combined this
year with the BIS bimonthly meeting, held in Sydney in February with the Reserve
Bank of Australia as host. For the fourth consecutive year, the event included a
12
For more information on the BISs banking activities, please refer to Financial services of the Bank,
page 160.
13
The 12 central banks are those of Australia, China, Hong Kong SAR, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea,
Malaysia, New Zealand, the Philippines, Singapore and Thailand.
159 BIS 84th Annual Report
roundtable with the chief executive offcers of large fnancial institutions active in
the region. The discussions covered current vulnerabilities in Asia, the role of asset
managers and the fnancing of infrastructure projects.
Other high-level events were the 16th meeting of the Working Party on
Monetary Policy in Asia, co-hosted by the Bank of Korea, in Seoul in May; the BIS-
SEACEN Exco Seminar, co-hosted by the Bank of Mongolia, in Ulaanbaatar in
September; the Ninth Meeting on Monetary Policy Operating Procedures, in Hong
Kong in November; and the Workshop on the Financing of Infrastructure
Investment, in Hong Kong in January.
The Americas Offce
The activities of the Americas Offce are guided by the Consultative Council for the
Americas (CCA). The CCA comprises the Governors of the eight BIS member central
banks in the Americas and is chaired by Jos Daro Uribe, Governor of the Bank of
the Republic, Colombia.
14
The Americas Offce has implemented a number of initiatives in the past year
to support regional central bank consultations and research. A newly established
Consultative Group of Directors of Operations (CGDO) brings together central bank
offcials who are typically responsible for open market and foreign exchange market
operations and foreign reserve management. The group held regular teleconferences,
and the Americas Offce co-hosted with the Bank of Mexico the groups frst
meeting, in March 2014. Meeting topics included the implications of changes in
global monetary conditions, policy responses and fnancial market structures.
In December 2013, the directors of fnancial stability from CCA central banks
held their frst meeting, hosted by the Central Bank of Brazil in Rio de Janeiro.
Among the issues discussed were responsibilities, instruments, governance and risk
assessment (including stress testing). The Americas Offce has supported efforts to
further strengthen the consultation process of this group.
The fourth annual CCA research conference was hosted by the Central Bank of
Chile in Santiago in April 2013. The theme of the conference was Financial stability,
macroprudential policy and exchange rates, and paper selection was organised
into each of those three topics.
A project of the CCA central bank research network introduces fnancial
stability considerations into central bank policy models. In October 2013, the
project held its frst conference in the newly opened facilities of the Americas
Offce. A policy exercise is focusing the projects models on the implications of a
credit boom. Some CCA central banks in the research network are also undertaking
a joint research project that will allow for cross-country comparison of the effects
of monetary or macroprudential policies.
The Americas Offce contributed to other meetings and outreach activities as
follows: (i) providing background material for the 17th BIS Working Party for
Monetary Policy in Latin America, hosted by the Central Bank of Chile in Santiago
in September 2013; (ii) organising and chairing a BIS-CEMLA roundtable on foreign
exchange market intervention, hosted by the Central Bank of Costa Rica in San Jos
in July 2013; (iii) providing economists for presentations at FSB regional consultative
group meetings and at central bank research conferences; and (iv) organising a
high-level central bank panel at the November 2013 annual meeting of the Latin
America and Caribbean Economics Association in Mexico City.
14
The eight central banks are those of Argentina, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru and
the United States.
160 BIS 84th Annual Report
Financial services of the Bank
The BIS, through its Banking Department, offers a wide range of fnancial services
designed to assist central banks and other offcial monetary authorities in the
management of their foreign exchange reserves and to foster international
cooperation in this area. Some 140 such institutions, as well as a number of
international organisations, make active use of these services.
Safety and liquidity are the key features of BIS credit intermediation, which is
supported by a rigorous framework of internal risk management. Independent
control units reporting directly to the BIS Deputy General Manager monitor and
control the related risks. A compliance and operational risk unit monitors
operational risk; a risk control unit controls the Banks fnancial risks ie credit,
liquidity and market risks and is also responsible for the coordination required for
an integrated approach to risk management.
BIS fnancial services are provided from two linked trading rooms: one in Basel,
at the Banks head offce; and one in Hong Kong SAR, at its Representative Offce
for Asia and the Pacifc.
Scope of services
As an institution owned and governed by central banks, the BIS possesses a
distinctive understanding of the needs of reserve managers their primary
requirement of safety and liquidity as well as their evolving need to diversify part of
their foreign exchange reserves. To meet those needs, the BIS offers investments
that vary by currency denomination, maturity and liquidity. The Bank offers tradable
instruments in maturities ranging from one week to fve years Fixed-Rate
Investments at the BIS (FIXBIS), Medium-Term Instruments (MTIs) and products with
embedded optionality (Callable MTIs); these instruments can be bought or sold
throughout the Banks dealing hours.
Also available are money market placements, such as sight/notice accounts
and fxed-term deposits, in most convertible currencies; in addition, the Bank
provides short-term liquidity facilities and extends credit to central banks, usually
on a collateralised basis. Moreover, the Bank acts as trustee and collateral agent in
connection with international fnancial operations.
The Bank transacts foreign exchange and gold on behalf of its customers,
thereby providing access to a large liquidity base in the context of, for example,
regular rebalancing of reserve portfolios or major changes in reserve currency
allocations. The foreign exchange services of the Bank encompass spot transactions
in major currencies and Special Drawing Rights (SDR) as well as swaps, outright
forwards, options and dual currency deposits (DCDs). In addition, the Bank provides
gold services such as buying and selling, sight accounts, fxed-term deposits,
earmarked accounts, upgrading and refning and location exchanges.
The BIS also provides asset management products and services. The products,
which predominantly consist of sovereign securities and other high-grade fxed
income instruments in major reserve currencies, are available in two forms:
(i) dedicated portfolio mandates tailored to each customers preferences; and
(ii) open-end fund structures that allow customers to invest in a common pool of
assets, ie BIS Investment Pools (BISIPs).
The BISIP structure is used for the Asian Bond Fund (ABF) initiative, sponsored
by EMEAP (Executives Meeting of East Asia-Pacifc Central Banks) to foster the
development of local currency bond markets. Further initiatives developed in
cooperation with a group of advising central banks have also been based on the
BISIP structure. These include the BISIP ILF1 (US infation-protected government
161 BIS 84th Annual Report
securities fund) and the BISIP CNY (domestic Chinese sovereign fxed income
fund).
The BIS Banking Department hosts global and regional meetings, seminars and
workshops on reserve management issues. These gatherings facilitate the exchange
of knowledge and experience among reserve managers and promote the
development of investment and risk management capabilities in central banks and
international organisations. The Banking Department also supports central banks in
reviewing their current reserve management practices.
Financial operations in 2013/14
The Banks balance sheet increased by SDR 10.6 billion, following a decrease of
SDR 43.7 billion in the previous year. The balance sheet total at 31 March 2014 was
SDR 222.5 billion (see graph).
Liabilities
Customer placements, about 94% of which are denominated in currencies and
the remainder in gold, constitute the largest share of total liabilities. On
31 March 2014, customer placements (excluding repurchase agreements) amounted
to SDR 191.8 billion, compared with SDR 183.7 billion at the end of 2012/13.
Currency deposits increased from SDR 166.2 billion a year ago to
SDR 180.5 billion at end-March 2014. That balance represents 2.1% of the worlds
total foreign exchange reserves which totalled nearly SDR 7.9 trillion at end-
March 2014, up from SDR 7.7 trillion at end-March 2013.
15
The share of currency
placements denominated in US dollars was 73%, while euro- and sterling-
denominated funds accounted for 13% and 6%, respectively.
Gold deposits amounted to SDR 11.3 billion at end-March 2014, a decrease of
SDR 6.3 billion for the fnancial year.
15
Excluded from the ratio calculation are funds placed by institutions for which data on foreign
exchange reserves are not available.
