Systems Theory
Systems Theory
Systems Theory
An Overview
Social Complexity: An Overview
Contents
1. Social Complexity
2. Social Systems
3. Social Agents
5. Institutions
6. Functions
7. Social Structure
9. Self-Organization
10. Synchronization
22. Evolution
Preface
This book is a first of its kind and somewhat experimental in nature, where
we will be drawing upon research from many different areas and using
complexity theory to contextualize it into a coherent paradigm, giving us a
fresh perspective with which to interpret some of the core questions within
the social sciences.
Content
The content is organized into four underlying parts, in each part we will
apply one of the major modeling frameworks from complexity theory to
interpreting social phenomena.
The third part of the book is dedicated to social network analysis, we will
cover the main topics in this new area as we talk about the basics of social
graphs, clustering, network structure and the process of diffusion.
Social Science
We can loosely define social science as the study of human beings and the
relations between those individuals that give rise to macro patterns of
social organization called society. Like all empirical sciences, it is engaged
in the enterprise of trying to describe some subset of phenomena in our
world. In this case, the phenomena of interest is human society, and we do
this by amassing empirical data and developing logically consistent
theoretical models to effectively interpret patterns within that data.
This set of assumptions that support a scientific domain and constitutes the
whole philosophical framework within which they work is called a paradigm.
The Oxford dictionary defines a paradigm as "a worldview underlying the
theories and methodology of a particular scientific subject". The paradigm
or set of assumptions within which the enterprise of modern science
operates was born approximately five hundred years ago with the massive
cultural transformation of the Renaissance and scientific revolution that
gave us the cultural foundations of our modern world.
This new paradigm really came together and first found its most coherent
full expression within the work of Sir Isaac Newton, whose work was
extremely influential for centuries to come and laid the foundations of
modern science and of course, built into this foundation was a set of
assumptions about how the world works. This whole set of assumptions is
called the Newtonian paradigm or the clockwork universe; in slightly more
technical terms it can also be called linear systems theory. Linear systems
theory forms the backbone to all of modern science. It is used in every
domain from physics to biology to economics to psychology.
This approach to the scientific inquiry called analysis was very successful
within classical physics and came to define what modern science is
considered to be and got applied to many different areas throughout the
18th, 19th and 20th century. Its application within the social sciences has
given us what is called methodological individualism used in many different
areas of the social sciences, most prominently within standard economics.
Complexity
We won't go into any more of the detail to this approach but sufficed to say
linear systems theory works well for simple linear systems, that is, systems
that have a finite amount of independent homogeneous elements
interacting in a well-defined fashion with a relatively low level of
connectivity. But this is often not what we see when dealing with social
phenomena. Many social phenomena such as whole economies, social
institutions, cultures, and the human psychology to name just a few are
fundamentally complex in nature. By complex, we mean that they consist of
many, autonomous, diverse components that are highly interconnected and
interdependent. In these complex systems, the scientific underpinnings of
our traditional formal approaches begin to break down.
And this leaves the social sciences somewhat divided in its response to the
question of whether we go on using these formal methods whose
assumptions when applied to social systems are floored, or do we abandon
formal methods altogether. For example, we can see this divide between
economics and sociology where standard economics has fully embraced
linear systems theory, giving it quite powerful formal mathematical models.
But in order for it to do that, it has to package up quite subtle and complex
social phenomenon into a relatively simple set of assumptions, leaving it
subject to continuous critic surrounding its foundational assumptions. While
much of sociology and other social sciences, feels this approach is
throwing the baby out with the bathwater, and continue to pursue their
enquiry without the support of any real coherent formal system. However,
this leaves certain doubts surrounding their status as science, as formal
languages are an integral part of the whole enterprise of science. And this
is giving us what is called economic imperialism where economics, the only
social science that has a formal basis, increasingly dominates the others.
Complexity Theory
Over the past few decades, we have seen the formation of the beginnings
of a formal language for modeling the complex systems that social
scientists study without resorting to reductionist methods, it is called
complexity theory. Complexity theory is based upon very abstract formal
mathematical models, but probably not the kind you are used to. And we
should be clear that although a lot of complexity theory really originates in
mathematics and physics is not another excuse for trying to reduce social
life to little particles of matter that get moved around on mass by forces. It
starts with a recognition that these reductionist methods have their
limitation.
So complexity theory starts with an alternative paradigm to that of analysis.
This paradigm is really inherited from systems theory. Systems theory is
based upon a process of reasoning called syntheses, which is the opposite
of analysis and reductionism. This paradigm is referred to as being what is
called holistic, meaning that it is characterized by the belief that the parts of
something are intimately interconnected and explicable only by reference to
the whole. Syntheses mean the combination of components or elements to
form a connected whole. It is a process of reasoning that describes an
entity through the context of its relations and functioning within the whole
system that it is a part of.
Paradigms like this are always quite abstract, so let's take a quick example.
Let's say we are trying to understand the origins of the First World War.
Well, from an analytical perspective we would talk about how Archduke
Ferdinand was assassinated in Sarajevo and how this effect caused a
reaction from Russia which caused another reaction from Germany which
in turn caused England to react and so on. In this paradigm, we would talk
about the properties of the parts and the cause and effect interactions.
Now, from a systems perspective, we would focus on quite the opposite.
We would be looking at the whole context both in space and the process in
time, the nexus of relations out of which this phenomenon emerged. We
might then talk about how, through industrialization and nationalization, the
international political environment within pre-war Europe self-organized into
a critical state and it was out of this whole context that we got the
emergence of the First World War. The assassination didn't then cause the
war; nothing directly caused the war. It was out of the nonlinear interactions
of many different factors that we got a critical state of the system and out of
that critical state we got these emergent phenomena.
New Models
So this gives us some insight into this alternative paradigm. But how does
this actually translate into models that we can use? Complexity theory
represents a combination of a number of different modeling frameworks
that have developed in different areas in order to deal with complexity. All of
which have in common a focus on the interactions between parts and how
these interactions give rise to emergent phenomena on the macro level.
Agent-based modeling is one good example of this. Agent-based models
are a class of computational model for simulating the actions and
interactions of autonomous agents in order to try and model their effect on
the system as a whole. As an example, we could think about trying to
model the spreading of some virus within a population. We have a
traditional equation-based model called SIR which will describe this
process in a top-down fashion, but we can also describe this with agent
models where we ascribe simple rules to the agents and then run the
program to see what aggregate phenomena emerge from the bottom up.
Tools
Finally, we will talk about the new set of practical methods and tools that
complexity science uses. Complexity science is a science fundamentally
based on computation. The rise of computation within the social sciences is
one of the quiet but major revolutions taking place in contemporary
science. let’s will quote the social network scientist, Duncan Watts in
describing this phenomena as such: "Up until about ten years ago it was
impossible to observe these (social) interactions and it is very, very hard to
do science when you can't observe things, it is very hard to do science
when you can't measure the things you are interested in. And what has
changed in the last ten years or so and why it is so exciting for people like
me to be at the intersection of social and computation science is that the
internet has really unveiled, has really made the invisible visible, has really
given us the capacity to measure the interaction between even hundreds of
millions of people in real time and over extended periods of time. .. it feels
like for many of us in the social sciences, like we have stumbled upon our
equivalent of the telescope, the device, the technology that makes the
invisible visible and historically that has lead to dramatic improvements in
science."
To date, the primary sources of data for social scientist were survey
research, government statistics and one off in-depth studies of particular
people. The statistical databases of governments and the World Bank are
full of information about individual people and their properties. They tell us
almost nothing about the connections between those individuals because
up until very recently we didn't have the computation capacity to manage
and utilize large complex databases of that kind. But with the rise of the
internet and particularly online social networks, this is all changing. We are
going from a limited amount of randomly selected historical data on
individuals to a mass of real data about the connections between people.
This big data is set to revolutionize our insight into human interaction. The
future of the social sciences is a lot to do with the new opportunities that
are arising from these new computational capabilities and data sources.
With these new opportunities for the first time, we have the capacity to not
just model society in terms of individuals and simple statistical interactions,
but instead in terms of context. We have for the first time in a rigorous way
the capacity to map and model context, the context of a choice, the context
of a behavior, and the complex interplay of a lot of different free parameters
all at once. This has always been very difficult because of lack of data and
computational intractability.
These new tools of computation and new data sources are very important,
but at the end of the day they are just tools, they will not in themselves,
help us solve difficult problems within social theory - age-old questions
about the relationship between individual agency and social structure,
questions about the exercise of social power, about the formation of the
individual, about the rise and fall of civilizations. But with these new
computational methods and a new set of sophisticated theoretical tools
from complexity theory, we can apply them to see what fresh insight we can
get on these perennial challenges within the social sciences.
Summary
Social Systems
A social system is then a set of social actors and the relations or ties
between them. Again, we could contrast a social system with a simple set
of people, such as a group of people waiting for a bus, which are simply a
collection of unassociated individuals. But now imagine when the bus
arrives, there is an elderly lady who needs help to get on the bus, so one
person comes to hold the door open and two others give her support on
each side. Now, we have a social system because the individuals are
interrelated and interdependent in affecting the joint outcome. All the
individuals are arranged in a particular fashion or occupy a particular state
in order to perform a collective function; as such the individuals are
interdependent. And this is the same for all social systems, such as a
corporation that has well-defined roles and relations between those roles
through which they perform a collective function of producing some goods
or services. A government is another example of a social system with well-
defined differentiated roles that relate to each other and are interdependent
in performing the collective function of social governance.
Social Actors
Social systems are made up of social actors or what are called agents
within complexity theory. Agents are abstract models of individuals or
organizations which have agency, meaning the capacity to make choices
and to act independently on those choices to affect the state of their
environment. In order to make choices, agents need some set of rules
under which to make those choices. This set of instructions or rules can be
based on some simple linear cause and effect model, such as a trader
choosing to sell a stock if it goes below a certain price. This basic set of
linear rules we call an algorithm. But these choices may be much more
complex such as when choosing whether to change carriers or not. These
more complex decisions are the product of many interacting factors. They
are not the product of simple cause and effect dynamic but they emerge
out of the agent’s representation of its environment and some set of values
called a schema. With this capacity of agency comes autonomy. In choices
and actions, agents define themselves as independent from other things
and thus define their own identity with associated responsibility for their
actions.
