Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications: Gunduz Caginalp, Mark Desantis
Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications: Gunduz Caginalp, Mark Desantis
Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications: Gunduz Caginalp, Mark Desantis
1. Introduction
The dynamics of asset prices and the underlying motivations have been of great interest for both theorists and
practitioners. A basic rationale for price movement is due to the changes in the value of the asset. In the absence of any
insight into the motivations of investors and traders, one might stipulate that prices should fluctuate randomly about this
basic valuation. One can regard this concept as a default hypothesis expressing a distinguished limit in which there is
(a) unlimited information, that ensures all participants share the same notion of valuation, and (b) essentially infinite
arbitrage capital, whereby informed investors vie with one another to quickly exploit any deviations from this valuation.
There is little doubt among practitioners that additional factors are at work in markets. The tumultuous financial markets
of September and October 2008 are a dramatic reminder of the diverse forces driving markets. These recent upheavals
capping a prolonged housing bubble are the most recent of a series of modern bubble/bust cycles. Among these are the
internet/high-tech bubble of the late 1990s and the Japanese stock bubble of the late 1980s. Due to their sheer magnitude,
these episodes have had an impact far beyond the immediate shareholders who lost trillions. The ensuing years of economic
slowdowns and job losses were among the consequences of these boom/bust cycles.
Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 412 624 8339, +1 412 624 8375 (Secretary); fax: +1 412 624 8397.
E-mail addresses: caginalp@pitt.edu (G. Caginalp), mjd34@pitt.edu (M. DeSantis).
1468-1218/$ see front matter 2010 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.nonrwa.2010.09.008
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1141
Yet it is surprising that only a relative handful of works focus on these phenomena, and finance textbooks hardly mention
them. Papers that discuss motivations beyond valuation are often expository in nature, and rarely have direct contact with
market data. As such it is easy for exponents of efficient market theories to dismiss them. In fact, it is often difficult to test
hypotheses or theories of markets due to the randomness inherent in valuation changes (see [1]). Thus studies that examine
stock prices for non-random behavior, such as trends, usually find only tiny effects (e.g. [2]).
An early study [3] highlighting the importance of trend examined two essentially identical closed-end funds, Future
Germany Fund and Germany Fund. Closed-end funds, unlike open-end funds, trade as other company stocks on the
exchanges (see, e.g. [4]). Thus the price can be higher or lower than the net asset value (NAV), and can vary independently
of this value. In the case of these two clone funds, any change in valuation will be identical in both funds, and the ratio of
valuation is constant in time. By considering the ratio of the trading prices of these funds as a time series they were able to
extract all noise attributable to valuation. They found that tomorrows price is not predicted well by todays price, as efficient
markets would suggest. But rather, tomorrows price is halfway between todays price and the price obtained by continuing
the pure trend from yesterday to today.
The persistence of a trend can be viewed as an underreaction, as it suggests that there is a delay in reaching a particular
price. On the other hand, the behavioral finance community has also stipulated that participants overreact to news, as recent
information tends to overshadow previously established facts (see, e.g. [5]). Madura and Richie [6] considered a data set of
daily opening and closing prices for AMEX-traded exchange traded funds (ETF) between August 1998 and August 2002. They
found evidence that ETF stock prices reverse (i.e., exhibit overreaction) following extreme price changes of greater than 5%.
They define overreaction as positive [negative] returns following negative [positive] price movements, while underreaction
is positive [negative] returns following positive [negative] price movements. Overreaction has also been observed on a larger
time scale (see, e.g. [7]).
Sturm [8] found evidence that if a stock with positive returns and/or increasing book value per share experiences a large
drop in price of at least 10%, then it has a tendency to rebound, supporting the Madura and Richie findings. In addition, Duran
and Caginalp [9] performed a large scale statistical study with 134,406 data points corresponding to daily stock prices for
closed-end funds. They found that large discrepancies between the trading price and the net asset value of the fund led
to significant price changes in the opposite direction of the discrepancy. Furthermore, the study established a precursor to
these large changes suggesting oscillatory behavior.
