Federalism
Federalism
Federalism
Federalism
International IDEA
Constitution-Building Primer
Federalism
International IDEA Constitution-Building Primer 12
Elliot Bulmer
© 2017 International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance (International IDEA)
Second edition
The electronic version of this publication is available under a Creative Commons Attribute-NonCommercial-
ShareAlike 3.0 (CC BY-NC-SA 3.0) licence. You are free to copy, distribute and transmit the publication as well
as to remix and adapt it, provided it is only for non-commercial purposes, that you appropriately attribute the
publication, and that you distribute it under an identical licence.
For more information on this licence visit the Creative Commons website:
<http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/3.0/>
International IDEA
Strömsborg
SE–103 34 Stockholm
Sweden
Telephone: +46 8 698 37 00
Email: info@idea.int
Website: <http://www.idea.int>
ISBN: 978-91-7671-117-0
Contents
1. Introduction ............................................................................................................. 3
5. Asymmetrical federalism...................................................................................... 21
References ................................................................................................................. 50
Annex.......................................................................................................................... 52
1. Introduction
4 International IDEA
2. What is the issue?
local people while maintaining national unity and the ability to act coherently in
matters of national policy (e.g. Germany, Argentina).
Federalism attempts to reconcile a desire for unity and communality on
certain issues with a desire for diversity and autonomy on others (see Figure
2.1). The question of whether federalism is suitable for a given country (and, if
so, what form federal institutions should take and to what extent the federal
principle should be applied) therefore depends chiefly on the balance between
common interests or identities, on the one hand, and divergent interests or
identities, on the other.
3. Advantages and
disadvantages of federalism
Scale
The origins of democracy can be traced to ancient and medieval city states where
citizens were able to participate directly in political life. Historically, it was
thought that democracy was possible only in small states, where decisions were
made through face-to-face discussions in the town square. The development of
representative institutions enabled democracy to be practised on the scale of the
nation state, but the problem of scale still remained.
Increasing the size of the political unit has a number of consequences. As the
geographical distance between the government and the people grows, the more
difficult it becomes for the people to make their voices heard, the more elites at
the centre begin to dominate the political process and the less likely it becomes
that the rulers will understand the needs, aspirations and priorities of the people.
This can lead to unpopular, inappropriate and unworkable policies, as well as to a
sense of alienation and frustration that can damage the reputation of the political
system as a whole. Federalism can help resolve this problem, since it enables
substantial powers to be exercised at the state or provincial level, in order to give
people greater opportunities to exercise democratic control and to tailor policies
to their own needs, while entrusting to the centre only those powers that need to
be handled centrally.
6 International IDEA
3. Advantages and disadvantages of federalism
Diversity
One of the main benefits of federalism is that it provides a framework for the
recognition of ethnic, religious, linguistic or other cultural communities,
reflecting their desire to be recognized as a people with a distinct identity and
particular interests. By guaranteeing substantial autonomy to such groups,
federalism can allow them to exercise partial self-government through state,
provincial or regional institutions while still sharing certain functions with other
communities through federal or national institutions. By satisfying demands for
autonomy and recognition, a federal constitution may protect minorities, prevent
conflict, increase the legitimacy of democratic institutions and reduce pressure for
secession.
However, federalism (at least as it has traditionally been understood and
practiced) is appropriate only where these communities are territorially
concentrated; if ethnic, religious or linguistic communities are not concentrated
in particular geographical areas, other ways of combining self-rule with shared
rule might be preferable (see section 10 of this Primer on possible alternatives to
federalism).
Federalism is therefore ‘suitable for some countries, [but] not all’ (Anderson
2008: 12). Small and homogeneous countries, if viable as independent units, will
generally have little reason to consider federalism. In a large country, or one with
distinct territorially concentrated minorities, federalism is likely to be high on the
agenda.
sovereign states but the constituent act or fundamental law of a new, composite,
federal state. The federal government did not derive its powers from the states but
directly from the people of the United States as a whole. Under it, US citizens
would be subject to two overlapping authorities—the federal and the state
governments—each having direct legislative power in their respective
constitutionally prescribed spheres of competence. This created the model from
which all subsequent federal systems have been (directly or indirectly) derived.