Organizations
Complex Interdependency
Agents within social systems have agency; they act based upon their
representation of the world or schema in order to affect some desired
outcome. And thus, as soon as we have two or more agents, we may have
some form of interaction between them as they both follow their agendas.
In this interaction, agents become interdependent. This dynamic of
interdependence is described within social interdependence theory, which
posits two different types of social interdependence, positive and negative.
Positive interdependence exists when there is a positive correlation among
individuals’ goal attainments, meaning that individuals perceive that they
can attain their goals if and only if the other individuals with whom they are
cooperatively linked attain their goals. Negative interdependence exists
when there is a negative correlation among individuals’ goal achievements;
individuals perceive that they can obtain their goals if the other individual
with whom they are competitively linked fail to obtain their goals. Along with
these two types of interaction, we may also have an interaction of simple
exchange which is described within standard economics by ration choice
theory. Here, agents are simply swapping one thing for another in a linear
fashion. These interactions can be formalized within game theoretical
terms. Positive interdependencies are zero or positive sum games,
meaning the whole pie may get bigger through cooperation. Negative
interdependencies are zero or negative sum games, meaning the whole
pies may get smaller through the interaction. Exchange interactions give us
zero-sum games; the whole is not changing, we are simply moving around
who gets what. These different types of interdependencies create attractors
towards fundamentally different types of interaction between agents; that of
cooperation derived from positive interdependence and that of conflict
derived from negative interdependence and trade from interactions of
exchange.
Exchange
Social Structure
Hierarchy
Utilitarian Organization
These different social structures have very different internal dynamics, that
is to say, processes through which the internal social structure changes
over time. The dynamics of hierarchical social systems composed
predominantly of competitive relations are described within sociology by
conflict theory. Conflict theory posits that the dominant strata within the
hierarchy will use their position and resources to maintain their privileged
position. In doing so, they will reduce social mobility and people of merit will
not be able to rise, meaning those in the upper stators become less
competent and there is also the accumulative effect called the rich get
richer, as the whole system becomes more polarized, ultimately leading to
an abrupt discontinuous change. As such conflict is seen as an inherent
part of the social dynamic, as Karl Marx put it “without conflict no progress:
this is the law that civilization has followed to this day.” From the conflict
perspective societies develop, because for every action of oppression there
is an equal and opposite force that accumulates over time as the two
become more diametrically opposed, ultimately leading to a state of
complete conflict and an ensuing regime shift. And this is considered the
primary dynamic which drives this type of social system as it develops over
time.
Adaptation
Evolution
This whole social system exists within some environment and is subject to
long term evolution as that environment changes. This change may be in
technology and economic conditions, such as the rise of the capitalist
system during the early modern era. It may be some change within the
natural environment or changes within the culture and beliefs of that
society, either way, the whole system goes through long-term processes of
change where new functions are required to be performed while others
become redundant.
Agents
Agents Complexity
Individual human agents are most rigorously studied within philosophy and
the behavioral sciences and we will broadly define two different accounts or
approaches to understanding individual social agents. Firstly that of the
behavioral sciences where people are primarily defined by their physiology.
That is, people are understood through their manifest behavior within some
physical environment in terms of motives and logic that transfer inputs from
the senses to outputs of behavior towards desired ends.
Linear Model
Firstly we will briefly outline the paradigm of the behavioral sciences that
follows the method of empiricism primarily within behavioral psychology
and cognitive science. Within this paradigm, social actors are essentially a
product of their environment. The behavioral sciences, as their name
implies, give us an account of social actors through their manifest behavior.
This is an account of people in terms of their senses, motives, physiology
and basic processes of reasoning. More recently, with the rise of cognitive
science, the computational model to human agents has become more
popular.
The fundamental concept of cognitive science is that "thinking can best be
understood in terms of representational structures in the mind and
computational procedures that operate on those structures." This
understanding of agents in terms of their behavior within a physical
environment is adopted as the primary model within mainstream economics
where it has widespread appeal due to its amenability to linear
mathematical models. It is essentially a linear model to how social agents
operate, as a function of stimulus from their environment, cognitive inputs
and outputs and goal-orientated behavior.
As the psychologist Albert Bandura put it: “Much of the early psychological
theorizing was founded on behavioristic principles that embraced an input-
output model linked by an internal conduit that makes behavior possible but
exerts no influence of its own on behavior. In this view, human behavior
was shaped and controlled automatically and mechanically by
environmental stimuli. The individual is a simple product of all these forces
shaping and reinforcing behavior and thus people are seen to have little or
no free will. For decades, the reigning computer metaphor of human
functioning was a linear computational system in which information is fed
through a central processor that cranks out solutions according to
preordained rules. The architecture of the linear computer at the time
dictated the conceptual model of human functioning“
Regulatory System
This basic model to social agents is most clearly expressed through the
idea of a regulatory system, which is a system for effecting, regulating or
controlling its environment. This capacity to regulate its environment gives
the agent the capacity to counterbalance or alter the influence that its
environment has on it, making it at least somewhat independent from its
environment. As such, the capacity to control or influence one’s
environment is a key component in defining the most basic level of
autonomy and agency.
Regulatory systems of all kind require some capacity to sense, process and
actuate. A regulatory system is then the actual apparatus through which the
agent receives information, processes it and then acts, for example for an
individual person this is our senses, that receive information, our brain that
processes that information and our muscles that perform the action. Or we
could also take a government as another example receiving information
about the state of the nation from the bureau of statistics, media and other
sources, with many different government officials analyzing and processing
this information to create a set of actions that are then put in into law and
enforced, acted out by government and social workers and supported by
law enforcement agencies. All of these different components to a regulatory
system need to be working and working together, in order for the agent to
be capable of affecting its environment. If I lose the strength in my muscles
or if a government loses the support of its armed forces it will lose its
capacity to act, which will reduce its autonomy and agency.
Nonlinear Model
In order to get this more complex form of agency, we will need a number of
different components. Agents will need to be endowed with some model or
representation of their environment. Agents will also need to have some
system of logic in order to process information. To able to make
independent choices, they will need some form of a value system on which
to base their choices and in order to act out those choices and affect their
environment, they will need a control system as previously outlined. With
this full capacity of agency comes autonomy. In their choices and actions,
agents define themselves as independent from other entities and thus
define their own identity with associated responsibility for their actions. We
will quickly go over each of these separately.
Schema
The first thing we will need to get agency is some form of what we call a
schema, which is a conceptual model or representation of the agent’s
environment, what might also be called an ontology, a set of conceptual
categories and relations between them. For example, a culture consists of
some body of shared knowledge, such as in Western culture where we
have science as our shared body of knowledge that defines different
categories and how they relate to each other. Along with an ontology, we
also need an epistemology, which is a mechanism for defining and
validating new information. An example of this might be the peer review
system within the scientific community. It is designed to filter new
information, designating it as either valid and incorporating it into the
ontology or invalid and rejecting it. As an example of this on the individual
level, we might think about how we are constantly receiving new
information and cross referencing it with what we already know to check if it
is valid before incorporating it into what we consider to be a fact. This
process is often modeled within computer science using some form of
Bayesian inferences.
Logic
Choices
Agents not only have a schema but they also make choices. In order to do
this, they have to evaluate options. That is to say, they have to have some
form of a value system which defines what is of greater and lesser value to
that agent, this is called an axiology, a system for defining the value of
different entities. These value systems give rise to desires, needs and
wants, that motivate agents into action what is called a teleology. When we
say that agents are teleological, it means that they exhibit goal-orientated
behavior. Their actions are not random, they are specifically designed for
the pursuit of the things they place positive value on and in avoidance of
the things on which they place negative value. This value may be of any
kind: social capital, cultural capital, financial capital etc. This teleological
behavior is also what we call an agenda, that is to say when agents act in a
goal orientated fashion they are said to be pursuing an agenda, which may
be defined as the underlying intentions or motives of a particular person or
group.
Identity
In having independent choice and action, an agent has autonomy. With this
autonomy, come both identity and responsibility. When something is
autonomous, it is identified as a distinct class and in the process of
classifying things we give them an identity, that agent’s identity is then
associated with and held responsible for its actions. Thus with agency and
autonomy of action comes responsibility and the ethics and morals
associated with responsibility. Thus to have full agency we also need to
have some system of ethics, a moral code that defines what is correct or
incorrect behavior in maintaining some responsibility, those responsibilities
can, of course, be of many different kind: social, cultural, economic etc. and
also context dependent.
Efficacy
Efficacy beliefs are the foundation of human agency. Unless people believe
they can produce desired results and forestall detrimental one’s by their
actions, they have little incentive to act or to persevere in the face of
difficulties. Whatever other factors may operate as guides and motivators,
they are rooted in the core belief that one has the power to produce effects
by one's actions. Efficacy beliefs play a central role in the self-regulation of
motivation through goal challenges and outcome expectations. It is partly
on the basis of efficacy beliefs that people choose what challenges to
undertake, how much effort to expend in the endeavor, how long to
persevere in the face of obstacles and failures, and whether failures are
motivating or demoralizing. When people feel disempowered they may
actively manipulate uncertainty and lack of information towards a pattern
that promotes their stability, religion, and ideology.
In many spheres of functioning, people do not have direct control over the
social conditions and institutional practices that affect their everyday lives.
Under these circumstances, they seek their well-being, security, and valued
outcomes through the exercise of proxy agency. In this socially mediated
mode of agency, people try by one means or another to get those who
have access to resources or expertise or who wield influence and power to
act at their behest to secure the outcomes they desire.
People also turn to proxy control in areas in which they can exert direct
influence when they have not developed the means to do so. They believe
others can do it better, or they do not want to saddle themselves with the
burdensome aspects that direct control entails. Personal control is neither
an inherent drive nor universally desired, as is commonly claimed. There is
an onerous side to direct personal control that can dull the appetite for it.
The exercise of effective control requires mastery of knowledge and skills
attainable only through long hours of arduous work.
Negative Interdependency
Conflict
Because conflictual relations are over a rival good where only one person’s
agency can prevail, in every interaction of conflict agents are defining who
has agency and who does not, or who controls the combined agency.
There is always a reduction in one agent’s possibilities and set of choices.