The fact that some studies find evidence of overreaction while others demonstrate underreaction has led some to assert
this as evidence that markets are efficient. Our perspective, however, is that perhaps there are nonlinear relationships
between price movements. One of our key goals is to demonstrate this nonlinearity and to establish its form on an empirical
and statistical basis. In particular, does an uptrend have a negative impact on daily returns after a particular threshold? And
how does the valuation enter into that threshold? A second goal is to have an objective measure of the impact of various
competing effects, e.g., price trend, valuation, etc.
In this paper we accomplish this by quantifying the effect of various factors on the daily relative price change. Given the
unambiguous nature of the definition of a closed-end funds valuation (namely, its NAV), we consider a data set comprised
of 111,356 daily closing prices for 119 closed-end funds. We perform linear regressions with the relative change in daily
price as the dependent variable and various decision-making factors as independent variables. Specifically, we consider
(i) the recent and long term trend in fund price; (ii) the valuation of the fund; (iii) the M2 Money Supply; (iv) the recent and
long term volatility of the stock price; (v) the recent trend in volume; and (vi) resistance, i.e., the idea that rising stock prices
tend to slow their increase when approaching a recent high price, which acts as a barrier. As shown by the regressions of
Caginalp and Ilieva [10], the incorporation of valuation in the appropriate form will greatly reduce the noise inherent in
the stochastic nature of the valuation and enable the analysis of these other contributing factors.
By standardizing the independent variables, i.e., subtracting the mean values and dividing by the standard deviations,
we are then able to easily compare the effects of each variable. Note that the methodology we employ to find quantitative
measures of effect can be extended for use on ordinary stocks provided a valuation measure for these stocks is employed. In
addition, this process is not limited to the above mentioned variables, but can be used to examine any decision-making factor
provided it may be expressed as a variable. An important aspect of this study involves a judicious definition of valuation.
Without a mechanism for extracting the valuation, the remaining terms would quite likely be masked by the noise inherent
in changes in valuation (see Regressions 4 and 5 in Appendix).
We utilize a data set consisting of 111,356 records corresponding to 119 funds (28 Generalized, 62 Specialized, and 29
World funds). The records correspond to daily closing prices for the time period October 26, 1998 through January 30, 2008.1
Relative price change
The basic quantity of interest is the Relative Price Change that we define as
P (t ) P (t 1)
R(t ) = ,
P (t 1)
1 Due to the definition of certain independent variables, all funds were required to have at least one years worth of data.
1142 G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151
which is sometimes called the return for day t. The Relative Price Change for day t + 1, namely R(t + 1), will be used as
the dependent variable in the regressions.
With the exception of the M2 Money Supply, the following variables, which are utilized as independent variables in the
regressions, are based upon the above mentioned daily closing prices and NAVs.
Valuation
Each of the funds included within our data set has both its price and NAV reported on a daily basis. It is, however, unusual
for the fund to trade at its NAV. Typically, the fund trades at a persistent premium (price exceeds NAV) or discount (price is
below the NAV). We define the Valuation, D(t ), of a closed-end fund to be the current days relative deviation between NAV
NAV(t )P (t )
and price, NAV(t ) , minus a weighted average of this relative deviation over the previous 10 days:
NAV(t ) P (t ) NAV(t k) P (t k)
10
1
e0.25k
D(t ) =
NAV(t ) 3.2318 k=1 NAV(t k)
where NAV(t ) is the funds net asset value on day t and P (t ) is the trading price.
We consider this deviation because if a fund has been trading at a 10% discount but is currently at a 5% discount, then
a valuation-based trader will probably not regard this fund as a bargain. To mitigate the effect of large deviationsabruptly
dropping out of the average, we utilize the scaling factor e0.25k and normalize it via the coefficient (3.2318)1 = e0.25k .
This tends to smooth the effect of historical prices and also emphasizes recent events more strongly than past events.
Price trend
As noted in the Introduction, one possible motivation for buying a stock is that the price is in an uptrend (and analogously
for selling). Since prices are fluctuating and changing direction frequently, the definition requires a choice of time scale,
which we take as ten days, and a scaling factor that determines the weightings of recent days relative to earlier days. We use
the exponential factor e0.25k for the weighting of the relative price change k days ago, as in the Valuation variable above.