Through successive waves of democratization, federalism has spread around the
world. Federal systems can now be found in emerging and consolidated
democracies; in common- and civil-law jurisdictions; in countries with
presidential, semi-presidential and parliamentary executives; and on every
inhabited continent. As federalism has spread, and as the number of names by
which federalism is known has grown (see Box 3.1), it has increasingly been used
as a means by which an existing state can decentralize power and, as such, has
become a tool for holding large or diverse countries together in the face of
autonomist or secessionist pressures. Thus we see two approaches to federalism: a
‘coming together’ federalism in which formerly independent countries unite into
a federal state, and a ‘holding together’ federalism in which a formerly unitary
state seeks a federal solution to the problems of scale and diversity.
Federal systems do not always use the term ‘federal’ to describe themselves. The federal level may
also be known as a ‘national’, ‘central’ or ‘union’ government. Constituent units may be known by a
variety of names, including ‘states’ (Australia, Malaysia, USA), ‘provinces’ (Argentina, Canada,
South Africa), ‘regions’ (Belgium, Italy), ‘cantons’ (Switzerland), ‘autonomous communities’ (Spain)
or ‘Länder’ (Austria, Germany). These differences in terminology do not necessarily correspond to
any particular formal models of federalism or to the substantive distribution of powers.
In this Primer, the terms ‘constituent unit’ and ‘subnational unit’ are used interchangeably as a
generic descriptor for such entities. Some such entities claim a distinct national identity or have a
recognized national status, and the use of the term ‘subnational’ is not to be read as implying a
denial of any such claim or recognition.
8 International IDEA
3. Advantages and disadvantages of federalism
greatly expanded access to medical care for low-income citizens despite the
absence of such a provision at the national level.
10 International IDEA
3. Advantages and disadvantages of federalism
Judicialization of politics
A strict constitutional division of power between levels of government may result
in an increased political role for the judiciary, as disputes between the
competences of national and subnational institutions are resolved in the courts
rather than through elected legislatures. In all democratic countries it is necessary
to maintain a careful balance between the independence and neutrality of the
judiciary, on the one hand, and the responsiveness and inclusivity of the judiciary
on the other, but in federal countries striking such a balance is particularly
important.
Think Point 1
Considering the advantages and disadvantages of federalism, how can a federal constitution help
ensure that the advantages are maximized and the disadvantages minimized?
12 International IDEA
4. Distribution of powers
4. Distribution of powers
There may also be list of concurrent powers, as found in India, Nigeria and
South Africa, over which both the federal and the state/provincial authorities may
legislate. In case of any conflict between them, the usual practice is for the federal
legislation to prevail over state/provincial legislation:
• South Africa has two lists: one (schedule 4) enumerating the exclusive
powers of the provincial authorities and the other (schedule 5)
enumerating the concurrent powers shared between the provincial and
national authorities.
• India has three lists: a Union List (schedule 7, list I) enumerating the
exclusive powers of the central legislature, a State List (schedule 7, list II)
enumerating the exclusive powers of the state legislatures and a
Concurrent List (schedule 7, list III) enumerating the areas of shared
authority.
Supremacy
If a constitution makes provision for concurrent powers, it must also—to avoid
conflict or legal uncertainty—specify which level of government has supremacy in
the event of any incompatibility or conflict between them. If supremacy rests with
the national or federal level (e.g. as in Germany and India), then the area of
concurrent legislative authority is essentially that which the federal legislature
chooses, by non-intervention, to leave to the states; at any time, the federal level
can intervene to impose its will over concurrent matters. On the other hand, if
supremacy rests with the states, provinces or regions (which is rare, but was
found, for example, in the 2005 Constitution of Iraq), then concurrent authority
is that which the subnational legislatures choose to leave up to the federal or
national legislature; at any time, the subnational legislatures may reclaim power
from the centre and assert their own legislative authority over a concurrent
matter.
