P1 PDF
P1 PDF
P1 PDF
I
Introduction
I
Health Expenditures and the Poor
The last century saw notable improvements in human health,
including longer average life expectancies and fewer infant and
child deaths. Indias life expectancy has shown remarkable
improvement, rising from 49 years in 1970 to 63 years in 1998.
Similarly, infant mortality rate IMR (which is considered a
sensitive indicator that responds to many underlying causes,
including general socio-economic conditions) dropped from 146
deaths per 1,000 births in the 1950s to 70 in 1999 [Registrar
General 1999]. But at the same time, deep economic inequalities
and social injustices continue to deny good health to many [Sen
et al 2002]. Though health has been considered a fundamental
human right since the Alma Ata Declaration (1978), expenditure
on health is often unexpected and can be catastrophic in nature.
This is even truer for the poor. A majority of the poor households,
especially the rural ones, reside in remote regions where neither
government facilities nor private medical practitioners are available. They have to depend on poor quality services provided by
local, often unqualified, practitioners and faith healers.
Health care expenditure cuts poor households budgets in two
ways. Not only do they have to spend a large amount of money
and resources on medical care but they are also unable to earn
during the period of illness. Moreover, rural people have a
relatively higher burden of indirect costs (such as expenses on
transport, food/stay, tips given to secure access to any person
or facility, opportunity cost of lost wages of the sick as well as
the accompanying person, etc) associated with an illness episode
[Sodani 1997]. Very often, the poor have to borrow funds at a high
interest rate to meet both medical expenditure and other household consumption needs, which carries them into indebtedness.
4141
Role of State
Health care, like education, housing, old age security and other
social provisions, has nowhere in the world been able to make an
effective contribution without the active participation of the state.
Even in the most advanced countries, the role of the state has been
extremely critical in assuring that health care becomes universally
and more or less equitably available [Duggal et al 1995].
India spends about 5.1 per cent of its GDP on health [WHO
2004]. But 82 per cent of total health care expenditure is spent
by the private sector and almost all of this represents private outof-pocket expenditure. Most of private spending is on curative
care: consultations, diagnostics and in-patient care. This out-ofpocket expenditure puts enormous financial burden on individuals [Ellis et al 2000]. The public health investment in the country
over the years has been comparatively low, and as a percentage
of GDP has declined from 1.3 per cent in 1990 to 0.9 per cent
in 1999. Even from this tiny public expenditure on health, the
benefits have been very uneven between the better endowed and
the more vulnerable sections of society. This is particularly true
for women, children and the socially disadvantaged sections of
society. Moreover nearly 60 per cent of all public health expenditure is in form of salaries [MoH and FW 2002], which suggests
that public health investments have been allocated inefficiently.
Another important feature of health care system in India is that
even visits to public facilities generally involve considerable outof-pocket expenditures. These expenditures may take the form
of payments for medicines, laboratory tests, dressing, linen and/
or direct payment to providers [Ellis et al 2000]. This happens
as medicines are often out of stock at public health facilities and
patients have to approach the market for medicines as well as
laboratory tests.
There is extensive literature that summarises the poor quality
of health care that is currently available to seekers of health care
in India. For instance, patients both rich and poor tend to
4142
Role of Market
The private sector in India accounts for 82 per cent of outpatient
care, 56 per cent of hospitalisations, 46 per cent of institutional
deliveries, and 40 per cent of pre-natal care visits. It provides
only 10 per cent of immunisations. A comparison of NSS 52nd
round with the corresponding estimates of the NSS 42nd round
reveals a discernible rise in the share of private sector [NSSO
1998]. Private sector in India accounts for more than 80 per cent
of all health spending, one of the highest proportions of private
spending found anywhere in the world [World Bank 2002]. Only
five countries (Cambodia, the Democratic Republic of the Congo,
Georgia, Myanmar, and Sierra Leone) have a higher dependence
on private financing in the health sector [WHO 2004].
But the situation is not much better with the private sector.