Thus with the normalization factor above, we define the Price Trend as
P (t k + 1) P (t k)
10
1
e0.25k .
T (t ) =
3.2318 k=1 P (t k )
For both the Price Trend and the Valuation variables, tests of robustness have shown similar results with a longer time
scale (e.g., 25 days) and different weighting factors [10].
M2 money supply
Previous theoretical [11], experimental [12,13] and empirical [10] studies have shown that an increase in the money
supply bolsters asset prices. We obtain the weekly M22 money data (not seasonally adjusted) for the time period of study
from the Federal Reserve website [www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h6/hist/ ]. We then performed a linear interpolation to
obtain daily data. The M2 Money Supply variable is defined as the relative change in this statistic on a daily basis, i.e.,
M (t ) M (t 1)
M2(t ) = .
M (t 1)
Volatility
Volatility is identified with the standard deviation of the return (daily relative stock price change). For our study we
compute the standard deviation of the Relative Price Change variable, R(t ), for two time frames. We consider the Short Term
Volatility as the standard deviation over the past eleven (including the current day, t) days, STV (t ) = stddev(R([t 10, t ]))
and define the Long Term Volatility over the prior year, LTV = stddev(R([t 251, t ])). To compute the standard deviation
i=t (R(i) Mean(R[t X , t ])) .
t X
we take the square root of the unbiased estimator of the variance: X1 2
This definition mitigates the effect of the trend in the price on the volatility. It determines the deviation of the relative
price change about the growth curve of the share price. So, if the relative price change is constant, then the price is an expo-
nential function of time. Indeed, representing the relative price change in a limiting form such as P1 dP
dt
yields the differential
equation P1 dP
dt
= C which implies P (t ) = K eCt , where K and C are constants. For example, if the stock price follows the
0.02t
pattern e (i.e., K = 1 and C = 0.02), then the Relative Price Change would be constant (e0.02 1 0.02) and the
Volatility would be zero.
52 week price trend
As with the Volatility variable, we are not only interested in the short term price trend, but also the longer term trend. As
such, we determine the 52 Week Price Trend variable as follows: (i) fit a straight line to the past 252 Relative Price Change
values (including the current day t), i.e., R([t 251, t ]); (ii) take the slope of this line and multiply it by 252 for conversion
to annual units. The resulting value is then denoted LT (t ).
2 M2 includes: Currency, Travelers checks, demand and other checkable deposits, retail MMMFs (money market mutual funds), savings, and small time
deposits. M2 is measured in trillions for this paper.
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1143
Volume trend
We treat volume and price similarly by considering weighted averages of their relative changes. The Volume Trend
variable is thus defined as:
Vol(t k + 1) Vol(t k)
10
1
e0.25k
VT (t ) =
3.2318 k=1 Vol(t k)
Remarks. 1. Theoretical studies have used the concept of a declining exponential in gauging investor sentiment and
incorporated it into differential equations models (see e.g. [11]). There is experimental evidence [5] that individuals tend to
emphasize recent events more heavily than earlier events in their decisions.
2. Traders have explained the concept of resistance by stating that investors who held the stock through the recent high
may experience regret at not having reaped a profit. Thus, as the shares again approach this recent high, these investors
seek to recover their perceived paper losses by selling; thereby lowering the stock price and preventing it from breaking
through this price barrier. Recently, the concept of resistance has received academic attention in a study that indicates that
the yearly return is influenced by the stocks proximity to the yearly high [14], though another study [15] demonstrates
some limitations of these findings and obtains more mixed results.
3. Methodology
The objective of this paper is to determine whether various factors such as Price Trend, Valuation, Money Supply, Volume
P (t +1)P (t )
Trend, and Volatility influence an assets Relative Price Change, R(t + 1) = P (t )
, where P (t ) is the asset price on day
t. This is accomplished by executing several linear regressions with the relative price change as the dependent variable and
subsets of the other factors as independent variables. The linear regression produces a regression coefficient, p-value, and
t-value for each independent variable. The regression coefficient provides the magnitude of the effect, while the statistical
significance (p-value and t-value) of the dependent variable determines whether the effect is truly present. This approach,
however, has two shortcomings: (i) our data set consists of multiple stocks, each with its own individual attributes, and
(ii) the scales of the variables vary over several orders of magnitude (e.g., the mean value for Price Trend is approximately
0.0004 while the mean value for the Volume Trend is 0.21).
