Politics and Poverty: A Background Paper For The World Development Report 2000/1 Mick Moore and James Putzel
Politics and Poverty: A Background Paper For The World Development Report 2000/1 Mick Moore and James Putzel
Politics and Poverty: A Background Paper For The World Development Report 2000/1 Mick Moore and James Putzel
Contents
Introduction: Practical Political Analysis
Five Strategic Guidelines
1. Democracy has differential outcomes for the poor
2. States create and shape the political opportunities for the poor
3. There is no reason to expect that decentralisation will be pro-poor
4. There is a wide range of possibilities for pro-poor political alliances
5. Many of the policies needed to improve governance will benefit the poor
Implications for Aid Donors
Bibliography
Background:
This is a synthesis, for the World Bank Team working on the World Development
Report 2000/1, of the conclusions of a research project on the Responsiveness of
Political Systems to Poverty Reduction commissioned by the Governance Department
of the UK Department for International Development (DFID). It is based principally
on the work of the following people, who wrote papers that were discussed at a
meeting held on 16-17 August 1999: Michael Anderson, Richard Crook, George
Gray-Molina, John Harriss, Ron Herring, Peter Houtzager, Marcus Kurtz, Jennifer
Leavy, Mick Moore, Kimberly Niles, Alan Sverrisson, Ashutosh Varshney, Howard
White and Lawrence Whitehead. We are deeply grateful to them for the high quality
of the work they did within a short time. The papers are listed in the Bibliography.
Further, we owe a great deal to colleagues who, variously, attended that meeting as
discussants, contributed to the framing of the project at a preparatory meeting held on
26-27 February 1999, or provided helpful comments on earlier drafts: Catherine
Boone, David Booth, Teddy Brett, Kathryn Clarke, Monica Dasgupta, Garth
Glentworth, Merilee Grindle, E. Gyimah-Boadi, David Lehmann, Fernando Limongi,
Ian McKendry, Dele Olowu, Elisa Reis, Alice Sindzingre, Rehman Sobhan, Richard
Thomas, David Wood and Geof Wood. We greatly benefited from the opportunity to
attend the Summer Research Workshop at the World Bank on 6-9 July 1999, that was
oriented around the World Development Report 2000/1. Ravi Kanbur, the Task
Manager for the World Development Report 2000/1, provided invaluable guidance at
several points. Kathryn Clarke of DFID helped manage the project on a day to day
basis, and Julia Brown and Jenny Edwards of the Institute of Development Studies
organised our meetings most expeditiously. For the final shape of this report, we are
deeply indebted to Merilee Grindle for insightful advice, and to Roger Wilson, Head
of the Governance Department of DFID, who conceived the project and played a
major constructive role at every stage.
1
The Institute of Development Studies at the University of Sussex, Brighton BN1
9RE, UK (Email - MickM@ids.ac.uk)
2
Development Studies Institute, London School of Economics, Houghton Street,
London WC2A 2AE (Email - J.Putzel@lse.ac.uk)
2
This kind of political analysis is not intrinsically difficult: politicians do it all the time.
It is more difficult for the staff of aid and development agencies, who have to deal
with many diverse situations to which they are outsiders. Angola is very different
from Bangladesh, and Bangladesh from Chile. There is no substitute for detailed
local, expert knowledge when it comes to country-level operations. Aid donors are
increasing their capacity to undertake operational political analysis. They need to do
more. They can however overcome some of their own bewilderment about the
complexity and diversity of developing country politics by using a few basic concepts
to map that diversity. Table 1 provides one such map in relation to the politics of
poverty. It is based around two fundamental dimensions of national political systems.
The first is the degree to which they are institutionalized, i.e. the extent to which
countries are ruled and administered through established, stable organisations and
procedures that are widely accepted as legitimate. The second is the extent to which,
within the more institutionalised states, rulers are chosen through genuinely open,
competitive processes - free elections of some kind. Electoral competition is
impossible without institutionalisation.
• The roles that poor people and the organisations representing them might play in
different situations
• The scope for both local political actors and external agencies to advance the
interests of the poor in the political process
Those people we label 'the poor' are diverse, even within localities. Much has been
said about that elsewhere. Table 1 illustrates the diversity of their political situations
and opportunities at national level. It also reflects something they have in common - a
critical feature of the politics of poverty that is explained in more detail below: the
scope for the poor to organise, and the ways in which they organise, are highly
interdependent with the character of the state or regime, the shape of public policy
and the behaviour of ruling elites. Small communities, groups or localities can
organise to tackle their immediate needs in the absence of effective government. But
large populations of the poor organise in relation to the forces that they are trying to
combat or influence. If the state is fragmented, unstable and incoherent, popular
organisations will develop along the same lines. The existence of effective
government is a condition for popular organisation that extends over large populations
and has the potential to influence public policy. The development of the political
capabilities of the poor should be an important objective of anti-poverty policy. That
is partly true by definition: empowerment is itself a dimension of poverty alleviation.
It is also true in a more instrumental sense: lasting, sustainable improvements in the
position of the poor will depend on their collective capacity to defend and build on
achievements.