A study in two districts of Maharashtra found a large number
of doctors practising modern medicine without being qualified
to do so; and several hospitals that lacked even the basic infrastructure and personnel to carry out their functions, and operating
without licences and registration [Nandraj and Duggal 1996].
Private for-profit health insurance, only recently allowed in
India under the Insurance Regulatory Development Authority
(IRDA) Act of 1999, is largely unavailable. Few companies have
introduced health insurance schemes and they are generally
targeted towards well-off people in selected cities. Nonetheless,
according to IRDA guidelines, it is mandatory for private
companies to fulfil certain rural and social obligations.1 However, these obligations are not exclusively for health insurance
schemes but for all categories of non-life insurance together.
Thus, there is no specific IRDA provision, which makes it
mandatory for private companies to cover the poor through their
health insurance policies.
A market, after all, recognises those who have the purchasing
power to enter in it. The poorest of the poor in India and in Gujarat
who survive on subsistence activities have a very low level of
interaction with market as consumers [Iyenger 2000]. They are
likely to be neglected by private insurance companies. Thus, most
of the informal sector remains outside any insurance cover
(provided by the state as well as the market) and hence there
is a great need to somehow bring them into the net of health
insurance so that their vulnerability can be reduced.
III
Community-based Health Insurance and NGOs
Given the rising expenditure on health care and the inability
of the state and the market to protect the vulnerable sections of
society, it becomes increasingly important to look at various
alternatives for financing this expenditure. There have been
attempts to augment the resources of health facilities through
the introduction of user fees. These attempts have not produced
any significant result. The all-India figures suggest that during
1992-93, the average hospital receipts amounted to about 1.4 per
cent of the total hospital expenditure incurred by the hospitals
[NIPFP 1994]. Moreover, evidence consistently shows that user
fees are most taxing to the poor and have a negative equity impact
[McPake et al 1992; Russell and Gilson 1997].
An important part of private health finance in India is the service
provided by voluntary and charitable organisations. As noted by
Berman (1996), while such groups do not account for a large
share in health care, they are often the only source of health
services, or the only trusted one, for the population they serve.
While it is very difficult to estimate even approximately the exact
coverage of these varied services, Berman speculates that they
cover more than 5 per cent of the population [Ellis et al 2000].
Many NGOs in India are involved in microfinancing initiatives.
Learning from their experiences from micro-credit programmes
(e g, health expenditure, a major cause of default), some have
started micro-insurance programmes. There are also some other
NGOs that are not into microfinance but into other developmental
activities and they have also started insurance schemes for the
poor. Most of these NGOs offer comprehensive assistance packages
with the underlying assumption that health is only one aspect
of development and should therefore be tackled along with other
social problems in holistic fashion [Ellis et al 2000]. According
IV
Health Profile of Gujarat
Gujarat, a state situated in north-western India, has a long and
varied history and is particularly well known as the birthplace
of Mahatma Gandhi, and sadly, as the site of recurrent communal
violence. At the time of 2001 census, the population of Gujarat
4143
Health Indicators
Role of NGOs
Gujarat has a long tradition of voluntary organisations. NGOs
rooted in Gandhian philosophy have covered a large field of
development activity including health in the state. Gujarat has
a relatively large number of voluntary initiatives for providing
health services in urban as well as rural areas. There are NGOs
(like ARCH-Vahini, Sewa Rural, Anjali, Ideal and few more)
run by professional doctors who are interested in public health
and committed to serve the poor. There are other NGOs like Aga
Khan, Self-Employed Women Association (SEWA) and
Tribhuvandas Foundation (TF) who provide health services as
a part of their other developmental activities. Most of these NGOs
have been functioning in relatively inaccessible interiors in the
rural districts with an emphasis on community participation.
