OrderFlowAndTheMonetaryModelOfExc Preview
OrderFlowAndTheMonetaryModelOfExc Preview
OrderFlowAndTheMonetaryModelOfExc Preview
Menzie D. Chinn*
University of Wisconsin, Madison
and NBER
and
Michael J. Moore**
Queen’s University, Belfast,
Northern Ireland, United Kingdom
Abstract
We propose an exchange rate model which is a hybrid of the conventional
specification with monetary fundamentals and the Evans-Lyons microstructure
approach. We argue that the failure of the monetary model is principally due to
private preference shocks which render the demand for money unstable. These shocks
to liquidity preference are revealed through order flow. We estimate a model
augmented with order flow variables, using a unique data set: almost 100 monthly
observations on inter-dealer order flow on dollar/euro and dollar/yen. The augmented
macroeconomic, or “hybrid”, model exhibits greater in-sample stability and out of
sample forecasting improvement vis a vis the basic macroeconomic and random walk
specifications.
One of the most enduring problems in international economics is the ‘exchange rate
The in-sample and forecasting goodness of fit of these models were evaluated by
Cheung, Chinn and Garcia Pascual (2005 (a) and (b)). Their conclusions are not
unfamiliar:
Recently, Gourinchas and Rey (2007) have used the external budget constraint to
devise a sophisticated measure of external imbalance which has forecasting power for
exchange rate changes over some horizons.1 However, the framework seems to be
limited to some of the institutional features of the US dollar and is ex-ante silent on
the timing and the composition of external adjustment between price and quantity.
The most theoretically and empirically startling innovation in the literature has been
exchange rate movements. In a series of papers Evans and Lyons2 (2002, 2005,
1
See an extended analysis on bilateral exchange rates using this framework in Alquist and Chinn
(2008).
2
These are just examples of their work. For a fuller account, see
http://www9.georgetown.edu/faculty/evansm1/Home%20page.htm
1
proportion of the high-frequency variation in exchange rates. Though their theoretical
framework is also very convincing, it was difficult for them to evaluate its merit at
standard macroeconomic frequencies because they were working with a daily data set
over four month period. Our data set is monthly over eight years. The variables in
the monetary model – money stocks, prices, measures of output are only available at
monthly or lower frequencies. The span and frequency of our data set enables us to
nest both the Evans Lyons model and the monetary within a hybrid general
specification. Other writers, most notably Berger et al. (2008), have also obtained
access to a long run of EBS order flow data – 6 years from 1999 to 2004 – but they
of the data we employ in this study. Section 4 replicates the Evans and Lyons (2002)
results at the monthly frequency, confirming the fact that the order flow data we use
(and the sample period examined) are representative. Our empirical methodology and
basic in-sample results are discussed in Section 5. The next section reports some of
the robustness tests implemented. Section 7 reports the preliminary results of our in-
sample and out-of-sample validation exercises that demonstrate the predictive power
of the hybrid model. The final section makes some concluding remarks.
2. Theoretical Background
The Evans-Lyons model (Evans and Lyons, 2002) introduces the portfolio shifts
model which argues that changes in exchange rates are determined by a combination
of innovations in public and private information. The latter is revealed through order
2
flow which is measured as the net of buyer over seller initiated trades in the foreign
as innovations in the international interest differential though Evans and Lyons are at
pains to emphasise that, in principle, they are referring to all public information
relevant to exchange rate determination. They imply that this includes international
money, output and inflation differentials and all of the variables that might be
considered in the standard monetary model. The only reason that they this is not
reflected in their empirical work is that their data is daily and the only type of public
fully solved out in Killeen, Lyons and Moore (2006) which expresses the level of
t t
Pt = λ1 ∑ ΔRτ + λ2 ∑ X τ (1)
τ =1 τ =1
In their notation (which we do not use in the rest of this paper), Pt is the level of the
exchange rate, ΔRτ is the public information innovation at time τ , X τ is order flow at
time τ and the λi , i = 1, 2 are parameters which are explicitly solved for in that paper.
A key feature of equation (1) to which we appeal in this paper is that order flow and
public information innovations are cumulated over time. In other words, λ1 governs
the level of public information while λ2 is the sensitivity to cumulative order flow. In
The discussion in the Introduction summarises the consistent lack of success of the
persists in believing that it must hold in some form at least in the long-run. In the
theoretical appendix, a model is sketched which suggests how this might be achieved.
3
In essence, it argues that one of the parameters of the utility function is privately
known and can only be revealed through trading. In the appendix example, the
parameter which governs the individual demand for money is stochastic and indeed
follows a unit root process. Because of its non-stationarity, this effect does not wash
out in the aggregate. Because it is idiosyncratic, its impact can only be observed
through trading i.e. through order flow. This is a simplified way of thinking about the
Flood and Rose (1999). More specifically, the existence of shocks to liquidity
demands is one of the motivations offered for the link between order flow and
exchange rates in the seminal paper by Evans and Lyons (2002). The contention of
this paper is that cumulative shocks to liquidity demand, as specified by equation (5)
in the theoretical appendix, are captured by cumulative foreign exchange order flow.