Residual powers
Since not every possible policy area can be provided for, a constitution must also
specify where residual, or unspecified, powers lie. In so-called ‘coming together’
14 International IDEA
4. Distribution of powers
16 International IDEA
4. Distribution of powers
General administration
Education
Economic powers
Source: Adapted from Commonwealth Local Government Forum, Commonwealth Local Government
Handbook 2013/14 (London: Commonwealth Local Government Forum, 2014).
Notes: This table indicates the levels of government at which policy delivery is principally handled.
This may differ from the distribution of legislative power. Attribution of a power to the state/
provincial level does not necessarily exclude further decentralization to local authorities.
To make these choices wisely, it is necessary to consider the degree and types of
autonomy that the subnational units seek, and to understand the reasons why
they seek it. For example, where federalism is a response to cultural diversity,
there will usually be a demand for education, language laws, broadcasting and
matters of cultural policy to be handled by the states, provinces or regions, while
there might be a general willingness to allow aspects of economic, fiscal and
welfare policy to be centralized. Conversely, if, in a culturally homogeneous
society, federalism arises from the desire for more local control over the
distribution of resources, these positions are likely to be reversed.
18 International IDEA
4. Distribution of powers
parties varies widely between different parts of the country, then those in power at
the subnational level may seek to use their powers in order to restrain, counteract,
frustrate, or simply steer a different course from, the national government. Thus,
within the same institutional structures, subnational institutions may have
minimal or maximal approaches to the use of their powers, and may have
cooperative or conflictual relations with the national or federal government,
depending on the partisan composition of the majorities at each level.
This may seem discouraging, since no constitutional agreement can be
definitive, but it also means that (a) federal systems can respond to changing
needs; and (b) those who do not get everything they want from the
decentralization provisions of a constitution at the outset can still pursue their
goals through the constitution as it is applied and adjudicated in future. A federal
constitution, in other words, provides a secure basis for the negotiation of powers
between institutions over time.
20 International IDEA
5. Asymmetrical federalism
5. Asymmetrical federalism
The distinction between the constituent units of a federation and the territories
of a federation usually arises because the territories are deemed unsuitable, in
some way, for full membership of the federation, usually because they have a very
small population, low governance capacity and a lack of fiscal resources (e.g. the
Cocos (Keeling) Islands in relation to Australia). Lands that have been obtained
by a federal country as a result of war might be governed as territories rather than
integrated as members of the federation (e.g. Puerto Rico in relation to the USA).
Although most territories belonging to democratic federations have some form
of representative government for local affairs, the citizens resident in territories
may have fewer political rights than their co-citizens resident in the constituent
units. In the USA, for example, representation is structured through the states, so
US citizens resident in a territory would not be represented in the US Congress
(except by a non-voting member). However, this is not an inevitability; in
Canada, voters in territories are in fact slightly over-represented in proportion to
their share of the total population in the lower house of the national parliament.
22 International IDEA
5. Asymmetrical federalism
Capital territories
Many federations establish a separate capital territory where the federal capital is
located (e.g. Canberra, Australia; New Delhi, India; Abuja, Nigeria; the District
of Columbia, USA). The creation of a capital territory has several advantages.
First, it asserts the neutrality of the federal capital in relation to the constituent
units, thus helping, for example, to avoid allegations of favouritism in the
distribution of federal funds. Second, it protects the personnel and institutions of
the federal government from the potential risk of interference by any state
government under whose jurisdiction they might otherwise fall.