There then emerges a new variant of a familiar paradox: development is often easier if
you are already halfway there than if you are still near the starting line. The capacity
for the poor to create effective organisations is greater in those - generally richer -
states where the quality of governance is higher. In designing policy for specific
countries, it is important to bear this paradox in mind. It is not however a cause for
despair. In countries afflicted by poor governance, the poor have much the same
primary interest as the great majority of the population: government that is less
repressive and arbitrary, more accountable, and more bound by law.
This report is organised around five key propositions about politics and poverty that
emerged from our extensive research and consultations. They are intended to help
policymakers think strategically about poverty reduction policy:
This list refers almost exclusively to the internal politics of developing countries. Are
we guilty, at this point in history when there is so much interest in the implications of
globalisation, of ignoring the international political dimensions of poverty? This is an
especially important issue because of the popularity of the view that globalisation
reduces the scope for governments to attend to poverty alleviation. There are several
variants of this argument. The core propositions are straightforward. They rest on the
notion that globalisation has produced a relative shift of power away from states to the
4
people who make decisions about large scale capital movements (the 'controllers of
capital'). Capital has become more mobile internationally. The greater the efforts that
governments make to tax or redistribute income or capital, preserve or increase social
protection, or influence where and how the private sector invests, the more, it is
claimed, they will be ‘punished’ by the controllers of capital. The controllers of
capital will reduce investments in countries (and cities or regions) ruled by regimes
lacking in ‘realism’ - or simply threaten to do so, pointing out how easy it is for them
to move money and plant away to more favourable business environments. The
spectre or the reality of declining tax revenues, rising unemployment and falling
political support will be enough to persuade most governments to accept 'reality': to
reduce business taxes, cancel promises to redistribute land, dilute proposals to extend
employee rights, and postpone plans to provide a basic income to all destitute
households.
There is some truth in these arguments. However, we do not in general believe that
globalisation has reduced the scope for (developing country) governments to be pro-
poor. There are powerful countervailing forces. Two are particularly important:
It is then quite appropriate to focus our strategic guidelines about poverty and politics
on the internal aspects of governance in poor countries.
which examined the experiences of a large number of countries, and defined 'pro-
poor' in a different fashion. Ashutosh Varshney (1999) examined the record of
countries at reducing the numbers of people below the poverty line, defined in terms
of income or consumption. Kimberly Niles (1999) measured the effort governments
put into protecting the poor against the adverse effects of economic adjustment. Mick
Moore et al. (1999) explored the extent to which national political-economic systems
converted national income into longevity, literacy and education for the mass of
citizens. All concluded that there was no consistent connection between pro-poorness
and democracy. While the very worst performers tend not to be democracies -
democracy does provide some kind of safety net - there are non-democracies among
the best performers. Over relatively long periods of time some authoritarian regimes,
like that which existed in Indonesia for over thirty-five years, made faster progress in
reducing poverty than other states which have enjoyed long periods of democracy -
like the Philippines, where the rate of poverty reduction has been much more modest.
Table 2 illustrates the kind of inconclusive patterns that result when we classify poor
countries according to their poverty reduction performance and degree of democracy.
What is going on here? Democracy does offer more voice and influence to the poor
than most non-democratic systems. Why does this not result in a clear association
between democracy and good performance in poverty reduction? There are two main
answers to that question. The first is that some of the best performers in poverty
reduction over the past half century have been the (former) socialist states, that were
undemocratic by conventional criteria but highly focused on improving mass welfare
for reasons of ideology and politics. The positive impacts of these histories of pro-
poor mobilisation are still evident in the poverty and welfare statistics for China, Cuba
and Vietnam. The impacts have faded in the case of most of the countries of the
former Soviet Bloc after their transition to market economies, and have turned
grotesque in North Korea. The residual effects of this experience of non-democratic
but pro-poor socialist regimes is one reason why democracy is not associated with
poverty reduction in the cross-national statistics. The other reason, of more relevance
to the future, lies in wide variations in the substantive content of formal, electoral
democracy.
If democratic politics were mainly about organising people to vote according to their
broadly-defined economic interests, one would expect the poor to have considerably
more influence and voice than they do (Varshney, 1999). There are three important
reasons why democracy does not work in this way:
• The actual participation of the poor, particularly women, does not reflect their
numbers in society. Many poor people are excluded from, or do not participate
actively in, the political process.
• When the poor do participate, their 'class' identities - as poor people in general or,
specifically, as small farmers, landless, wage workers, tenants, recipients of food
subsidies, squatters etc.- are not the only influences on the way they vote or on the
politicians, parties or programs that they support. The forces that move them are
often more tangible, short-term, direct and local than relatively abstract notions
6
In sum, in many democracies the poor are often badly organised and ill-served by the
organisations that mobilise their votes and claim to represent their interests.
While civil society organisations are important sources of assistance and mobilisation
for specific groups among the poor, it is the organisations of political society within
democratic systems that are crucial to the character and conduct of public policy.
Chief among these are political parties. Political parties can range from temporary
alliances of powerful individuals, through more stable organisations constructed
around regional, patronage, ethnic or religious networks, to organisations based on
clearly defined ideologies and programs, and run by committed voluntary members
operating through a democratic institutional structure. The more that parties are
located toward this latter end of the spectrum, the more likely they are to represent the
poor effectively.
(Insert Box 1 - Competitive politics and the poor in two Indian states - about here)
Contrasts between the states of India illustrate how variations in the pattern of
democratic political competition affect the extent to which governments are pro-poor.