With the master-slave dynamic being a good example, we are reducing the
slave’s agency, possibilities, and choices, in order to enable those of the
master. This dynamic was first fully describe by G. W. F Hegel’s in his book
The Phenomenology of Spirit, where he noted that when two conscious
beings, who believe themselves to be absolutely free and unrestrained,
encounter each other, there is a struggle for recognition, leading to the
“master-slave dialectic”, where one member ultimately has to submit to the
other and become the lesser party (constrained) in the combined agency.
Power
This creates a power dynamic between agents. Power is the ability to make
others do things they would not otherwise choose to do, that is to say, the
capacity to control the agency of another. We tend to think of power as
being the property of a person, but this is really shorthand. Power is really a
relation between two people. Power only exists in one’s capacity to
influence another’s attainment of some positive goal or avoidance of some
negative event. As such, power only really exists in our dependency on
another in achieving (or avoiding) a certain outcome. This is what is called
the dependency theory of power, which posits that the basis of power is
dependency. A depends on B if A has goals and needs that B can fulfill. For
example, an employee depends on her company for a paycheck. Similarly,
a company depends on its employees for their work.
Dependency
So from this perspective, if we were to ask why did the Catholic Church
have such power over people during the Middle Ages in Europe? We could
derive two answers based on this theory. Firstly we might answer because
people wanted to go to heaven and they were dependent upon the church
in obtaining that goal. When people stopped believing in and wanting this
apparent goal the dependency on the church declined, reducing their
power. Equally we might answer that it was because Protestantism and
Calvinism came along providing a new doctrine that allowed people to
bypass the church in attaining this desired goal.
Synergies
Social institutions are a central object of study within the social sciences.
They represent enduring patterns of organization or structures built up
around some social function. Religions, governments, and families are all
institutions that have stood the test of time because they provide essential
structure and serve basic functions within social systems.
The concept of a social institution is really very abstract and it is one of the
most complex concepts within all of the social sciences, but it is also a very
powerful one in that it gives us some kind of unifying concept to all forms of
organization within a social system. As such, an institution is really what we
would call in systems theory a subsystem. They are meso-level structures
between the individual and the whole macro system of a society. Thus,
institutions are subsystems, that perform differentiated functions and
provide critical structure.
As you may have noticed from this, there are really two different
interpretations of this concept of an institution. It may be understood with
reference to structure or function. For example in this definition from the
Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy they defined institutions as,
“structures or mechanisms of social order and cooperation governing the
behavior of a set of individuals within a given community“. We can see in
this definition the idea that institutions primarily exist to maintain order and
structure. But here is another widely used definition for social institutions as
”a persistent constellation of status, roles, values and norms that respond
to important societal needs.” This interpretation places emphases on the
idea of social needs and intuitions as mechanisms for performing functions
to solve those needs.
Functions
Social institutions emerge from and are determinant of the actions and
relations between agents. Institutions are at the end of the day a type of
social system, thus composed of agents and relations through which they
are interdependent. All systems perform some function, they take in
resources of some kind and process those according to some set of
instructions in order to generate an output. In order to perform this function
the system needs some form of order or structure to enable the
coordination of the elements in performing that process. Systems perform
their function only ever to some degree of efficiency, that is to say with any
system we can define a simple parameter that maps from a low level of
efficiency to a high-level efficiency, this is largely a theoretical construct as
in real world complex systems, like institutions efficiency is rarely well
defined, but this theoretical construct does help in structuring our
reasoning.
Efficiency
Functionalism
Conflict theory
And this is, of course, the same for social systems. Within any given social
system, a number of collective functions need to be performed for the
system to be maintained and develop over time. These functions might
include, basic biological reproduction of the population for which we have
the institution of the family; or economic functions such as manufacturing
products for which we have businesses; or political functions such as
collective social decision making for which we have the institution of
government.
All of these are social systems that have to aggregate individuals, assign
functional roles to them. With all of these roles being integrated within
some overarching process that takes in resources of some kind and
performs an operation on them to produce some required output.
Roles
The division of functional tasks in a social system takes the form of the
interaction among heterogeneous specialized positions, what we call roles.
A social role defines a set of behaviors and activities of someone who holds
a particular social status. Roles such as mother, manager or teacher
constitute a set of responsibilities, expectations, norms, and behaviors that
a person has to fulfill in order for the institution to function effectively. Roles
define differentiated states that an individual must occupy in order for the
organization to fulfill some collective function, as such they typically exist in
relation to each other, what is called reciprocation roles, such as the role of
doctor and patient, student and teacher, father and daughter etc.
Relations
Next, in order for the system to perform some collective function we need
to define what exactly that function is. If we think about writing a business
model, we are really trying to define the functioning of that enterprise by
answering the questions of what problem will this business solve, who will it
solve it for, and what resources will it use to do that.
So systems take in inputs and through some process, they perform a set of
operations on these inputs to generate some output. We could think about
the military as an example, it will take in people, technology, finance and
other resources in order to generate the desired functional output of
securing a nation.
In order to do this there needs to be some set of rules that define how the
whole process should be performed, thus formal social institutions are
typically endowed with a set of instructions as to how their function should
be conducted. For example, governments have a well-defined set of rules
encoded in the constitution and law as to how they should conduct the
process of governing a country, how decisions should get made, and what
they can and can’t do during this process. The same would be true for an
institute of education or even religion. These rules might be formal, as in
these examples. Or they might be more informal, as we might have best
practices within a business, or even within our culture, we have constructs
of how an ideal family, friend, community etc. should be. This is essentially
an informal set of rules as to how to perform that functional role what we
might call a norm, the specific cultural expectations for how to behave in a
given situation.
Dissipative systems
We can describe this more formally with reference to what are called
dissipative systems. The idea of a dissipative system was introduced to the
scientific literature by the chemist and physicist Ilya Prigogine to describe
thermodynamic systems, but it has come to be seen as applicable to all
complex adaptive systems. We will be talking about complex adaptive
systems in future chapters, but what is of relevance here is that closed
systems obey the second law of thermodynamics, meaning there is an
increase in entropy over time. A natural accumulation of increasing levels of
random disorder. Dissipative systems and complex adaptive systems, like
societies and institutions, avoid this natural decay process because they
are open systems. They import energy and resources and they export
entropy. If they are successful in doing this, they will be able to accumulate
resources in order to either consume more or develop their internal
structure to become more functional. Like a biological organism, ingesting
food to grow larger, equally if they can not export this entropy then their
internal structure will be degraded and thus their capacity to function
equally degraded. How the social system manages to export entropy is
then critical to understanding how it works and why it is the way it is.
But this idea of social entropy is of course very abstract in that it represents
any form of disorder within a social system. The exporting of entropy then
may be an individual's use of violence against another, or corruption that
degrades the functionality of the overall organization.
Formal institutions are made explicit and are socially excepted functions.
For example, the family unit is a socially accepted functional unit, which is
made formal and explicit by the process of marriage. But we also have
functions within society that are not socially accepted and are thus not
made formal, but at the same time they do not go away, they simply persist
in an informal fashion. Prostitution might be an example here, the rules and
roles to the workings of that institution are not made explicit and formalized,
they remain latent.
Social institutions have both manifest and latent functions. Manifest being
those that are made explicit as the function of that institution, latent being
those that are performed but not made explicit. For example, universities
have the manifest function of teaching students the knowledge and skills
necessary form some occupation, but universities also serve the latent
function of socialization.
Summary
As a famous Swiss man once said: "Man is born free, and everywhere he is
in chains.” This short quote goes to the heart of one of the central
phenomena of study within the social sciences. That is the idea of social
order or structure and its relationship to agency, freedom and the capacity
to change this social structure.
Social structures provide the paths and roads in our lives; they are the
default positions that have already been created, the established
institutions of culture, politics and the economy that enable us to go further,
fast, easier, to do more. They enable us but they also constrain us, and
they are the frameworks through which power is exercised. When we take
these pathways we give over our agency and choices to travel along roads
that have been created by someone else. Someone else is defining our
choices along this path, and in so doing they have power over us.
Social Structure
Order
Coercion
Hierarchy
Inherent to the conflict theory of social order is that conflict is the normal
state within a society, not the exception. This is most famously captured by
Thomas Hobbes's book the Leviathan, where he posits that man, in a state
of nature, is in a continuous war of all against all. Order is then seen to only
be maintainable through some powerful centralized force.
Chain of Command
Coercive social structures have strong rules and follow a strict chain of
command through a hierarchal structure that represents a systematic way
to integrate the activities of members with divergent agendas by having a
clear line of command and thus automatic method for resolving conflicts. In
order to control an organization in a hierarchical fashion, it has to be
linearized. Nonlinearity is inherently uncontrollable through a hierarchical
model. By linearizing I mean that you have to define a closed system,
creating a boundary around it in order to regulate and constrain inputs and
outputs to a relatively low level. Equally, you have to reduce the number of
nonlinear interactions within the system, meaning you need information to
be primarily flowing up and down the hierarchy not horizontally, because
this would empower the agents on the lower levels of the organization and
have a corrosive effect on the top-down exercise of control.
Agency & Structure
There is, of course, a strong dichotomy here between agent and structure.
Within coercive organizations, individual agency is not some natural right
that all members have. Members are typically stripped of individuality and
forced to conform the culture is of strict obedience. Goals would be an
example of this. Membership is not voluntary. The individual is stripped of
their personal belonging and forced to wear identical clothes, they are
identified by a number instead of by name, all of this is to reduce the
diversity and individuality of the agents and facilitate their manipulation
through the social structure. Agency is really derived from your place in the
social structure. For example, within the feudal system, the individual had
no inalienable rights, you got rights from your place in the social hierarchy,
and there was very little social mobility.
Change
Utilitarian Organizations
When agents give over their agency based upon their own perceived
interests within an exchange system, we get what is called utilitarian
organizations. People engage in this type of organization because they
have something to gain. Thus the culture is one of productivity and
efficiency. Legitimacy is based on the organization's or person's capacity to
deliver in the exchange. Utilitarian organizations dominate modern
societies. With the Enlightenment came the idea of reason and people as
rational self-interested agents driven to maximize their utility. On this new
understanding of the individual, we built a whole new set of social
institutions that are utilitarian in nature. They are designed to provide
people with as much return on their investment of time, energy, money or
freedom as possible.