Bjønnes and Rime (2005) and Killeen, Lyons and Moore (2006) provide evidence that
exchange rate levels and cumulative order flow are cointegrated in high frequency
data. If equation (9) in the theoretical appendix were correct, exchange rate levels
should be cointegrated with both cumulative order flow and the traditional vector of
The model is merely illustrative. Any latent variable or preference shift could
conceivably perform the same function. In addition, the model must be incomplete
because it does not specify a Bayesian updating process about private information.
What it does achieve is to show that equation (1) and the monetary model are not
incompatible.
4
3. Data
The data is monthly from January 1999 to January 2007 (see the Data Appendix for
greater detail, and summary statistics). Two currency pairs are considered:
An attractive feature of the data is its long span of inter dealer order flow. It is by no
means the first paper to have a long span of order flow type data – see Bjønnes, Rime,
and Solheim (2005) and its citations – but to the best of our knowledge, it is the
longest span of inter dealer order flow to be used in an academic setting. The data
was obtained from Electronic Broking Services (EBS), one of the two major global
• Order Flow: Monthly buyer initiated trades net of seller initiated trades, in
For dollar/euro, the base currency is the euro while the dollar is the base currency for
OFEURUSD into dollar terms so that the order flow variable enters into each
equation analogously.3 In some of the robustness checks, the order flow variables are
normalized by volume (also adjusted into dollar terms). The untransformed order flow
3
OFUSDJPY is multiplied by a negative sign to generate the corresponding yen variable.
5
A note of caution about the definition of order flow is worth entering at this point.
We follow the convention of signing a trade using the direction of the market order
rather than the limit order. For the current data set, this is carried out electronically by
EBS and we do not need to rely on approximate algorithms such as that proposed by
Lee and Ready (1991). The reason why the market order is privileged as the source
of information is that the trader foregoes the spread in favor of immediacy when she
hits the bid or takes the offer in a limit order book. Nevertheless, an informed trader
can optimally choose to enter a limit order rather than a market order though she is
less likely to do so. For a fuller discussion of this issue, see Hollifield, Miller and
The other data are standard. Monthly data were downloaded from the IMF’s
International Financial Statistics. The exchange rate data used for prediction are end-
of-month. The exchange rate data used to convert order flow, as well as the interest
rate data, are period average, which is most appropriate given the order flow data are
in flow terms. In our basic formulation, money is M2 (the ECB-defined M3 for Euro
The key variables, the exchange rates and transformed order flow series are displayed
in Figures 3 and 4 for the dollar/euro and dollar/yen, respectively. Note that in these
graphs, the exchange rates are defined (dollar/euro and dollar/yen) and order flow
4
As noted in Section 6, we also check to see if the results are robust to use of M1 as a money variable,
or real GDP (at the quarterly frequency) as an activity variable. M1 and real GDP are also drawn from
IFS.
5
Note that we have also run the regressions with the raw order flow and cumulative demeaned raw
order flow data. The qualitative aspects of the regression results do not change – order flow remains
important in both a statistical and economic sense.
6
4. Replicating the Evans-Lyons Results
In order to verify that the results we obtain are not driven by any particular
idiosyncratic aspects of our data set, we first replicate the results obtained by Evans
∆ ∆ (2)
Where i are short term nominal interest rates and of is order flow. The estimates we
obtain are reported in Table 1. Several observations are noteworthy. First, the
(with the anticipated sign6) when the order flow variables are omitted, and then only
in the dollar/euro case. Inclusion of the order flow variables reduces the economic and
statistical significance of the interest rate differential in this case. In short, any
dispelled. The results are, however, consistent with those of Berger et al. (2008) who
argue that the Evans Lyons result is relatively weaker at lower frequencies.
5. Empirics
We implement the rest of the portion of the paper in the following manner.
6
The negative slope is consistent with a sticky price monetary model story, though not, of course with
uncovered interest parity.
7
fundamentals (here taken to be the flexible-price model determinants – money,
All the monetary fundamentals – money, industrial production and interest rate
differentials – and cumulative order flow, appear to be integrated of order one (see the
Data Appendix).7 The first step in the cointegration test procedure is to determine the
optimal lag length. We evaluated the VAR specifications implied by the monetary
model and the monetary model augmented by the order flow variable (in this case
The Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) typically selects a fairly short lag length of
one or two lags in the VAR specification. However, these specifications also typically
when three lags are included in the VARs. Hence, we fix on the three lag
specification.
Using this lag length, we applied the Johansen (1988) maximum likelihood procedure
to confirm that the presence of cointegration, and to account for the possibility of
7
We use the Elliott-Rothenberg-Stock DF-GLS test (Elliott, Rothenberg and Stock, 1996), allowing for
constant and trend. The ERS unit root test is more powerful than the standard ADF test. In no case is
the unit root null rejected for the levels data. In all cases – save the US-euro area interest differential –
the unit root null is rejected for the first differenced data. Even in the case of the interest differential,
the non-rejection is borderline.
