Forecasting Profits&EARN
Forecasting Profits&EARN
University of Chicago
Graduate School of Business
Eugene F. Fama
Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago
Kenneth R. French
Sloan School of Management, MIT
An index to the Working Papers in the Center for Research in Security Prices Working Paper Series is located
at: http//gsbwww.uchicago.edu/fac/finance/papers/
First draft: June 1997
Revised: February 1999
Not for Quotation: Comments Welcome
Abstract
reverting. We provide corroborating evidence. In a simple partial adjustment model, the estimated rate of mean
reversion is about 40 percent per year. But a simple partial adjustment model with a uniform rate of mean
reversion misses rich non-linear patterns in the behavior of profitability. Specifically, we find that mean reversion
is faster when profitability is below its mean and when it is further from its mean in either direction. We also
show that the mean reversion in profitability produces predictable variation in earnings.
*
Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago (Fama); Sloan School of Management, MIT, and NBER
(French). The comments of Douglas Diamond, Elizabeth Gordon, Douglas Hanna, and a referee are gratefully
acknowledged.
There is a strong presumption in economics that profitability is mean reverting. For example, Stigler
“There is no more important proposition in economic theory than that, under competition, the rate of
return on investment tends toward equality in all industries. Entrepreneurs will seek to leave relatively
unprofitable industries and enter relatively profitable industries…”
These standard economic arguments imply that in a competitive environment, profitability is mean
reverting within as well as across industries. Other firms eventually mimic innovative products and technologies
that produce above normal profitability for a firm. And the prospect of failure or takeover gives firms with low
Mean reversion in profitability implies that changes in profitability and earnings are to some extent
predictable. There is a large literature, mostly in accounting, that attempts to identify predictable variation in
earnings and (less commonly) profitability. The evidence is, however, difficult to judge, for three reasons.
(i) Some early studies that produce tantalizing suggestions of predictability provide no formal tests [for
(ii) When formal tests are provided, they are often based on time-series models fit separately to
individual firms. To enhance power, the tests are restricted to firms with long earnings histories; requiring 20
years of data is common. Although 20 years is a long period in a firm’s life, 20 observations on annual earnings
produce imprecise estimates of a time-series model. As a result, evidence that suggests economically interesting
predictability is typically statistically weak [for example, Lev (1969), Freeman, Ohlson and Penman (1982)].
(iii) Cross-section regressions of changes in profitability or earnings on lagged changes and other
variables seem to produce more reliable evidence of predictability [Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman (1982), Ou
and Penman (1989), Collins and Kothari (1989), Easton and Zmijewski (1989), Elgers and Lo (1994), Basu
(1997)]. With the exception of Elgers and Lo (1994), however, the standard errors of the regression slopes in
these tests are not adjusted for the correlation of regression residuals across firms. In effect, the standard errors
are based on the patently unrealistic assumption that there is no correlation across firms in current changes in
profitability and earnings (due, for example, to current macro-economic or industry shocks) beyond that absorbed
We take a different tack that preserves the power of the cross-section tests but produces inferences that
allow for residual cross-correlation. In the spirit of Fama and MacBeth (1973), we forecast profitability and
earnings with year-by-year cross-section regressions, and we use the average slopes and their time-series standard
errors to draw inferences. This approach allows us to use large samples, an average of 2304 firms per year. And
the year-by-year variation in the slopes, which determines the standard errors of the average slopes, includes the
effects of estimation error due to the correlation of the residuals across firms.
Allowing for residual cross-correlation is important. The average slopes from our year-by-year cross-
section regressions are essentially equivalent to the slopes from pooled time-series cross-section regressions that
include annual dummies that allow the average values of the variables to change through time. Pooled time-series
cross-section regressions are a popular choice for solving the power problem in times-series tests on individual
firms [for example, Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman (1982), Fairfield, Sweeney, and Yohn (1996)]. And the
inference problem created by residual cross correlation is typically ignored. Without showing the details, the
Fama-MacBeth standard errors of our average regression slopes (which account for residual cross correlation)
are typically two to five times larger than the OLS standard errors from pooled time-series cross-section
regressions.