This is one way of understanding how economics and the idea of the
market have become so domain within modern societies as an exchange
mechanism for creating social order. A good example of a utilitarian
organization would be a business. People consent to join and give over
their agency to part of that organization in exchange for some
remuneration. That is to say, they work in exchange for pay. When they feel
this exchange is no longer of value to them, they can discontinue it. The
idea of the social contract would be another example of this. The modern
theory of the social contract propounds that individuals have consented,
either explicitly or tacitly, to surrender some of their freedom and submit to
the government, in exchange for protection of their remaining rights. We
are exchanging the constraint of our actions for the agency that
governments gives back to us in the form of rights that it will protect.
Normative Organizations
Complexity
We should remember that almost all real-world social systems will involve
some combination of these three forms of basis to their structure and order.
For example, many people go to work both out of a profit motive and
because they believe in the value of what their organization is doing. Or if
we take the military as another example, we might see all three forms.
People may join the military out of a belief in the value of securing their
nation but also for personal financial benefit. And once they are there, rules
are enforced in a coercive fashion.
Summary
We talked about the different types of social structure and how they can be
modeled in terms of the condition under which the agents gave over their
choices and actions. Starting on the most basic level of coercion that
places an emphasis on structure over agency in a rigidly hierarchical
organization resistant to change. Next, we talked about utilitarian
organizations where agents partake in exchange relations based on mutual
self-interest with the result being bureaucratic organizations focused on
efficiency that have come to dominate modern industrial societies. Finally,
we talked about the normative organizations we get when people
voluntarily coordinate towards some collective outcome that is of normative
value through an inclusive decision-making process.
Nonlinear Social Science
Nonlinear systems as the name implies are defined by what they are not,
and thus to get a basic understanding of the concept we need to define
firstly what we mean by a linear system. Linear systems are defined by
their adherence to what is called the superposition principles of
homogeneity and additivity. Additivity simply means that the parts of a
linear system can be added up to give us a description of the whole
system. The whole is nothing more than the sum of its parts, thus linear
systems theory is very much focused on giving an account of the individual
elements in a system and their properties, being able to form an account of
the whole by simply adding all the parts up. A thing to note here is that,
because things are simply additive, and the whole is simply a summation of
its parts, this means that the relations between the parts are of little
significance, as they appear to add nothing of great value.
Homogeneity means that the inputs and outputs to a system are always
proportional to each other. So for example, if we had twice as many
teachers per student in a school, then if this was a linear system, we would
have twice the level of student productivity. Linear systems are
synonymous with simple systems. A simple linear social system would be
one where the individuals have no special relation between them. As an
example, we might think of a group of four people in an elevator. They are
all strangers with no specific relation between them and thus the group is
nothing more than the summation of its individual members. We can give
an account of the whole group by simply listing the properties of the
individuals.
In this part of the book, we will be starting the major theme of nonlinearity
and self-organization within social systems. We will use this chapter to give
an outline to the overarching process of self-organization. Then, in future
chapters, dig further into the different topics covered here.
Self-organization
Bottom-Up
This dance then has what we would call a symmetry. This idea of symmetry
is at the heart of modern mathematics. During the mid-eighteen hundreds,
we came to understand algebra on a deeper level, concerning symmetric
transformations and invariance. We have since gone on to use this within
fundamental physics to understand the basic workings of our universe in
terms of these transformations - because these symmetries and
transformations apply to all forms of organizations.
Feedback loops are the mechanisms through which some small local
event, which is often random in nature, can get amplified into a new macro
level pattern of organization and this is the heart of the whole process of
self-organization.
Attractors
Externalities
Emergence
But of course, this is not always the case. We can also get positive
externalities. The net result being emergence as the different local
attractions overcome their differences and we get the emergence of some
global pattern of organization. Emergence is a process whereby larger
entities, patterns, and regularities arise through interactions among smaller
or simpler entities that themselves do not exhibit such properties. As such,
it is very much analogous to self-organization but subtly different.
Almost all real world complex systems are going to have randomness,
fluctuations, and noise in them. Nothing is perfectly ordered. But these
small events typically do not affect the overall pattern of organization. If we
take any large enough society, there will always be some people who are
discontent with the current state of the socio-political system and trying to
change it. But they will typically not gain traction, thousands or even
millions of small events will take place without any effect, because of the
overall state of the system.
Predictability
Summary
Finally, we saw how linear cause and effect breaks down within these
nonlinear systems, phenomena emerge out of the distributed state of the
system and the feedback loops over time, making events fundamentally
unpredictable in nature.
Synchronization
Random Correlation
Negative Correlations
These first two types of relations we have outlined are linear. Meaning that
the gains to one agent are balanced by the losses to another. It is linear
because when everything is added and subtracted it sums up to zero. If we
take the distribution and make one side positive and the other side
negative, when we add all the samples up they will sum to zero. Because
of this nice even normal distribution, we can collapse it all down to the
average value, this method is most explicit and well formulated within what
is called Mean Field Theory.
Mean Field Theory comes from physics and in particular statistical
mechanics where researchers are dealing with many interacting variables,
such as gas molecules in a chamber. The main idea of mean field theory is
to replace all interactions to any one body with an average interaction. This
reduces any multi-body problem into an effective one-body problem. The
ease of solving MFT problems means that some insight into the behavior of
a complicated system can be obtained at a relatively low cost.
This model has been adopted within game theory giving us mean field
game theory, which is the study of strategic decision making in very large
populations of small interacting individuals. This approach will work in many
social scenarios whenever we have these two first forms of correlation -
differences nicely cancel one another out and we can use some form of the
mean field theory. For example, consider tracking the behavior of a swarm
of bees. If you observe any one bee in the swarm, its behavior is pretty
erratic. Making an exact prediction of that bee’s next location is nearly
impossible; however, keep your eye on the center of the swarm—the
average—and you can detect a fairly predictable pattern. In such worlds,
assuming behavior embodied by a single representative bee who averages
out the flight paths of all of the bees within the swarm both simplifies and
improves our ability to predict the future. And this is the nature of simple
linear systems, where reductionism will often work well as an
approximation. We can reduce things down to a single homogenous state
variable, but this does not work in nonlinear systems.
Positive Links
This illustrates how these positive links are nonlinear. When we add and
subtract the gains and losses to all agents in the interaction, they do not
sum to zero thus defying the additivity principle. This nonlinear nature to
positive links makes these phenomena less well studied and understood.
Wherever we have synergies or interference within a social system, we will
get nonlinearity. This might be the synergy between two partners in a
relationship, between tow businesses engaged in a merger or different
countries collaborating on cross-border security. Tt might be the negative
synergy between tow sides in a civil war, two companies competing on
advertising, two cultures that contradict each other. These nonlinear
phenomena are ubiquitous in our world.
Feedback Loops
Nonlinear Dynamics
But as we know, in the real world, many social phenomena of change are
not like this, they involve feedback loops over a period of time. What
happens in the past, feeds into effect what happens now and what happens
now will feed into effect the future. Through this, we can get a compounding
effect as things build on top of themselves. Our business can actually get
better at what it does every year so that the input-output ratio to the system
will not stay constant.
Types of Feedback
Feedback systems define how an event may feedback on itself over time,
and what we are interested in is whether what feeds back will make the
system do more of what it did in the past or less. This will be definitive in its
overall pattern of development, as we will discuss. When what happened in
the past feeds into making the system do more of what it did previously,
then this is a positive feedback loop. Everything is moving together in the
same direction over time. With negative feedback loops, the values move in
the opposite direction. If we have more of something now, we will have less
of it in the future. Thus these negative feedback relations over a period of
time will lead to stability, and little change as what one does now is
counterbalanced with what happens in the future.
Examples
Riots
Conflict
Irrational Exuberance
Inequality
Another good example would be what is called the Matthew effect within
sociology, which describes the fact that advantage tends to beget further
advantage. Thus this phenomenon is also known as the rich get richer as
these feedback loops tend to increase initial inequalities. We might think
about the fact that bank managers are more likely to lend money to people
who already have lots of money. Likewise, those who are already well
connected within society will have greater potential for making more
influential connections. This accumulative effect is described within network
science by the concept of preferential attachment, which explains that
those nodes that initially acquire more connections than others will increase
their connectivity at a higher rate, and thus an initial difference in the
connectivity between two nodes will increase further as the network grows.
Whereas linear development may maintain the system within its current
attractor, exponential growth through positive feedback drives the system
far-from-equilibrium and is a key characteristic of a system going through
what is called a phase transition. Phase transitions represent periods of
critical and rapid change within a system's development. The parameters
with which we define the system change fundamentally. The melting of ice
into water is an example of a phase transition. We get a sudden
transformation, and a regime shift as water is a very different substance to
solid ice.
Examples of phase transitions within social systems might include the fall
of the Berlin Wall. Before this rapid critical phase transition, the global
political environment was largely defined by a bipolar regime. Before the
fall, this bipolar model was the parameter we used to define the system.
After the event, the political environment was described with reference to a
new set of parameters relating to globalization. The Arab Spring might be
another example. The Arab Spring is widely believed to have been
instigated by dissatisfaction with the rule of local governments. After many
decades of the Middle East being held within a particular configuration or
political regime, the Arab Spring was a punctuation of this equilibrium. That
previous regime was a set of negative feedback loops that balanced the
system into some equilibrium. We might say there was some balance of
power, but this balance got broken through some small fluctuation, the self-
sacrifice of a street vendor in Tunisia. This small event then got amplified
by positive feedback into a large systemic transformation. Through this
positive feedback, the balance of power was broken temporarily and the
political system across the Middle East moved into a phase transition.
Tipping points
So for example, if we take two groups of people and each individual has a
propensity to adopt some new phenomena as seen described by: 0, 1, 2, 2,
2 & 1, 1, 1, 2, 2. Then, we will notice that the first group will adopt the new
phenomena as soon as it is introduced because the lowest threshold within
that group is zero and once that person adopts then the next person at one
will do likewise and then the rest. But the other group will not become
adopters because they require one person before they will change.
The thing to note here is that both groups have the same average
propensity for adoption, both groups as a whole are equally as receptive to
this new phenomenon. We can then see that the average or normal is not
important; it is the outliers that matter. You have to know the distribution or
variance and how they are connected. With more people in the tail, you are
more likely to get a collective action.
And thus we can say that within these nonlinear systems it is the tail that
wags the dog. Because of heightened connectivity and interdependence,
major new phenomena start at the fringes and then through positive
feedback build up and make their way into affecting the mainstream.