Some NGOs (like Lowcost Medicine) are also instrumental in
4144
V
Case Studies of Four CBHI Schemes
Gujarat
India
Kerala
25.6
7.6
3.89
62
61.53
62.77
3.2
27.2
8.9
4.58
72
62.36
63.39
3.5
17.4
6.3
2.34
17
68.8
74.4
1.8
Gujarat
India
Hospital
Dispensaries
PHCs
Beds
Doctors
Nurses
4.34
15.22
3.24
145.76
52.98
59
1.32
3.25
3.55
78.70
47.19
36.88
85
58
67.8
72.8
India
68
37
38
39.9
Tribhuvandas Foundation
TF, named after one of the pioneers of the white revolution
and founder chairman of AMUL dairy, the late Tribhuvandas
Patel, has been actively involved in various development oriented
activities, and particularly concerned with the health of women
and children in the villages of Kheda and Anand districts of
central Gujarat since 1980. The foundation covers 638 villages
out of 900 villages of Kheda/Anand district. TF has trained one
voluntary health worker (VHW) for work in every village. VHWs
are paid an honorarium by the community and they have been
trained at TF headquarters to treat primary illnesses and to identify
at-risk cases so that they can be referred to TF. In addition to
primary health care, TF is also involved in income-generating
projects.
The health insurance scheme named as Sardar Patel Aarogya
Mandal came into existence on January 26, 2001. TF was already
providing primary health care through its infrastructure, but it
felt the need of a health insurance scheme that could cover the
expensive hospitalisation. So the scheme was created to provide
inpatient care. Under this new scheme (TF had already been
experimenting with prepayment for more than 20 years), three
paisa per litre of milk deposited, plus Rs 26 (Rs 25 for TF
membership and Rs 1 for the scheme) per year are collected as
premium from each household. Originally the purpose behind
deducting three paisa per litre of milk deposited was to build
up a corpus and the interest on it would pay for the premium.
This three paisa per litre, was being collected years before the
scheme was started. For those who have paid the premium, 100
per cent of hospitalisation expenses (excluding medicine, transport and other indirect cost) are covered for the entire family.
Only those who are members of both, milk cooperative
(doodhmandli) as well as TF can enrol in this scheme. They must
deposit a minimum 300 litres of milk per year. If they cannot
then they are not entitled to the benefits. Another important clause
is that members must not sell any amount of milk to AMUL
competitors. If they are found selling milk to competitors, they
are disqualified from participating in the scheme.
Under this scheme, members when in need, have to approach
TF or any of its sub-centres for referral to hospital. TF has signed
a memorandum of understanding (MoU) with nine hospitals. All
hospitals were selected after careful consideration of factors like
geographic location, quality of health care provided, fees and
support of the management. One common element among all
these hospitals is that they are all trust hospitals. Patients can
be admitted into the hospital by showing the membership card.
This card (in fact a small booklet known as chopdi among the
4145
4146
Meloj
Methan
Year of
Total HH
Inception in the Area
1995
2002
550
720
Covered
HH
Amount
thatDairy
Is Paying
Contributions
towards Centres
Cost (Per Cent)
350
217
30,000
15,000
25
15
Meloj
Varsila
Samoda
Methan
Year of
Inception
No of
Total HH
1995
1997
1999
2002
550
217
450
720
Covered Premium
HH
per HH (Rs)
27
90
80
114
200
125
200
200
Contribution
towards Centres
Cost (Per Cent)
5
12
8
19
Navsarjan
The focus of Navsarjan, which was established in 1988, is the
dalit community. The main objective of the organisation is to
unearth atrocities against dalits and fight against these atrocities
by providing legal assistance so that dalits can lead a life of selfrespect and dignity. Today Navsarjan is working in 11 districts
of Gujarat and has a team of 194 workers. Of late, Navsarjan
has also started working for the poor non-dalits and thus the focus
is shifting from caste to class.
One enthusiastic and committed worker of Navsarjan, who
belongs to the north Gujarat region, initiated an idea of health
insurance. Navsarjan decided to buy the mediclaim policy from
New India Assurance (Sanand branch) and pay the premium. The
coverage period was from March 17, 1999 to March 16, 2000.