Accurate inferences are important, but our main contribution is substantive. Confirming standard
economic arguments, we find strong evidence that profitability (measured as the ratio of year t earnings before
interest to total book assets, Yt/At) is mean reverting. In a simple partial adjustment model, the rate of mean
reversion is about 40 percent per year. But a simple partial adjustment model with a uniform rate of mean
reversion does not do justice to the rich patterns in the behavior of profitability. Specifically, we find that the rate
of mean reversion is higher when profitability is far from its mean, in either direction. The rate of mean reversion
Like changes in profitability, changes in earnings are predictable. When we restrict the explanatory
variables to lagged earnings changes, we confirm the early qualitative evidence of Brooks and Buckmaster (1976)
that changes in earnings tend to reverse from one year to the next, and large changes of either sign reverse faster
3
than small changes. We also confirm the formal evidence of Elgers and Lo (1994) that negative changes in
For the mostpart, the existing literature does not examine the links between the predictability of
profitability and the predictability of earnings. This is true even in the rare papers that examine both variables
[for example, Beaver (1970), Ball and Watts (1972)]. In contrast, like Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman (1982)
and Lev (1983), our hypothesis is that much of what is predictable about earnings is due to the mean reversion
of profitability. And our tests confirm the hypothesis. Our results thus imply that real-world forecasts of
earnings (for example, by security analysts) should incorporate the mean reversion in profitability. There is,
however, predictable variation in earnings beyond that captured by our model for profitability. Specifically,
negative changes in earnings and extreme changes seem to reverse faster than predicted by our specific non-linear
We begin (section I) with estimates of a simple partial adjustment model for profitability in which the
rate of mean reversion is a constant, that is, it does not depend on how profitability deviates from its expected
value. Section II fine-tunes the model to allow for non-linear mean reversion. Section III tests for predictable
As a first test for predictable variation in profitability, we estimate, for each year t from 1964 to 1995,
a simple cross-section partial adjustment regression for the change in profitability from t to t+1,
At is a firm’s total book assets at the end of year t; Yt is earnings before interest and extraordinary items but after
taxes; Yt/At is our measure of profitability; E(Yt/At) is its expected value; CPt = Yt/At – Yt-1/At-1 is the change
in profitability from t-1 to t; and DFEt = Yt/At – E(Yt/At) is the deviation of profitability from its expected value.
4
To simplify the notation, we omit the firm subscript that should appear on the regression variables and residuals,
and the year subscript that should appear on the regression coefficients.
We use a two-step approach to estimate (1). Each year t, we regress Yt/At for the firms in our sample
on variables meant to capture differences across firms in expected profitability. We then use the fitted values
from this first-stage regression as the proxy for E(Yt/At) in the cross-section estimate of (1) for year t.
We use three variables to explain expected profitability in the first-stage regressions. (i) An old
hypothesis is that dividends have information about expected earnings because firms target dividends to the
permanent component of earnings [Miller and Modigliani (1961)]. Thus one of our proxies for expected
profitability is Dt/BEt, the ratio of year t dividends to the book value of common equity at the end of the year.
(ii) Fama and French (1999) find that firms that do not pay dividends tend to be much less profitable than
dividend payers. To capture any resulting non-linearity in the relation between dividends and expected
profitability, our second variable is a dummy, DDt, that is 0.0 for dividend payers and 1.0 for non-payers. (iii)
Since the market value of a firm, Vt, is the current value of all future net-cash-flows, we use the market-to-book
ratio, Vt/At, to pick up variation in expected profitability missed by the dividend variables. [Additional proxies
for expected profitability tried but dropped for lack of explanatory power include the log of total assets (a
measure of size) and the ratio of depreciation expense to total assets (a measure of capital intensity).] The proxy
for expected profitability, E(Yt/At), in (1) is then the fitted value from the cross-section regression,
The tests exclude financial firms and utilities. Financial firms and utilities are highly regulated during
much of our sample period, and regulation may produce unusual behavior of profitability. We are also concerned
that influential observations might dominate the regressions. The variables in (1) and (2) are scaled by assets
or book equity. This can create influential observations when At and BEt are close to zero. To address this
problem, firms with total assets less than $10 million and book equity less than $5 million are not used in the
tests. These exclusions still leave us with hefty cross-sections, an average of 2304 firms per year.