India has enjoyed a relatively stable system of competitive elections and basic formal
democratic rights since independence in 1948. The southern state of Kerala has long
enjoyed very high levels of mass literacy, education, health and longevity in relation
to its average income levels. There is a large literature that attempts to explain this
'Kerala exceptionalism', and no consensus on the relative roles of the various
explanatory factors - a strong popular communist movement, a particular caste
structure, or a range of contingent historical factors. Even if one can explain
7
Where there are political parties actually competing for the votes of the poor, the poor
have a better chance of influencing policy or seeing policy formed that addresses their
needs. In the 1980s, competitive politics in Peru allowed the women’s movement,
organised through a vast network of community-based kitchens known as comedores,
to exercise limited but substantive influence over social policy, including the
enactment of new legislation (Houtzager, 1999). Kimberly Niles (1999) explains the
way in which the pattern of party competition affects the extent and way in which
parties compete for the votes of the poor. She compares countries in terms of the
extent to which parties are stable or fluid and fragmented. Where parties are stable,
elections are generally dominated by two to three competing programmatic parties
with a degree of party discipline. Each party needs to win a high proportion of votes
to enter government. Parties operate with relatively long time horizons. They
accumulate a great deal of information about potential voters and the potential pay-
offs to different political strategies. Each tries to appeal to a broad constituency of
voters. The system tends to produce parties and governments with high commitment
to the poor. In fragmented systems, politics are personalistic. There are many poorly
disciplined parties, that do not need to obtain a large proportion of votes to have a
chance of entering government. They have shorter time horizons and face higher
information costs because politicians are continually engaging in new activities, with
new allies or opponents, and seeking the support of different voters. These systems
tend to produce governments with low commitments to the poor.
Even when allied together in broad social movements, local community and non-
governmental organisations cannot play the same role in shaping public policy that is
played by well institutionalised programmatic democratic political parties. In
particular, they lack the mandate granted by the ballot box. These organisations can
help increase the political capabilities of the poor, influence national politics, and
perhaps lay the basis for more enduring, institutionalised and accountable political
parties.
2. States create and shape the political opportunities for the poor
What circumstances lead to the enhancement of the political capabilities of the poor?
Citizens of developing and transitional economies have had so much experience of
oppressive and ineffective states over recent decades that the answer to this question
is often seen to lie in some kind of autonomous popular action. Citizens' movements,
NGOs, and civil society are seen as the alternatives to failing states. This is a
misleading myth. It is especially misleading in relation to movements of the poor. It
is certainly true that failing states can in some circumstances stimulate local level
alternatives. There are many accounts, for example, of how Ugandan rural
communities coped with a long period of civil war and then of a fragile peace by
taking control of and financing their own primary schools. But the operative word
9
here is local. Effective, large scale organisation by poor people - the kind of
organisation that can make a consistent difference to public policy and affect a large
population - is dependent on the character of the state and the policies it pursues. One
can illustrate how states affect the scope for building the political capabilities of the
poor by examining three different levels of state capacity and action:
Poor peoples' movements respond to the same logic. Where the state is fragmented,
organisations of the poor hardly exist, or are the creation of external actors, like
international aid donors or non-governmental organisations (Houtzager, 1999). The
modern state eliminates rival centres of authority within society. This provides the
basis for social groups to organise on a national scale and to create collective
identities that cut across geographic regions. Whether social groups organise to
influence the state depends on whether they believe the state has the authority and
capacity to meet their demands. If the national state has little authority, why bother to
organise at the national level? Better to concentrate limited political resources - and
political resources are always limited - on exercising influence in different ways:
negotiating an acceptable level of informal taxes with the guerrilla movement in this
region; using ethnic linkages with a minister to remove oppressive policemen from
this town; building up connections with the aid donors who might provide money for
local NGOs in that district. Building large membership movements of the poor is
unlikely to be the most efficient means of exercising influence through these kinds of
channels. Global maps of effective states and effective social movements would look
very similar. Where the state is ineffective, social movements are rare, weak,
exclusive, localised and often closely connected with armed secessionists and
smugglers. Where states are ineffective, improving their capacity may be the best
way to stimulate effective organisations of the poor.
mechanisms through which public policy affects the mobilisation of the poor are
indirect and less obvious:
• Some of the most powerful incentives for the poor to organise can stem from a
sense of exclusion - the existence of a public program that benefits some people
but not other people who appear to have an equally valid claim. For example, one
reason why Sri Lanka became an early 'welfare state' and an exemplar of high
levels of human development at low levels of per capita income was the existence
of health and education services for the immigrant estate labour force. These
services were mandated by the British colonial government of Sri Lanka (then
Ceylon), at the insistence of the British colonial government of India, whence the
immigrants came. Their existence led to demands, from the 1930s, that similar
services be extended to the entire population (Wickremeratne, 1973).
Joshi and Moore (1999) explore these issues on the basis of comparative case
material, stressing that the most important role for external agencies (government
agencies, NGOs) may not be directly to support the mobilisation of the poor, but to
create an enabling environment - an environment in which the poor have an incentive
to mobilise. At present, the environment in which poor people and external
organisations interact is frequently hostile to collective action by the poor, because
characterised by uncertainty, arbitrariness and inequality. External agencies should
focus more on creating incentives to collective action, above all by removing the
obstacles that they themselves create. Four dimensions of the performance or
behaviour of external agencies are cited:
• Tolerance - collective action on the part of the poor is more likely where the
political environment is not hostile and punitive.
