Rostows Five Stages
Rostows Five Stages
Rostows Five Stages
The Rostow's Stages of Economic Growth model is one of the liner economic models
of historic economic growth. It was presented by American economist Walt Whitman
Rostow in 1960 as an alternative view of Marxist interpretation of history. Thus the
model was recognized as political theory as well as descriptive economic analysis of
growth and development (Thirwall, 2006). Rostow argued that economic take-off must
initially be led by a few individual sectors. This belief was based on the theory of
comparative advantage presented by David Ricardo. He criticized Marxist revolutionary
views on economic transition. This became one of the important concepts in the theory
of modernization in social evaluation (Wikipedia, 2016)
Rostow's model does not disagree with John Maynard Keynes regarding the importance
of government control over domestic development which is not generally accepted by
some ardent free trade advocates. The basic assumption given of Rostow’s theory is
that countries want to modernize and grow and that society will agree to the materialistic
norms of economic growth.
Thus Rostow’s thesis has identified five stages of economic development according to
the historic economic performance of developed countries.
1. Traditional society
2. Preconditions for self-sustaining growth
3. Take-off
4. Drive to maturity
5. The stage of High mass consumption
1. Traditional Society
Wars, famines and epidemics like plague caused initially expanding populations
to halt or shrink, limiting the single greatest factor of production: human manual
labor. Volume fluctuations in trade due to political instability are frequent;
historically, trading was subject to great risk and transport of goods and raw
materials was expensive, difficult, slow and unreliable. The manufacturing sector
and other industries have a tendency to grow but are limited by inadequate
scientific knowledge and a "backward" or highly traditionalist frame of mind which
contributes to low labor productivity. In this stage, some regions are entirely self-
sufficient.
Thus it is characterized by
• Secondly, trade and other commercial activities of the nation broaden the
market's reach not only to neighboring areas but also to far-flung regions,
creating international markets.
On the social front, new elites must emerge to construct the industrial society
and it must be superseded authority of land based elites of the traditional
society. Surpluses must be channeled by new elites from agriculture to industry
(Thirwall, 2006).
In summary, the country would be able to achieve following requirements at this stage.
All these changes effectively prepare the way for "take-off" only if there is basic
change in attitude of society towards risk taking, changes in working
environment, and openness to change in social and political organizations and
structures. The pre-conditions of take-off closely track the historic stages of the
(initially) British Industrial Revolution.
3. Take Off
The characteristics of takeoff are sometimes difficult to distinguish from the stage
of pre-condition to take off. However, since the pre condones for the takeoff have
been met in the transition stage, take off is a short stage of development that
takes nearly two decades. Development become self-sustaining and investment
must rise exceeding 10 percent of national income so as to increase per capita
income and level of investment. According to historical records, domestic finance
for takeoff has fulfilled through two main sources i.e. agricultural taxes, rents
(Meiji reforms, Japan, and voluntary investment by land lords.
Development of export industries has led to take off in some countries. Example
grains in USA, Canada and Russia, Timber in Sweden. Sector or the sectors that
led to take off were varied according to countries. However, Rostow has
concluded that any industry can play the role of leading sector in the take off
stage that to be met with (Thirwall, 2006):
That the market for the product is expanding rapidly to provide a firm basis
for the growth of output.
That the sector has an adequate and continual supply of capital from
surplus profit
S/K/l
K2
K1
K0
I1 T1
Io T0
0
Y0 Yi Y2
National output
S represents savings
According Rostow, savings rate and capital output ratio is inelastic (slope of
saving curve is high) during the pre-condition of take off period. It happens due to
low savings during precondition of take off period. However savings ratio is
increased during takeoff period and consequently investment ratio also
increased. Thus during pre-condition period, at I0 investment, national output
increase by 0Yo -0Yi and at 0I1 investment, national output increase by Ti y1/Y1-
Y2. Thus capital output ratio is decreased during takeoff period.
4. Drive to Maturity
Rostow defines it as the period when a society has effectively applied the range
of modern technology to the bulk of its resources." Now regularly growing
economy drives to extend modern technology over the whole front of its
economic activity.
On comparing the dates of take-off and drive to maturity these countries reached
the stage of maturity in approximately 60 years.