8
multiple cointegrating vectors. Table 2 reports the results of these tests. The first
monetary fundamentals. Columns 4-6 pertain to the monetary model augmented with
cumulative order flow. Columns [1] and [4] pertain to model specifications allowing a
constant in the cointegrating equation, columns [2] and [5] to ones allowing a constant
in both the cointegrating equation, and in the VAR, and columns [3] and [6] allowing
intercept and trend in the cointegrating equation, and a constant in the VAR (in all but
columns [1] and [4], deterministic time trends are allowed in the data).
The numbers pertain to the implied number of cointegrating vectors using the trace
and maximal eigenvalue statistics (e.g., “3,1” indicates the trace and maximal
estimated in the VARs, we also report the results obtained when using the adjustment
to obtain finite sample critical values suggested by Cheung and Lai (1993). Hence,
“Asy” entries denote results pertaining to asymptotic critical values, and “fs”, to finite
using only monetary fundamentals (money, income and interest rate differentials).
The specification selected by the AIC for the monetary model is one that includes a
constant in the cointegrating equation and the VAR equation for the dollar/euro, and
one including a constant and trend in the cointegrating vector and a constant in the
detected.
9
In contrast, for the hybrid model, the AIC indicate the presence of a constant in both
the cointegrating relation for the dollar/euro, and a constant in both the cointegrating
relation and VAR for the dollar/yen. Using the finite sample critical values does not
change the conclusions. The evidence for cointegration is relatively strong for the
The resulting conclusions are suggestive that there is one cointegrating vector in
almost all cases, at least insofar as the hybrid model is concerned. Hence, we proceed
in our analysis assuming only one cointegrating vector.8 This conclusion points to an
important role for cumulative order flow in determining long term exchange rates but
We estimate the short run and long run coefficients in an error correction model
should take on a negative value significantly different from zero, if the exchange
cointegrating coefficients.
8
Note that while we could rely upon the Johansen procedure to obtain estimates of the long run and
short run coefficients, we decided to rely upon estimation of the single equation error correction
specification, in large part because the estimates we obtained via the Johansen procedure were so
implausibly large, and sensitive to specification.
10
Equation (2) invokes the Granger representation Theorem (Engle and Granger, 1987).
section 5.1 has an error correction representation. Note that equation (2) does not
provide for contemporaneous order flow nor indeed any contemporaneous first
differenced variable to enter the ECM. However, this specification is implied if order
flow is weakly exogenous for the cointegrating vector (Johansen, 1992). We can test
for this condition using a likelihood ratio test on the restriction that order flow does
The test results are reported in Table 2.2. Using asymptotic critical values, the weak
level. However, Bruggeman (2002) notes that in small samples, the likelihood ratio
obtain the test statistics reported in Table 2.3. Now, we fail to reject weak exogeneity
in all cases.
Using the theorem of Johansen (1992), we implement equation (2) by adding the
current value of order flow as a right hand side variable. Conveniently, the Johansen
result also enables us to estimate using OLS without instrumenting the current value
We estimate (3) using nonlinear least squares, with two lags of first differenced
monetary fundamentals. When the order flow fundamentals are introduced, they are
11
lagged cumulative variable, and then finally with both these variables, as well as two
models with short lags (a lag or at most two of first differenced terms), with perhaps
models, we present the results of models incorporating two lags of the differenced
monetary fundamentals.
The results of estimating these equations for the dollar/euro and dollar/yen are
reported in Tables 3 and 4, respectively.10,11 Note that the error correction term is in
all cases negative and statistically significant. This implies that the exchange rate
reverts to a conditional mean, confirming some form of long run linear relationship.
Since the estimation procedure does not necessarily lead to consistent estimates of the
standard errors for the long run coefficients, we report the coefficient estimates
10
We rely upon a single equation estimation methodology focused on the exchange rate as the
dependent variable, which is appropriate if the “fundamentals” are weakly exogenous. We tested for
this condition, and this is typically the case.
11
In all cases, the specifications pass diagnostics for serial correlation, as indicated by the Q-statistics
and Breusch-Godfrey LM test.
12
We use two leads and two lags of the right hand side variables in the DOLS regressions. The long
run covariance estimate incorporates a Bartlett kernel, with Newey-West bandwidth set to 4). Point
estimates and standard error estimates obtained using the Phillips-Hansen FMOLS procedure are
similar to these DOLS estimates.
12
Turning first to Table 3, columns [1]-[2], one finds little evidence that the exchange
rate reacts to the long run monetary fundamentals, at least in the manner indicated by
the simple monetary model (note that while order flow is included in columns [2] , it
is not in the cointegrating relation). The money stock variable coefficient points in the
wrong direction. All the other coefficients are not statistically significant.
explained rises dramatically, from 0.02 to 0.34. The estimated short run effect is
1.889, indicating that a $1 billion dollar increase in order flow leads to a dollar
The cointegration tests suggest that cumulative order flow does enter into the
signed.
