Including Outsiders in Latin America
Including Outsiders in Latin America
Including Outsiders in Latin America
1.1 Introduction
Throughout the twentieth century, much of the population of Latin
America lacked access to health care services, stable income, and pen-
sions. Although states introduced social protections for workers in the
formal sector (those with labor contracts), workers outside the formal
labor market and their dependents, whom I call “outsiders,” remained
unprotected or underserved by social policy. Outsiders include the urban
informal sector – the self-employed, street vendors, and employees hired
off the books – as well as rural workers and the unemployed. In the last
decade of the twentieth century, outsiders represented between 40 per-
cent and 80 percent of the population in the middle-income countries of
the region, and a large share of them lived in poverty.1
Two macro-level transformations that occurred in the last decades of
the twentieth century – the adoption of democratic regimes and economic
liberalization – raised contradictory expectations about the likelihood
that Latin American states would extend social protections to outsiders.
Democracies institutionalized electoral participation and opened chan-
nels for the expression of interests and demands, which seemed to augur
well for initiatives to reduce the welfare gap. Yet the debt crisis of the
early 1980s and the implementation of market-oriented reforms gave rise
to a period of state retrenchment marked by the remarkable spread of
pension privatization in the 1990s and the extension of small-scale, tar-
geted, and often clientelistic benefits to the very poor. In light of these
1
Estimates with government data (see Appendix 1). See also Portes and Hoffman (2003:
49, 53).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
2 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
2
See, for example, Haggard and Kaufman (2008); Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo (2001);
Rudra (2002); on pension reform, see Brooks (2001; 2009); Huber and Stephens (2000);
Kay (1998); Madrid (2002; 2003); Mesa-Lago (1994); on clientelism, see Cornelius et
al. (1994); Dresser (1994); Kurtz (2004a); Magaloni (2006); Roberts (1995); Weyland
(1996a).
3
Calculated with data on formal-sector pension coverage for people 65 and older in 2011
and benefits for outsiders in 2010 from SEDESOL.
4
In South America, exceptions include Paraguay, Peru, and Venezuela. The latter two cases
are discussed in Chapter 8. As discussed in Chapter 2, I use the threshold of 35 percent to
operationalize expansion.
5
Author’s estimate with government data of pensions, cash transfers and population. For
more information and sources, see Appendix 1.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
3
97%
79%
74% 72%
55% 58%
48%
36%
30% 27%
25%
10%
0% 0% 0% 0%
Figure 1.1 Share of outsider seniors and children with benefits before and after
expansion, selected countries.
Note: Outsider seniors 65+ (60+ Brazil, 1980).
Source: Author’s calculations with government sources (see Appendix 1).
These social policy innovations for outsiders are puzzling for a num-
ber of reasons. First, not only did social policy expansion take place at
a time of state retreat, but these benefits also reached the most vulner-
able and disempowered sectors of the population. This outcome runs
counter to the widely held assumption that outsiders lack the capacity to
exert political influence and attain meaningful policy responses in Latin
America’s nascent democracies. According to the literature, outsiders
face formidable obstacles to collective action because they have hetero-
geneous interests stemming from their diverse and often individualistic
economic activities (e.g., working as street vendors), which limit their
ability to coordinate around common goals and demands and develop
organizations to represent their interests (see Cross 1998; Kurtz 2004a).
At the same time, if organizations form among outsiders, these are seen
as having scarce resources. This prevents these organizations from hav-
ing a meaningful influence on state policy and often leads them to suc-
cumb to co-optation and clientelism.6 Furthermore, scholars argue that
in the context of scarcity produced by the debt crisis and market reforms,
powerful insiders prioritized the protection of their own benefits over
6
See particularly Kurtz (2004a). For a critique and discussion of this literature, see Arce
and Bellinger (2007); essays in Collier and Handlin (2009); Garay (2007); Holland and
Palmer-Rubin (2015).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
4 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
7
On bureaucracies, see Calvo and Murillo (2004) and Luna and Mardones (2014). On
party systems, see Hagopian (2014); Kitschelt et al. (2010); Mainwaring (1999); Roberts
(2014). On clientelistic linkages, see Luna (2014).
8
Levitsky (2003); for the recent period, see Etchemendy and Garay (2011).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
5
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
6 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
9
Haggard and Kaufaman’s book on Latin America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe reaches
this conclusion (2008).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
7
10
Haggard and Kaufman (2008); Huber, Mustillo, and Stephens (2008); Rudra (2002);
Rudra and Haggard (2005); Segura-Ubiergo (2007).