The structural changes in the society during this stage are in three ways:
During this stage a country has to decide whether the industrial power and
technology it has generated is to be used for the welfare of its people or to gain
supremacy over others, or the world in total.
This diversity leads to reduction in poverty rate and increasing standards of living, as
the society no longer needs to sacrifice its comfort in order to build up certain
sectors
The age of high mass consumption refers to the period of contemporary comfort
afforded many western nations, wherein consumers concentrate on durable
goods, and hardly remember the subsistence concerns of previous stages.
Rostow uses the Buddenbrooks dynamics metaphor to describe this change in
attitude. In Thomas Mann's 1901 novel, Buddenbrooks, a family is chronicled for
three generations.
Each country in this position chooses its own balance between these three goals.
There is a desire to develop an egalitarian society and measures are taken to
reach this goal. According to Rostow, a country tries to determine its uniqueness
and factors affecting it are its political, geographical and cultural structure and
also values present in its society.
Historically, the United States is said to have reached this stage first, followed by
other western European nations, and then Japan in the 1950s.
National Output
I II III IV V
Time
Criticism of the Model
1. Rostow is historical in the sense that the end result is known at the outset and is
derived from the historical geography of a developed, bureaucratic society.
2. Rostow is mechanical in the sense that the underlying motor of change is not
disclosed and therefore the stages become little more than a classificatory
system based on data from developed countries.
3. His model is based on American and European history and defines the American
norm of high mass consumption as integral to the economic development
process of all industrialized societies.
4. His model assumes the inevitable adoption of Neoliberal trade policies which
allow the manufacturing base of a given advanced polity to be relocated to lower-
wage regions.
5. Rostow's model does not apply to the Asian and the African countries as events
in these countries are not justified in any stage of his model. The stages are not
identifiable properly as the conditions of the take-off and pre take-off stage are
very similar and also overlap.
7. There are two unrelated theories of take off one is that take is a sectoral and a
non-linear notion and other is that it is highly aggregative.
Rostow's thesis is biased towards a western model of modernization, but at the time of
Rostow the world's only mature economies were in the west, and no controlled
economies were in the "era of high mass consumption." The model de-emphasizes
differences between sectors in capitalistic vs. communistic societies, but seems to
innately recognize that modernization can be achieved in different ways in different
types of economies.
The most disabling assumption that Rostow took is of trying to fit economic progress
into a linear system. This assumption is false as due to empirical evidence of many
countries making false starts then reaching a degree of progress and change and then
slipping back. E.g.: In the case of contemporary Russia slipping back from high mass
consumption to a country in transition, the main cause being the end of the Cold War
and geopolitical struggles.
Another problem that Rostow's work has is that it considered large countries with a
large population (Japan), with natural resources available at just the right time in its
history (Coal in Northern European countries), or with a large land mass (Argentina).
He has little to say and indeed offers little hope for small countries, such as Rwanda,
which do not have such advantages. Neo-liberal economic theory to Rostow, and
many others, does offer hope to much of the world that economic maturity is coming
and the age of high mass consumption is nigh. But that does leave a sort of 'grim
meathook future' for the outliers, which do not have the resources, political will, or
external backing to become competitive.
Simon Kuznets threw doubts upon Rostow's theory. He argued that many
countries which have now reached developed status did so without seeing a
significant increase in their savings rate.
The theory does not account for exceptions, e.g. falling output in the USSR
under a communist regime; the corrupt and failing government in Zimbabwe has
reversed development advances; increased globalization means that a country's
growth rate does not lie solely in its own hands and international competition and
protectionism may prevent an economy from moving through the latter stages
Recommended Reading
Rostow, W. W. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist
Manifesto. Cambridge University Press.
Baran, P.; Hobsbawm, E. J. (1961). "The Stages of Economic Growth". Kyklos 14
(2): 234–242.
Hunt, Diana (1989). "Rostow of the Stages of Growth" . Economic Theories of
Development: An Analysis of Competing Paradigms. New York: Harvester
Wheatsheaf. pp. 95–101. ISBN 0-74500237-4.
Meier, Gerald M. (1989). "Sequence of Stages". Leading Issues in Economic
Development (Fifth Ed.). New York: Oxford University Press. pp. 69–72. ISBN 0-
19-505572-1.