Prior studies [10] have shown that the first issue can be circumvented by performing a mixed effects linear regression
which accounts for the unique statistical characteristics of each fund.
The second issue can be addressed by standardizing the data, a methodology whereby all independent variables are
placed on a common footing to facilitate comparisons of effect [16]. This is accomplished by subtracting the mean and
dividing by the standard deviation. This makes the variables and resulting regression coefficients unitless by putting them
on the scale of standard deviations. It also facilitates comparison, for example, of a two standard deviation event for one
variable compared with another. However, as noted by Bring [17], a drawback of this approach to standardization is that the
standard deviation unit may vary across groupsin our case funds within the data set. To mitigate this issue we standardize
the coefficients by fund. That is, we compute the mean and standard deviation for each variable by fund, and then standardize
each funds data with these values. Ultimately, as noted by Cohen et al. [16], the standardized regression coefficient is often
the most useful coefficient for answering questions about the influence of one variable on another, with or without other
variables in the equation.
3 Note that the Volume may be zero on certain days. This would cause the Volume Trend to be infinite on those days. As such, we did not include any
funds with zero Volume in our data set.
1144 G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151
All of the independent variables have been standardized with the exception of the Resistance Indicator, Q (t ), and the
time variable, Time(t ). The Resistance Indicator is a highly skewed binary variable in that it is either set (corresponding
to 1) or not set (corresponding to 0) and less than 1% of the records satisfy the criteria. Consequently, standardizing this
binary variable would distort the results.4
The Time variables are included in regressions to determine if the historical periods have an effect that could be disguised
as one of the other variables. For example, Regression 2 below includes the same variables as Regression 1, but also
incorporates the Time variables. Thus, any discrepancies in the output for the variables common to both regressions are
due to the inclusion of the Time variables. While we are concerned with the statistical significance of the Time variables,
their coefficients are not directly relevant to this study. Also, the Time variable is already scaled between zero and one. As
such, we do not standardize this variable.
When utilizing standardized coefficients, one has the option to either standardize or not standardize the dependent
variable. We choose not to standardize the Relative Price Change to facilitate the interpretation of results. For example,
Regression 1 below shows the Price Trend variable to have a regression coefficient of 0.0012. In other words, a positive
one standard deviation change in the recent trend will yield, on average, a 0.12% positive change in the daily relative price
change (i.e.,the Relative Price Change variable).
4. Results
where xi is one of the above independent variables or a product of these variables. Since the variables have been standardized
(as discussed above), i may be interpreted as the standardized regression coefficient determined by the mixed effects linear
regression. The intercept term, 0 , is present as we do not standardize the dependent variable, and it may be interpreted
as the drift of classical finance. In other words, this is the average relative daily price change. The dependent variable is
evaluated at day t + 1 which indicates that it represents the following days relative price change or return.
Note that for each regression the total number of observations is 80,351 corresponding to 108 funds. The number of
observations included in the regressions does not equal the total number of records in the data set because the calculations
for some (long term) variables required data from the previous year. For example, the computation of the Long Term Price
Trend and Long Term Volatility records required the previous 251 data points.
Regression 1. We consider the Relative Price Change regressed against all of the above mentioned variables with the exception
of the Time variables. This regression has the form:
R(t + 1) = 0 + 1 T (t ) + 2 D(t ) + 3 M2(t ) + 4 STV (t ) + 5 LTV (t ) + 6 LTT (t ) + 7 VT (t ) + 8 Q (t ).