5
We use the average slopes and the time-series standard errors of the average slopes in (1) and (2) to draw
inferences. A benefit of this approach is that the standard errors of the average slopes include estimation error
due to the correlation of the regression residuals across firms. Autocorrelation in the slopes from the year-by-year
regressions is also a problem. The higher-order autocorrelations are random about zero, but first-order
autocorrelations are sometimes large, around 0.5. We could adjust the standard errors of the average slopes for
the estimated autocorrelation of the annual slopes. But with just 32 observations on the slopes for 1964-95,
autocorrelation estimates are imprecise; the standard errors are around 0.18. We use a less formal approach to
allow for the autocorrelation of the annual regression slopes. With first-order autocorrelations around 0.5, the
variances of the average slopes, calculated assuming serial independence of the annual slopes, are too small by
about 50%, and the standard errors of the average slopes should be inflated by 40%. Thus we require t-statistics
Part A of Table 1 shows average slopes from the first-stage regressions of Yt/At on Vt/At, DDt, and
Dt/BEt. All three variables have information about expected profitability, E(Yt/At). The positive average slope
on Dt/BEt is 8.44 standard errors from zero. The negative average slope on DDt confirms that the relation
between profitability and dividends is non-linear; the expected profitability of firms that do not pay dividends
is 0.025 lower (t = - 8.27) than predicted by the relation between Yt/At and Dt/BEt. The strong positive average
slope on Vt/At (t = 10.82) is consistent with the hypothesis that the market-to-book ratio captures variation in
Part B of Table 1 shows average slopes from second-stage estimates of the partial-adjustment model (1)
that do not constrain the slopes on expected profitability, E(Yt/At), and observed profitability, Yt/At. The partial-
adjustment model predicts that the Yt/At slope is negative, the E(Yt/At) slope is positive, and the two slopes are
equal in absolute value. The average Yt/At and E(Yt/At) slopes, -0.40 and 0.37, confirm these predictions. These
1
Elgers and Lo (1994) use annual cross-section regressions to model the autocorrelation of changes in earnings. Somewhat
uniquely, they also use the time-series standard errors of average regression slopes to allow for the correlation of residuals
across firms. But they do not adjust the standard errors of the average slopes for the autocorrelation of the annual slopes.
And they examine a much narrower range of models for the predictability of earnings.
6
average slopes are also quite precise (t = -18.00 and 13.55). All this is striking evidence that profitability is mean
reverting.
The lagged change in profitability, CPt = Yt/At – Yt-1/At-1, is included as an explanatory variable in (1)
to test whether the mean reversion captured by the partial adjustment term, DFEt = Yt/At – E(Yt/At), is the sole
source of predictable variation in profitability. Table 1 shows that when the lagged change in profitability, CPt,
is used alone to explain CPt+1, the slope on CPt is strongly negative; on average, the change in profitability from
t to t+1 reverses 30 percent (t = -10.84) of the lagged change. But allowing for mean reversion, that is, including
Yt/At and E(Yt/At) in the regression, moves the CPt slope close to zero, -0.09. Still, the average CPt slope is -4.72
standard errors from zero. Thus there is small but statistically reliable negative autocorrelation in changes in
It is worth noting that the strong evidence that the change in profitability is predictable from the lagged
change is testimony to the power of the cross-section regressions. In a typical time-series test using 20 years of
annual changes, the standard error of the autocorrelation of successive changes is (1/19)½ = 0.23. Thus, the
coefficient -0.30, which is -10.84 standard errors from zero in the cross-section regressions, would be only 1.30
standard errors from zero in a time-series regression with 20 observations. This is the generic power problem
in tests that attempt to identify predictable variation in profitability (or earnings) using time-series models fit to
individual firms.
Our estimate of the rate of mean reversion of profitability, in the neighborhood of 0.40 (40 percent per
year) is similar to the median of the estimates for individual firms in Lev (1969). He fits separate partial
adjustment models to 20 years of time-series data for individual firms. The resulting estimates of the rate of mean
reversion are imprecise; the median is only 1.71 standard errors from zero. The cross-section partial adjustment
regressions in Fairfield, Sweeney, and Yohn (1996) also produce rates of mean reversion near 0.4 (0.35). But
they test the reliability of the estimates with out-of-sample forecasts that do not adjust for the correlation of the
forecast errors across firms. We corroborate these earlier estimates, but with more precise methods.
7
Finally, simple economic stories say that competitive forces push profitability toward a common
economy-wide mean. In the partial adjustment model (1), however, we allow E(Yt/At) to vary across firms.