• Credibility - the extent to which, in their relations with the poor, public officials
can be relied on to behave like good partners in an enterprise, i.e. to do their job
correctly, and to be reliable.
• Predictability - this refers to the form of external programs: the extent to which
they are stable over time in content, form, and procedural requirements.
• Rights - the extent to which (a) the benefits received under external programs are
recognised as moral or, better, legal entitlements, and (b) there are recognised
(preferably legal) mechanisms that the beneficiaries can access to ensure that
these entitlements are actually realised.
One of their case studies is the Employment Guarantee Scheme in Maharashtra, India.
Over the 23 years from 1975/6 to 1998/9, this massive scheme has provided an annual
average of 132 million work days, on 341,661 separate work sites - soil and water
conservation, small scale irrigation, reforestation, and local roads. When first
introduced, the Employment Guarantee Scheme appeared innovative and received
considerable attention from the outside world. It has received much less attention
over the past decade, and is gradually shrinking in scale, in large part because
economic growth has reduced the demand for off-season manual work at minimum
wages. Despite its many problems, the Employment Guarantee Scheme has been a
success. It continues to provide relatively cost effective and reliable income support
for significant sections of the rural poor of Maharashtra. Joshi and Moore
demonstrate that a major reason is that jobseekers, via political representatives of
various kinds, have continuously been mobilised to demand their rights. And that in
turn stems from the ways in which the framing and implementation of the Scheme
contribute to creating an enabling environment for mobilisation. These include:
• Incentives to collective action are built into the Scheme: a minimum number of
people need to be in search of employment before work sites can be opened.
• The public agencies involved enjoy a degree of credibility, and the Scheme is
predictable in important respects. It has been in place a long time, is likely to
continue because it is legally mandated, and is implemented effectively partly
because, unlike many (emergency) public works programs, it is being
implemented continuously. Public officials are skilled in managing public works
projects.
• Above all, there is a legal right to employment provided certain conditions are
met. These rights can be pursued through the courts, and have a great deal of
moral force.
12
Given the great diversity of processes labelled decentralisation, it is not surprising that
an intensive study of all available evidence by Crook and Sverrisson (1999) yielded
no support for the contention that decentralisation is intrinsically or generally pro-
13
poor. Indeed, they found little hard evidence of any kind about impact. The
conclusions from twelve cases on which there was the most reliable information are
summarised in Table 3. Crook and Sverrisson assessed the programs along two main
axes: (1) impact on participation by, representation of, and responsiveness to, the
poor; and (2) impact on the social and economic position of the poor measured by
growth, equity, human development and spatial equity (between regions/localities).
They found an unambiguously positive impact of decentralisation only in West
Bengal state, India. The study suggested that four key sets of variables determine
performance in terms of both responsiveness and pro-poor social and economic
outcomes:
a) The politics of the relations between newly empowered local government and
central government
Central government needs to support the decentralised system with financial and
administrative resources and legal powers and also needs to have the capacity to
control and monitor their use. It also needs to have both an ideological commitment
to pro-poor policy and an active engagement with local politics to challenge local elite
resistance. In West Bengal and some parts of Brazil, pro-poor outcomes were the
product of this kind of synergy between action at the local and central/state
government level. Conservative local elites were challenged by local groups who had
the support of central authorities. In Bangladesh, Nigeria, and Kenya, although
substantial resources were transferred, central governments failed to ensure their
proper use. Conservative elites were empowered through decentralisation because the
main concern of central government was to create a power base in the countryside.
This eventually happened in Ghana as well. In Cote d’Ivoire and Mexico,
decentralisation was used by ruling parties intent on renewing party support without
any commitment to pro-poor policies, which might have threatened those networks.
These cases stood in contrast to apparently more successful programs in parts of
Colombia, where a strong political party or local elites seeking legitimacy were
committed to poverty reduction. In Bolivia, decentralisation has meant not the
abolition of long-established clientelist networks from the centre to the local areas,
but the introduction of competition in the form of newly empowered local networks
that contain some poor people (Whitehead and Grey-Molina, 1999). Evidence from
comparative work on Indian states reinforces conclusions about the pivotal role of
central-local relations in making decentralisation more favourable to the poor. In
India, the federal system has allowed enough room for state governments controlled
by alliances favourable to the poor to implement programs with more positive poverty
reduction outcomes than elsewhere. At the same time, the existence of central
government programs has often proved crucial to providing both the resources and
political leverage necessary for local authorities to implement policies favourable to
the poor (Harriss, 1999; Herring, 1999). Only after a national constitutional
amendment in 1993 did four states adopt a local government reform that reserved
33% of seats for women and seats for Scheduled Castes and Tribes according to their
proportions in the population.
Fair and competitive elections were crucial to establishing accountability in the more
successful cases. In Colombia, the most successful mayors in terms of responsiveness
and pro-poor outcomes were those who relied on a public constituency for their
office. More negative outcomes were seen in Cote d’Ivoire, where mayors had almost
no connection with the electorate. At the institutional level, it was important that,
even where the interests of poor people were represented, there was a proper balance
between political control and the legal accountability provided by a well-established
and reasonably autonomous administration.