The Valuation, Price Trend, Money Supply, Short Term Volatility, and Volume Trend terms are all highly statistically
significant with positive coefficients. The coefficient of Price Trend indicates that a one standard deviation change in the
Price Trend will induce a 0.12% change in the Relative Price Change in the same direction, i.e., if the Price Trend increases,
then so will the Relative Price Change (provided all other independent variables are unchanged). The standardization allows
a comparison of impact of the different independent variables. Thus, the Price Trend coefficient is approximately one half
the magnitude of the Valuation coefficient. The M2 Money Supply variable has a coefficient that is approximately half the
magnitude of the Price Trend. This supports theoretical [11], experimental [12,13] and empirical [10] studies which suggest
that an influx of cash will bolster the trading price. These studies have helped in resolving the paradox of experimental
bubbles (see, e.g. [18,19]). The volatility variables are quite interesting in that both are statistically significant, but while
the Long Term Volatility has a negative coefficient, the Short Term Volatility coefficient is positive. Thus, recent volatility
in the fund price tends to raise the price, while longer term volatility has a negative effect on the price. The Long Term
Trend variable is only marginally statistically significant. However, its small negative coefficent agrees with the findings of
Poterba and Summers [2] of stock price regression to the mean over longer time frames. The Volume Trend is also statistically
significant with a positive coefficient that is approximately one quarter the magnitude of the Price Trend coefficient. This
confirms a widely held belief among traders that rising volume is associated with rising prices. Finally, we note that the
Resistance variable has a negative coefficient which indicates that when the Resistance criteria are satisfied, the price is
4 Gellman [21] notes that we run the risk of overstating the importance of such a binary variable relative to the other standardized variables if our
standardization procedure only divides by one standard deviation. He considers the possibility of division by two standard deviations. He indicates that
a binary variable with equal probabilities has a mean of 0.5 and a standard deviation of 0.5. Then, the difference between a 0 and a 1 on the original
(unstandardized) scale is actually 2 standard deviations. Now, suppose the binary variable is highly skewed, which our Resistance variable isonly
1
approximately 1% of the records meet the criteria (so, the mean is 0.01 and the standard deviation is approximately (0.01 0.99) 2 ). Then, the difference
between a 0 and a 1 on the original (unstandardized) scale is actually approximately 9.8 standard deviations. Thus, Gelman suggests that by not
standardizing the Resistance variable, we might actually overstate its importance because standardization in this case will actually yield larger values,
which in turn will result in smaller regression coefficients.
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1145
Table 1
Regression 1 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
Table 2
Regression 2 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
pushed downward. However, the statistical significance of this variable is marginal, probably due to the small number of
records in the data set that met these criteria (518 out of 80,351). The Intercept term is both statistically significant and
positive (Table 1).
Regression 2. The Time variables are included to ascertain whether any of the results from Regression 1 are artifacts of a
particular era. This regression has the form:
R(t + 1) = 0 + 1 T (t ) + 2 D(t ) + 3 T 2 (t ) + 4 T 3 (t ) + 5 D2 (t )
+ 6 D3 (t ) + 7 T (t )D(t ) + 8 T 2 (t )D(t ) + 9 T (t )D2 (t ).
5 The number of degrees of freedom for each regression is dependent upon the number of independent variables. As such, this statistic is included for
each regression.
1146 G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151
Table 3
Comparison of coefficients between Regressions 1 and 2.
Variable Regression 1 coefficient Regression 2 coefficient % Change
The relative change in magnitudes of the Intercept, Long Term Volatility, and Long Term Trend coefficients are significant (greater than 20%). Also, note
that the Long Term Volatility coefficient changed from negative to positive.
Table 4
Regression 3 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
Fig. 1. The plot was produced using the coefficient values from Regression 3. These coefficients define a cubic polynomial in two variables, Price Trend (T )
and Valuation (D). The surface describes the effect on the following days Relative Price Change (R), and exhibits the nonlinear relationship between D, T
and R. Overreaction is evident as a large positive trend can result in a negative Relative Price Change (analogously for negative trend). The precise point at
which the magnitude changes sign depends nonlinearly on the valuation.
With the exception of the interaction of Price Trend with the square of the Valuation, all of the independent variables are
statistically significant. Using these results, we define a function representing the Relative Price Change as a function of the
Price Trend and Valuation:
R(T , D) = 0.0003 + 0.0017T + 0.0029D 0.0001T 2 0.0001T 3
+ 0.0001D2 0.00001D3 0.0003TD 0.0001T 2 D 0.00001TD2 .