The establishment of a capital territory, distinct from the capital of any
constituent unit, and geographically removed from the capital of the former
unitary state, may also serve as a clear signal of the government’s commitment to
the (physical and geographical) decentralization of power. The degree of
autonomy granted to capital territories varies. In the District of Columbia, all
laws are directly made by the US Congress, while local administration is in the
hands of an elected mayor and city council. In contrast, Delhi, the Indian
National Capital Territory, has (since the 69th Amendment) a form of
government closely resembling an Indian state, with an elected legislative
assembly and chief minister exercising state-like powers.
24 International IDEA
6. The boundaries of constituent units
Area Factors
Economic Efficiency, effectiveness, viability (an argument for avoiding many small or economically poor
affairs units) and grouping economic regions
Political May mean breaking up one or more dominant regions, or a region that may have separatist
balance tendencies, or avoiding a structure with just two or three units (that are often characterized
by divisive politics)
Historic Which people often identify with, and which can serve as a useful reference point and obviate
boundaries the need for detailed consideration of other factors in drawing boundaries
Source: Anderson, G. and Choudhry, S., ‘Constitutional Transitions and Territorial Cleavages’,
International IDEA Working Paper, June 2015, <http://www.idea.int/publications/catalogue/
constitutional-transitions-and-territorial-cleavages>, accessed 28 July 2017
26 International IDEA
7. Institutions of government within constituent units
7. Institutions of government
within constituent units
The ability of each unit to adopt its own constitution means there can be
considerable variation between them. For example, provisions with regard to
electoral systems, terms of office, direct democracy, second legislative chambers
and other details can differ between subnational units in response to particular
needs and preferences.
28 International IDEA
7. Institutions of government within constituent units
8. Fiscal federalism
30 International IDEA
8. Fiscal federalism
This provides the subnational units with a maximum degree of fiscal freedom
and responsibility to their own citizens, as well as fiscal levers through which to
influence economic development, but it may have several adverse consequences,
including:
• economic efficiencies arising from different forms and rates of taxation;
• tax shopping (taxpayers relocating to the least burdensome area) and a
resulting race to the bottom (whereby subnational authorities race to cut
taxes in order to attract businesses, thereby eroding their revenue-raising
ability, with severe implications for public finances and the delivery of
public services);
• increased economic disparities between subnational units; and
• a weak federal government, which becomes overly dependent on the
goodwill of subnational units in order to meet its financial needs. For these
reasons, full fiscal autonomy is rare in federations and more common in
loose confederations or situations of special autonomy.
Borrowing powers
Borrowing is another potential source of revenue for subnational governments.
Federal systems vary in the extent to which they permit subnational governments
to incur debts and the extent to which they guarantee such debts. A federal
guarantee of debts can protect subnational governments from bankruptcy but
may also encourage a lax approach to borrowing and spending unless such
guarantees are accompanied by federal supervision of subnational budgets.
raised from such taxes are to be reserved for use by subnational authorities.
Revenues may be divided on the basis of the location of derivation (i.e. each
subnational unit is entitled to a share of the revenues raised in that unit, meaning
that each unit has incentives to maximize its own tax base, even though this may
increase regional discrepancies) or on the basis of population or assessed fiscal
needs (which can have an equalizing effect between units).
32 International IDEA
9. Federalism and the constitution as a whole
The decision to adopt a federal system will shape the rest of the constitutional
structure, with implications for the structure of the legislature, the constitutional
amendment process and other aspects of constitutional design.
In situations where federalism is adopted primarily as a response to the
diversity of a heterogeneous society, federalism’s commitment to territorial
decentralization cannot be considered in isolation but only in relation to the
whole package of constitutional provisions that form the bargain between
communities, including such matters as language, religion and minority
representation.
In a federal country, the process for amending the constitution might have to
be designed so that it prevents any change to the distribution of powers without
the consent of the subnational units:
• Australian states have a constituent role: reflecting the federal nature of the
polity, sovereignty is shared, through the amendment procedure, between
the people of Australia as a whole and the people of each state as a unit.
Thus, an amendment to the Constitution of Australia must be approved
not only by a nationwide popular majority but also by a majority in at
least four out of the six states.