The error correction specification, allowing the cumulative order flow to enter into the
long run relationship, explains an even larger proportion of variation in the exchange
rate change (37%). Finally, allowing the inclusion of two lags of order flow slightly
raises the proportion of variation explained (38%), although the lagged order flow and
13
Turning to the dollar/yen results in Table 4, one finds in column [1] a significant error
correction term, although the money coefficient is again wrong-signed. However, the
equation does not explain a large proportion of variation. Only when the
contemporaneous order flow variable is included (column [2]) does the fit improve
substantially, to 57%. Interestingly, in the case of dollar/yen rate, the inclusion of the
cumulative order flow in the long run relationship (columns [3]-[4]) does not have a
column [4] is consistent with the cointegration test results for the hybrid model, it is
To sum up the results from this section, there does appear to be significant evidence
augmented by cumulative order flow. Even when cumulative order flow might be
argued to not enter into the long run relationship (i.e., in the case of the dollar/yen), it
is clear that order flow does enter into the short run relation.
6. Robustness Tests
• M1 vs M2
• Inclusion of inflation
14
Order flow issues. The order flow variables are included in dollar terms. It is
reasonable to scale net order flow variable by the volume of order flow. The results in
the Evans and Lyons regressions are basically unchanged. Using this normalized
order flow variable in the hybrid model specifications (conforming to columns [2]-[3]
in Tables 3 and 4) does not result in any appreciable change in the results.13
Money measures. While the substitution of narrow money for M2 results in slightly
different results, particularly with respect to the short- and long-run coefficients on
the money variable, the impact on the general pattern of estimates is not significant. In
particular, the coefficient on the cumulative order flow variable remains significant.
sticky-price monetary model. Over the given sample period, the inflation differential
substantive changes in the findings regarding the importance of order flow variables.14
one can switch to quarterly data. The benefit is that one can then use real GDP as a
measure of economic activity, rather than the more narrow industrial production
13
Another point related to order flow is that net order flow is positive in the raw data. This could be
ascribed to a data recording error. As long as the level of order flow enters in the level in the error
correction specification, then only the constant is affected. However, when the cumulated order flow
enters into the long run relationship, a deterministic trend is introduced. We can address this by
allowing a deterministic trend in the data. A direct way to address this issue is by demeaning the raw
order flow data. Using demeaned order flow has no impact on the order flow coefficient, but changes
substantially the long run coefficient on cumulative order flow.
14
A previous version of this paper incorporated sticky-price monetary fundamentals, with inflation
measured as annualized month-to-month CPI growth rates. Using 3 month growth rates yielded similar
results.
15
variable. As a check, we re-estimated the error correction models (both in a
using OLS). What we find is that we recover the same general results as that obtained
using the monthly data. While money coefficients remain wrong-signed (as do income
variables for the yen), the order flow and cumulative order flow variables show up as
7. Model Validation
stability of the monetary versus hybrid models. The second is a comparison of out-of-
the sample observation by observation, with the parameter estimates updated with
each additional observation. The recursive residual for period t is the actual minus
predicted based on the parameter estimates obtained on the sample up to t-1. This
process of recursive estimation is repeated until all the sample points have been used.
If the estimated model is valid, then the resulting errors should be i.i.d., and normally
distributed. The one-step ahead forecast error resulting from these sequential
predictions can then be tested, after scaling by the standard deviation, to see if they
16
In Figures 5-8, the recursive residuals and ±2 standard error bands are illustrated for
the error correction models.15 We compare the monetary against hybrid models
(respectively, specifications in columns [1] and [4] of Tables 3 and 4), for the
substantial instability, with nine structural breaks indicated by the one-step ahead
recursive residuals, using the 10% msl. In contrast, the hybrid model residuals, shown
in Figure 6, indicate only five breaks (only two, using the 5% msl). For the
dollar/yen, the differences are not as striking. Nonetheless, using the 15% msl, the
hybrid model (in Figure 8) exhibits fewer breaks than the monetary model (Figure 7).
Furthermore, the n-step ahead recursive residuals test (essentially a sequence of Chow
tests) indicates instability at the beginning and end of the samples for the monetary
As is well known in the exchange rate literature, findings of good in-sample fit do not
often prove durable. Hence, we adopt the convention in the empirical exchange rate
modeling literature of implementing “rolling regressions.” That is, the error correction
forecasts produced, then the sample is moved up, or “rolled” forward one observation
before the procedure is repeated. This process continues until all the out-of-sample
hand side variables are used. In this sense, our exercise works as a model validation
15
These tests are applied to the unconstrained error correction models estimated by ordinary least
squares, rather than the constrained equations estimated by nonlinear least squares.