Balance sheet total and customer placements by product
End-quarter figures, in billions of SDR
0
75
150
225
300
2011 2012 2013 2014
Balance sheet total FIXBIS
MTIs
Gold deposits
Other instruments
The sum of the bars indicates total customer placements.
162 BIS 84th Annual Report
Assets
As in the previous fnancial year, most of the assets held by the BIS consisted of
government and quasi-government securities plus investments (including reverse
repurchase agreements) with commercial banks of international standing. In
addition, the Bank held 111 tonnes of fne gold in its investment portfolio at
31 March 2014. The Banks credit exposure is managed in a conservative manner,
with most of it rated no lower than A.
The Banks holdings of currency assets totalled SDR 184.4 billion at
31 March 2014, compared with SDR 157.1 billion at the end of the previous fnancial
year. The Bank uses various derivative instruments to manage its assets and
liabilities effciently.
16
Governance and management of the BIS
The governance and management of the Bank are conducted at three principal
levels:
the General Meeting of BIS member central banks;
the BIS Board of Directors; and
BIS Management.
The General Meeting of BIS member central banks
Sixty central banks and monetary authorities are currently members of the BIS and
have rights of voting and representation at General Meetings. The Annual General
Meeting (AGM) is held no later than four months after 31 March, the end of the BIS
fnancial year. The AGM approves the annual report and the accounts of the Bank
and decides on the distribution of a dividend, makes adjustments in the allowances
paid to Board members and elects the Banks auditor.
16
Further information on the Banks assets and liabilities can be found in the notes to the fnancial
statements and the risk management section.
163 BIS 84th Annual Report
BIS member central banks
Bank of Algeria
Central Bank of Argentina
Reserve Bank of Australia
Central Bank of the Republic of Austria
National Bank of Belgium
Central Bank of Bosnia and Herzegovina
Central Bank of Brazil
Bulgarian National Bank
Bank of Canada
Central Bank of Chile
Peoples Bank of China
Bank of the Republic (Colombia)
Croatian National Bank
Czech National Bank
National Bank of Denmark
Bank of Estonia
European Central Bank
Bank of Finland
Bank of France
Deutsche Bundesbank (Germany)
Bank of Greece
Hong Kong Monetary Authority
Magyar Nemzeti Bank (Hungary)
Central Bank of Iceland
Reserve Bank of India
Bank Indonesia
Central Bank of Ireland
Bank of Israel
Bank of Italy
Bank of Japan
Bank of Korea
Bank of Latvia
Bank of Lithuania
Central Bank of Luxembourg
National Bank of the Republic of Macedonia
Central Bank of Malaysia
Bank of Mexico
Netherlands Bank
Reserve Bank of New Zealand
Central Bank of Norway
Central Reserve Bank of Peru
Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (Philippines)
National Bank of Poland
Bank of Portugal
National Bank of Romania
Central Bank of the Russian Federation
Saudi Arabian Monetary Agency
National Bank of Serbia
Monetary Authority of Singapore
National Bank of Slovakia
Bank of Slovenia
South African Reserve Bank
Bank of Spain
Sveriges Riksbank (Sweden)
Swiss National Bank
Bank of Thailand
Central Bank of the Republic of Turkey
Central Bank of the United Arab Emirates
Bank of England
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(United States)
164 BIS 84th Annual Report
The BIS Board of Directors
The Board is responsible for determining the strategic and policy direction of the
BIS, supervising Management and fulflling the specifc tasks given to it by the
Banks Statutes. The Board meets at least six times a year.
The Board may have up to 21 members, including six ex offcio Directors,
comprising the central bank Governors of Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, the
United Kingdom and the United States. Each ex offcio member may appoint
another member of the same nationality. Nine Governors of other member central
banks may be elected to the Board.
In addition, one member of the Economic Consultative Committee serves as
observer to BIS Board meetings on a rotating basis. The observer participates in the
Boards discussions and may be a member of one or more of the Boards four
advisory committees, described below.
The Board elects a Chairman from among its members for a three-year term
and may elect a Vice-Chairman.
Four advisory committees, established pursuant to Article 43 of the Banks
Statutes, assist the Board in its work:
The Administrative Committee reviews key areas of the Banks administration,
such as budget and expenditures, human resources policies and information
technology. The Committee meets at least four times a year. Its Chairman is
Jens Weidmann.
The Audit Committee meets with internal and external auditors, as well as with
the compliance unit. Among its duties is the examination of matters related to
the Banks internal control systems and fnancial reporting. The Committee
meets at least four times a year and is chaired by Luc Coene.
The Banking and Risk Management Committee reviews and assesses the Banks
fnancial objectives, the business model for BIS banking operations and the risk
management frameworks of the BIS. The Committee meets at least once a year.
Its Chairman is Stefan Ingves.
The Nomination Committee deals with the appointment of members of the BIS
Executive Committee and meets on an ad hoc basis. It is chaired by the Boards
Chairman, Christian Noyer.
Board of Directors
17
Chairman: Christian Noyer, Paris
Mark Carney, London
Agustn Carstens, Mexico City
Luc Coene, Brussels
Jon Cunliffe, London
Andreas Dombret, Frankfurt am Main
Mario Draghi, Frankfurt am Main
William C Dudley, New York
Stefan Ingves, Stockholm
Thomas Jordan, Zurich
Klaas Knot, Amsterdam
Haruhiko Kuroda, Tokyo
Anne Le Lorier, Paris
17
As at 1 June 2014. The list includes the observer mentioned above.
165 BIS 84th Annual Report
Stephen S Poloz, Ottawa
Raghuram G Rajan, Mumbai
Jan Smets, Brussels
Alexandre A Tombini, Braslia
Ignazio Visco, Rome
Jens Weidmann, Frankfurt am Main
Janet L Yellen, Washington
Zhou Xiaochuan, Beijing
Alternates
Stanley Fischer, Washington
Paul Fisher, London
Jean Hilgers, Brussels
Joachim Nagel, Frankfurt am Main
Fabio Panetta, Rome
Marc-Olivier Strauss-Kahn, Paris
In memoriam
The Bank was saddened to learn of the death of Lord Kingsdown on 24 November
2013 at the age of 86. A former Governor of the Bank of England, Lord Kingsdown
was a member of the BIS Board of Directors from 1983 to 2003 and was its Vice-
Chairman from 1996 to 2003. He made important contributions to the BIS, in
particular overseeing the creation of the Boards Audit Committee and serving as
that Committees frst Chairman.
BIS Management
BIS Management is under the overall direction of the General Manager, who is
responsible to the Board of Directors for the conduct of the Bank. The General
Manager is advised by the Executive Committee of the BIS, which consists of seven
members: the General Manager as Chair; the Deputy General Manager; the Heads
of the three BIS departments the General Secretariat, the Banking Department
and the Monetary and Economic Department; the Economic Adviser and Head of
Research; and the General Counsel. Other senior offcials are the Deputy Heads of
the departments and the Chairman of the Financial Stability Institute.
General Manager Jaime Caruana
Deputy General Manager Herv Hannoun
Secretary General and Head of General Peter Dittus
Secretariat
Head of Banking Department Peter Zllner
Head of Monetary and Economic Department Claudio Borio
Economic Adviser and Head of Research Hyun Song Shin
General Counsel Diego Devos
166 BIS 84th Annual Report
Deputy Head of Monetary and Economic Philip Turner
Department
Deputy Secretary General Monica Ellis
Deputy Head of Banking Department Jean-Franois Rigaudy
Chairman, Financial Stability Institute Josef Toovsk
BIS budget policy
Management begins preparing the BIS annual expenditure budget by establishing a
broad business plan and fnancial framework. Within that context, business areas
specify their plans and corresponding resource requirements. The process of reconciling
detailed business plans, objectives and overall resources culminates in a draft budget,
which must be approved by the Board before the start of the fnancial year.
The budget distinguishes between administrative and capital expenditures. In
2013/14, these expenditures collectively amounted to CHF 306.5 million. The Banks
overall administrative expense amounted to CHF 277.4 million.