• In some countries, the role of the subnational units may be invoked only
when the proposed amendment concerns the powers or jurisdiction of
those units or other essential parts of the constitution integral to the
federal arrangement. In India, for example, the constitution can be
amended by a two-thirds majority of votes cast in both houses of the
central parliament, but amendments concerning the distribution of powers
between the central government and the states, the representation of the
states in the central parliament, and the judiciary, as well as certain other
provisions, must also be approved by a majority of the state legislatures.
• In some cases, a unanimity rule may apply. The Constitution of Canada
provides a general amending formula by which amendments must be
approved by the legislatures of two-thirds of the provinces, having between
them at least 50 per cent of the population. This rule was designed to
ensure that each of the two most populous provinces (Ontario and
Quebec) would, in most cases, have a veto over amendments. Certain
specified amendments, however (including those relating to the status of
English and French as official languages and the composition of the
Supreme Court), require unanimous approval by all provinces.
Amendments that specifically limit the powers and rights of provinces
apply only to those provinces adopting the amendment, giving each
province an opportunity to opt out to protect its rights.
• The principle of federalism may be an unamendable provision, protected
by a so-called eternity clause (e.g. Germany). Courts may also decide that
federalism is such an essential and defining feature of the basic structure of
the political system that it is, in principle, beyond the reach of the
amending power (e.g. India).
34 International IDEA
9. Federalism and the constitution as a whole
Think Point 2
If federalism is primarily intended to provide recognition and autonomy for particular ethnic,
linguistic, cultural or religious groups, it is important for those engaged in constitutional
negotiations to consider how these objectives can be balanced and supported by provisions for
inclusion at the centre. What scope is there for trade-offs between autonomy and inclusion? What is
more important: decentralization of power to communities or the inclusion of those communities in
the central government?
36 International IDEA
9. Federalism and the constitution as a whole
Judicial institutions
The judiciary in a federation is often called upon to resolve disputes between the
different levels of government and to make pronouncements on the powers and
responsibilities of each level. This places a special responsibility on the supreme or
constitutional court at the apex of the judicial system, which must have an
unassailable reputation for independence, neutrality and competence. In countries
where federalism is a response to cultural diversity, there might be a need to
ensure the representation of different communities on the court or their balanced
participation in the judicial appointments process. In Canada, for example, one-
third of the members of the Supreme Court must be appointed from Quebec. For
more information on the composition of supreme or constitutional courts, see
International IDEA Constitution-Building Primer No. 4, Judicial Appointments.
38 International IDEA
10. Possible alternatives to federalism
Federalism has many disadvantages. Even when some form of territorial power-
sharing is needed, federalism is not the only way (and not necessarily the best way
in all contexts) of achieving it. There are four major alternatives: confederation,
devolution, regionalism and special autonomy (federacy).
Confederation
In some cases, confederation may be an alternative to federalism. Confederalism
usually implies a looser form of union than is common in modern federalism.
Representation tends to be organized on an intergovernmental rather than elective
basis, with each state government or state legislature sending delegates to the
confederal assembly. States might have weighted votes, in proportion to their tax
base or population, but typically members of a confederal assembly vote en bloc
as state delegations. The powers of the confederal institutions are typically limited
to a very small range of policy areas such as foreign affairs, defence, trade and
possibly citizenship. The decisions of confederal institutions are typically binding
only on the states, which have to translate them into state law, rather than being
directly binding on the people.
This sort of confederal system is sometimes demanded by groups in federal
systems that are seeking greater autonomy than is permitted under the federal
constitution without the destabilizing effects of full independence. Confederal
solutions have historically been proposed, for example, in Belgium, Spain and
Canada.