Plotting this function yields the three dimensional surface depicted in Fig. 1.
To better understand the nonlinear relationship between Price Trend and Valuation we consider the cross-sections of
the above graph for D = 1, 0, and 1.
R(T , 1) = 0.0003 + 0.0017T + 0.0029(1) 0.0001T 2 0.0001T 3 + 0.0001(1)2
0.00001(1)3 0.0003T (1) 0.0001T 2 (1) 0.00001T (1)2 .
Fig. 2 displays the cross-section of the surface in Fig. 1 with the valuation held constant at D = 1. This cubic
function intersects the T -axis at T = 4.9891, 1.3847, and 3.6044. So, for a negative one standard deviation change in
the Valuation variable, the Relative Price Change will also be negative for 4.9891 < T < 1.3847 and T > 3.6044. But, for
1.3847 < T < 3.6044, the Relative Price Change will be positive implying that the Price Trend will have a greater impact
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1147
Fig. 2. With the Valuation held constant at 1, the Relative Price Change may be represented as a cubic function of the Price Trend variable, T . For a large
enough positive change in the Price Trend, T > 3.6044, the next days Relative Price Change is negative. Analogously, for a Price Trend < 4.9891 the
next days Relative Price Change is positive.
Fig. 3. A cross-section of Fig. 1 is represented with the Valuation variable held constant, D = 0. As in Fig. 2, overreaction is present if the Price Trend
variable, T , is large enough in magnitude, i.e., for T > 3.7486 the next days Relative Price Change is negative, while for T < 4.5736, the next days
Relative Price Change is positive. Hence an uptrend has a postive influence on price change for T satisfying 4.5736 < T < 3.7486.
on the price than the Valuation. Approximately 92% of the Price Trend values will actually be less than 1.3847 standard
deviations.
Fig. 3 corresponds to the cross-section of Fig. 1 with D = 0. If the Price Trend is positive, then the Relative Price Change
is also positive up to 3.7486 standard deviations. However, if the Price Trend is greater than 3.7486 standard deviations,
the Relative Price Change is negative. Thus, we see that a large (and unusual) change in the Price Trend produces a negative
Relative Price Change supporting the theory of overreaction. Similarly, a negative Price Trend yields a negative Relative
Price Change unless the change in the Price Trend is less than 4.5736 standard deviations. Thus, there is evidence for
underreaction for 4.5736 < T < 3.7486 (approximately 99.9921% of the time) and evidence for overreaction when large
(either positive or negative) changes in the Price Trend occur.
1148 G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151
Fig. 4. A cross-section of Fig. 1 is represented with the Valuation variable held constant, D = 1. Thus, we have the next days Relative Price Change, R, as
a function of the Price Trend, T . If T > 3.8435, then the next days Relative Price Change is negative, thereby providing evidence to support overreaction
in stock prices. However, notice that for T < 3.8435, the Relative Price Change is always positive. Thus, a one standard deviation change in the Valuation
variable is large enough to counteract the effects of any negative Price Trend.
Part of the curve lies above the negative T axis for 0.17498 < T < 0 due to the drift (intercept) term from the regression.
R(T , 1) = 0.0003 + 0.0017T + 0.0029(1) 0.0001T 2 0.0001T 3 + 0.0001(1)2
0.00001(1)3 0.0003T (1) 0.0001T 2 (1) 0.00001T (1)2 .
With the Valuation fixed at 1 in Fig. 4, we see that the cross-section only crosses the T -axis once at T = 3.8435. Thus, a
negative Price Trend of any size does not have enough of an impact on the Relative Price Change to counteract the positive one
standard deviation change in Valuation. However, a positive change in Price Trend of more than 3.8435 standard deviations
results in a negative Relative Price Change and exhibits overreaction.
Fig. 5 depicts the relationship between Relative Price Change and Valuation (holding Price Trend constant). This
relationship is essentially linear suggesting that an increase in value is always positive for stock prices:
R(0, D) = 0.0003 + 0.0017(0) + 0.0029D 0.0001(0)2 0.0001(0)3 + 0.0001D2
0.00001D3 0.0003(0)D 0.0001(0)2 D 0.00001(0)D2 .