17
To standardise the results, we generate our forecasts for the monetary model from the
simple specifications of column (1) in both Tables 3 and 4. For the hybrid model, we
Forecasts are recorded for horizons of 1, 3, and 6 months ahead. We could evaluate
forecasts of greater length, but we are mindful of the fact that the sample we have
reserved for the out of sample forecasting constitutes only three years worth of
observations. Forecasts at the 3 month horizon for the random walk, monetary and
One key difference between our implementation of the error correction specification
and that undertaken in some other studies involves the treatment of the cointegrating
over the entire sample, and then out of sample forecasting undertaken, where the short
run dynamics are treated as time varying but the long-run relationship is not. This
approach follows the spirit of the Cheung, Chinn and Garcia Pascual (2005b) exercise
The results for the dollar/euro are reported in Table 5.1. Mean error, standard errors,
Theil U statistic, and the Clark-West statistic (2007) are reported. The Theil U
statistic is the ratio of the model RMSE to the benchmark model (in this case random
walk) RMSE. Ratios greater than unity indicate the model is outpredicted by the
benchmark model. The Clark-West statistic is a test statistic that takes into account
16
All of these regressions contain the lagged interest differential as regressors. Consequently a
forecasting model based on carry trade returns is nested within the exercise.
18
estimation error, and is normally distributed at 0 under the null that the forecasts from
The first two rows pertain to the no-drift random walk forecast. The next two blocks
of cells pertain to the monetary model, and the hybrid model. The final block is the
Evans-Lyons model, which we include for purposes of comparison. Note that the
Turning first to the dollar/euro exchange rate, notice that monetary model does very
badly relative to the random walk at all horizons. The ratio of the monetary model to
the random walk RMSE (the Theil U-statistic) is 1.6, 1.6 and 2.0 at the 1, 3 and 6
month horizons. In contrast, the mean error is smaller for the hybrid model at all
horizons, and Theil statistic (vis a vis the random walk) is much smaller: 1.1, 0.9, and
Perhaps more remarkable, the RMSE for the hybrid model is smaller than the random
walk at the 3 and 6 month horizons. The upward bias in the model-based RMSE
versus the random walk RMSE (see Clark and West, 2007) suggests that the hybrid
models exhibit noticeable improvement vis à vis the random walk benchmark.
Unfortunately, inspection of the Clark-West statistic indicates that the hybrid model
never outperforms the random walk at conventional significance levels.18 The Evans-
17
The particular specification we use conforms to columns [3] and [7] in Table 1.
18
An order flow augmented sticky-price hybrid model does outperform a random walk at the 17%
significance level, at the 3 and 6 month horizons.
19
Lyons model does particularly badly at all horizons, but the performance is only
statistically worse than that of the random walk at the 6 month horizon.
The results are somewhat different in the case of the dollar/yen. There, by the RMSE
criterion, the hybrid model substantially outperforms the monetary model at all
horizons. However, the Evans-Lyons specification in this case does best, with the
lowest Theil statistic at horizons at all horizons. The specification in column [4] can
[2] outperforms a random walk, according to the Clark-West statistic, at the 5% msl.
Interestingly, all the structural models outperform the random walk benchmark – after
accounting for estimation error. That being said, only the monetary model at the one
noticeable feature is that the hybrid model is the only one that that returns a positive
8. Conclusion
We have laid out a simple and transparent framework in which non-stationary private
liquidity preference shocks give rise to instability in the demand for money and the
apparent failure of the monetary model of exchange rates. Cumulative order flow
tracks these shocks and is a candidate for the ‘missing link’ to augmenting the
explanatory power of conventional monetary models. We show that the hybrid model
beats both the monetary model and a random walk in a simple forecasting exercise.
Berger et al. (2008) concluded that while order flow plays a crucial role in high-
20
frequency exchange rate movements, its role in driving long-term fluctuations is much
In summary, we find substantial evidence to support our proposition that order flow is
is that consumption in country j also depends on the unit root parameter ξ t j . This
therefore on order flow from our interpretation. This may go some distance to explain
work.
21
Data Appendix
End of month data used for exchange rates when used as a dependent variable.
Interest rates are monthly averages of daily data, and are overnight rates (Fed Funds
for the US, interbank rates for the euro area, and call money rate for Japan). In the
Order flow was obtained from Electronic Broking Services (EBS). In order to make
the specifications consistent across currencies, the order flow data is converted to
dollar terms by dividing by the period-average exchange rate (for OFEURUSD) and
by putting a negative in front (for OFUSDJPY). Hence, the exchange rates are defined
(USD/EUR, USD/JPY) and order flow transformed so that the implied coefficient is
positive19. In the regression results (Tables 1, 3 and 4), the order flow variable is
divided by 1,000,000.
In some unreported regressions, the order flows are normalized by volume. Order
flow volume was also converted to dollar terms, in the same manner that order flow
was converted.
19
Any differences in results caused by the choice of numeraire would arise from Jensen’s inequality.