18
As with organisations
similar to the BIS, spending for Management and staff including remuneration,
pensions, and health and accident insurance amounts to around 70% of
administrative expenditure. New staff positions were added during the year in
accordance with the Banks business plan, which emphasised the Basel regulatory
process, BIS fnancial statistics, and BIS banking activities and internal controls.
The other major categories of administrative spending are information
technology (IT), buildings and equipment, and general operational costs, each
accounting for about 10%.
Capital spending, relating mainly to buildings and IT investment, can vary
signifcantly from year to year depending on projects in progress. For 2013/14,
capital expenditure amounted to CHF 29.1 million, including a special item of
CHF 13.6 million for the purchase of the offce building at Centralbahnstrasse 21,
near the BIS head offce.
BIS remuneration policy
At the end of the 2013/14 fnancial year, the BIS employed 656 staff members
from 57 countries. The jobs performed by BIS staff members are assessed on
the basis of a number of objective criteria including qualifcations, experience
and responsibilities and classifed into distinct job grades. The job grades are
associated with a structure of salary ranges, and the salaries of individual staff
members move within the ranges of the salary structure on the basis of
performance.
Every three years, a comprehensive survey benchmarks BIS salaries (in Swiss
francs) against compensation in comparable institutions and market segments, with
adjustments to take place as of 1 July in the following year. In benchmarking, the
18
The fnancial statements report a total administrative expense of CHF 360.9 million. That fgure
consists of the CHF 277.4 million actual administrative expense reported here plus CHF 83.5 million
of fnancial accounting adjustments for post-employment beneft obligations. This additional
expense is not included in the budget for the coming fnancial year because it depends on actuarial
valuations as at 31 March, which in turn are not fnalised until April, after the budget has been set
by the Board.
167 BIS 84th Annual Report
Bank focuses on the upper half of market compensation in order to attract highly
qualifed staff. The analysis takes into account differences in the taxation of
compensation at the surveyed institutions.
In years between comprehensive salary surveys, the salary structure is adjusted
as of 1 July on the basis of the rate of infation in Switzerland and the weighted
average real wage development in industrial countries. As of 1 July 2013, this
adjustment produced a decrease of 0.95% in the salary structure.
The salaries of senior offcials are also regularly benchmarked against
compensation in comparable institutions and market segments. As of 1 July 2013,
the annual remuneration of senior offcials, before expatriation allowances, is based
on the salary structure of CHF 766,220 for the General Manager;
19
CHF 648,340 for
the Deputy General Manager; and CHF 589,400 for Heads of Department.
BIS staff members have access to a contributory health insurance plan and a
contributory defned beneft pension plan. At the Banks headquarters, non-Swiss
staff members recruited from abroad, including senior offcials, are entitled to an
expatriation allowance. The allowance currently amounts to 14% of annual salary
for unmarried staff members and 18% for married staff members, subject to a
ceiling. Expatriate staff members are also entitled to receive an education allowance
for their children, subject to certain conditions.
The Annual General Meeting approves the remuneration of members of the
Board of Directors, with adjustments taking place at regular intervals. The total
fxed annual remuneration paid to the Board of Directors was CHF 1,114,344 as
of 1 April 2014. In addition, Board members receive an attendance fee for each
Board meeting in which they participate. Assuming the full Board is represented
in all Board meetings, the annual total of these attendance fees amounts to
CHF 1,061,280.
Net proft and its distribution
The net proft for 2013/14 was SDR 419.3 million (2012/13: SDR 895.4 million). The
proft represented a return of 2.4% on average equity (2012/13: 4.9%).
Financial results
The BISs fnancial results for 2013/14 were shaped by greater stability in most
fnancial markets compared with recent years as well as continuing low interest
rates. This environment resulted in lower returns on the Banks investment assets
and a compression of intermediation margins, which led to a decline in proftability.
The total comprehensive income of the BIS includes unrealised valuation
movements on available for sale assets (the BISs own gold and investment
securities) and re-measurements of the actuarial liabilities for post-employment
beneft arrangements. As the market price of gold fell (22% on the year), the
valuation of the Banks own gold declined. At the same time, there was a revaluation
loss on own funds investment securities. These effects were partly offset by a
gain on the re-measurement of defned beneft obligations. The resulting
total comprehensive income for 2013/14 was SDR 570.4 million (2012/13:
SDR +718.2 million). The total return on equity was 3.2% (2012/13: +3.9%),
primarily because of the fall in the price of gold.
19
In addition to the basic salary, the General Manager receives an annual representation allowance and
enhanced pension rights.
168 BIS 84th Annual Report
Taking into account the 2012/13 dividend of SDR 175.8 million, which was paid
during 2013/14, the Banks equity decreased by SDR 746.2 million during the year
ended 31 March 2014.
Proposed dividend
It is proposed for the fnancial year 2013/14 to declare a dividend of SDR 215 per
share, which is consistent with BIS dividend policy and with the reduction in proft
in the context of the global fnancial environment.
At 31 March 2014, there were 559,125 issued shares; these include the
1,000 shares of the Albanian issue, which are suspended, held in treasury and
receive no dividend. The dividend is therefore to be paid on 558,125 shares. The
total cost of the proposed dividend would be SDR 120.0 million, after which
SDR 299.3 million would be available for allocation to reserves. The dividend would
be paid on 3 July 2014 in one of the component currencies of the SDR (US dollar,
euro, yen or sterling) or in Swiss francs according to the instructions of each
shareholder named in the BIS share register at 31 March 2014.
Proposed allocation of net proft for 2013/14
On the basis of Article 51 of the BIS Statutes, the Board of Directors recommends
that the General Meeting allocate the 2013/14 net proft of SDR 419.3 million in the
following manner:
(a) SDR 120.0 million to be paid as a normal dividend of SDR 215 per share;
(b) SDR 15.0 million to be transferred to the general reserve fund;
20
and
(c) SDR 284.3 million, representing the remainder of the available proft, to be
transferred to the free reserve fund.
Independent auditor
Election of the auditor
In accordance with Article 46 of the BIS Statutes, the Annual General Meeting is
invited to elect an independent auditor for the ensuing year and to fx the auditors
remuneration. This election is based on a formal proposal by the BIS Board, which
in turn is based on the recommendation of the Audit Committee. This annual
process ensures a regular assessment of the knowledge, competence and
independence of the auditor and of the effectiveness of the audit. The 2013 Annual
General Meeting elected Ernst & Young as the BIS auditor for the fnancial
year ended 31 March 2014. The Board policy is to rotate the auditor on a regular
basis, with the new auditor chosen following a selection process involving BIS
Management and the Audit Committee. The fnancial year ended 31 March 2014
was the second year of Ernst & Youngs term as auditor.
Report of the auditor
In accordance with Article 50 of the BIS Statutes, the independent auditor has full
powers to examine all books and accounts of the BIS and to require full information
20
At 31 March 2014, the general reserve fund exceeded fve times the Banks paid-up capital. As
such, under Article 51 of the Statutes, 5% of net proft, after accounting for the proposed dividend,
should be allocated to the general reserve fund.
169 BIS 84th Annual Report
as to all its transactions. The BIS fnancial statements have been duly audited by
Ernst & Young, who have confrmed that they give a true and fair view of the BISs
fnancial position at 31 March 2014 and the results of its operations for the year
then ended. The Ernst & Young report is to be found immediately following the
fnancial statements.
171 BIS 84th Annual Report
Financial statements
as at 31 March 2014
The financial statements on pages 173244 for the financial year ended
31 March 2014 were approved on 12 May 2014 for presentation to the Annual
General Meeting on 29 June 2014. They are presented in a form approved by
the Board of Directors pursuant to Article 49 of the Banks Statutes and are
subject to approval by the shareholders at the Annual General Meeting.