Fig. 6 displays a contour plot of the Relative Price Change function, R(T , D), for R = 0.01, 0, and 0.01, which correspond
to relative price changes of 1% and 0%. These provide an intriguing view of the nonlinear relationship between the
Valuation and Price Trend variables.
5. Conclusion
We have presented an empirical methodology that is capable of testing almost any quantitative hypothesis involving
dynamics of asset prices. We have utilized the mixed effects regressions on a set of independent variables: valuation, short
and long term trends, short and long term volatility, the M2 money supply, volume trend and resistance. The results exhibit
strong statistical support for the assertion that the short term price trend is a factor that tends to increase trading prices. The
magnitude of this effect is almost half of that for valuation. Unlike some previous studies in which raw data were analyzed,
displaying a tiny effect for trend, our study shows that the effect of the trend is very important. This is largely due to a
methodology in which the changes in valuation (amounting to noise) are considered in a multi-regression in an appropriate
form. Similarly, positive statistically significant coefficients were found for short term volatility, volume trend and the money
supply. The latter confirms the assertions of the asset flow theory (supported by experiments and empirical studies cited in
Section 2) that additional cash fuels trading price increases.
The positive coefficient obtained for short term volatility is surprising in the context of classical finance since the inverse
riskreward relationship stipulates that high volatility should be interpreted as greater risk that would diminish the price
that traders would pay for the stock. The positive coefficient for short term volatility may be explained by the hypothesis
that traders are attracted to higher volatility as it offers the opportunity for greater profits. As more capital is attracted, the
increased level of cash (as shown with the money supply and prior studies) would tend to bolster prices. The role of long
term volatility is quite small compared to trend. Also, it is more ambiguous and complicated. While we obtain a negative
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1149
Fig. 5. A cross-section of Fig. 1 is represented with the Price Trend variable held constant, T = 0. This shows that the Relative Price Change variable, R, is
essentially linear in the Valuation variable, D.
10
D -2
-4
-6
-8
-10
-12
-14
Fig. 6. Using the coefficient values from Regression 3, one can express the following days Relative Price Change, R, as a cubic function of two variables,
the Price Trend, T , and the Valuation, D. This figure is a contour plot of this function. The curves represent level sets on which R is held fixed at 1% and
0%. The innermost curve, i.e. the union of the inner loop and the curve closest to the right side of the frame, corresponds to R = 1, the middle curve to
R = 0, and the outermost curve to R = 1.
coefficient (provided the historical time is not taken into account) consistent with the expectations of classical finance, as
shown in Regression 1, we also find that the coefficient is positive in Regression 2, where the time variables are included.
However, the coefficient has only about one-tenth of the magnitude of the short term trend. A basic classical finance tenet is
that investors are rational and seek to avoid risk and increase return (see e.g. [20]). This is followed by the assumption that
risk can be identified with volatility. Our study shows that the only interpretation in which this classical concept is upheld
is that a time period exhibiting high volatility is followed by a period of slightly more negative price changes.
1150 G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151
Table 5
Regression 4 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
The methodology uses a technique of standardizing the data prior to executing the linear regressions. This has the salient
feature that it allows direct comparison of the distinct hypothesized factors. In particular, it allows us to go beyond the
question of whether these effects are actually present to the possibility of quantifying, for the first time, their relative
importance. In particular the aggregate effect of short term trend, short term volatility and M2 money supply is comparable
to that of the valuation.
Another feature of our methodology is that the data are standardized with respect to individual stocks. This tends
to mitigate the distortion introduced by the large variations in magnitudes of the independent variables. As a practical
application, one should be able to obtain more accurate results by performing the regressions on only one stock of interest at
each time. Although the statistical significance and scientific impact would be diminished, the practical results for prediction
would be enhanced.
While our sample is inadequate to make a strong statistical assertion on resistance (the tendency for prices to move down
while nearing a recent high), the fact that the size of the coefficient is comparable to most of the other variables (except short
term trend and valuation) suggests that a larger sample could result in establishing this as an important factor.