11
See Appendix 1 for further reference.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
8 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
connection between welfare and women unfolds and what its ramifica-
tions are across different models of social policy for outsiders constitutes
a fundamental topic of research, as gender inequality has been associ-
ated with many pernicious social dynamics worldwide.
A key political question, then, is why outsiders matter in some coun-
tries, to the point of becoming the target of large-scale policy innova-
tions. The next section discusses alternative explanations for social policy
expansion, and the following sections present the argument advanced in
this book.
12
Contrasts in average regional rates of economic growth are not particularly marked
between the 1990s, when Latin America grew on average 2.6 percent, and the 2000s,
when the region’s average growth rate was 3.2 percent (GDP rates of growth from
ECLAC; CEPALSTAT).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
9
13
Data from Cepalstat (www.cepal.org, accessed March, 2015), shows that in 2010,
Mexico’s primary exports represented 24 percent of total exports while in the middle-
income economies of South America, primary exports represented between 62.9 percent
and 95.7 percent of total exports. Between 2002 and 2013, the average share of primary
exports was 23.4 percent in Mexico and it ranged from 55.3 to 92.5 percent in the coun-
tries of South America.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
10 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
10% Arg_P
Arg_HC
Ur_HC+ P
Chi_HC Ecu_HC Ecu_HC
Bol_P+IS
5% Bra_HC Bol_P Mex_HC Chi_P
Ecu_IS Mex_P Bol_IS
GDP Change
Bra_P Mex_IS
Bra_IS Bra_IS Arg_IS Ec_P
0% Uru_IS Uru_IS
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
–5%
Bra–P
–10% Arg_IS
–15%
Year of Expansion
Figure 1.2 Timing of expansion and GDP change, selected countries, 1992–2010.
Note: IS: Income Support (cash transfer programs); P: Pensions; HC (health care).
Sources: Author’s estimates of timing of expansion, GDP from World Bank
Development Indicators and ECLAC.
14
I discuss the cases of Peru and Venezuela in Chapter 8.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
11
20
15
10
% GDP Growth
0
1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014
–5
–10
Year
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
12 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
2007). In cases in which the state did not control revenues from commod-
ities directly but captured them via export taxes or royalties, businesses
and producers also pressured to avoid taxation (see Fairfield 2015).
Understanding why governments paid so much attention to outsiders
beginning in the 1990s, in the context of state retreat, economic crisis, or
high levels of growth, requires an explanation that goes beyond the avail-
ability of increased resources. Resources in and of themselves do not tell
us why governments were willing to reach out to outsiders, historically
the poorest and most politically vulnerable sectors of the population, and
why they chose to allocate resources through social policy transfers and
services instead of prioritizing other initiatives such as food subsidies or
employment-creation programs. This book argues that specific political
factors are fundamental to understanding governments’ social policy
decisions and the incentives that led incumbents – regardless of having
windfall revenue or not – to embark on expansion.
15
See Levitsky and Roberts (2011); Weyland, Madrid, and Hunter (2010).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
13
Diffusion of Policy Models
A final potential explanation for the expansion of social policy and the
models adopted is based on the diffusion of policy models. The scholarly
literature on market reforms does emphasize diffusion as an important
factor contributing to the adoption of social policy change, particularly
privatization, in Latin America’s nascent democracies. As discussed by
Weyland (2006; 2004), theories of diffusion contend that policy change
results from the spread of policy principles (such as universality) or policy
models (such as social security) in temporal waves across geographically
proximate countries (see Weyland 2006: 19–21). Despite background
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
14 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
15
18
On variation in income transfers, see Garay (2016).
19
On the classic literature on diffusion and emulation, see Heclo (1974); Meyer and
Rowan (1977); on sociological institutionalism, see Thelen (1999). For diffusion in Latin
America, see Collier and Messick (1975).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
16 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
20
See Chapter 3 for further reference.
21
See Chapter 3 for full discussion.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
17
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
1950s–1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s 2000s 2010s
to social security, we see that this share declined at different rates with
industrialization and the growth of public-sector employment between
the 1950s and 1980s. By the early 1980s or 1990s, it reached a plateau,
making up between 40 percent and 60 percent of the total population –
including both workers and their dependents – in the cases under inves-
tigation (Figure 1.4). The size of the outsider population did grow at
different moments during crises, but usually on a temporary basis. Within
the workforce, informal and rural workers are the groups that generally
fall into the ranks of the unemployed during economic shocks, recessions,
and times of high inflation.22
At the same time that the relative size of the outsider population
stagnated – growing during crises – the political relevance of outsiders
increased significantly in the last quarter of the twentieth century.