Jaime Caruana Herv Hannoun
General Manager Deputy General Manager
173 BIS 84th Annual Report
Balance sheet
As at 31 March
SDR millions
Notes 2014 2013
restated
2012
restated
Assets
Cash and sight accounts with banks 4 11,211.5 6,884.1 4,077.8
Gold and gold loans 5 20,596.4 35,367.1 35,912.7
Treasury bills 6 44,530.8 46,694.1 53,492.3
Securities purchased under resale agreements 6 50,554.4 28,469.5 46,210.8
Loans and advances 7 19,600.3 19,676.8 22,757.1
Government and other securities 6 70,041.1 62,643.3 77,877.7
Derivative fnancial instruments 8 3,002.2 5,855.7 7,303.9
Accounts receivable 9 2,777.4 6,171.2 7,845.5
Land, buildings and equipment 10 196.2 190.6 193.0
Total assets 222,510.3 211,952.4 255,670.8
Liabilities
Currency deposits 11 180,472.2 166,160.3 195,778.5
Gold deposits 12 11,297.5 17,580.9 19,624.0
Securities sold under repurchase agreements 13 1,169.3
Derivative fnancial instruments 8 2,632.9 3,402.3 4,727.0
Accounts payable 14 8,411.5 5,335.3 16,745.5
Other liabilities 15 799.0 999.5 871.5
Total liabilities 204,782.4 193,478.3 237,746.5
Shareholders equity
Share capital 16 698.9 698.9 698.9
Statutory reserves 17 14,280.4 13,560.8 12,989.4
Proft and loss account 419.3 895.4 739.8
Less: shares held in treasury 18 (1.7) (1.7) (1.7)
Other equity accounts 19 2,331.0 3,320.7 3,497.9
Total equity 17,727.9 18,474.1 17,924.3
Total liabilities and equity 222,510.3 211,952.4 255,670.8
Prior-year figures have been restated due to a change in accounting policy see note 3.
174 BIS 84th Annual Report
Profit and loss account
For the fnancial year ended 31 March
SDR millions
Notes 2014 2013
restated
Interest income 21 1,599.8 2,154.0
Interest expense 22 (830.3) (1,122.5)
Net interest income 769.5 1,031.5
Net valuation movement 23 (179.6) (17.1)
Net interest and valuation income 589.9 1,014.4
Net fee and commission income 24 5.0 3.1
Net foreign exchange gain / (loss) 25 (33.3) 26.7
Total operating income 561.6 1,044.2
Operating expense 26 (273.9) (260.8)
Operating proft 287.7 783.4
Net gain on sales of securities available for sale 27 40.5 82.7
Net gain on sales of gold investment assets 28 91.1 29.3
Net proft for the fnancial year 419.3 895.4
Basic and diluted earnings per share (in SDR per share) 29 751.3 1,604.3
Prior-year figures have been restated due to a change in accounting policy see note 3.
175 BIS 84th Annual Report
Statement of comprehensive income
For the fnancial year ended 31 March
SDR millions
Notes 2014 2013
restated
Net proft for the fnancial year 419.3 895.4
Other comprehensive income
Items either reclassifed to proft and loss during the
year, or that will be reclassifed subsequently when
specifc conditions are met
Net valuation movement on securities available for sale 19A (229.9) (55.5)
Net valuation movement on gold investment assets 19B (942.9) (67.8)
Items that will not be reclassifed subsequently to
proft and loss
Re-measurement of defned beneft obligations 19C 183.1 (53.9)
Total comprehensive income for the fnancial year (570.4) 718.2
Prior-year figures have been restated due to a change in accounting policy see note 3.
176 BIS 84th Annual Report
Statement of cash flows
For the fnancial year ended 31 March
SDR millions
Notes 2014 2013
restated
Cash fow from / (used in) operating activities
Interest and similar income received 2,183.3 2,923.9
Interest and similar expenses paid (668.0) (911.9)
Net fee and commission income 24 5.0 3.1
Net foreign exchange transaction gain 25 1.6 14.3
Operating expenses 26 (258.6) (243.9)
Non-cash fow items included in operating proft
Valuation movements on operating assets and
liabilities 23 (179.6) (17.1)
Net foreign exchange translation gain / (loss) 25 (34.9) 12.4
Change in accruals and amortisation (745.8) (980.5)
Change in operating assets and liabilities
Currency deposit liabilities held at fair value through
proft and loss 10,617.5 (14,079.8)
Currency banking assets (21,947.9) 30,314.5
Sight and notice deposit account liabilities 6,014.4 (12,021.8)
Gold deposit liabilities (6,283.4) (2,043.1)
Gold and gold loan banking assets 13,807.7 472.2
Accounts receivable 1.2 0.3
Other liabilities / accounts payable 216.9 89.6
Net derivative fnancial instruments 2,084.1 123.5
Net cash fow from operating activities 4,813.5 3,655.7
Cash fow from / (used in) investment activities
Net change in currency investment
assets available for sale 6B (1,682.4) (489.6)
Net change in currency investment
assets held at fair value through proft and loss 677.5 (56.8)
Securities sold under repurchase agreements 595.9
Net change in gold investment assets 5B 111.3 34.8
Net purchase of land, buildings and equipment 10 (21.1) (14.5)
Net cash fow used in investment activities (318.8) (526.1)
177 BIS 84th Annual Report
SDR millions
Notes 2014 2013
restated
Cash fow from / (used in) fnancing activities
Dividends paid (175.8) (168.4)
Net cash fow used in fnancing activities (175.8) (168.4)
Total net cash fow 4,318.9 2,961.2
Net effect of exchange rate changes on cash and
cash equivalents 282.3 (66.5)
Net movement in cash and cash equivalents 4,036.6 3,027.7
Net change in cash and cash equivalents 4,318.9 2,961.2
Cash and cash equivalents, beginning of year 30 7,225.6 4,264.4
Cash and cash equivalents, end of year 30 11,544.5 7,225.6
Prior-year figures have been restated due to a change in accounting policy see note 3.
178 BIS 84th Annual Report
Movements in the Banks equity
For the fnancial year ended 31 March
Other equity accounts
SDR millions
Notes Share
capital
Statutory
reserves
Proft
and loss
Shares
held in
treasury
Defned
beneft
obligations
Gold and
securities
revaluation
Total
equity
Equity at 31 March 2012 698.9 13,057.2 758.9 (1.7) 3,866.0 18,379.3
Change in accounting policy
for post-employment beneft
obligations 3 (67.8) (19.1) (368.1) (455.0)
Equity at 31 March 2012
restated 698.9 12,989.4 739.8 (1.7) (368.1) 3,866.0 17,924.3
Payment of 2011/12 dividend (168.4) (168.4)
Allocation of 2011/12 proft
restated 571.4 (571.4)
Total comprehensive income
2012/13 restated 19 895.4 (53.9) (123.3) 718.2
Equity at 31 March 2013
restated 698.9 13,560.8 895.4 (1.7) (422.0) 3,742.7 18,474.1
Payment of 2012/13 dividend (175.8) (175.8)
Allocation of 2012/13 proft
restated 719.6 (719.6)
Total comprehensive income 19 419.3 183.1 (1,172.8) (570.4)
Equity at 31 March 2014 698.9 14,280.4 419.3 (1.7) (238.9) 2,569.9 17,727.9
Prior-year figures have been restated due to a change in accounting policy see note 3.
179 BIS 84th Annual Report
The accounting policies set out below have been applied to
both of the financial years presented unless otherwise stated.
1. Scope of the financial statements
These financial statements recognise all assets and liabilities that
are controlled by the Bank and in respect of which the economic
benefits, as well as the rights and obligations, lie with the Bank.
To provide services to central bank customers, the Bank operates
investment entities that do not have a separate legal personality
from the BIS. Transactions are undertaken for these entities in
the Banks name, but for which the economic benefit lies with
central bank customers and not with the Bank. The assets and
liabilities of these entities are not recognised in these financial
statements. The Bank does not prepare consolidated financial
statements. Note 33 provides information on off-balance sheet
assets and liabilities.
The Bank operates a staff pension fund that does not have
a separate legal personality from the BIS. Transactions are
undertaken in the Banks name, but for the economic benefit of
the fund. The funds assets and liabilities are included in these
financial statements on a net basis in accordance with the
accounting policy for post-employment benefit obligations.
Note 20 provides information on the Banks staff pension fund.