The coverage amount was up to Rs 15,000 and the premium was
Rs 175 per member. New India Assurance gave a 5 per cent group
discount so per capita premium came to Rs 159. The total
premium paid for the scheme was Rs 91,216. This amount was
partly funded by Hivos (a funding agency) and partly from
Navsarjan Social Security membership fund (a larger comprehensive scheme which was also on pilot basis for two years and
included accidental death, maternity benefits, etc. The membership fee was Rs 400 per annum and was paid by individuals).
Thus the scheme was partially financed by the community through
the social security fund. Five panel doctors (2 orthopedic surgeons, 1 gynaecologist, 1 physician and 1 general surgeon) were
approached in Patan town and it was decided that the members,
in case of need, would visit them in Patan. The doctors agreed
to receive payment after three months, i e, they would provide
treatment on credit. Each member was given a membership card.
One staff member of Navsarjan was transferred to Patan to sit
in the premises of the hospital to help the members of the
scheme. He looked after all documents like bills and drug prescriptions, and file the mediclaim application form. The village
Navsarjan workers often accompanied members to the hospital
in Patan. The policy was just for one year and was on pilot
basis only.
It can be seen from Table 6 that 574 individuals (51 per cent
of them were women) were covered under the scheme. According
to the data provided by Navsarjan, during the period of scheme
operation 57 claims were made of Rs 81,130. From these claims,
21 were totally rejected (rejection rate 36.8 per cent) and in many
case full amount was not sanctioned. The total sanctioned amount
was Rs 46,030. Out of the total 21 claims that were rejected,
since the amount was substantial in two cases, Navsarjan bore
the cost. The rest of the 19 members had to pay for the treatment.
The average cost of hospitalisation works out to be Rs 1,423
whereas the average cost of reimbursement comes to Rs 808.
Those members, whose claims were not sanctioned, were
quite unhappy. They did not understand the reasons for non
VI
Discussion and Conclusion
Tables 7 and 8 compare salient features of all four schemes. It is
quite evident from these tables that the schemes are diverse in
terms of their design and management (number of members,
target population, pattern of enrolment, unit of membership, level
of premium, scheme benefit package, etc). Therefore, it is somewhat difficult to make comparisons across the schemes. Each
scheme is unique and has its own strengths and weakness.
Two out of four (AKHS and TF) are health NGOs. The other
two (SEWA and Navsarjan) are also engated in other developmental activities and health insurance has been introduced by
them as a part of social security package. In case of Navsarjan,
the NGO was working as an intermediary between the insurance
company and the community. As far as size of the scheme is
concerned, Aga Khan and Navsarjan are quite small whereas
SEWA and TF have been able to insure a large number of people.
Both TF and Aga Khan have piggybacked on dairy cooperative
structures for health insurance. It is worth noting here that apart
from health insurance, dairy cooperatives have done many
welfare activities both for the betterment of the community as
well as cattle. This structure has the leverage of political
backing but then it makes membership mandatory as members
of dairy cooperative automatically become members of health
insurance schemes. SEWA and Navsarjan only provide inpatient care whereas AKHS only provides outpatient care
Table 6: Details of Navsarjan Scheme
No of members
Premium collected in Rs [B]
Claims (amount in Rs)
Average cost of hospitalisation in Rs
Claims settled (amount) [E]
Average amount reimbursed in Rs
Rejection rate (per cent)
Surplus in Rs [B] [E]
574
91,216
57 (81,130)
1423
36 (46,030)
808
36.8
45,186
4147
Tribhuvandas Foundation
(TF)
Navsarjan
Integrated Insurance
Scheme (IIS)
Year of Inception
Location
1992
11districtsofGujarat
2001
Kheda/Anand district
1995
Sidhpur taluka of Patan district
in north Gujarat
1999
Sami and Harij taluka of
PatandistrictinnorthGujarat
Status
Ongoing
Ongoing
Ongoing
Stopped in 2000
Target Population
Ismailiesandoflateothervillagers
Dalits
Unit of membership
Individual
Family
Family
Individual
Members
1,00,000individuals
83,000families
(i)311familiesinfoursectors
of Sidhpur
(ii)467familiesintwosectors
of Sidhpur
574
NA
Negligible,lessthan1percent
No
No
Use of Management
Yes
Information System (MIS)
No
No
Self-sufficientornot
No
Nostatisticsavailable
Heavily subsidised by AMUL.