Beginning in the late 1970s, Latin America witnessed the longest, broadest,
and deepest wave of democratization in the region’s history, which
afforded outsiders political weight in different ways. First, compared to
previous episodes of democratic rule, outsiders gained often unprecedented
22
On the informal economy, see Beccaria and Maurizio (2003); Schijman and Dorna
(2012); Portes and Hoffman (2003).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
18 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
23
See, for example, Houtzager (1998), Huneeus (2000), and Novaes (1991), and references
in Chapter 3.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
19
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
20 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
24
On process tracing, see Bennett and Checkel (2015) and Seawright and Collier (2004).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
21
25
On single-country studies, see Díaz-Cayeros, Estévez, and Magaloni (forthcoming). On
large-N analysis using social expenditure see Huber, Mustillo, and Stephens (2008);
Rudra (2002); Rudra and Haggard (2005); Segura-Ubiergo (2007).
26
Several studies of social expenditure use IMF expenditure data that a) only capture
direct national-level spending and thus severely underestimate social service expendi-
ture in federal systems, and that b) group spending by theme into two categories –
social services, and social security and welfare – which prevents students from observing
variations across individual policy areas. See, for example, Carnes and Mares (2009);
Haggard and Kaufman (2008); Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo (2001); Segura-Ubiergo
(2007).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
22 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
27
The most industrialized countries in the region are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico,
Uruguay, and Venezuela. These are also the countries with the highest GDP per capita,
and the ones that have developed systems of social protection for insiders since the first
half of the twentieth century. At the same time, they comprise close to 75 percent of the
population in the region (see CEPAL 2009).
28
See Brooks (2001); Madrid (2003); Weyland (2004).
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
23
Broader Comparisons
In Chapters 3 and 8, the main findings of this book are further assessed
against two additional comparison sets of cases: (a) a longitudinal analy-
sis of the four cases under investigation since the establishment of ben-
efits for insiders in the 1920s and 1940s, and (b) a broader cross-country
comparison within and beyond Latin America.
Longitudinal Comparison. In Chapter 3, I examine the period that starts
with the creation of benefits for insiders in the 1920s and 1940s and
that ends with the recent adoption of large policies for outsiders. This
comparison has two main goals. First, I seek to assess the explanatory
power of this study’s framework against a period in which most ben-
efits were extended to insiders and outsiders were largely neglected.
Second, this longitudinal comparison also permits the analysis of varia-
tion in social policy provisions incumbents extended to outsiders under
nondemocratic political regimes and different economic circumstances.
Specifically, I investigate why incumbents in some authoritarian regimes
provided some benefits to outsiders while others did not introduce social
policy innovations, and I analyze the specific features of those provisions
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
24 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
(e.g., scope, benefit levels, nondiscretionary access) and why they were
adopted.
Cross-country Comparison. The second broader comparison involves
three additional middle-income countries in the region – Peru, Uruguay,
and Venezuela – as well as South Africa, a middle-income country with
high levels of economic inequality, which has been analyzed in compara-
tive political economy and public policy studies together with middle-
income countries of Latin America (see Lieberman 2003, 2009; Seidman
1994). These four cases display broad variation across both explanatory
factors and outcomes. Venezuela and Peru allow us to assess social policy
dynamics in cases without significant expansion of large-scale nondiscre-
tionary benefits, and without a strong presence of the key factors pro-
pelling incumbents to expand. Uruguay in turn exemplifies dynamics of
expansion propelled by electoral competition for outsiders and exhibits
intertemporal variation in the process of policy design, with conserva-
tives dominating policy making in the early expansions and social move-
ments engaging in the process of expansion through an allied party at a
later stage. Finally, South Africa provides an excellent case for assessing
the applicability of the argument in a context of no electoral competi-
tion for outsider voters. In this particular case, social movements allied
to a dominant party played a prominent role in prompting adoption and
shaping policy in specific areas.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
25
29
Folha de São Paulo, O Estado de São Paulo, Jornal do Brasil, Jornal da Tarde, Jornal de
Brasília, Correio Brasiliense, and O Globo. Some articles from other newspapers have
also been used.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
26 Social Policy Expansion in Latin America
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001
27
from below pressing for social benefits. I further show that governments
adopted different models of social policy depending on whether incum-
bents negotiated policy design with the congressional opposition or
whether they (also) responded to social mobilization and granted social
movements access to the process of policy design. The concluding chapter
extends the argument to a broader comparison of middle-income coun-
tries and assesses the social and political effects and theoretical implica-
tions of these social policy transformations.
Downloaded from https:/www.cambridge.org/core. Columbia University Libraries, on 25 Jun 2017 at 20:33:49, subject to the Cambridge
Core terms of use, available at https:/www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316585405.001