Cross-sectional differences in expected profitability can occur for several reasons. First, even with perfect
competition, differences in risk produce differences in expected profitability. Second, our measure of
profitability, Yt/At, is a noisy proxy for true economic profitability. For example, even if all firms share the same
true expected profitability, systematic differences between the historical and replacement costs of assets create
systematic differences in E(Yt/At). Third, differences in expected profitability can be the result of monopoly
rents.
How are the estimates of (1) affected if we assume all firms revert toward one overall equilibrium level
of expected profitability? With this assumption, the partial adjustment model in (1a) simplifies to
and profitability reverts to the grand mean at the rate -b. Table 1 shows that the estimated rate of mean reversion
from (3) is 31 percent per year (t = 14.53). The somewhat higher rates of mean reversion produced by (1) then
suggest that (2) captures meaningful differences across firms in expected profitability.
Though they attempt no formal inferences, Brooks and Buckmaster (1976) present evidence that changes
in earnings are likely to reverse from one year to the next, the reversals are stronger for extreme changes of either
sign, and they are stronger for negative changes. Elgers and Lo (1994) formally confirm the last result. These
papers focus on changes in earnings. Given our hypothesis that the predictability of earnings should be largely
due to mean reversion in profitability, it is interesting to test whether there is similar non-linearity in the behavior
of profitability. To this end, we expand the partial adjustment model (1) as,
NDFEDt, PDFEDt, NCPDt, and PCPDt are dummy variables. NDFEDt is 1.0 when DFEt (the deviation of
profitability from its expected value) is negative, and zero otherwise; PDFEDt is 1.0 when DFEt is positive;
NCPDt is 1.0 when CPt (the change in profitability from t-1 to t) is negative; PCPDt is 1.0 when CPt is positive.
The derived variables in (4b) are negative deviations of profitability from its expected value (NDFEt), squared
negative deviations (SNDFEt), squared positive deviations (SPDFEt), negative changes in profitability (NCPt),
squared negative changes (SNCPt), and squared positive changes (SPCPt). In brief, b2, b3, and b4 measure non-
linearity in the mean reversion of profitability, that is, in the speed of adjustment of profitability to its expected
value. And c2, c3, and c4 measure non-linearity in the autocorrelation of changes in profitability.
Table 1 suggests that there is non-linearity in the autocorrelation of changes in profitability similar to
that observed by Brooks and Buckmaster (1976) and Elgers and Lo (1994) for changes in earnings. When we
estimate (4b) without the mean reversion variables (that is, suppressing b1 to b4), we find that changes in
profitability tend to reverse (the CPt slope is negative), negative changes tend to reverse faster than positive
changes (the NCPt slope is negative), and reversal is stronger for more extreme changes (the SNCPt slope is
positive and the SPCPt slope is negative). But most of these results are statistically weak. Only the SNCPt slope
We are more interested in whether the autocorrelation of changes in profitability can be attributed to
mean reversion in the level of profitability. Table 1 shows that when we add the mean reversion variables, that
is, we estimate the full version of (4b), the slopes c1 to c4 on the autocorrelation variables move toward zero, and
c1, c2, and c4 are less than 1.25 standard errors from zero. The slope c3 on SNCPt falls by about two-thirds in
In the end, non-linear mean reversion is a fairly complete story for the predictable variation in
profitability. Allowing for non-linearity pushes the slopes on Yt/At and E(Yt/At) (the two components of the
linear partial adjustment term, DFEt) toward zero, but they remain opposite in sign, strikingly close in absolute
value (-0.15 and 0.14), and more than five standard errors from zero. And the rate of mean reversion is highly
9
non-linear. Mean reversion is stronger when profitability is below its mean; the slope on NDFEt is -0.12 (t =
-2.71). Mean reversion is also stronger when profitability is further from its mean; the slopes on the quadratic
terms SNDFEt and SPDFEt, 1.02 and -1.89, are more than 4.5 standard errors from zero.
From an economic perspective, it is plausible that the rate of mean reversion is higher when profitability
is below its mean and when it is far from its mean in either direction. When profitability is low, the prospect of
failure or takeover gives firms an incentive to allocate assets to more productive uses. And the incentive is
stronger the further profitability is below its mean. Conversely, the incentives of other firms to mimic the
products and technologies of their rivals increase when the rivals are more profitable. It is also possible, however,
that non-linear mean reversion, and mean reversion itself, trace in part to accounting decisions. For example,
Basu (1997) argues that bias toward conservative reporting leads firms to report losses quickly but to spread
gains over longer periods. Such a tendency could help explain why profitability reverts more quickly when it is
low.