What emerges clearly is that the success of decentralisation programs in securing pro-
poor outcomes depends in important ways on the role of central governments. In the
history of the United States, the role of the federal government has often been pivotal
in programs aimed at poverty reduction. Its failure to act on behalf of the poor at key
moments had devastating effects. The failure to break local landed power in the
South after the Civil War reinforced the long-term deprivation of the former slave
population (Herring, 1999). A wide range of evidence seems to warn against what
Herring calls ‘a premature celebration of the local’ in development strategies that aim
to reduce poverty.
When international aid and development agencies produce reports on poverty, they
rarely say much about the political dimensions. What they do say typically focuses
on conflicts of interests between poor and non-poor, and the need somehow to
overcome the resistance of the rich if governments are to be more committed to
poverty reduction. Some reference may be made to the need for political movements
that mobilise large numbers of poor people in order to counteract the influence of the
rich.
Most members of the Brazilian political, business and governmental elite are in
favour of land reform (Reis, 1999). We can assume that the supporters do not include
15
the minority of that elite who themselves are landowners. Even so, this finding will
surprise people who believe that political divisions will generally reflect economic
self interest, and that rich and poor will generally find themselves on different sides.
Why is the idea of land reform so appealing to rich Brazilians? Part of the
explanation does lie in perceived self-interest: '…. the optimistic expectation that land
redistribution would improve living conditions in the large cities where members of
the elite live. They appear to have a dream of exporting the poor to the countryside
where they could not only produce for their own consumption but even generate a
marketable surplus. …. (elite) respondents would systematically mention high
criminality rates and pressure on the provision of public goods in large cities as the
major consequences of poverty and inequality. They would blame poverty and
inequality for the lack of personal security, dirty and dangerous public spaces, and
related problems' (Reis, 1999: 131-2). But surely the Brazilian elite are deluded? No
feasible land reform is actually going to reduce the numbers of the poor in Brazil's big
cities. It will at best reduce the rate of rural-urban migration. True. But the fact that
members of the elite are willing to believe something different reflects the skill of
many politicians, especially those associated with the influential Landless Workers
Movement, in constructing a case for land reform that is both plausible and congruent
with what elites like to believe about themselves and the world. In this case, an
important element of the story is that ('feudal') landlordism is seen as old-fashioned, a
constraint on the modernisation of Brazil, and a potential stain on the image of Brazil
as a fast developing industrial nation. Elite Brazilians are open to arguments for land
reform that have little to do with their self interest in any direct sense of the term.
The Brazil case helps illustrate some points about the politics of anti-poverty policy
that are easily overlooked by people who begin from those assumptions about the
political process that we have labelled interest group economism:
matter of dividing up a fixed cake: more dollars for the poor clearly implies fewer
dollars for someone else. By contrast, presenting poverty as deprivation - the inability
to feed children, to send them to school, or to give young women an alternative to
prostitution; powerlessness in the face of policemen extorting protection money; or
the helplessness of sick people who simply have no access to medical treatment - has
much more constructive political implications. These deprivations are intrinsically
moral. People who are not poor may imagine or perceive themselves as sharing
similar problems, and therefore empathise. In thinking of solutions, they may believe
that their interests overlap with those of the poor, rather than compete: better
schooling/security/public services may be a platform around which all can unite.
This contrast between deprivation and income concepts of poverty illustrates wider
points about poverty and politics. First, 'as politicians know only too well but social
scientists often forget, public policy is made of language' (Majone, 1989:1). The
terms in which issues are presented for public debate can greatly influence the
outcome of that debate. Second, there is a wide range of choice about how one
presents poverty issues. Neither the character, the causes of, nor the solutions to
poverty are immutable facts, clear to and agreed by all parties concerned. On the
contrary, they are all malleable concepts, which can be reinterpreted and represented
in a variety of ways, many of them conducive to public action against the poor. In
late Victorian Britain, Charles Booth helped effect a major opinion shift in favour of
public action to support the majority, ordinary working poor, by presenting the middle
and upper classes with a new interpretation of 'poverty'. Although he invented the
concept of the 'poverty line', Booth defined it more in social than in material terms.
This was the line below which even decent working families were likely to lose the
battle for respectability and fall into the ranks of paupers - the exotic, feckless,
threatening, immoral class against whom public 'poverty' policy had traditionally been
directed. The notion of respectability at risk was something to which the British
middle and upper classes could relate in a positive manner. 'Booth "re-moralized" the
poor by separating them from the "very poor" and freeing them from the stigma of
pauperism and degradation' (Himmelfarb, 1991: 11). In the immediate aftermath of
Booth's work, 'Instead of yet another revision of the Poor Law dealing with paupers,
Parliament enacted laws for the benefit of the laboring poor; housing, workmen's
compensation, extended schooling, school meals, old age pensions, cheap trains, labor
exchanges, unemployment and health insurance' (Himmelfarb, 1991: 12). In the early
twentieth century, American state governments were persuaded, mainly by national
middle class women's organisations, to spend public money on supporting poor
families on the grounds that this was the only way to protect the moral and physical
integrity of the nation (Skocpol, 1992).