Punctuated Equilibrium
Path Dependence
We saw how these positive feedback loops can be a powerful force that, if
left unchecked, will take the system out of its current overall state and into
a phase transition as it moves into a new regime, with this model giving us
a pattern of development that is marked by prolonged periods of stability
that are punctuated by these rapid phase transitions.
Attractor and Chaos
State space
To build this state space model, we have to define one or more parameters
to the system that we are interested in, where a parameter is simply a
measurement of something about the system. So if we were interested in a
sales person’s finances, we could define a parameter, to measure their
income, but this would not be very interesting, it would simply go up and
down depending on their sales. So what we are typically interested in then
is the relationship between two or more different parameters. So we might
define another parameter to their overall savings or wealth. Now at each
day, we will take a sample of both of these parameters, putting a dot at the
corresponding value and stay doing this over a period of time.
What we will see after doing this for a few weeks is some kind of typical
behavior, during the week they are earning some amount, then it goes up
on Saturday with lots of sales but then down on Sunday when they are not
working and then starts again the next week. What we will typically see is
that these different states do not go around every single state in the whole
space, but are confined to a limited subset of all the possible states. So we
can say that this subset of the phase space of the dynamical system
corresponding to its typical behavior is the attractor.
A bowl containing a ball may be used to illustrate the concept. The ball will
move around the bowl until eventually, it comes to rest at the lowest point.
We can say that it is 'attracted' to that point, so each part of the bowl can
be regarded as leading to that stationary point, and the whole bowl is what
we call the system's basin of attraction.
Systems, like this ball, are typically held within their attractor because of the
different forces placed upon them by their environment. An animal stays on
a particular patch of fertile land and does not stray too far from it because it
needs to eat; a person gets up and goes to work every day because they
need the money to support themselves. What is happening here is that
these dynamical systems are dissipative, meaning they need some source
of energy to maintain their dynamic state. They are continuously inputting
new energy and then dissipating it, and they cycle through this process
always having to come back to the source of energy that is maintaining
their dynamic state. It is in that cycling that we get all the different states
within the attractor.
Social Attractors
Bifurcation
To help us understand what this might mean, let's think about the French
Revolution as an example, in particular, what is called the tennis court oath
which was a pivotal event during the first days of the French Revolution.
When Third Estate, after being locked out from the government, made a
makeshift conference room inside a nearby tennis court, calling themselves
the National Assembly they, went on to form the new political republic of
France.
Prior to this event, we had a single attractor within the political state space
to the nation. It was an absolute monarchy. All political activity was beneath
and in relation to the monarch. This tennis court oath was then a bifurcation
in the topology as a new attractor formed.
Symmetry Breaking
Any agent within this state space after the bifurcation is going to have to
choose one of the attractors. Whereas previously before this bifurcation
everyone was under the same political regime of the monarch, that is to
say, everyone had a symmetric homogeneous state, but now that we have
two attractors people have to choose one state or another, and this is
called symmetry breaking.
Symmetry breaking is a phenomenon in which critical points decide a
system's fate by determining which branch of a bifurcation is taken. Such
transitions usually bring the system from a symmetric but disorderly state
into one or more definite states. As such, symmetry breaking plays a major
role in pattern formation, as we are now getting differentiation and some
form of organization, that is to say, that there is now some relationship
between these different parts.
Onset of Chaos
We will not go into the details of this logistic map, but what it tells us is that
there is what is called a period doubling in the rate of bifurcation. After we
have this initial bifurcation, we then get more bifurcations happening faster,
doubling in rate each period and this is called the onset of chaos as we are
moving towards a state of more and more attractors, great and great
differentiation.
Summary
In this chapter, we have been talking about attractors and the fundamental
role they play within social dynamics, both with respect to self-organization
and chaos. We firstly gave an outline to the model of a state space, that
allows us to quickly identify recurring patterns within a system's long-term
behavior. We talked about how these dissipative systems typically only
occupy a small subset of the overall space as they cycle through some set
of states relating to an underlying process of energy consumption and
dissipation. And it is this subset of states that we called the attractor, that
may be interpreted as an agent's path of least resistance. We discussed
bifurcations as a topological transformation that results in the emergence of
two different attractors, requiring agents to adopt a specific state within
either attractor, resulting in the process of symmetry breaking. Lastly, we
saw how this process of continuous doubling in bifurcations is a universal
feature of systems as they move into a chaotic and complex regime
consisting of multiple attractors and multiple equilibria.
Edge of Chaos
The idea of social order and chaos has fascinated people from many
different domains for millennia, but these very big ideas have remained
largely outside the scope of modern science. With our analytical and
reductionist methods, we never really had the conceptual means with which
to approach these very abstract concepts. As we have previously
discussed, we have some tools within mathematics and fundamental
physics (some of the ideas we have been discussing around symmetry and
symmetry breaking), but they never really generalized to outside of these
domains. With the rise of chaos theory and complexity, we have started to
get the very bare outlines of some form of a language for approaching
these very fundamental questions.
Edge of Chaos
Too much order and change will not cross impermeable boundaries. Too
much chaos and the system loses its organization. It is thought then that
complex adaptive systems maintain themselves between this randomness
and order where they can somehow use both in order to configure and
reconfigure themselves, going through both integration and differentiation
in evolving to become more complex.
Social Dynamics
Linear
Non-equilibrium
We get positive feedback when the system starts to move in one direction
without a counterbalancing force being exerted. Through this positive
feedback, we get nonlinear exponential change, and the system is now out
of control. Nonlinear change and non-equilibrium are a product of some
broken negative feedback. This means the system is not paying the full
price for its operation. There is some free source of energy being imported
to the system and/or entropy is being exported to the system's
environment. As an example, we might think about the huge change within
human society as we moved into the modern era. Human society,
demographics and economic output remained relatively stable for
thousands of years due to the fact that it was fueled by manual labor that
represents a negative feedback loop. In order to produce physical
resources you had to do physical work, thus you are taking from your own
stock of resources. In order to get more, you had to give more, thus
balancing each other and maintaining some equilibrium. With the rise of
modern technologies and the use of petroleum, we have broken this
negative feedback loop. We now no longer have to do all of this manual
labor, and this has lead, among other factors, to exponential growth driven
by this positive feedback loop. But of course, as we know, these fossil
fuels and modern systems of technology are creating negative externalities.
Negative externalities
Percolation
Criticality
When we have all these factors: positive feedback driving the system down
a particular trajectory; negative externalities degrading alternative options;
the growing cost of maintaining the system's complexity; tight coupling,
interdependencies, and high percolation. Then the system is moving into a
critical regime. The term critical in mathematics and physics relates to or
denotes a point of transition from one state to another, these critical points
before a transition are studied within the domain of nonlinear dynamics
called catastrophe theory. Catastrophe theory studies dramatic changes
within the system's topology, the most famous of which being what is called
the cusp curve where the topology dramatically folds back on itself,
creating a cliff like structure.
Beyond the critical point, we get some runaway effect, a tipping point has
been passed and the system moves into a phase transition as it is now
irreversibly moving into a new state. At this stage, the system becomes
extremely nonlinear, cause and effect break down almost completely.
Massive direct interventions within the system can have very negligible
effect. You as a government can put billions into the market buying up toxic
assets and only have a negligible effect on the price. Because the failure is
distributed, out any small event can trigger a large systemic effect. In this
situation, there is no real possibility for control. Previously unknown
interconnections and interdependencies become revealed and random
events can determine significant outcomes. This is what is called societal
collapse. The system is moving to a lower state of functionality as the
social structure breaks down.
Self-Organizing Criticality
Summary
We have been using these very simple tools of feedback loops to describe
what are in reality very complex processes of change. Feedback loops do
offer us some deep insight into this dynamic, but if we wanted to get a more
sophisticated and complete representation, we would need to add a few
more tools to our toolbox. That includes the ideas of adaptation, diversity
and the process of evolution - all of which would help us to understand
better how social systems manage to develop more sustainably. We will be
covering evolution and adaptation in the last part of the book so we will
move on for the moment.
Self Organized Criticality
The model is taken from the empirical observation that when we drop small
grains (of something like sand) on top of each other, they will build up into a
pile with occasional grains running off - one or two at a time, in proportion
to the rate at which we are dropping them. This is the linear equilibrium
state to the system's development. Grains of sand are held on the pile by
its low incline and the friction from other grains that have already built up
(this is the attractor).
But at some critical point, the pile of sand has built up to such an extent
that the incline on the side has reached a critical level. By dropping just one
additional grain of sand we can cause a cascading avalanche, a positive
feedback as each new grain of sand that cascades down destabilizes the
system more which will feedback to effect more grains to slide off.
The sandpile phenomena is a classical example of nonlinear change. Here
again, we can note the prolonged period for which the system was held
within a stable equilibrium and the very short period of rapid nonlinear
change. This is an illustration of punctuated equilibrium, prolonged periods
of stability and then rapid phase transitions characteristic of nonlinear
change and as we previously noted we cannot predict when these
nonlinear change events will happen.
Social Network Science
Flow
Social Actors
The topology is the environment and the flow is the connections within that
environment. As we are analyzing social systems here, this environment
may be a physical one
where we are talking about basic demographics, the movement of people,
migration, the spreading of viruses, urban transportation etc. All of these
are social connections that take place within a physical environment. But
also we can have an economic environment, giving us networks of financial
and economic connections. We can have a political environment through
which power flows, a cultural environment through which beliefs, values,
and ideologies flow. All of these are very different topologies, with different
forces acting on them. In order to understand these networks we need to
understand these forces that are acting within that environment.
Micro Macro
There are really two different ways to start analyzing a network. By either
taking a micro level bottom up perspective, where we are talking about the
agents, why and how they make connections or a more global perspective,
where we are looking at the overall network and the environmental context
to see how this shapes the system of connections. Within any social
network, we have some agent that is choosing to make that connection.
Agents typically make connections based upon some return on their
investment of time energy, interest, social capital or some other resource
that they value. We make friends with people whose company we like, we
believe in ideologies that we value, we watch television channels that we
find interesting. These are all connections that we make because we value
what we get more than what we have to give in making the connection.
Environment
But there is also the context or environment within which an agent is acting.
That environment is exerting some force resisting or enabling them to make
that connection.
As an example we might think about an oppressive political regime that
uses intimidation, coercion, and propaganda to prevent people from
forming counter political movements. This is a form of resistance - the
agents have to overcome their fear in order to make political connections
within this environment.