This is, of course, second order.
22
For the quarterly regressions (not reported), we use end-of-period exchange rates, and
the last month of each quarter for interest rates and inflation rates. The income
variable is US GDP (2000$), and for Euro area and Japan, GDP volume (1995 ref.).
For each variable EU, denotes Euro Area, and JP denotes Japan, relative to the United
States variable. LX## is the log exchange rate, M2_## is the relative log M2 money
23
stock, Y_## is the relative log industrial production, I_## is the relative short term
interest rate, Z1## is order flow, and CUMZ1## is cumulated order flow.
Tables A3 and A4 report unit root tests for the variables and their first differences.
24
Theoretical Appendix
Let the utility function be the following special case of a CES function:
θ
θ −1 θ −1
⎡ θ −1 ξj ⎤
⎢( C j ) θ + e θ
t
⎛ M j
⎞ θ
⎥
⎜ j ⎟ ⎥
t
⎢ t ⎝ t ⎠ ⎥
P
∞
⎢
E0 ∑ δ t ⎣ ⎦ (3)
t =0
θ
θ −1
The CES parameter, θ , and the discount rate, δ , are common knowledge but the
parameter governing the demand for money is idiosyncratic and follows a unit root
process as follows:
ξt j = ξt −j 1 + ε t j (4)
The idea that preference shocks can used to explain asset pricing is not eccentric.
This is the main concept behind Campbell and Cochrane (1999) which has already
been applied to an exchange rate setting by Moore and Roche (2010) as well as
Verdelhan (2010).
Bt j
Wt j = Pt j Ct j + M t j + (5)
1 + it j
Where it j is the nominal return on one period riskless bonds and Bt j is the number of
bonds held. Wt j is wealth, the only state variable and the control variables are Ct j , M t j
25
Wt +j1 = Pt +j1Yt +j1 + Bt j + M t j (6)
The solution to this is straightforward and the demand for money (using lowercase
Denoting the home price of foreign currency as st and using PPP, st = ptH − ptF , we
have:
The terms in the square brackets on the right hand side of equation (8) constitute a
standard way of expressing the monetary model. The novel feature is the final term in
curly brackets. Assuming the substitution semi-elasticity of the demand for money, θ
, is ‘small’, variations in velocity for each country’s will be largely driven by ξt j . The
‘exchange rate disconnect’ puzzle is here explained by instability in the demand for
money itself. Since the parameters ξt j (and their relation), are unknown in advance,
they can only be revealed though the act of trading itself i.e. through foreign exchange
order flow.
⎛ ij ⎞
20
In equations (7) and (8), rt j = Log ⎜ t j ⎟ .
⎝ 1 + it ⎠
26
References
Berger, David, Alain Chaboud, Sergei Chernenko, Edward Howorka, and Jonathan
Wright (2008). “Order Flow and Exchange Rate Dynamics in Electronic Brokerage
System Data,” Journal of International Economics, 75, pp. 93–109.
Bjønnes, Geir H and Dagfinn Rime (2005), “Dealer Behavior and Trading Systems in
the Foreign Exchange Market", Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 75, issue 3
(March), pp. 571-605.
Bjønnes, Geir H., Dagfiin Rime and Haakon O.Aa. Solheim (2005), "Liquidity
Provision in the Overnight Foreign Exchange Market", Journal of International
Money and Finance, 24(2), pp. 177-198.
Brüggeman, Ralf (2002), “On the Small Sample Properties of Weak Exogeneity
Tests in Cointegrated VAR models,” Sonderforschungsbereich 373 2002-2, (Berlin:
Humboldt University, January).
Cheung, Yin-Wong, Menzie D. Chinn, and Antonio Garcia Pascual (2005), “What do
we know about recent exchange rate models? In-sample fit and out-of-sample
performance evaluated,” In: DeGrauwe, P. (Ed.), Exchange Rate Modelling: Where
Do We Stand? MIT Press for CESIfo, Cambridge, MA, pp. 239-276 (a).
Cheung Yin-Wong, Menzie D. Chinn and Antonio Garcia Pascual (2005), “Empirical
exchange rate models of the nineties: Are any fit to survive?” Journal of
International Money and Finance ,24, pp 1150-1175 (b).
Clark, Todd E. and Kenneth D. West (2007), “Using Out-of-Sample Mean Squared
Prediction Errors to Test the Martingale Difference Hypothesis,” Journal of
Econometrics, forthcoming.
Elliot, Graham, Thomas J. Rothenberg, and James H. Stock (1996), “Efficient Tests
for an Autoregressive Unit Root,” Econometrica 64(4): 813-36.
Engle, Robert F., and Clive W.J. Granger (1987), “Co-Integration and Error
Correction: Representation, Estimation and Testing”, Econometrica, 55, pp 251-276.
27
Evans, Martin and Richard K. Lyons (2002) “Order Flow and Exchange Rate
Dynamics. Journal of Political Economy, 110(1), pp. 170–180.