2. Functional and presentation currency
The functional and presentation currency of the Bank is the
Special Drawing Right (SDR) as defined by the International
Monetary Fund (IMF).
The SDR is calculated from a basket of major trading currencies
according to Rule O1 as adopted by the Executive Board of
the IMF on 30 December 2010 and effective 1 January 2011. As
currently calculated, one SDR is equivalent to the sum of
USD 0.660, EUR 0.423, JPY 12.1 and GBP 0.111. The composition
of the SDR currency basket is subject to review every five
years by the IMF; the next review is due to be undertaken in
December 2015.
All figures in these financial statements are presented in SDR
millions unless otherwise stated.
3. Currency translation
Monetary assets and liabilities are translated into SDR at the
exchange rates ruling at the balance sheet date. Other assets
and liabilities are recorded in SDR at the exchange rates ruling
at the date of the transaction. Profits and losses are translated
into SDR at an average rate. Exchange differences arising from
the retranslation of monetary assets and liabilities and from the
settlement of transactions are included as net foreign exchange
gains or losses in the profit and loss account.
4. Designation of financial instruments
Upon initial recognition the Bank allocates each financial
instrument to one of the following categories:
Buildings 50 years
central banks whose Governor is a member of the Board of Directors and institutions that are connected with these central banks.
A listing of the members of the Board of Directors and senior officials is shown in the sections of the Annual Report entitled Board of
Directors and BIS Management. Note 20 provides details of the Banks post-employment benefit arrangements.
A. Related party individuals
The total compensation of the Board of Directors and senior officials recognised in the profit and loss account amounted to:
For the financial year ended 31 March
CHF millions 2014 2013
Salaries, allowances and medical cover 7.7 7.8
Post-employment benefits 2.0 2.1
Total compensation 9.7 9.9
SDR equivalent 6.9 6.9
Note 26 provides details of the total compensation of the Board of Directors.
The Bank offers personal deposit accounts for all staff members and its Directors. The accounts bear interest at a rate determined by the
Bank based on the rate offered by the Swiss National Bank on staff accounts. The movements and total balance on personal deposit
accounts relating to members of the Board of Directors and the senior officials of the Bank were as follows:
For the financial year ended 31 March
CHF millions 2014 2013
Balance at beginning of year 27.2 24.1
Deposits taken including interest income (net of withholding tax) 5.5 4.2
Withdrawals (14.4) (1.1)
Balance at end of year 18.3 27.2
SDR equivalent 13.4 19.1
Interest expense on deposits in CHF millions 0.3 0.4
SDR equivalent 0.2 0.3
Balances related to individuals who are appointed as members of the Board of Directors or as senior officials of the Bank during the financial
year are included in the table above along with other deposits taken. Balances related to individuals who cease to be members of the Board
of Directors or senior officials of the Bank during the financial year are included in the table above along with other withdrawals.
In addition, the Bank operates a blocked personal deposit account for certain staff members who were previously members of the Banks
savings fund, which closed on 1 April 2003. The terms of these blocked accounts are such that staff members cannot make further deposits
or withdrawals and the balances are paid out when they leave the Bank. The accounts bear interest at a rate determined by the Bank based
on the rate offered by the Swiss National Bank on staff accounts plus 1%. The total balance of blocked accounts at 31 March 2014 was
SDR 17.0 million (2013: SDR 18.6 million). They are reported under the balance sheet heading Currency deposits.
216 BIS 84th Annual Report
B. Related party central banks and connected institutions
The BIS provides banking services to its customers, which are predominantly central banks, monetary authorities and international financial
institutions. In fulfilling this role, the Bank in the normal course of business enters into transactions with related party central banks and
connected institutions. These transactions include making advances, and taking currency and gold deposits. It is the Banks policy to enter
into transactions with related party central banks and connected institutions on similar terms and conditions to transactions with other,
non-related party customers.
Currency deposits from related party central banks and connected institutions
For the financial year ended 31 March
SDR millions 2014 2013
Balance at beginning of year 36,727.9 49,428.8
Deposits taken 146,205.7 118,064.6
Maturities, repayments and fair value movements (123,938.5) (126,159.1)
Net movement on notice accounts 6,421.9 (4,606.4)
Balance at end of year 65,417.0 36,727.9
Percentage of total currency deposits at end of year 36.2% 22.1%
Gold deposit liabilities from related central banks and connected institutions
For the financial year ended 31 March
SDR millions 2014 2013
Balance at beginning of year 10,849.7 13,767.1
Net movement on gold sight accounts (3,662.7) (2,917.4)
Balance at end of year 7,187.0 10,849.7
Percentage of total gold deposits at end of year 63.6% 61.7%
217 BIS 84th Annual Report
Securities purchased under resale transactions with related party central banks and connected institutions
For the financial year ended 31 March
SDR millions 2014 2013
Balance at beginning of year 3,994.3 5,760.6
Collateralised deposits placed 1,038,178.0 1,378,767.4
Maturities and fair value movements (1,040,814.6) (1,380,533.7)
Balance at end of year 1,357.7 3,994.3
Percentage of total securities purchased under resale agreements at end of year 2.7% 14.0%
Derivative transactions with related party central banks and connected institutions
The BIS enters into derivative transactions with related party central banks and connected institutions, including foreign exchange deals
and interest rate swaps; the total nominal value of these transactions during the year ended 31 March 2014 was SDR 18,430.1 million
(2013: SDR 18,843.4 million).
Other balances and transactions with related party central banks and connected institutions
The Bank maintains sight accounts in currencies with related party central banks and connected institutions, the total balance of which was
SDR 11,202.1 million as at 31 March 2014 (2013: SDR 6,858.1 million). Gold held with related party central banks and connected institutions
totalled SDR 20,292.9 million as at 31 March 2014 (2013: SDR 35,074.5 million).
During the year ended 31 March 2014 the Bank acquired SDR 361.2 million of securities issued by related party central banks and connected
institutions (2013: SDR 22.4 million). A total of SDR 171.2 million of such securities matured or were sold during the financial year
(2013: SDR 1,109.0 million). At 31 March 2014 the Bank held SDR 271.2 million of related party securities (2013: SDR 81.2 million).
During the financial year, the Bank purchased third-party securities from central banks and connected institutions amounting to
SDR 1,688.6 million, all of which were subsequently disposed of before the end of the year (2013: SDR 7,061.0 million).
The Bank provides committed standby facilities for customers and as at 31 March 2014 the Bank had outstanding commitments to extend
credit under facilities to related parties of SDR 271.1 million (2013: SDR 285.7 million).
39. Contingent liabilities
In the opinion of the Banks Management there were no significant contingent liabilities at 31 March 2014.
218 BIS 84th Annual Report
Capital adequacy
1. Capital adequacy frameworks
As an international financial institution that is overseen by a Board composed of Governors of major central banks and that, by nature, has
no national supervisor, the Bank is committed to maintaining its superior credit quality and financial strength, in particular in situations of
financial stress. To that end, the Bank continuously assesses its capital adequacy based on an annual capital planning process that focuses
on two elements: an economic capital framework and a financial leverage framework.
The Bank discloses risk-related information on its exposure to credit, market, operational and liquidity risk based on its own assessment of
capital adequacy.
To facilitate comparability, the Bank has implemented a framework that is consistent with the revised International Convergence of Capital
Measurement and Capital Standards (Basel II Framework) issued by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision in June 2006. Following
that framework, the Bank discloses a Tier 1 capital ratio (Pillar 1), risk-weighted assets and more detailed related information. The Bank
maintains a capital position substantially in excess of the regulatory minimum requirement in order to ensure its superior credit quality.