So we can understand this environmental context as a form of transaction
cost, a cost that is being placed on an agent for them to make a
connection. Inversely, it might be a payment where the environment is
conducive to them making that connection. We might think about an
ecosystem as an analogy, where when we turn down the temperature all
the creatures hibernate and when we turn it up they come out and interact.
But the cost of making a connection is not evenly distributed out. Some
options will be easier, some more difficult. It is like water running through
some rocks where it finds the course of least resistance.
Integration
Because networks are all about connectivity and processes taking place
through those connections, a central and overarching question will be that
of network integration.
One of the most important factors with respect to the nature of any society
is the question of social cohesion or structural cohesion, where we are
asking about the degree of integration to the overall system, as this
correlates to such things as social solidarity, shared norms, identity,
collective behavior, etc. The idea of social capital is often used as a metric
to a society's degree of cohesion. Social capital may be defined as the
network of relationships among people who live and work in a particular
society, enabling that society to function effectively.
Density
Clustering
Path Length
Degree distribution
Finally, the last almost universal feature of social networks is a very high
degree of inequality between how connected people are within the network.
Here, we are talking about degree distribution. A high degree distribution
means some people have lots of links while others very few. And we often
see that this inequality is quite extreme. In fact, it follows a power law,
meaning that there will be some who have a very high level of connections,
such as a celebrity. Again, there is a positive feedback loop driving.
In this chapter, we will be talking about social networks on the micro level,
looking at agents and their local communities. We will quickly talk about the
basics of social graphs, before going on to discuss a number of different
metrics for trying to understand how significant an agent is within a
network. Finally, we will discuss interpersonal ties as we talk about strong
and weak connections.
The basic constituents of a social graph are nodes and edges, nodes are
people or groups of people. Edges also called ties, represent the
relationships between these social actors, which can come in many
different kinds, such as friendship, kinship, colleague etc. These edges may
be weighted meaning that we can ascribe some quantitative value to them,
such as the amount of time one person spends talking to another. We can
also ascribe positive and negative values to this weight. To depict positive
and negative relations, such as trust or lack of trust, loans, and debts, etc.
These edges can also be directed, giving us an idea to which direction the
resource being exchanged is flowing, with this net flow being depicted by
an arrow. Here, we can have undirected relations that go only in one
direction, such as the influence that a celebrity might have over others
without this influence being reciprocated. Or it may be a bidirectional
relation like a typical friendship with each influencing each other.
Degree Centrality
And thus the primary measure to the significance of any social actor within
a network is his or her degree of connectivity, which is simply how many
connections they have and the weight of those connections if relevant. This
tells us the likelihood of a node contacting or being able to effect in some
way whatever is being exchanged within their immediate network. It tells us
something about their embeddedness within that network. Thus, a higher
degree of connectivity may be a positive or negative thing depending on
what is spreading within the network. A node with a high degree of
connectivity is termed a hub. But this simple degree of connectivity
measurement is a very blunt way of interpreting a node's significance that
can often be misleading. We will need a number of other metrics to support
it.
Closeness Centrality
Betweenness centrality
This is also called occupying a structural whole, meaning that the agent
who is working as a link between two clusters is filling some gap within the
network that is critical in maintaining its overall integration. This actor is
bridging two communities and may play a critical role in transferring
information or some other valued resource. For example, they may be
transferring information between two scientific domains or playing a critical
role as mediator during periods of conflict between two clustered
communities.
Prestige Centrality
Interpersonal Ties
Next, we will talk about the local connections that agents make, what are
called interpersonal ties. As we previously discussed, making connections
typically costs something in terms of resources. Laying cables to transport
information costs money, making new friends or developing a diplomatic
relation with another country takes time and some effort. Added to this, we
can recognize that making connections between different components
typically requires more resources than making those same connections
between similar component, whether we are talking about connections
between computers with different operating systems, trade between
countries with different import procedures or communications between
different cultures. The fact that it requires less resource to make
connections between components with similar attributes is a key factor in
the make-up of many networks and particularly so with social networks.
It in many ways defines the difference between strong and weak ties that
describe the intensity of interpersonal ties between actors. A strong tie is
between two agents that interact frequently and typically share similar
attributes. Thus, they are connections that are typically easier for us to
enact. Inversely, a weak tie connects people to different social circles, they
can be more challenging in that they require the agent to overcome some
difference between groups, but they also expose the person to novel
phenomena and information. The "strength" of an interpersonal tie is a
product of many different factors. It may be a combination of the amount of
time, the emotional intensity, the intimacy, or some other reciprocal service
that, in that relation, the greater the exchange, the stronger the tie.
Clustering
Most of the time, most people interact through strong ties with a fairly small
subset of others, many of whom know one another and this creates a
distinct substructure within the network, what we call a cluster. This
clustering pattern is an almost universal feature of social networks. Social
clustering can be understood by simply asking how many of the people that
someone is connected to are also connected to each other. Evidence
suggests that in most real-world networks, and in particular social
networks, nodes tend to create tightly knit groups characterized by a
relatively high density of ties and clustering. These closely knit clustered
communities can maintain their diversity in the face of homogeneity within
the larger network.
Weak Ties
Small World
When we combine both strong links within clusters and these weak
bridging links we get an effective network for spreading information even
though it may have high clustering. This type of social graph that has both
high clustering and some random bridging links, giving it a low average
path length is called a small world network. These characteristics result in
networks with the unique property of regional specialization and efficient
long range information transfer. Social networks are intuitive examples of
this small world phenomenon, in which cliques or clusters of friends are
strongly interconnected, but also people often have some random
acquaintances within other far of groups. By using these weak ties, we find
that even within very large social networks consisting of many millions or
even billions of people, any person may be only five or six links away from
anyone else within the system, giving us the famous six degrees of
separation theory.
Multiplex Graph
Simple graphs allow for just one type of connection between nodes, but we
can also have multiplex graphs that allow us to model a number of different
relations between nodes. So, in a multiplex graph, we would draw two
different edges between people to describe how they are, say, work
colleagues as well as friends. Of course, this adds a significant amount of
complexity to our model, but it gives us a much more realistic
representation as social actors are often embedded within a multiplicity of
different networks. Social, political, cultural, economic and so on. With a
multiplex network, we can try and capture how these different connections
interact and affect each other. This is a much more realistic picture that lies
behind many social phenomena and a lot more faithful to one of the basic
premise of complexity theory. That is that many phenomena are in fact the
product of a multiplicity of nonlinear interacting forces. As a quick example,
we might think about the recent uprisings in Egypt. When we first look at
this phenomenon, we would consider it political in nature and start
analyzing the political network. But research has shown a robust correlation
between spikes in the price of basic foods and the occurrence of these
riots. Thus, these events are an emergent phenomenon of different
interacting networks. Social, political and economic all putting stress on the
social system. In this situation, it would be of use to use a multiplex network
to try and model the overall dynamic. Phenomena like this are very
complex, they are embedded within many different overlapping networks.
Simply modeling one of these networks can only ever give us a partial
insight. This is the nature of complex systems of all kind, they are multi-
dimensional.
Summary
In this chapter, we have been looking at social networks on the micro level,
talking about local communities. We started off by laying down the basics of
graph theory and talking about centrality measures that can help us in
modeling how influential or powerful an agent is within a network. Based
upon their connections, we talked about four different metrics, citing degree
of connectivity as a primary consideration, but also closeness centrality and
betweenness centrality.
We then went on to talk about interpersonal ties that are divided into strong
and weak. Strong ties being typically between people with similar attributes
that interact more frequently and intensely. While weak ties are random in
nature working to bridge between communities playing an important role in
transferring information. We talked about clustering and how a combination
of both strong clustering and some random weak ties can give us the small
world phenomena with a surprisingly low average path length - even within
very large networks. Finally, we touched upon the topic of multiplex
networks in order to get a more complete representation of complex social
systems as the interaction of a number of different relational types.
Network Structure
Network Density
Path Length
We can also note that the longer the path length the easier it is for sub
groups to form and disintegrate the overall social network. Agents act and
adapt to their local environment. If we turn up the average path length
between agents or groups, they will not identify with, or adapt to those
other members, and we may get the formation of incompatible local
clusters. In trying to achieve global coordination within such a system, we
would likely mean having to impose it in some top-down fashion.
But now, if we turn down the average path length, which could happen
through better transportation or communications technology, people now
interact more often making it easier for them to synchronize their states and
easier for them to recognize their interdependence and common identity.
Degree Distribution
Probably the second most important question we can ask about the overal
structure to a social network relates to its degree distribution. Degree
distribution is a measurement of how evenly or unevenly the degree of
connectivity is distributed out among the agents. Degree distribution is
important because it is really telling us how equal or unequal resources are
distributed out in the system. It is asking the question do some people have
a lot of connections and others have very few? Or does everyone have
roughly the same degree? This is clearly going to tell us a lot about the
nature of power within that system. High degree distribution will mean
inequality of some kind that will be detrimental to social integration, and it is
in many ways this inequality in connectivity that is the means through which
power can be exerted.
Within the Kibbutzim, the principle of equality was taken very seriously up
until recently. Members did not individually own tools or even clothing. They
ate meals together in the communal dining hall, and major decisions about
the future of the community were made by consensus or by vote amongst
all. Distributed social systems like this have limited centralized institutions.
Everyone is responsible for maintaining the system and power is thus
distributed out. Although distributed social networks may exist, they are
often the product of some random process, or a small informal network, or
a network in its early formation where it has not developed any overall
formal organization. Or, as in this example, of the Kibbutz the social
network has been specifically designed to be egalitarian in nature.
Scale-Free Networks
But more often, what we see is that, as a social network develops and
particularly when it becomes more formal, we get greater differentiation
between degrees of connectivity. Many real world social networks show a
skewed node-degree distribution in which most nodes have only few links
but, by contrast, there exist some nodes which are extremely well
connected. This heavy-tailed distribution is known as a power-law or scale-
free network. Here we are getting the emergence of major hubs and high
degrees of social inequality.
There may be two different reasons for this inequality. Firstly, some people
are simply better at doing certain things than others. We all watch certain
people play football, sing or act simply because they are better at it than
others. And what we mean by that is that they provide us with a better
return on our investment of time, energy or money and thus many of us
choose to make connections to that particular node, while others do not
receive our attention. Thus, giving us this unequal, centralized model and
this process is meritocratic in nature. This explanation is largely intuitive to
us, but it might not be sufficed to explain how we can get such extreme
differences in connectivity within these scale free social networks.