Evans, Martin and Richard K. Lyons (2008), “How Is Macro News Transmitted to
Exchange Rates?”, Journal of Financial Economics, 88, pp. 26-50.
Hollifield, B., R. Miller, and P. Sandas, (2004), “Empirical Analysis of Limit Order
Markets”, Review of Economic Studies, 71(4), pp. 1027 - 1063.
Johansen, Søren, and Katerina Juselius (1990), “Maximum likelihood estimation and
inference on cointegration – with applications to the demand for money,” Oxford
Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 52(2): 169–210.
Killeen, William, Richard K. Lyons and Michael Moore (2006), “Fixed versus
Flexible: Lessons from EMS Order Flow”, Journal of International Money and
Finance 25, pp. 551-579.
Lee, C., and M. Ready, (1991), “Inferring Trade Direction from Intraday Data”,
Journal of Finance, 46(2), 733-46.
Meese, Richard, and Kenneth Rogoff (1983), “Empirical Exchange Rate Models of
the Seventies: Do They Fit Out of Sample?” Journal of International Economics 14,
pp. 3-24.
Moore, Michael J. and Roche, Maurice J. (2010), “Solving Exchange Rate Puzzles
with neither Sticky Prices nor Trade Costs”, Journal of International Money and
Finance 29(6), pp. 1151-1170.
Parlour, Christine A., (1998) “Price Dynamics in Limit Order Markets”, Review of
Financial Studies, Volume 11(4), pp. 789-816.
28
Stock, James, and Watson, Mark, 1993, “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrated Vectors
in Higher Order Integrated Systems,” Econometrica 61: 783-820.
29
Table 1: Evans-Lyons specification, 1999M02-2007M01
adj.R sq. 0.05 0.16 0.17 0.15 0.01 0.34 0.35 0.34
N 96 96 96 96 96 96 96 96
Notes: Dependent variable: First log difference of exchange rate, dollars per foreign currency
unit. OLS regression coefficients (Newey-West robust standard errors in parentheses). Bold
face denotes coefficients significant at the 10% marginal significance level. “Int. diff.” is the
money market interest differential, in decimal form, OF is net order flow measured in trillions
of USD.
30
Table 2.1: Johansen Cointegration Test Results, 1999M04-2007M01
[1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6]
Monetary Fundamentals Hybrid
USD/EUR asy 0,0 0,0 0,0 3,1 3,0 3,0
fs 0,0 0,0 0,0 1,0 0,0 1,0
Notes: Implied number of cointegrating vectors using Trace, Maximal Eigenvalue statistics
and 1% marginal significance level. “Asy” (“fs”) denotes number of cointegrating vectors using
asymptotic (finite sample) critical values (Cheung and Lai, 1993). Columns [1] and [4] indicate
a constant is allowed in the cointegrating equation and none in the VAR; columns [2] and [5]
indicate a constant is allowed in the cointegrating equation and in the VAR; columns [3] and
[6] indicate an intercept and trend is allowed in the cointegrating equation and a constant in
the VAR. “Monetary fundamentals” include the exchange rate, money, income, and interest
differentials. “Hybrid” includes the exchange rate, money, income and interest differentials,
and cumulative order flow. Bold italics denote the specification with the lowest Akaike
Information Criterion for the single cointegrating vector case. All results pertain to
specifications allowing for 3 lags in the levels-VAR specification.
Notes: For an explanation of the three specifications [4], [5] and [6], see the notes to Table
2.1. Likelihood ratio test statistic for restriction that order flow does not respond to
disequilibrium, distributed Chi-squared. [p-value for restriction α=0, in brackets].
Table 2.3: Tests for weak exogeneity of order flow, adjusted statistics
[4] [5] [6]
Hybrid
USD/EUR Chi-Sq 2.581 0.358 0.031
p-val. 0.108 0.5496 0.860
Notes: For an explanation of the three specifications [4], [5] and [6], see the notes to Table
2.1. Likelihood ratio test statistic for restriction that order flow does not respond to
disequilibrium, adjusted for small sample (Bruggeman, 2002), distributed Chi-squared. [p-
value for restriction α=0, in brackets].
31
Table 3: USD/EUR Monetary/Order Flow Hybrid Exchange Rate Regression
Results, 1999M04-2007M01
Notes: Dependent variable: First log difference of exchange rate, dollars per foreign currency
unit. Estimates from error correction model, estimated using nonlinear least squares, (Newey-
West robust standard error in parentheses), except for lagged long run coefficients, which are
estimated used DOLS(2,2), using Bartlett kernel, and Newey-West bandwidth set to 4.
Coefficients for first difference terms for monetary fundamentals not reported. OF is order flow
measured in trillions of USD. Adj-R sq., SER, and serial correlation diagnostics for error
correction regression. Q(6) and Q(12) are Box Q-statistics for test of serial correlation of order
6 and 12, respectively. LM(6) is the Breusch-Godfrey LM test statistics for serial correlation of
order 6. [p-values in brackets]. Bold face denotes significance at 10% msl.