2. Economic capital
The Banks economic capital methodology relates its risk-taking capacity to the amount of economic capital needed to absorb potential
losses arising from its exposures. The risk-taking capacity is defined as allocatable economic capital that is derived following a prudent
assessment of the components of the Banks equity, which are set out in the table below:
As at 31 March
SDR millions
2014 2013
restated
Share capital 698.9 698.9
Statutory reserves per balance sheet 14,280.4 13,560.8
Less: shares held in treasury (1.7) (1.7)
Share capital and reserves 14,977.6 14,258.0
Securities revaluation account 132.4 362.3
Gold revaluation account 2,437.5 3,380.4
Re-measurement of defined benefit obligations (238.9) (422.0)
Other equity accounts 2,331.0 3,320.7
Profit and loss account 419.3 895.4
Total equity 17,727.9 18,474.1
Allocatable economic capital is determined following a prudent evaluation of the Banks equity components for their loss absorption
capacity and sustainability. The components of capital with long-term risk-bearing capacity are the Banks Tier 1 capital and the sustainable
portion of the securities and gold revaluation reserves (sustainable supplementary capital). Only this allocatable capital is available for
allocation to the various categories of risk. The portion of revaluation reserves that is considered more transitory in nature is assigned to
the capital filter together with the profit accrued during the financial year.
219 BIS 84th Annual Report
As at 31 March
SDR millions
2014 2013
restated
Share capital and reserves 14,977.6 14,258.0
Re-measurement of defined benefit obligations (238.9) (422.0)
Tier 1 capital 14,738.7 13,836.0
Sustainable supplementary capital 1,661.3 2,164.0
Allocatable capital 16,400.0 16,000.0
Capital filter 1,327.9 2,474.1
Total equity 17,727.9 18,474.1
As part of the annual capital planning process, Management allocates economic capital to risk categories within the amount of allocatable
capital. As a first step, capital is assigned to an economic capital cushion that provides an additional margin of safety and is sufficient to
sustain a potential material loss without the need to reduce the capital allocation to individual risk categories or to liquidate any holdings
of assets. The level of the economic capital cushion is determined based on stress tests that explore extreme but still plausible default events.
Allocations are then made to each category of financial risk (ie credit, market and other risks) as well as operational risk. Other risks are
risks that have been identified but that are not taken into account in the economic capital utilisation calculations, and include model risk
and residual basis risk. The Banks economic capital framework measures economic capital to a 99.995% confidence level assuming a one-
year horizon, except for settlement risk (included in the utilisation for credit risk) and other risks. The amount of economic capital set aside
for settlement risk and other risks is based on an assessment by Management.
The following table summarises the Banks economic capital allocation and utilisation for credit risk, market risk, operational risk and
other risks:
As at 31 March
2014
2013
SDR millions Allocation Utilisation Allocation Utilisation
Insolvency and transfer risk 8,200.0 7,474.1 7,800.0 5,983.6
FX settlement risk 300.0 300.0 300.0 300.0
Credit risk 8,500.0 7,774.1 8,100.0 6,283.6
Market risk 4,100.0 2,178.4 4,600.0 2,308.6
Operational risk 1,200.0 1,200.0 700.0 700.0
Other risks 300.0 300.0 300.0 300.0
Economic capital cushion 2,300.0 2,300.0 2,300.0 2,300.0
Total economic capital 16,400.0 13,752.5 16,000.0 11,892.2
The Banks economic capital framework is subject to regular review and calibration. The increase of economic capital utilisation for credit
risk and operational risk since 31 March 2013 is partly due to a review of the respective methodologies and parameterisations during the
reporting period. The relatively low level of utilisation of economic capital for market risk is largely attributable to the exceptionally low
volatility of the main market risk factors during the period under review.
220 BIS 84th Annual Report
3. Financial leverage
The Bank complements its capital adequacy assessment with a prudently managed financial leverage. The Bank monitors its financial
leverage using a leverage ratio that compares the Banks Tier 1 capital with its total balance sheet assets. As such, derivatives transactions,
repurchase agreements and reverse repurchase agreements are included in the leverage ratio calculation on a gross basis in accordance
with the Banks accounting policies.
The table below shows the calculation of the Banks financial leverage ratio:
As at 31 March
SDR millions
2014 2013
restated
Tier 1 capital (A) 14,738.7 13,836.0
Total balance sheet assets (B) 222,510.3 211,952.4
Financial leverage ratio (A) / (B) 6.6% 6.5%
The following table summarises the development of the financial leverage ratio over the last two financial years:
For the financial year 2014 2013
restated
Average High Low At 31 March Average High Low At 31 March
Financial leverage ratio 6.8% 7.5% 6.0% 6.6% 6.3% 6.9% 5.3% 6.5%
221 BIS 84th Annual Report
4. Risk-weighted assets and minimum capital requirements under the Basel II Framework
The Basel II Framework includes several approaches for calculating risk-weighted assets and the corresponding minimum capital requirements.
In principle, the minimum capital requirements are determined by taking 8% of the risk-weighted assets.
The following table summarises the relevant exposure types and approaches as well as the risk-weighted assets and related minimum capital
requirements for credit risk, market risk and operational risk:
As at 31 March
2014 2013
SDR millions
Approach used Amount of
exposure
Risk-
weighted
assets
(A)
Minimum
capital
requirement
(B)
Amount of
exposure
Risk-
weighted
assets
(A)
Minimum
capital
requirement
(B)
Credit risk
Exposure to
sovereigns, banks
and corporates
Advanced internal
ratings-based
approach, where
(B) is derived as
(A) x 8% 144,885.9 10,152.5 812.2 131,684.4 8,934.3 714.7
Securitisation exposures,
externally managed
portfolios and
other assets
Standardised
approach, where
(B) is derived as
(A) x 8% 1,078.6 386.2 30.9 1,823.5 1,142.6 91.4
Market risk
Exposure to
foreign exchange risk
and gold price risk
Internal models
approach, where
(A) is derived as
(B) / 8% 11,244.9 899.6 11,748.1 939.8
Operational risk Advanced
measurement
approach, where
(A) is derived as
(B) / 8% 10,154.1 812.3 4,612.5 369.0
Total 31,937.7 2,555.0 26,437.5 2,114.9
For credit risk, the Bank has adopted the advanced internal ratings-based approach for the majority of its exposures. Under this approach,
the risk weighting for a transaction is determined by the relevant Basel II risk weight function using the Banks own estimates for key inputs.
For securitisation exposures, externally managed portfolios and relevant other assets, the Bank has adopted the standardised approach.
Under this approach, risk weightings are mapped to exposure types.
Risk-weighted assets for market risk are derived following an internal models approach. For operational risk, the advanced measurement
approach is used. Both these approaches rely on value-at-risk (VaR) methodologies.
More details on the assumptions underlying the calculations are provided in the sections on credit risk, market risk and operational risk.
222 BIS 84th Annual Report
5. Tier 1 capital ratio
The capital ratio measures capital adequacy by comparing the Banks Tier 1 capital with its risk-weighted assets. The table below shows the
Banks Tier 1 capital ratio, consistent with the Basel II Framework:
As at 31 March
SDR millions
2014 2013
restated
Share capital and reserves 14,977.6 14,258.0
Re-measurement losses on defined benefit obligations (238.9) (422.0)
Tier 1 capital 14,738.7 13,836.0
Expected loss (19.9) (20.8)
Tier 1 capital net of expected loss (A) 14,718.8 13,815.2
Total risk-weighted assets (B) 31,937.7 26,437.5
Tier 1 capital ratio (A) / (B) 46.1% 52.3%
Expected loss is calculated for credit risk exposures subject to the advanced internal ratings-based approach. The expected loss is calculated
at the balance sheet date taking into account any impairment provision which is reflected in the Banks financial statements. The Bank had
no impaired financial assets at 31 March 2014 (2013: nil). In accordance with the requirements of the Basel II Framework, any expected loss
is compared with the impairment provision and any shortfall is deducted from the Banks Tier 1 capital.
The Bank is committed to maintaining its superior credit quality and financial strength, in particular in situations of financial stress. This is
reflected in its own assessment of capital adequacy. As a result, the Bank maintains a capital position substantially in excess of minimum
capital requirements under the Basel II Framework.
223 BIS 84th Annual Report
Risk management
1. Risks faced by the Bank
The Bank supports its customers, predominantly central banks, monetary authorities and international financial institutions, in the
management of their reserves and related financial activities.