The existing predictability literature focuses primarily on earnings rather than profitability. Moreover,
the literature is largely agnostic about the economic forces that cause earnings to be predictable. Notable
exceptions are Freeman, Ohlson, and Penman (1982) and Lev (1983). They argue that competitive forces
produce mean reversion in profitability, which is then the source of predictable variation in earnings. This is also
the stance adopted here. We now examine whether changes in earnings are predictable and how much of the
Table 2 shows estimates of (4) in which the dependent variable is the (scaled) change in earnings, CEt+1
= (Yt+1 – Yt)/At, rather than the change in profitability, CPt+1 = Yt+1/At+1 – Yt/At. The new regression is,
The explanatory variables in the first line of (5a) and (5b) are those used in (4a) and (4b) to capture the mean
reversion of profitability. The new variables are in the second line of (5a) and (5b). They are designed to pick
up autocorrelation in earnings changes left unexplained by the mean reversion of profitability. NCEDt and PCEDt
in the second line of (5a) are dummy variables. NCEDt is 1.0 when CEt (the change in earnings from t-1 to t) is
negative and zero otherwise. PCEDt is 1.0 when CEt is positive. The derived variables in the second line of (5b)
are negative changes in earnings (NCEt), squared negative changes (SNCEt), and squared positive changes
(SPCEt). Thus, c2, c3, and c4 are meant to pick up non-linearity in the autocorrelation of changes in earnings.
Table 2 says that there is indeed non-linearity in the autocorrelation of earnings changes. When we use
only the lagged change, CEt, to predict CEt+1, the slope is -0.14. This corroborates time-series evidence [Beaver
(1970), Ball and Watts (1972)], that the linear autocorrelation of successive changes in earnings is weak; earnings
seem to behave much like a random walk. In our cross-section tests, however, the autocorrelation of -0.14 is -
4.33 standard errors from zero. Thus, even in a linear model, the deviation of earnings from a random walk is
reliable. When we add negative changes in earnings to the linear model, the slope on CEt turns slightly positive,
but the NCEt slope is strongly negative, -0.48 (t = -8.81). This is in line with the evidence in Elgers and Lo
(1994) that the reversal tendency of changes in earnings is more reliable for negative changes. But our tests also
say that reversal is stronger for more extreme changes in earnings of either sign. When we add squared positive
and squared negative changes in earnings (SPCEt and SNCEt) to the regressions that include CEt and NCEt, the
slope on NCEt remains strongly negative (-0.42, t = -7.64) and the SNCEt and SPCEt slopes, 1.71 and -0.63, are
In short, there is a rich non-linear pattern in the autocorrelation of successive changes in earnings. The
reversal tendency of earnings changes is stronger for more extreme changes of either sign. And reversal is
stronger when earnings have declined. All of this is formal corroboration of the early informal evidence on
We are interested in whether the autocorrelation of earnings changes can be attributed in whole or in part
to non-linear mean reversion in the level of profitability. Table 2 shows that when we add the linear mean
reversion variables Yt/At and E(Yt/At) to the regressions that also include the four autocorrelation variables (CEt,
NCEt, SNCEt and SPCEt), there is strong evidence that mean reversion leads to predictable variation in
profitability; the slopes on Yt/At and E(Yt/At), -0.32 and 0.46, are -13.07 and 13.19 standard errors from zero.
But the average slopes on the autocorrelation variables remain strong (more than four standard errors from zero).
Allowing for the non-linear mean reversion behavior of profitability (adding DFEt, SNDFEt, and SPDFEt to the
regressions) moves the slopes on most of the autocorrelation variables closer to zero, but the CEt, NCEt, and
SPCEt slopes are still more than four standard errors from zero. Thus, it seems that the non-linear behavior of
profitability is far from a complete story for the predictable variation in earnings.
Since the specific functional form we use to model profitability is surely not a complete story for the
mean reversion of profitability, it is not surprising that it misses some of the predictability of earnings changes.