Devolution
Devolution is a mechanism for decentralizing power without sharing
sovereignty (see Box 10.1. for an example). The essence of devolution is that the
central level (e.g. a national parliament) establishes decentralized institutions (e.g.
a provincial parliament or assembly) and determines the nature and the scope of
the powers that are delegated to those institutions. In principle, if not always
easily in practice, the powers of devolved institutions can be revoked or
overturned, or their institutional arrangements changed, by a unilateral decision
of the central legislature. Devolution is a flexible arrangement that can overcome
some of the difficulties associated with federalism. It does not necessarily require a
rigid constitution or strong judicial review, since most disputes between the
centre and the devolved regions can ultimately be resolved by political
negotiations, not by judicial decisions.
However, this flexibility means that devolution depends on a high degree of
trust and goodwill. If subnational units cannot trust the national legislature to
protect their interests and autonomy by political means, then devolution may
provide insufficient guarantees to the devolved regions.
The United Kingdom consists of four nations: two kingdoms (England and Scotland), a principality
(Wales) and a province (Northern Ireland). Each has its own culture, political parties and
institutions. Previously, it was a unitary state with all parts of the United Kingdom being governed
directly by the British Parliament in Westminster.
Since 1997, a process of devolution of power to Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland has been
taking place, based on specific arrangements for each country, such that each has a different
degree of autonomy. Because the UK has no written constitution, the autonomy of devolved bodies
depends on decisions of the British Parliament, and the balance of powers can in principle be
changed by a unilateral decision of the Parliament.
Regionalism
40 International IDEA
10. Possible alternatives to federalism
the central legislature but permit the amendment of the constitution without the
consent of subnational units. Italy, for example, developed an innovative regional
structure following the restoration of democracy after the Second World War. In
those parts of Italy that had a notable linguistic minority, or that were
geographically removed from the centre by virtue of being an island, this created,
with immediate effect, five special regions (Aosta Valley, Friuli-Venezia Giulia,
Sardinia, Sicily and Trentino-Alto Adige), each with its own constitutionally
guaranteed autonomy. The rest of Italy was subsequently divided into a further
15 ordinary regions, with fewer powers, in a second wave of regionalization in the
1970s. This was mainly in response to demands for better governance. Thus, in
Italy two approaches to decentralization applied: in the special regions, extensive
decentralization was a means of accommodating cultural differences, while in the
ordinary regions decentralization was a means of improving governance.
However, the improvements in governance have been variable, with some regions
performing better than others (Putnam 1994). The constitutional amendment
process allows any five regional councils to demand a referendum on an
amendment unless the amendment is passed by a two-thirds majority in both
houses of parliament.
Locus of legal Ultimately remains Divided between In the country as a In the country as a
sovereignty in the several the several states whole, although whole (in central-
states and the some special level institutions)
federation regions may have a
more bilateral or
conditional status
Extent of Almost all aspects Variable: there is no necessary connection between the formal
decentralization of domestic policy constitutional type and the actual degree of decentralization (either
are determined by in terms of the rangeof legislative powers that are decentralized or
the several states; the fiscal arrangements supporting subnational governments)
confederation
mainly limited to
defence, foreign
affairs and trade
Typical fiscal States raise all of Federal and state National and Varies: may be
arrangements their own legislatures each regional similar to
revenues and have their own legislatures each regionalism, or the
make payments to basis for raising have their own devolved legislatures
confederation to revenue; may be basis for raising may depend on bloc
pay for common some revenue; perhaps grants from the
services redistribution by some central authorities
the federal redistribution
government
between the Some regions may
states have special fiscal
powers
42 International IDEA
10. Possible alternatives to federalism
Representation Confederal authority Typically (but not Varies: regions Varies, but typically
is a congress of always) two may have some devolved
delegates of the houses of a special institutions, being a
states, often with an federal legislature, representation in creation of ordinary
intergovernmental one elected by the the national statutes, have no
character people as a whole, legislature special
and one representation in
representing the central institutions
federal units
Examples Luxembourg in the Australian states, Regions of Italy, Scotland, Wales and
Benelux Union, US states, Indian autonomous Northern Ireland in
Hungary in the Austro- states, Canadian communities of the UK
Hungarian Empire provinces, Spain
Argentine states
Countries that are difficult to classify, such as Spain or South Africa, may be
considered by some as regionalist but by others as federal (or perhaps as quasi-
federal or as federal in all but name). Besides, these formal differences are not
always reflected in the degree of substantive decentralization. It is not necessarily
the case, for instance, that a formal federation is more decentralized, in substance,
than a regionalized or devolved state. Spain, for example, does not formally define
itself as a federation, but some of its autonomous communities (especially those
with special historical rights, such as the Basque Country) have extensive and
well-entrenched autonomy, while some formal federations, such as Austria and
Malaysia, are highly centralized.