Banking activities form an essential element of meeting the Banks objectives and ensure its financial strength and independence. The BIS
engages in banking activities that are customer-related as well as activities that are related to the investment of its equity, each of which
may give rise to financial risk comprising credit risk, market risk and liquidity risk. The Bank is also exposed to operational risk.
Within the risk frameworks defined by the Board of Directors, the Management of the Bank has established risk management policies
designed to ensure that risks are identified, appropriately measured and controlled as well as monitored and reported.
2. Risk management approach and organisation
The Bank maintains superior credit quality and adopts a prudent approach to financial risk-taking, by:
adopting a conservative approach to its tactical market risk-taking and carefully managing market risk associated with the Banks
strategic positions, which include its gold holdings; and
Human factors: insufficient personnel, lack of requisite knowledge, skills or experience, inadequate training and development, inadequate
supervision, loss of key personnel, inadequate succession planning, or lack of integrity or ethical standards.
Failed or inadequate processes: a process is poorly designed or unsuitable, or is not properly documented, understood, implemented,
followed or enforced.
Failed or inadequate systems: a system is poorly designed, unsuitable or unavailable, or does not operate as intended.
External events: the occurrence of an event having an adverse impact on the Bank but outside its control.
Operational risk includes legal risk, but excludes strategic risk.
The Banks operational risk management framework, policies and procedures comprise the management and measurement of operational
risk, including the determination of the relevant key parameters and inputs, business continuity planning and the monitoring of key risk
indicators.
The Bank has established a procedure of immediate reporting for operational risk-related incidents. The Compliance and Operational Risk
Unit develops action plans with the respective units and follows up on their implementation on a regular basis.
For the measurement of operational risk economic capital and operational risk-weighted assets, the Bank has adopted a VaR approach using
a Monte Carlo simulation technique that is consistent with the advanced measurement approach proposed under the Basel II Framework.
In line with the assumptions of the Basel II Framework, the quantification of operational risk does not take reputational risk into account.
Internal and external loss data, scenario estimates and control self-assessments to reflect changes in the business and control environment
of the Bank are key inputs in the calculations. In quantifying its operational risk, the Bank does not take potential protection it may obtain
from insurance into account.
A. Economic capital for operational risk
Consistent with the parameters used in the calculation of economic capital for financial risk, the Bank measures economic capital for
operational risk to a 99.995% confidence interval assuming a one-year holding period. The table below shows the key figures of the Banks
exposure to operational risk in terms of economic capital utilisation over the past two financial years.
For the financial year
2014 2013
SDR millions Average High Low At 31 March Average High Low At 31 March
Economic capital
utilisation for
operational risk 1,075.0 1,200.0 700.0 1,200.0 700.0 700.0 700.0 700.0
B. Minimum capital requirements for operational risk
In line with the key parameters of the Basel II Framework, the calculation of the minimum capital requirement for operational risk is
determined to a 99.9% confidence interval assuming a one-year time horizon. The table below shows the minimum capital requirements
for operational risk and related risk-weighted assets.
As at 31 March
2014 2013
SDR millions
VaR Risk-
weighted
assets
Minimum
capital
requirement
VaR Risk-
weighted
assets
Minimum
capital
requirement
(A) (B) (A) (B)
Operational risk,
where (A) is derived as (B) / 8% 812.3 10,154.1 812.3 369.0 4,612.5 369.0
240 BIS 84th Annual Report
6. Liquidity risk
Liquidity risk arises when the Bank may not be able to meet expected or unexpected current or future cash flows and collateral needs
without affecting its daily operations or its financial condition.
The Banks currency and gold deposits, principally from central banks and international institutions, comprise 94% (2013: 95%) of its total
liabilities. At 31 March 2014 currency and gold deposits originated from 175 depositors (2013: 168). Within these deposits, there are
significant individual customer concentrations, with five customers each contributing in excess of 5% of the total on a settlement date basis
(2013: five customers).
Outstanding balances in the currency and gold deposits from central banks, international organisations and other public institutions are the
key drivers of the size of the Banks balance sheet. The Bank is exposed to funding liquidity risk mainly because of the short-term nature of
its deposits and because it undertakes to repurchase at fair value certain of its currency deposit instruments at one or two business days
notice. In line with the Banks objective to maintain a high level of liquidity, it has developed a liquidity management framework, including
a ratio, based on conservative assumptions for estimating the liquidity available and the liquidity required.
A. Maturity profile of cash flows
The following tables show the maturity profile of cash flows for assets and liabilities. The amounts disclosed are the undiscounted cash flows
to which the Bank is committed.
241 BIS 84th Annual Report
As at 31 March 2014
SDR millions
Up to 1
month
1 to 3
months
3 to 6
months
6 to 12
months
1 to 2
years
2 to 5
years
5 to 10
years
Over 10
years
Total
Assets
Cash and sight
accounts with banks 11,211.5 11,211.5
Gold and gold loans 20,374.5 222.6 20,597.1
Treasury bills 10,075.7 22,334.5 7,135.5 4,400.3 323.6 44,269.6
Securities purchased under
resale agreements 33,792.9 8,497.3 42,290.2
Loans and advances 9,645.7 9,955.7 19,601.4
Government and
other securities 3,990.7 7,821.5 8,208.5 11,422.5 12,341.6 26,177.5 1,458.7 71,421.0
Total assets 89,091.0 48,609.0 15,344.0 16,045.4 12,665.2 26,177.5 1,458.7 209,390.8
Liabilities
Currency deposits
Deposit instruments
repayable at 12 days
notice (9,115.8) (19,975.2) (16,886.1) (17,351.8) (16,795.8) (23,879.9) (16.1) (104,020.7)
Other currency deposits (47,374.8) (17,579.2) (7,913.1) (3,210.3) (76,077.4)
Gold deposits (11,077.0) (221.1) (11,298.1)
Total liabilities (67,567.6) (37,554.4) (24,799.2) (20,783.2) (16,795.8) (23,879.9) (16.1) (191,396.2)
Derivatives
Net settled
Interest rate contracts 11.2 71.0 102.8 117.3 105.6 (37.7) (3.9) 366.3
Gross settled
Exchange rate and
gold price contracts
Inflows 44,188.7 40,218.5 8,699.9 7,240.7 100,347.8
Outflows (44,213.3) (39,986.0) (8,752.1) (7,211.6) (100,163.0)
Subtotal (24.6) 232.5 (52.2) 29.1 184.8
Interest rate contracts
Inflows 32.6 0.2 186.1 282.9 400.1 25.5 927.4
Outflows (36.8) (1.8) (214.0) (331.5) (458.9) (28.6) (1,071.6)
Subtotal (4.2) (1.6) (27.9) (48.6) (58.8) (3.1) (144.2)
Total derivatives (17.6) 301.9 22.7 97.8 46.8 (40.8) (3.9) 406.9
Total future
undiscounted
cash flows 21,505.8 11,356.5 (9,432.5) (4,640.0) (4,083.8) 2,256.8 1,438.7 18,401.5
242 BIS 84th Annual Report
As at 31 March 2013
SDR millions
Up to 1
month
1 to 3
months
3 to 6
months
6 to 12
months
1 to 2
years
2 to 5
years
5 to 10
years
Over 10
years
Total
Assets
Cash and sight
accounts with banks 6,884.1 6,884.1
Gold and gold loans 35,086.8 282.1 35,368.9
Treasury bills 11,036.4 23,042.0 9,643.5 2,994.5 46,716.4
Securities purchased under
resale agreements 21,795.6 4,664.6 26,460.2
Loans and advances 10,034.4 8,640.8 318.9 18,994.1
Government and
other securities 1,576.3 5,590.8 8,649.6 10,677.1 11,246.0 23,018.8 1,951.0 1,062.8 63,772.4
Total assets 86,413.6 41,938.2 18,612.0 13,671.6 11,528.1 23,018.8 1,951.0 1,062.8 198,196.1
Liabilities
Currency deposits
Deposit instruments
repayable at 12 days
notice (7,383.7) (10,649.5) (17,483.0) (19,696.1) (14,744.0) (23,859.4) (67.9) (93,883.6)
Other currency deposits (40,783.3) (19,228.9) (7,980.9) (2,603.5) (70,596.6)
Gold deposits (17,301.9) (280.5) (17,582.4)
Securities sold short 82.8 13.2 (0.9) (1.7) (3.4) (10.3) (17.2) (149.6) (87.1)
Total liabilities (65,386.1) (29,865.2) (25,464.8) (22,301.3) (15,027.9) (23,869.7) (85.1) (149.6) (182,149.7)
Derivatives
Net settled
Interest rate contracts (1.2) 107.8 133.1 199.8 238.0 94.6 (17.0) 755.1