c) The poor and the 'middle strata' often have common interests
The extent to which different fractions of a population have a common interest varies
widely. It depends in part on the policy issue involved and in part on the way in which
populations are divided into social or political groupings. If ethnic and religious
distinctions cut across income categories, the more prosperous groups may actively
support pro-poor policies that they believe will benefit poor members of their ethnic
group. Indeed, it is those aspects of shared identity cutting across class that have
achieved many gains for women. If income is relatively equally distributed, there will
be more similarities of income and lifestyle between different strata, and thus more
common interests, than in situations where income distribution is very unequal. If
17
poor and non-poor live in the same localities, they are likely to work together to press
for better roads, water supply or health services. If they are physically segregated,
each group may seek to solve its own problems separately. The complexity and
uncertainty of the possibilities for political alliances involving the poor may be
frustrating for people searching for general truths. However, it can be a source of
inspiration for politicians seeking widespread support. They have incentives to
identify public programs that will benefit many people, alienate few and, if possible,
remain affordable. We can learn from their insights.
(Insert Box 3 - Agrarian Reform and Poverty Reduction: new Political Possibilities)
case of school textbooks in Sri Lanka, the main potential sources of opposition lay
within the government itself, particularly the Ministry of Finance. In the absence of
opposition from this source, the program was quickly implemented and accepted as
routine. It is not a cure for poverty but makes a significant contribution at low cost.
Provided they can avoid stirring up opposition, governments can often take positive
pro-poor initiatives without the support of the poor. Indeed, the support of the poor
can sometimes be a problem, because it does threaten to stir up the non-poor, and to
mobilise opposition that might otherwise lie dormant. Let us conclude with some
quotations from the most extensive study ever undertaken of the politics of 'reformist'
pro-poor redistribution in poor countries (of Latin America) - William Ascher's
Scheming for the Poor (1984):
“The case studies show that the image of the poor confronting the rich is
profoundly misleading. On the one hand, the most effective strategy for securing
the political viability of a redistributive policy often is to gain the backing of a
selected part of the higher-income population. .... On the other hand, one of the
most serious problems of carrying out redistributive programs is that the already-
benefited poor often resist the spread of benefits to other segments of the needy”
(Ascher 1984: 34).
“.... the support of beneficiaries is of limited political value: those who have
already benefited from redistribution are not likely to behave in grateful ways, and
those who may benefit from contemplated redistributive policies are often
incapable of being mobilized sufficiently to help the government vis-à-vis typical
opposition tactics” (Ascher 1984: 310).
“There are many sub-sets of ‘the poor’, often with opposing interests with respect
to a given economic policy. Food subsidies for the urban poor, generally
engineered to the detriment of the rural poor, are the classic example. The
implication is that mobilizing ‘the poor,’ far from being a straightforward task,
turns out to be a complicated and often unrewarding exercise insofar as the
differences among lower-income segments are likely to be substantial and
politically divisive ” (Ascher 1984: 310-11).
Contrary to the pessimistic 'interest group economism' discussed above, there are
many reasons why non-poor groups and actors are willing and able to support pro-
poor policies, and a wide range of potential pro-poor alliances. We have not explored
the full range of possibilities. In particular, we have not discussed the important
contribution that religious organisations have often made to the creation of pro-poor
alliances and movements. To emphasise the role of non-poor groups is not to lose
sight of the importance of building up the political capabilities of the poor. That only
happens when organisations representing the poor develop some autonomy. In this
respect, non-poor allies can be both a help and a hindrance. Social science throws
light on the subtleties of such relationships, but warns us against drawing simple
conclusions (Houtzager and Kurtz, forthcoming).
5. Many of the policies needed to improve governance will benefit the poor
19
Improved governance has been a development policy priority for some years. The
current focus of aid donors on poverty reduction might be thought to compete or
conflict with this. In fact, there is no competition. The two are in most respects
consistent with one another. Indeed, they are to a large degree complementary: better
governance is good for the poor, and many pro-poor policies imply or promote better
governance. One aspect of this complementarity has already been discussed above:
the fact that effective states are a condition for the creation of effective poor people's
movements. The basis for what is potentially the widest and most significant pro-
poor political alliance lies in the high incidence of bad governance in much of the
developing world: governments that are simultaneously oppressive and unaccountable
and lack the capacity and resources to provide basic services, including law and order,
for the mass of their populations. Almost everyone has an interest in better
governance; the poor feel this most strongly.
Providing police and other public officials with coercive legal authority can often be a
significant obstacle to the functioning of poor people's political organisations and
development of the political capabilities of the poor. Even in democratic India,
magistrates retain the statutory power to ban public assemblies - a power that dates
from colonial times and appears blatantly to violate the constitutional right to freedom
of assembly.
At the other, more complex, end of the combined poverty-governance agenda lie a set
of issues about the interactions between public expenditure, taxation, citizenship and
accountable government that are certainly not amenable to quick or simple solutions,
but are fundamental to both poverty reduction and good government, and merit
attention because they are so frequently overlooked.