Tribhuvandas Foundation
(TF)
Navsarjan
Rs 85
Benefit
Onlyinpatientcare.
Both inpatient and
Hospitalisationcover,plus
outpatientcare.
one time payment for denture Freehospitalisationat
and hearing aid. Delivery
selectedreferralhospitals
benefitsforfixeddeposits
members.
Onlyinpatientcare.
Free hospitalisation up to
Rs 15,000 at a particular
hospital in Patan
Cap on reimbursement
Rs 2000
Rs 7 to 10,000 on an average N A
but TF management can
reimburse up to Rs 1 lakh in
exceptional cases
Rs 15,000
Services excluded
Pre-existingconditions,
normaldelivery,conditions
related to HIV/AIDS
Angiography, angioplasty,
bypass surgery, all cancers,
major orthopedic operations
(joint replacement) kidney
transplant AIDS and TB
Allhospitalisationexcept
delivery
Minimum period
ofhospitalisation
24 Hours
Not specified
NA
48 hours
4148
financially self-sustainable. None of the schemes is fully financially self-sustainable by this yardstick. Although it is important,
financial sustainability may not be the top priority for the organisers
and administrators of any CBHI scheme. Often, these schemes
are initiated with the acknowledgement that there is a trade-off
between financial sustainability and equity, and that it may simply
not be possible to provide insurance services to the very poor
without some form of external subsidy. In the process of making
schemes economically viable, premiums usually go up which
adversely affects the members who are at the bottom from the
income point of view. All of these four schemes that we have
studied received some form of external support at some point
of time, without which they probably could not have survived
on their own.
From our discussions with community member, we can say
that they view CBHI in a positive way. However, they feel that
there is room for improvement in a variety of ways. Two schemes
(SEWA and Navsarjan) were in collaboration with General
Insurance Corporation. According to the scheme manager of
Navsarjan, the administration at GIC was quite supportive but
at the same time they were careful not to incur any losses. For
example, Navsarjan scheme manager was told by the GIC official
that even if all claims are genuine in nature, they could not afford
to pay beyond the amount that they were receiving by collecting
premium. Since the scheme is relatively new in case of TF, it
would be pre-mature to draw any concrete conclusions. But looking at the enrolment conditions, it is fairly evident that scheme
excludes those people who cannot deposit 300 litres of milk in
a year. This means, those households who are poor and cannot
afford to own a milch animal are unable to avail of benefits.
Generally, CBHI covers very small populations, so has a limited
impact from a public health point of view. And the schemes that
require significant out-of-pocket payment (e g, SEWA) may not
protect from indebtedness, particularly among those who experience the most expensive hospitalisations.
The presence of health insurance cover may induce individuals
either to take fewer precautions or to use more health services
when they fall ill. Both actions tend to increase health expenditure. This phenomena is known as moral hazard. But in case
of low income population where the health services utilisation
is already low, this increased spending may be socially desirable
[Ellis et al 2000]. In cases like Navsarjan and TF, when doctors
knew the fact that the patient was insured, they over prescribed
drugs and went for unnecessary clinical investigations. Due to
this problem of moral hazard, TF had to withdraw the medication/
outpatient cover.
The FGDs were designed to understand the exposure to, and
awareness of the community regarding CBHI, willingness to join
and pay, choice of health care provider, and desire of modification
in CBHI schemes. We must note that in some cases the awareness
level is very low and some members of CBHI schemes, especially
where there is tie-up with dairy cooperatives (TF and Aga Khan)
do not even know that they are members of such a scheme. At
SEWA, it is not uncommon for members to recall details of their
life insurance (part of the SEWA insurance package) but to forget
that they are also entitled to health insurance benefits. These
limited levels of awareness highlight the need for any CBHI
scheme to be accompanied by an ongoing education and information campaign to keep members informed about their insurance policy. Reminder visits between annual campaigns appear
to be a necessity.