Gross settled
Exchange rate and
gold price contracts
Inflows 32,788.8 46,454.6 17,827.6 5,835.2 102,906.2
Outflows (31,785.2) (46,067.1) (17,536.6) (5,623.4) (101,012.3)
Subtotal 1,003.6 387.5 291.0 211.8 1,893.9
Interest rate contracts
Inflows 114.2 133.6 115.4 84.3 475.8 365.3 1,288.6
Outflows (114.5) (156.1) (128.0) (107.9) (518.1) (402.6) (1,427.2)
Subtotal (0.3) (22.5) (12.6) (23.6) (42.3) (37.3) (138.6)
Total derivatives 1,002.1 472.8 411.5 388.0 195.7 57.3 (17.0) 2,510.4
Total future
undiscounted
cash flows 22,029.6 12,545.8 (6,441.3) (8,241.7) (3,304.1) (793.6) 1,848.9 913.2 18,556.8
243 BIS 84th Annual Report
The Bank writes options in the ordinary course of its banking business. The table below discloses the fair value of the written options
analysed by exercise date:
Written options
SDR millions
Up to 1
month
1 to 3
months
3 to 6
months
6 to 12
months
1 to 2
years
2 to 5
years
5 to 10
years
Over 10
years
Total
As at 31 March 2014 (0.3) (0.1) (3.3) (3.8) (9.3) (16.8)
As at 31 March 2013 (0.1) (0.2) (1.1) (1.4)
The table below shows the contractual expiry date of the credit commitments as at the balance sheet date:
Contractual expiry date
SDR millions
Up to 1
month
1 to 3
months
3 to 6
months
6 to 12
months
1 to 2
years
2 to 5
years
5 to 10
years
Maturity
undefined
Total
As at 31 March 2014 267.5 194.1 2,461.3 2,922.9
As at 31 March 2013 256.6 200.1 2,597.1 3,053.8
B. Liquidity ratio
The Bank has adopted a liquidity risk framework taking into account regulatory guidance issued by the Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision related to the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR). The framework is based on a liquidity ratio that compares the Banks available
liquidity with a liquidity requirement over a one-month time horizon assuming a stress scenario. In line with the Basel III Liquidity Framework,
the underlying stress scenario combines an idiosyncratic and a market crisis. However, the liquidity ratio differs in construction from the LCR
to reflect the nature and scope of the BIS banking activities in particular, the short-term nature of the Banks balance sheet. Within the
Banks liquidity framework, the Board of Directors has set a limit for the Banks liquidity ratio which requires the liquidity available to be at
least 100% of the potential liquidity requirement.
Liquidity available
The liquidity available is determined as the cash inflow from financial instruments over a one-month horizon, along with potential additional
liquidity which could be generated from the disposal of highly liquid securities, or by entering into sale and repurchase agreements for a
part of the Banks remaining unencumbered high-quality liquid securities. The assessment of this potential additional liquidity involves two
steps. First, there is an assessment of the credit quality and market liquidity of the securities. Second, the process of converting the identified
securities into cash is modelled by projecting the amount that could be reasonably collected.
Liquidity required
Consistent with the stress scenario, the Bank determines the liquidity required as the sum of the cash outflow from financial instruments
over a one-month horizon, the estimated early withdrawal of currency deposits, and the estimated drawings of undrawn facilities. As regards
the calculation of the liquidity needs related to currency deposits, it is assumed that all deposits that mature within the time horizon
are not rolled-over and that a proportion of non-maturing currency deposits is withdrawn from the Bank prior to contractual maturity. At
31 March 2014 the estimated outflow of currency deposits in response to the stress scenario amounted to 42.9% of the total stock of
currency deposits. Moreover, it is assumed that undrawn facilities committed by the Bank would be fully drawn by customers, along with a
proportion of undrawn uncommitted facilities.
244 BIS 84th Annual Report
The table below shows the Banks estimated liquidity available, liquidity required and the resulting liquidity ratio:
As at 31 March
SDR millions
2014
Liquidity available
Estimated cash inflows 70.5
Estimated liquidity from sales of highly liquid securities 56.9
Estimated sale and repurchase agreements 6.1
Total liquidity available (A) 133.5
Liquidity required
Estimated withdrawal of currency deposits 76.1
Estimated drawings of facilities 4.3
Estimated other outflows 1.1
Total liquidity required (B) 81.5
Liquidity ratio (A) / (B) 163.8%
245 BIS 84th Annual Report
Independent auditors report
to the Board of Directors and to the General Meeting
of the Bank for International Settlements, Basel
We have audited the accompanying financial statements of the Bank for International Settlements, which
comprise of the balance sheet as at 31 March 2014, the related profit and loss account, statement of
comprehensive income, statement of cash flows and movements in the Banks equity for the year then
ended, and a summary of significant accounting policies and other explanatory information.
Managements responsibility
Management is responsible for the preparation and fair presentation of the financial statements in
accordance with the accounting principles described in the financial statements and the Statutes of the
Bank. This responsibility includes designing, implementing and maintaining an internal control system
relevant to the preparation of financial statements that are free from material misstatement, whether due
to fraud or error. Management is further responsible for selecting and applying appropriate accounting
policies and making accounting estimates that are reasonable in the circumstances.
Auditors responsibility
Our responsibility is to express an opinion on these financial statements based on our audit. We conducted
our audit in accordance with International Standards on Auditing. Those standards require that we comply
with ethical responsibilities and plan and perform the audit to obtain reasonable assurance whether the
financial statements are free from material misstatement.
An audit involves performing procedures to obtain audit evidence about the amounts and disclosures
in the financial statements. The procedures selected depend on the auditors judgment, including the
assessment of the risks of material misstatement of the financial statements, whether due to fraud or
error. In making those risk assessments, the auditor considers the internal control system relevant to the
entitys preparation of the financial statements in order to design audit procedures that are appropriate
in the circumstances, but not for the purpose of expressing an opinion on the effectiveness of the entitys
internal control system. An audit also includes evaluating the appropriateness of the accounting policies
used and the reasonableness of accounting estimates made, as well as evaluating the overall presentation
of the financial statements.
We believe that the audit evidence we have obtained is sufficient and appropriate to provide a basis
for our audit opinion.
Opinion
In our opinion, the financial statements for the year ended 31 March 2014 give a true and fair view of
the financial position of the Bank for International Settlements and of its financial performance and its
cash flows for the year then ended in accordance with the accounting principles described in the financial
statements and the Statutes of the Bank.
Ernst & Young Ltd
Victor Veger John Alton
Zurich, 12 May 2014
246 BIS 84th Annual Report
Five-year graphical summary
Operating profit Net profit
SDR millions
SDR millions
Net interest and valuation income Average currency deposits (settlement date basis)
SDR millions
SDR billions
Average number of employees Operating expense
Full-time equivalent
CHF millions
The financial information in the Operating profit, Net profit and Operating expense panels have been restated to reflect a change in
accounting policy for post-employment benefits made in this years accounts.
0
500
1,000
1,500
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
0
500
1,000
1,500
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
0
400
800
1,200
1,600
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
On investment of the Banks equity
On the currency banking book
0
50
100
150
200
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
0
150
300
450
600
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
0
100
200
300
400
2009/10 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14
Depreciation and adjustments for post-employment
benefits and provisions
Office and other expenses budget basis
Management and staff budget basis
Printed in Switzerland Werner Druck & Medien AG, Basel