Public spending does not necessarily contribute to poverty reduction. But it clearly
plays an important role in effective public action. And public spending, as a
percentage of GDP, is not high in developing countries. Indeed, it is low by any
comparative standard. It is low partly because overall levels of taxation are low. And
they are low in large part because the better-off people - those who could afford to
pay income, consumption, turnover or property taxes - actually pay relatively little tax
in most developing countries. The reasons for this are various. They include the fact
that structural adjustment programmes have generally involved a reduction in the
export and import taxes that have been a major source of public revenue in poor
20
countries. While this has been balanced by the gradual spread of value-added taxes,
that are often effective at raising resources, aid and development agencies have not in
practice placed sufficient emphasis on increasing governments' tax take to pay for the
programs that are needed to reduce poverty and meet other urgent needs. The OECD-
based culture of capping total taxation and public expenditure at current levels has in
effect been exported to poor countries where levels are too low. In some cases at
least, this is because aid and development agencies are wary of upsetting the elites
with whom they do business - who would be visible losers from, for example, the
introduction and enforcement of reasonable levels of property and corporate taxation.
The link from taxation and public expenditure to poverty reduction is in principle
clear. There is however another causal link - from taxation and public expenditure to
citizenship and governance - that is less evident but no less important. There is a long
tradition in political science of viewing taxation as one side of a social contract
between citizens and states. The other side of the contract comprises the services that
states provide to citizens in return. This contract is more easily enforced by citizens
in a democracy. But the underlying dynamics still operate in non-democratic
environments. Where states are dependent for their incomes on taxing their citizens,
they face incentives (a) to treat their citizens reasonably and indeed to help enrich
them, in order to increase the tax base; and (b) establish a competent public
bureaucracy to raise tax revenues, with positive spill-over effects on the quality of
public services generally. The poor governance of many developing states stems in
part from the fact that their governments are largely independent of most citizens for
revenue: they are funded by large revenue inflows from direct control over oil wells
or other sources of mineral revenue and, to a lesser extent, large aid inflows.
This notion of a tax-mediated social contract leads to the expectation that the
developing country governments that are most dependent on their own citizens - for
revenue and other resources - would tend to perform best in terms of poverty
alleviation. This was the finding of one of our papers, that used cross-national
statistical analysis to examine the relative performance of national political-economic
systems at converting national income into human development (longevity, adult
literacy, school enrolment) for the mass of citizens (Moore et. al., 1999). Where
governments are (a) dependent on their citizens for revenue and (b) not propped up
politically and militarily by a former colonial power, levels of human development
are high in relation to average levels of income. Where governments have access to
substantial mineral revenues and enjoy strong political and military support from an
external power, levels of human development are low in relation to income levels.
Those working in international development have long known that domestic politics
often determine whether an aid program or project can be effective in contributing to
poverty reduction. Nevertheless, little attention has been paid to increasing the
capacity within the agencies to carry out political analysis. It has often been easier to
approach development intervention as a series of technical problems abstracted from
the ‘messy’ world of politics, which in any case, is a domestic affair. In addition to
the strategic guidelines presented above, a number of other lessons emerge for aid
donors out of the study of political systems and poverty reduction:
• Donors must also recognise that they are, in fact, political actors. The choices
they make about the countries in which to work, about whom they consult and
with whom they deal are all highly political. Understanding who the potential
participants in reform coalitions are in any given situation will allow donors to
provide encouragement and support.
• Developing the political capacities of the poor is a long-term enterprise which cuts
against the grain of the donor mentality (and domestic politics in the donor
countries) that wants to assess the ‘return on investment in aid’ over relatively
short periods of time. In terms of policy intervention, donors might be best
advised to adopt as a first principle, ‘to do no harm’. This implies that in some
cases, rather than trying to promote pro-poor policy, they should instead
encourage governments, in the first instance, to at least eliminate those aspects of
current practice and policy that are clearly ‘anti-poor’.
22
There is some evidence to suggest that democratic decentralisation has increased the representation of
non-elites in Colombia. In 1988, the Liberal and Conservative parties – an effective oligarchy at the
municipal level for a century - had 80% of the popular vote, increasing to 90% in 1990, and controlled
almost 90% of municipalities. By 1992, this had decreased to 65% of the popular vote and non-
traditional parties controlled about 300 of Colombia’s 1,007 municipalities.
Some municipalities have adopted a participatory approach to local governance. In Valledupar, local
government staff wear badges which proclaim “we govern with your participation”, and the mayor has
established various means of dissemination through local media. In other municipalities, community
participation occurs in just one sector, or independently of the municipal administration. Some of these
participatory practices pre-date decentralisation and in many places traditional elite run patronage
politics remain strong.