The growing evidence for factors influencing asset market dynamics may appear, upon cursory analysis, to be
contradictory. For example, there are studies that demonstrate the presence of underreaction, exhibited by the continuation
of a price trend. There are also studies showing that overreaction is present as prices reverse course. The statistical analysis
involving 111,356 data points supports our assertion that the presence of both under- and overreaction is a manifestation
of the underlying nonlinearity of trader motivations. In particular, Fig. 1, which displays the daily return as a function of
trend and valuation, shows that while an uptrend is positive for stocks in one region (e.g., the uptrend is not too large and
the valuation range is far from zero), it may be negative in another region (e.g., when the trend is very large or the valuation
change is large). Thus, nonlinearity is the key to understanding competing motivations.
By incorporating the squared and cubic price trend and valuation terms as well as the interactions (up to third order)
of these two key variables, we are able to express the relative price change as a nonlinear function of the price trend and
valuation. Plotting this function in various ways (3d and 2d with valuation constant, as well as level sets) illuminates the
nonlinear relationship between these variables and renders a quantitative and empirical explanation for how the competing
effects of overreaction and underreaction can coexist within the same data set. For example, it yields the precise information
that a positive change in valuation at the level of one standard deviation will not be counteracted, on average, by any short
term trend. However, a similar negative change in valuation will be balanced by a positive trend at the level of 1.38 standard
deviations.
As noted above, the key to obtaining meaningful coefficients for the independent variables involves formulating a suitable
definition for the valuation. To illustrate this point, suppose that we perform a linear regression in the manner of most
financial studies, i.e., without making any attempt to subtract out the valuation. If we consider the most significant of the
remaining variables, namely, Price Trend, then we obtain the relation below.
Regression 4. As a baseline we consider the linear regression with the single independent variable, Price Trend:
R(t + 1) = 0 + 1 T (t ).
The regression results are included in Table 5.
From this we see that although the Price Trend is statistically significant, the coefficient has one-tenth of the magnitude
of the previous regressions, and the opposite sign. Without accounting for changes in valuation, a one standard deviation
change in the Price Trend variable corresponds to a change of 0.00016 in the Relative Price Change.
Regression 5. By incorporating the Valuation variable in the regression, namely,
R(t + 1) = 0 + 1 T (t ) + 2 D(t ),
we can readily demonstrate that the true effect of the Price Trend is extracted. Indeed the regression results are summarized
in Table 6.
Hence, the Price Trend is now much more significant (t-value 20.25 versus 3.34), positive, and approximately 10 times
larger in magnitude. By accounting for the Valuation, we find that the trend in price is statistically significant and has roughly
half the effect of Valuation on the Relative Price Change.
From these two regressions, we can conclude that ignoring the changes in value (as most studies have done in the past)
leads to coefficients for Price Trend that are essentially useless in terms of practical trading.
G. Caginalp, M. DeSantis / Nonlinear Analysis: Real World Applications 12 (2011) 11401151 1151
Table 6
Regression 5 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
Table 7
Regression 6 results.
Term Value Std. error t-value p-value
Regression 6. To further explore the nonlinear relationship between Price Trend and Valuation we consider a regression that
incorporates all of the significant variables from Regression 2 as well as the Price Trend and Valuation interaction terms.
This regression has the form:
R(t + 1) = 0 + 1 T (t ) + 2 D(t ) + 3 M2(t ) + 4 STV (t ) + 5 LTV (t ) + 6 LTT (t ) + 7 VT (t ) + 8 T 2 (t )
+ 9 T 3 (t ) + 10 D2 (t ) + 11 D3 (t ) + 12 T (t )D(t ) + 13 T 2 (t )D(t ) + 14 T (t )D2 (t )
+ 15 Time(t ) + 16 Time2 (t ) + 17 Time3 (t ).
Comparing the results in Table 7 with those from Regression 3, we find that the Intercept, Price Trend2 , and Price Trend
Valuation2 terms are the only variables with significant (i.e., greater than 20%) relative changes in the magnitudes of their
coefficients.
References