Moreover, these labels may not be very helpful during the negotiations and
deliberations leading to the adoption or reform of a constitution. In a
constitution-building process, some participants may become symbolically
attached to labels like ‘federalism’ or ‘regionalism’. It would be wise, instead, to
first consider the practical needs of the country and of its particular subnational
units, and then to think about how these needs can best be met through a
constitutional design that is both workable and broadly acceptable without
getting too fixated on whether the resulting constitutional framework should be
classified as federal, regional or devolved.
During the 1980s and 1990s, many in Scotland sought to establish a Scottish Parliament that would
have broad legislative powers over domestic affairs. This was, however, strongly opposed by the
British Government. Instead, the UK made use of a variety of alternatives to macro-decentralization.
These ranged from the symbolic (e.g. the return of ‘the Stone of Destiny’, a historical object of
cultural significance, to Scotland) to the institutional (e.g. allowing Scotland to be over-represented
in parliament, in proportion to its share of the British population, or strengthening the legislative
role of the Scottish Grand Committee).
One of the measures attempted was to reform local government in Scotland, creating a new
structure of 32 single-tier local authorities. It was hoped that such local devolution would outflank
demands for national devolution (to a Scottish parliament). These measures proved unsuccessful,
however, and by the time the question was put to the people in a second referendum, in 1997,
there was a broad public consensus in favour of creating a Scottish parliament.
Non-territorial autonomy
44 International IDEA
10. Possible alternatives to federalism
India, for example, Muslims, Hindus and Christians have their own law codes
governing matters such as marriage and divorce: a Muslim man in India may
lawfully enter into a polygamous marriage; a Hindu man may not. In this sense,
law is personal rather than territorial, and, for these purposes, two neighbours
may be subject to the jurisdiction of different laws. Such decentralization of the
law may be accompanied by the decentralization of the judiciary. In Kenya, for
example, there are special courts for Muslim citizens, with jurisdiction over
personal status, marriage, divorce and inheritance, and in which judges (kadhis)
must be practising Muslims trained in Islamic law (Constitution of Kenya 2010,
article 170).
Forms of non-territorial autonomy may be also applied on linguistic grounds,
particularly in the field of education. The Canadian province of Ontario, for
example, makes provision for separate English- and French-language school
boards, and for secular and Catholic school boards for each language. By this
means, the French-speaking and English-speaking communities, as well as both
Catholic and non-Catholic citizens, are able to exercise some cultural autonomy
over education.
Proportional representation
One way of encouraging such accommodation at the centre is to adopt a system
of proportional representation for legislative elections. Electoral systems that
award seats on the basis of a plurality or a majority of the votes cast in single-
member districts are likely to exaggerate any differences in voting patterns
between regions. If a majority of the people in a particular region tend to vote
against the party in power at the centre, this is likely to have two undesirable
consequences: first, the party in power at the centre will have little incentive to
pay attention to the needs and interests of the region in question—if it cannot
win a plurality of the votes, it matters little whether it alienates all voters or only
the majority of them; second, the parliamentary delegation of the party in power
at the centre is likely to have few or no members representing the region in
question and is therefore likely to become increasingly out of touch. This is a
recipe for alienation. Proportional representation can address these two problems.
The governing party at the centre might only win a minority of votes in the
region, but those votes will count in terms of winning seats, giving the party
(a) an incentive to pay attention to that region; and (b) a block of members of
parliament elected from that region who understand the region’s needs.