Researchers have then also come up with another explanation behind the
formation of these scale free networks, that of preferential attachment.
Preferential Attachment
Summary
In this chapter, we have been talking about three of the major factors
shaping the overall make-up to a social network. We started by talking
about the density of connections as a primary factor, as it defines whether
we are actually dealing with a network or just a group of independent
people. This level of overall connectivity will fundamentally change the
whole system as, when we turn it up, our focus has to shift from the
properties of the parts to the flow of resources within the network. We then
talked about average path length as a second key overall metric one that
will tell us a lot about the network's overall cohesion. Lastly, we looked at
degree distribution as playing an important role in defining the degree of
equality within the system. Degree distribution tells us a lot about how
centralized or distributed the network is, which is of major significance in
understanding the dynamics of power and how something will flow through
the whole system.
Network Diffusion
Forces
Firstly, we need to understand the forces acting on the network. What are
the forces pushing the phenomena over the network? That is to say how
contagious is it? And inversely we need to ask what are the counteracting
forces resisting its spreading. So we are talking about the infectiousness of
the phenomena on the one hand, and the resistance of the agents to that
phenomena on the other. These are two counteracting forces.
Density
The density of the network is important for the obvious reason that with a
high level of connectivity something has more channels through which to
spread. But beyond this, we also need to ask whether the agents within the
system can actually spread the phenomenon themselves or not. As we turn
up the overall connectivity within the system, the nature of the diffusion
changes fundamentally. At a low level of connectivity, when we are dealing
with an isolated group of people, we have to try and affect the whole group.
We try and broadcast to everyone, as exemplified by traditional advertising
and political campaigns, that put up posters and billboards in public spaces
where the mass of people will get exposure to them, this is a kind of brute
force method to diffusion that is necessary at low levels of connectivity.
Clustering
Centralized/Distributed
But we should always remember that centralized social systems will have
strong power dynamics because of the high degree distribution, and this
can distort the diffusion process. For example, if we think about giving aid
to some African country such as the Democratic Republic of Congo, a large
percentage of that money may well get siphoned off at the central hub of
the network before diffusion really takes place. Or we might think about
broadcast media, which again is a centralized system that can be very
effective at disseminating information to a broad group of people. And we
have seen how it has been used effectively as a means for creating
national solidarity amongst millions of people within a country. But again we
know it is often used as a means for manipulation and propaganda
spreading.
And this is the nature of centralized networks in general. They have a high
concentration of power allowing them to be very coherent, effective and
capable of rapid diffusion. But they can also be more dysfunctional as in
these examples. Centralization is essentially a top-down method, meaning
that few people are trying to affect many. This centralized mechanism
always comes at an expense and has its limitations. And this ties back to
our previous discussion about the agents within the network working to
spread the phenomena. That can only happen with distributed connectivity
- the agents have to be connected to each other in a peer-to-peer fashion,
but centralized systems will typically repress and work to exclude these
distributed connections. Thus there may be a certain trade-off here.
Network Effect
Networks don't always grow linearly but may grow exponentially. Whenever
there is exponential growth there is typically some positive feedback driving
it, and in this case, it is what is called the network effect. The network effect
arises when users gain value from others using the same network. The
more people that join, the more value for everyone else, this is a positive
feedback loop. A good example of this would be a language. The value of
some language is relative to the number of other users of that language,
the more people that adopt that language, the more valuable it will be.
People learn English, Spanish and Chinese as a second language not
because those languages are in anyway better than others, but simply
because billions of people speak these languages, giving them a powerful
network effect and lots of value. The network effect may be seen behind
the formation and spreading of many phenomena within social networks,
such as the spreading of some fashion, and as always with positive
feedback, it will give us exponential growth, tipping points, and cascades as
we have previously talked about.
What is happening with the network effect is that there is really a positive
externality. When I chose to learn a particular language, I am not just
generating value for myself, but also some of the value is being
externalized to everyone else who is using that network, as they now have
more communications options available to them due to this positive
externality. The network effect gives us what is called Metcalfe’s law, which
suggests that the value of a network is proportional to the square of the
number of users of that network. Because of all of these positive
externalities, the system as a whole now has value greater than it
individuals.
With the network effect, people will not only adopt a phenomenon based
upon its value in isolation but also on the assessment of how many others
will also adopt the phenomenon. We choose to go to a party or some
gathering only if we think others will also go, and thus expectation becomes
very important. People not only have to value something but they have to
expect that others will also adopt it. And thus expectation can be a very
high leverage point with respect to diffusion on social networks. The
network effect is also notorious for creating lock-in because there is so
much value created by everyone simply using the same network. This
creates a strong force towards convergence, everyone using the one
network at the expense of all others, we can see this with the dominance of
English as a global language with the decline of many other smaller
languages.
Tipping Points
This network effect may give the diffusion process a strong tipping point,
because below a certain level of people adopting that phenomenon the
value is very low - we might say sub-linear. Adopting some radical new
fashion when no one else has, will come at great social cost. But doing it
when everyone else has will come at a much greater value. Thus, the
pioneers of some new phenomena, whether we are talking about a new
political opinion, a new social movement or a new style, these first adopters
will have to be very committed putting in a lot of resources and getting little
out. But if the phenomenon does spread then the network effect will take
hold. There will be a snowball effect due to the positive externalities. There
will be some tipping point or phase transition where it rapidly goes from a
fringe activity to a mainstream phenomenon and the course of least
resistance.
Complex Contagion
When we allow for this more complex form of contagion, we now have to
start to take into account different sources of contagion that may be
conflicting, as we noted when talking about clustering. The spreading of
propaganda may be an example of this. Within a very simple homogeneous
scenario where we have just one national broadcaster, we will have a
relatively simple contagion process, with just one single message being
propagated. But in a more complex setting with multiple channels, there
may be conflicting messages and we have to understand the network of
interacting messages that people are receiving and also the significance
that they ascribe to those different channels.
Summary
In this chapter, we have been talking about the diffusion process within
social networks looking at some of the primary considerations. Talking
firstly about the two counteracting forces of the infectiousness of the
phenomena on the one hand and the resistance of the agents. We
highlighted network density as a second factor, whereas we turn up the
overall degree of distributed connectivity within the system the nature of the
diffusion changes fundamentally allowing for a peer-to-peer process of
sharing. We noted how clustering can create a certain resistance to uniform
spreading and centralized networks can be very effective at enabling the
diffusion process through large hubs. We touched upon the network effect
and how it can create rapid diffusion once a tipping point is reached due to
positive externalities. Finally, we expanded our model to include complex
contagion where an agent must be exposed to a number of different
sources before adopting it.
Fitness Landscape
In this part of the book, we will be using models derived from complex
adaptive systems theory to try and interpret social phenomena. Complex
adaptive systems can be understood as a special class of complex system
that has the capacity of adaptation. When we use this paradigm, we are
essentially looking at social systems as an environment within which we
have many different agents who are acting and reacting to each other's
behavior as they adapt and evolve over time. A good example of this would
be the world of organized crime, where we have a social system consisting
of law enforcement agencies and criminal networks who each have
counteracting agendas, and they are acting, reacting and adapting to each
other's behavior, creating a very dynamic system.
Adaptation
The most coherent and robust formal model we have for understanding this
process of adaptation as a search, is what is called a fitness or adaptive
landscape. It is a very solid formal mathematical model we can use to
describe complex adaptive systems.
Fitness Function
Now, we can put our agents into this landscape, so these agents might be
countries within the international political environment. Their elevation
representing their capacity to influence the global political system and
those with similar political regimes and ideologies would be in proximity to
each other. Or as another more concrete example, we might be modeling
the different drug cartels within Mexico, where their control over territory
and resources would be their elevation within the landscape.
Agents are then trying to reach higher elevations within this landscape, but
they typically do not have a global vision of the entire landscape. They do
not know if they are on a global optimal solution or just on a local one. We
do not know if we break up with our partner whether we will find a more
suitable one in the future. We don't know if we overthrow the current
political regime whether the next one will be any better, etc. Thus at any
given time agents are faced with two different option of either exploiting
their current position or investing resources in exploring for better options.
Types of Landscapes
Linear Environments
The most simple environments are static in nature and consist of the least
amount of interacting variables. As an example, we might think about an
absolute monarch or absolute dictatorship where all social, economic and
cultural institutions are controlled and held constant through the political
hierarchy. Within such an environment everything is in relation to one
political institution, simply succeeding within that single organization can
achieve global success. Or as another example, we might think about
some homogeneous cultural system that defines clearly what is considered
right and wrong and from this the one correct way to live one's life. These
are examples of linear socio-cultural environments that would give the
landscape a single dominant peak, one optimal solution that is well defined,
and because of this, the agent needs only to follow some linear
optimization algorithm.
Interconnected Environments
Adaptive Environment
If we now allow for the different interacting variables to adapt and change
over time we now have a complex environment. We now have a landscape
where actors are acting and reacting to each other's behavior, constantly
adapting. And it is out of this interdependence and adaptation that we get a
landscape where the peaks and valleys are moving up and down over time.
An example of this might be the current international political environment,
as we move into an increasingly multipolar world. With the rise of China
and the other emerging economies, we are now no longer in an
international environment dominated by the homogeneous Western
ideology of the Bretton Woods institutions. But increasingly have many
more actors, both public and private, each with their own strategies and
interest that are constantly acting and reacting to each other. And this
means the end target is constantly changing any solution that may be
effective now, may cease to be effective when others adapt to it, which
once again alters the payoffs on the landscape as it moves up and down
over time
Open Environments
Lastly, this whole complex adaptive social system of agents acting and
reacting is receiving some set of input values from external sources.
Whether this is the natural environment or the technology infrastructure to
that society. A major change in these input values can cause the whole
landscape to transform. In such circumstances, we are no longer talking
about the agents acting and reacting to each other, but instead, we are
talking about the whole topology to the landscape transforming. This is like
a paradigm shift within science or culture where the whole landscape gets
changed. We can think about the paradigm shift in our culture as we moved
into the modern era, everything got recontextualized, through a scientific
and materialistic context. With this cultural paradigm shift, virtually every
single social and cultural institution within the entire landscape had to
reinvent itself within this new context. Education, governance, work, etc.,
everything got redefined and those that weren't have slowly lost relevance.