32
Table 4: USD/JPY Monetary/Order Flow Hybrid Exchange Rate Regression
Results, 1999M04-2007M01
Notes: Dependent variable: First log difference of exchange rate, dollars per foreign currency
unit. Estimates from error correction model, estimated using nonlinear least squares, (Newey-
West robust standard error in parentheses), except for lagged long run coefficients, which are
estimated used DOLS(2,2), using Bartlett kernel, and Newey-West bandwidth set to 4.
Coefficients for first difference terms for monetary fundamentals not reported. OF is order flow
measured in trillions of USD. Adj-R sq., SER, and serial correlation diagnostics for error
correction regression. Q(6) and Q(12) are Box Q-statistics for test of serial correlation of order
6 and 12, respectively. LM(6) is the Breusch-Godfrey LM test statistics for serial correlation of
order 6. [p-values in brackets]. Bold face denotes significance at 10% msl.
33
Table 5.1: USD/EUR Out of Sample Forecasting Performance, 2004M02-
07M01
Notes: Mean error for out-of-sample forecasting. Newey-West robust standard errors. ***(**)
denotes significance at 1%(5%) marginal significance level. Theil U-statistic is the ratio of the
model RMSE relative to random walk RMSE. A U-statistic > 1 indicates the model performs
worse than a random walk. Clark-West is the Clark-West statistic distributed Normal (0,1).
CW statistic > 0 indicates the alternative model outperforms a random walk.
Notes: Mean error for out-of-sample forecasting. Newey-West robust standard errors. ***(**)
denotes significance at 1%(5%) marginal significance level. Theil U-statistic is the ratio of the
model RMSE relative to random walk RMSE. A U-statistic > 1 indicates the model performs
worse than a random walk. Clark-West is the Clark-West statistic distributed Normal (0,1).
CW statistic > 0 indicates the alternative model outperforms a random walk.
34
50,000 1,800,000
40,000 1,600,000
30,000 1,400,000
20,000 1,200,000
10,000 1,000,000
0 800,000
-10,000 600,000
-20,000 400,000
99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06
OFEURUSD VOLEURUSD
Figure 1: EUR/USD monthly order flow and order flow volume, in millions of euros. Order
flow, left axis; order flow volume, right axis.
60,000 1,100,000
50,000 1,000,000
40,000 900,000
30,000 800,000
20,000 700,000
10,000 600,000
0 500,000
-10,000 400,000
-20,000 300,000
-30,000 200,000
99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06
OFUSDJPY VOLUSDJPY
Figure 2: USD/JPY monthly order flow and order flow volume, in millions of dollars. Order
flow, left axis; order flow volume, right axis.
35
.08
.06
.04
.02
DLXEU
.00
-.02
-.04
-.06
-20,000 0 20,000 40,000
Z1EU
Figure 3: First difference of log USD/EUR exchange rate and monthly net order flow in
millions of USD (purchases of euros)
.06
.04
.02
.00
DLXJP
-.02
-.04
-.06
-.08
-40,000 -30,000 -20,000 -10,000 0 10,000
Z1JP
Figure 4: First difference of log USD/JPY exchange rate and monthly net order flow in
millions of USD (purchases of yen)
36
.08
.04
.00
-.04
.000
.025 -.08
.050
.075
.100
.125 Equation [1]
USD/EUR
.150
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
One-Step Probability
Recursive Residuals
Figure 5: Recursive one step ahead recursive residuals for monetary model, USD/EUR.
.06
.04
.02
.00
-.02
-.04
.000
-.06
.025
.050
.075
.100
Equation [4]
.125
USD/EUR
.150
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
One-Step Probability
Recursive Residuals
Figure 6: Recursive one step ahead recursive residuals for hybrid model, USD/EUR.
37
.08
.04
.00
.000 -.04
.025
-.08
.050
.075
.100
Equation [1]
.125
USD/JPY
.150
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
One-Step Probability
Recursive Residuals
Figure 7: Recursive one step ahead recursive residuals for monetary model, USD/JPY.
.06
.04
.02
.00
-.02
.000 -.04
.025 -.06
.050
.075
.100
.125 Equation [4]
USD/JPY
.150
2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006
One-Step Probability
Recursive Residuals
Figure 8: Recursive one step ahead recursive residuals for hybrid model, USD/JPY.
38
.35
Actual
.30 Hybrid
Random
walk
.25
.20
.15
.10
Monetary
.05
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I
2004 2005 2006
Figure 9: Out-of-sample forecasts of USD/EUR, 3 month horizon
-4.55
Monetary
-4.60
Actual
-4.65
Hybrid
-4.70
Random
-4.75 walk
-4.80
-4.85
I II III IV I II III IV I II III IV I
2004 2005 2006
Figure 10: Out-of-sample forecasts of USD/JPY, 3 month horizon
39