4149
Notes
1 Part III, Section IV of Insurance Regulatory and Development Authority
(Obligations of Insurers to Rural and Social Sectors) Regulations, 2000
2 Banks, NGOs, Panchayats allowed to sell Insurance, The Economic
Times, October 21, 2002, p 1.
References
ASCI (1996): Feasibility Study for Introducing Health Insurance Schemes
in India, Administrative Staff College of India, (mimeo).
Bennett, S et al (1998): Health Insurance Schemes for People Outside Formal
Sector Employment, Division of Analysis, Research and Assessment,
World Health Organisation.
Bhat, Ramesh (1999): A Note on Policy Initiatives to Protect the Poor from
High Medical Costs, Indian Institute of Management (IIM-A), Ahmedabad
(mimeo).
Berman, Peter (1996): Healthcare Expenditure in India in Monica Dasgupta
et al (eds), Health Poverty and Development in India, Oxford University
Press, Delhi, pp 331-58.
Datt, Ruddar (ed) (1997): Organising the Unorganised Workers, Vikas
Publishing House, New Delhi.
Dave, P (1991): Community and Self-financing in Voluntary Health
Programmes in India, Health Policy and Planning 6(1).
Dave, Sen (1997): Community Control of Health Financing in India: A
Review of Local Experiences, Technical Report No:8, Abt Associates Inc.
Duggal, Ravi, Sunil Nandraj and Asha Vadair (1995): Health Expenditure
Across States Part I and II, Economic and Political Weekly, 30 (15
and 16), pp 834-44 and 901-08.
Ellis Randall, Alam Moner, Gupta Indrani (2000): Health Insurance in India:
Prognosis and Prospectus, Economic and Political Weekly, January 22,.
Fairbank, Alan and Pamela Putney (1998): Sustaining Community Based
Healthcare Systems in Gujarat, Abt Associates Inc, US.
Government of India (2000): Savrekhshana, Ministry of Health, GoI.
Griffin, C (1989): Strengthening Health Services in Developing Countries
through the Private Sector, World Bank.
Gumber A, V Kulkarni (2000): Health Insurance for Informal Sector: Case
Study of Gujarat, Economic and Political Weekly, September 30.
ILO (2002): Social Security for the Informal Sector: Issues, Options and
Tasks Ahead, Social Security Department, ILO.
ILO-Universitas Programme (2002): Extending Social Protection through
Community-Based Health Organisations: Evidence and Challenges,
Geneva, Switzerland.
International Institute of Population Studies and ORC Macro (2000): National
Family Health Survey (NFHS-2), 1998-99, IIPS, Mumbai, India.
Iyenger, Sudarshan (2000): Role of Non-Governmental Organisations in
Development of Gujarat, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol 35,
Nos 35 and 36, August 26-September 2.
Mahadevia, Darshini (2002): Health for All in Gujarat: Is It Achievable?
in Hirway, Kashyap and Shah (ed), Dynamics of Development in Gujarat,
Concept Publishing, New Delhi.
Mahal, Ajay (1999): Potential Implications of Private Health Insurance in
India: Is IRDA Sufficient?, National Council of Applied Economic
Research, New Delhi (mimeo).
Mathiyazhagan, K (1998): Willingness to Pay for Rural Health Insurance
through Community Participation in India, International Journal of
Health Planning and Management, 13, p 47-67.
McPake, B, K Hanson, A Mills (1992): Implementing the Bamako Initiative
in Africa, London School of Hygiene and Tropical Medicine.
MoH and FW (2002): National Health Policy 2002, Ministry of Health and
Family Welfare, Government of India.
Misra, R, R Chatterjee and S Rao (2003): India Health Report, Oxford
University Press, New Delhi.
Nandraj, Sunil and Ravi Duggal (1996): Physical Standards in the Private
Health Sector, Radical Journal of Health, 2(2/3):141-84.
4150