This is a long term systemic change where we are no longer talking about
adaptation but instead evolution.
From this, we should see that different environments require different types
of adaption. Within the first simpler environment agents only need a
relatively simple linear form of adaptation which is an optimization
algorithm. The second environment is again algorithmic in nature, but it
requires a greater investment of computation as it is no longer a simple
trade-off between two variables but now a number of different variables
interacting.
In neither of these first two environments does the system really have to
adapt. It simply has to make an initial investment of resources exploring the
environment before converging to some optimal position and can then
remain there. Because the landscape is not changing, the process of
exploration and adaptation is transient in nature; we only have to do it for a
period of time before the system can settle into some basin of attraction.
The aim of the game here is to find the best solution and then just stay
using it. You don't really have to adapt, this is like becoming the biggest fish
in the pond so that no one can affect you. Or the single superpower in a
monopolar political environment, so that you have significant enough
resources that you don't really have to adapt to what others are doing.
Strategies that work well in one environment may well fail in another and
this if often a limitation to long-term sustained development. Where an
agent adopts a strategy that works well in a simple environment and
enables them to develop into a more complex environment, wherein they
stay applying their previous strategy which works to prevent them from
developing a more appropriate one for the new context. Here we can
identify that success often creates a positive feedback loop, such as we
have previously discussed with the phenomena of irrational exuberance,
where success makes the agent overconfident in their strategy and drives
them forward into a more complex environment where their strategy may
be inappropriate. But the positive feedback loop of irrational exuberance
limits their capacity to recognize that and change accordingly, giving us
unsustainable development and this might be cited as a form of self-
organized criticality.
As Albert Einstein would say; "We can't solve problems by using the same
kind of thinking we used when we created them." As an example, we might
think about how our industrial technologies and solutions that were
developed when we had a much lower ecological impact, have taken us
into a more complex environment where we are for the first time
significantly altering earth's core regulatory systems, such as the climate
and polar icecaps. Solving problems within this more complex environment
requires a form of collaboration that our industrial systems of organization
such as the nation state, that previously may have worked well, are not well
designed for. The point to take away here is that strategy is context
dependent. Complexity is a fundamental parameter to a system when we
turn it up or down we can expect strategy to change fundamentally,
requiring greater or less capacity for adaptation.
Summary
In this chapter, we have been looking through the lense of adaptive system
theory to see what insight it can offer us on macro-social phenomena.
Firstly, we talked about adaptation as a process through which an agent
tries to change its state in response to some change within its environment,
doing this in order to optimize its position and payoff within that
environment. We gave an outline to the adaptive landscape, that can be
used as a formal model for representing whole complex social systems
consisting of many interacting agents both on the micro level of individuals
and on the macro level of interacting organizations.
Strategies
Resistance
All complex adaptive systems are in some way dependent upon their
environment. They are what we would call thermodynamically open
systems. They require the input of energy and resources in order to
maintain their dynamical state - without it, they will slowly or rapidly decay.
And thus the regulatory system has to ensure that the system as a whole is
and will be receiving the required input values from its environment. The
regulatory system then has to know what the parameters to those input
values are and direct the system towards a state that will optimize them. If
we are cold and there is a fire nearby, we will move towards it. If we are
very poor, we will be driven to make money. If our economy requires a high
input of oil, we will try and secure that resource. These are all examples of
homeostasis, where the regulatory system monitors, controls and adjusts
the system as a whole so as to maintain it within the optimal set of input
values required to preserve and develop its level of structure and
functionality. And this is the same for all complex adaptive systems.
Regulatory systems always define a desired state for the system and
parameters or boundaries around that which are requisites for it to achieve
that desired state. Here we are defining what the system is. That is to say,
there is some structure or function through which it defines itself. This might
be the identity of being Indian, of being a good person, of being an athlete
of being a tough guy. But in order to be any of these things you have to
stay within a certain set of parameters - you can't be a good person and
take lots of drugs and steal lots of things, you can't be a tough guy and go
around wearing pink flowery t-shirts all the time.
All of these identities are dependent upon a set of boundary conditions that
must be maintained in order to maintain that state of functionality. In order
to occupy that state, you are dependent upon those input values. When we
as groups or individuals form an identity that is defining what we are, this
identity also typically depends upon some resource, such as the territory
that a nation occupies, the job status that an individual occupies, or a
position within some social hierarchy. In defining what we are, we are also
defining what we are not. We are creating some kind of boundary condition,
limits to our existence. These dependencies and boundary conditions
create a structure that holds the system within a certain configuration
creating inertia and the resistance to change.
Path Dependence
Resistance Strategy
Once the adaptive system has defined a boundary condition and becomes
locked into that condition, we will get Inertia - the resistance to change.
Resistance as a strategy means the control system trying to limit the
number of possible eventualities and maintain only a limited number of
responses. In order to try and reduce the number of possible eventualities
to some small subset that is conducive to the system, we have to try and
control the environment. The farther we go down this path of resistance,
the more we are trying to control the environment, and the more we are
trying to reduce the possible input values to the system. In order to properly
control a system, we have to linearize it. Nonlinearity is uncontrollable we
have to externalize it from the system, in so doing reducing diversity,
reducing redundant components and by linearizing it we can increase the
coupling. All of these will give increases in short-term efficiency. But also, of
course, this leads to long term self-organizing criticality as the system
becomes more dependent upon a narrower band of input values and any
small change in those critical values can create systemic shock. The
classical example of this being our current dependency on petroleum,
where small changes in the input value can ramify across the whole system
and here again this critical state was created by path dependency, a
process driven by positive feedback and negative externalities as we
previously saw when we talked about carbon lock-in. But this state of
inertia reduces the system's adaptive capacity and requires the heavy
maintenance of a control system in order to insure that these critical values
are not altered.
Adaptation
Edge of Chaos
And this whole discussion ties back to the previous chapter where we
touched upon the theory of the edge of chaos. The hypothesis that
successful complex adaptive systems somehow maintain themselves
between chaos or randomness and order, where they are exposed to
perturbations that broaden the possible set of input values and remove
those components that do not add to its overall adaptive capacity. The
system uses the two regimes in order to configure and reconfigure itself,
enabling it to evolve over time in a sustainable fashion.
Here again, we see path dependency, and again most of this can be
understood in terms of positive feedback and negative externalities. These
stresses on the macro level accumulate because some regulatory system
on the micro level has learned to displace a lot of its problems to its
external environment – quite simply, it pushes them beyond its boundaries.
But it is really just pushing them onto the macro level, distorting the process
of evolution and leading to macro level self organized-criticality, that it can
not effect through its fast control variables on the micro level. The system
might become increasingly competent at managing everything within its
boundaries, through linearization and externalizing things it can’t manage
well. And the big idea here is that of sustainability, which we haven't had
the chance to touch upon, but we might say is the ultimate aim of adaptive
capacity.
Summary
Complexity
The question of what exactly complexity is, is one of the big open questions
within complexity theory, as there are a number of different approaches to
trying to answer it. We can, for example, talk about it in terms of
computation or interconnectivity, among various other approaches. But
evolution offers us one answer to this question. This perspective starts with
a recognition that systems do not start out complex. All systems start out
simple and evolve to become complex. Through this process of evolution,
the subcomponents within the system become more specialized and
differentiated, but it also involves a process of reintegration, increased
interconnectivity and interdependence between those differentiated
subsystems. As an example, we can think about the human body. Of
course, we started out as very simple unicellular organisms like every other
creature. But through a long process of evolution, different cells have come
to work together while also becoming increasingly specialized. And it is
through this combination of integration and differentiation during the
process of evolution that our bodies have become the complex systems
they are today. From this evolutionary perspective, a complex system is a
system that is both differentiated and integrated, and out of that, we get
synergies and the emergence of complex phenomena.
Evolution
The first thing to note is that evolution is not something that only happens
to dinosaurs and monkeys. It is a pervasive phenomenon in our world. The
mechanism of evolution in the abstract is a process of development for any
type of adaptive system. Ecosystems, economies, societies, cultures,
football teams, ideas, religions, political parties and the list goes on.
Evolution is the same process as adaptation, but now operating on the
macro scale. Adaptation is how an individual responds to change within
their environment. Evolution is the process through which a whole
population of agents responds to change within its environment. Both
adaptation and evolution are characterized as processes of change without
centralized coordination. Both adaptation and evolution do not require a
centralized regulatory system. They both happen in a distributed fashion.
With evolution, there is no one single divine entity that gets to make
choices about which creatures will live or die. That choice is distributed out
across the entire ecosystem. Just as no one in a free market economy gets
to say which products will be produced or not produced, that choice is
made by many different producers and consumers across the entire market
as part of an evolutionary process. The point to take away is that evolution
is a macro scale process of development within any adaptive system that is
characterized by a distributed mechanism for selection.
Within this world of evolution, there is no right or wrong, good or bad. There
is only really survival and adaptation. Survival means being able to
effectively intercept and transform resources within some environment.
Adaptation means being able to alter your state so as to be able to
continue performing this function when the input values from the
environment change. It is through being able to do both of these that you
can ensure your survival. And this environment may be ecological where
we are talking about some biological creature, or it may be some business
within an economy, some political movement within a society, some
ideology within a culture, etc. For all of these entities to survive, for them to
be continued within their particular environment, they have to be
intercepting and transforming resources effectively and be capable of
adapting as the environment changes. If you can't do that then over time
you will become irrelevant within that environment and ultimately
discontinued. The whole mechanism through which this operates is called
the process of evolution.
Process of Evolution
Variety
Operation
Selection
Although diversity and variety may be necessary for evolution and change,
they also carry a cost. Once these different belief systems, cultures, social
movements or other intuitions have explored the full state space of
possibilities within that social context, and we have some metric for
understanding which ones perform best, there then needs to be some
mechanism for selecting those most successful variants and replicating
them so that they will become more prevalent within the future life-cycle of
the whole system, while those that have proven less effective are not
replicated and left to expire. Within democracies, political parties are
subject to selection at the ballot box, companies are subject to selection by
their consumers, when people stop believing and spreading an ideology it
becomes discontinue. But in that discontinuing, we get the release of
resources that were previously occupied and the system makes space for
those resources to be reconfigured through those patterns of organization
that have proven most successful within this cycle of the evolutionary
process.
Sustainability
Complexity
Summary