Secession
In some cases, secession may be an attractive solution. Rather than being awkward
cohabitees of a tense and unwieldy federation, it may be better for two countries
to separate and to relate to one another as neighbours. This simplifies governance
arrangements, removing a whole layer of complex federal institutions. Secession
can also help create a smaller, more convenient public space in which democratic
participation can take place; the existence in each state of a more unified demos,
with greater homogeneity of culture, values and interests, may provide conditions
in which the solidarity and social cohesion necessary for effective democracy can
flourish.
A small number of constitutions contain explicit provisions giving the
constituent parts, or certain specified parts, a right to secession. In providing a
right to secession, the constitution can also limit that right or provide procedural
channels for its proper exercise. The 1994 Constitution of Ethiopia, for example,
recognizes the ‘unconditional right to self-determination, including the right to
secession’ of its constituent units, but this right can be exercised only at the
initiative of a two- thirds majority of the members of the legislature of that unit.
Similarly, Nevis, part of the Caribbean nation of St Kitts and Nevis, has a
constitutional right to declare itself independent by a two-thirds majority of the
votes cast in a secession referendum. While such a high procedural barrier may be
an effective guarantee of unity for members of substantial minorities in a
secessionist territory, it may also, depending on the demographics and the
political situation, render a constitutionally protected right to secession difficult
to claim in practice.
The disadvantages of secession may be mitigated when the seceding entities can
meet their needs for security and trade by belonging to a wider international bloc,
such as the European Union, the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) or
other intergovernmental organization. The short-lived Czechoslovak Federation,
46 International IDEA
10. Possible alternatives to federalism
for example, gave way relatively quickly and painlessly to the independent Czech
and Slovak republics, both of which are now members of the EU and NATO.
However, secession is usually only available if the seceding territory is
economically viable and has sufficient state capacity to make independence work;
it might not be a suitable alternative for very small or very poor territories, or
those without a history of stable governance. Moreover, this option is only
attractive if the process of secession can take place peacefully in a mutually agreed
manner; the secession of a territory without the agreement of the central
government may lead to violent conflict and perhaps to a humanitarian crisis that
may then require external intervention. The secession negotiations may need to
consider the rights of minorities in the seceding territory, the distribution of assets
and liabilities, the relocation of inhabitants, the establishment of new state
institutions (such as an army and a diplomatic service) for the territory and
transitional rules for matters such as currency or public pensions. These
arrangements may incur significant costs.
48 International IDEA
11. Decision-making questions
References
The constitutional texts referred to in this Primer, unless otherwise stated, are drawn from the
website of the Constitute Project, <https://www.constituteproject.org/>.
Anderson, G. and Choudhry, S., ‘Constitutional Transitions and Territorial
Cleavages’, International IDEA Working Paper, June 2015, <http://
www.idea.int/publications/catalogue/constitutional-transitions-and-
territorial-cleavages>, accessed 28 July 2017
Bodnar, C. D., ‘Practice and Principle: Asymmetrical Federalism in Canada’,
Paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the Canadian Political Science
Association, Dalhousie University, Halifax, Canada, 2003
50 International IDEA
References
Filippov, M. and Shvetsova, O., ‘Federalism, Democracy and Decentralisation’,
in A. Benz and J. Broschek (eds), Federal Dynamics: Continuity, Change, and
the Varieties of Federalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press 2013)
Irving, H., Gender and the Constitution: Equity and Agency in Comparative
Constitutional Design (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2008)
John Paul II, Centesimus Annus [Encyclical Letter on the Hundredth Anniversary
of Rerum Novarum], 1991, <http://w2.vatican.va/content/john-paul-ii/en/
encyclicals/documents/hf_jp-ii_enc_01051991_centesimus-annus.html>,
accessed 28 July 2017
Annex
<http://www.idea.int>
52 International IDEA
Annex