In terms of responsiveness, a key element of the Colombian reform programme is the move towards a
‘demand-driven’ approach to public services, involving extensive participation. Competition for political
office acted as a catalyst for responsible leadership, which in turn became the driving force behind
capacity building, but performance still depends heavily on the leadership qualities of individual
administrations. There has been an increase in ‘voice’, with protests leading to local government action
and some local governments establishing channels for systematic expression of needs and problems by
the community. The World Bank team studying this case found quite reliable evidence of improved
performance in the fields of education, water supply and local roads. (Crook and Sverrison, 1999)
27
In a study of the political conditions for agrarian reform, Ron Herring (1999) identified seven
reasons why the prospect of using agrarian reform to fight poverty has become politically more
possible:
• Both the nature of agriculture and its place in most developing economies has changed and
landownership is less central as a site of accumulation than it once was, which has reduced
its political salience;
• Land is more clearly understood as an anchor of natural systems and redistributing
ownership and stewardship rights has become important to those concerned with
environmental sustainability;
• Increased recognition of the gender differences in patterns of poverty has opened up a new
public policy debate about the distribution of rural assets and brought women more clearly
into the possible alliances backing redistributive agrarian reform;
• New forms of organisation of indigenous peoples and claims for ancestral domain and world-
wide interest in their cause form yet another potential political ally backing redistributive
reforms;
• Democratic transitions have offered new possibilities for putting reform on the political
agenda and there is some grounds for understanding that redistributing rural assets is crucial
to developing a sense of citizenship among the rural population;
• Technological changes in agriculture have made it increasingly possible to farm productively,
whether on a part-time or full-time basis, on smaller areas of land in many agricultural
systems;
• The proliferation of NGOs and human rights movements has created a more conducive
environment for the development of rural agrarian movements.
Redistributive reforms have known and proven results in reducing poverty which makes the
ethical case for supporting them much more clear cut than many indirect approaches to poverty
reduction. Where thorough going reforms have been carried out, the political power of the
minority who might oppose other poverty reduction measures has been significantly reduced.
Even in sites of partial reform, like in the Philippines and Brazil, new possibilities for the
mobilisation and organisation of rural poor people and their allies have been created (Putzel,
1999; Houtzager, 1999).
28
REFERENCES
(Papers prepared for the purposes of this project are starred -*)
*Anderson, M. R., 1999, ‘Access to justice and legal process: making legal institutions responsive to
poor people in LDCs’.
Ascher, W., 1984, Scheming for the Poor. The Politics of Redistribution in Latin America,
Cambridge MA and London: Harvard University Press
*Crook, R. C., and Sverrisson, A. S., 1999, ‘To what extent can decentralised forms of government
enhance the development of pro-poor policies and improve poverty-alleviation outcomes?’.
Grindle, M. S., and Thomas, J. W., 1991, Public Choice and Policy Change. The Political Economy
of Reform in Developing Countries, Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University
Press.
*Harriss, J., 1999, ‘How much difference does politics make? Regime differences across Indian States
and rural poverty reduction’.
*Herring, R. J., 1999, ‘Political conditions for agrarian reform and poverty alleviation’.
Himmelfarb, G., 1991, Poverty and Compassion: The Moral Imagination of the Late Victorians,
New York: Alfred Knopf.
Hossain, N., and Moore, M., 1999, ‘Elite perceptions of poverty: Bangladesh’, IDS Bulletin, Vol. 30,
No. 2, pp. 106-16.
Houtzager, P. P. and Kurtz, M. (forthcoming), 'The Institutional Roots of Popular Mobilization: State
Transformation and Rural Politics in Brazil and Chile, 1960-95', Comparative Studies in History
and Society.
*Houtzager, P. P., and Pattenden, J., 1999, ‘Finding the shape of the mountain: when ‘the poor’ set the
agenda’.
Joshi, A., and Moore, M., forthcoming, ‘Rights, institutions and poverty’ in A. Booth and P. Mosley
(eds), The New Poverty Strategies: What Have they Achieved?, Macmillan: London.
*Kurtz, M., 1999, ‘The political economy of pro-poor policies in Chile and Mexico’.
Majone, G., 1989, Evidence, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process, New Haven and
London: Yale University Press.
Moore, M., 1999, ‘Politics Against Poverty? Global Pessimism and National Optimism’, IDS Bulletin,
Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 33-46.
*Moore, M., Leavy, J., Houtzager, P. and White, H., 1999, ‘Polity qualities: how governance affects
poverty’.
*Niles, K. J., 1999, ‘Economic adjustment and targeted social spending: the role of political institutions
(Indonesia, Mexico and Ghana)’.
Putzel, J., 1997, ‘Accounting for the dark side of social capital’, Journal of International
Development, Vol. 9, No. 7, pp. 939-49.
Putzel, J., 1995, ‘Managing the main force: the Communist Party of the Philippines and the peasantry’,
Journal of Peasant Studies, July, pp. 645-71.
Reis, E., 1999, ‘Elite perceptions of poverty: Brazil’, IDS Bulletin, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 127-36.
Rieger, E., and Liebfried, S., 1998, ‘Welfare State limits to globalization’, Politics and Society, Vol.
26, No. 3, pp. 363-90.
Rodrik, D., 1998, ‘Why do open economies have bigger governments?’, Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 106, No. 5, pp. 997-1032.
Skocpol, T., 1992, Protecting Soldiers and Mothers. The Political Origins of Social Policy in the
United States, Cambridge MA and London: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.
Toye, J., 1999, ‘Nationalising the Anti-Poverty Agenda’, IDS Bulletin, Vol. 30, No. 2, pp. 6-12.
*Varshney, A., 1999, ‘Democracy and poverty’.
*Whitehead, L., and Gray-Molina, G., 1999, ‘The long term politics of pro-poor policies’.
Wickremeratne, 1973, ‘The emergence of a Welfare Policy, 1931-1948’, in K. M. de Silva (ed.),
History of Ceylon, Volume 3: From the Beginning of the Nineteenth Century to 1948,
Peradeniya: University of Ceylon.