But there is another reason to question the specification of the earnings change regressions. Unconditional
expected earnings growth, E(Yt+1 – Yt)/At = E(CEt+1), surely differs across firms. As a result, some of the
apparent forecast power of the explanatory variables in the CEt+1 regressions is probably driven by differences
in unconditional expected earnings changes rather than by true predictability of earnings. In contrast, since
profitability cannot drift forever up or down, the unconditional expected value of the change, CPt+1 = Yt+1/At+1
– Yt/At, is probably close to zero for most firms. Thus, the profitability regression (4) is probably better specified
There is evidence that variation across firms in unconditional expected earnings growth is a problem in
the estimates of (5). Though noisy, the lagged change in earnings is a likely candidate to pick up variation across
firms in E(CEt+1). Since reversal seems to be the general characteristic of earnings changes, the positive slope
on CEt in the full version of (5), 0.18 (t = 5.56), suggests that this variable does identify variation in
One might get cleaner estimates of the predictability of changes in earnings by modeling variation across
firms in expected earnings growth. But our view is that profitability, not earnings, is the interesting economic
variable. And the interesting predictability issue is whether competitive forces produce mean reversion in
profitability.
IV. Conclusions
Standard economic arguments say that in a competitive environment, profitability is mean reverting. Our
evidence is in line with this prediction. In a simple partial adjustment model, the rate of mean reversion is about
40 percent per year. But the mean reversion of profitability is highly non-linear. Mean reversion is faster when
profitability is below its mean and when it is far from its mean in either direction.
There is also predictable variation in earnings. Much of it traces to the mean reversion of profitability.
An important practical implication of this result is that forecasts of earnings (for example, by security analysts)
should exploit the mean reversion in profitability. There does, however, seem to be predictable variation in
earnings beyond that captured by our model for profitability. In particular, negative changes in earnings and
extreme changes seem to reverse faster than predicted by our specific model for the mean reversion of
profitability.
13
References
Ball, Ray, and Ross Watts, 1972, Some time-series properties of accounting income, Journal of Finance 27,
663-682.
Basu, Sudipta, 1997, The conservatism principle and the asymmetric timeliness of earnings, Journal of
Accounting and Economics 24, 3-37.
Beaver, William H., 1970, The time series behavior of earnings, Journal of Accounting Research 8
(Supplement), 62-99.
Brooks, LeRoy D., and Dale A. Buckmaster, 1976, Further evidence of the time series properties of accounting
income, Journal of Finance 31, 1359-1373.
Collins, Daniel W., and S.P. Kothari, 1989, An analysis of intertemporal and cross-sectional determinants of
earnings response coefficients, Journal of Accounting and Economics 11, 143-181.
Easton, Peter D., and Mark Zmijewski, 1989, Cross-sectional variation in the stock market response to
accounting earnings announcements, Journal of Accounting and Economics 11, 117-141.
Elgers, Peter T., and May H. Lo, 1994, Reductions in analysts’ annual earnings forecast errors using information
in prior earnings and security returns, Journal of Accounting Research 32, 290-303.
Fairfield, Patricia M., Richard J. Sweeney, and Teri Lombardi Yohn, 1996, Accounting classification and the
predictive content of earnings, Accounting Review 71, 337-355.
Fama, Eugene F., and Kenneth R. French, 1999, Dividends, debt, investment, and earnings, manuscript, Graduate
School of Business, University, of Chicago, January.
Fama, Eugene F., and James D. MacBeth, 1973, Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests, Journal of
Political Economy 81, 607-636.
Freeman, Robert N., James A. Ohlson, and Stephen H. Penman, 1982, Book rate-of-return and prediction of
earnings changes: An empirical investigation, Journal of Accounting Research 20, 639-653.
Lev, Baruch, 1969, Industry averages as targets for financial ratios, Journal of Accounting Research 7
(Autumn), 290-299.
Lev, Baruch, 1983, Some economic determinants of time-series properties of earnings, Journal of Accounting
and Economics 5, 31-48.
Lookabill, Larry L., 1976, Some additional evidence on the time series properties of accounting earnings, The
Accounting Review 51 (October), 724-738.
Miller, Merton H., and Franco Modigliani, 1961, Dividend policy, growth, and the valuation of shares, Journal
of Business 34, 411-433.
Ou, Jane A., and Stephen H. Penman, 1989, Accounting measurement, price-earnings ratio, and the information
content of security prices, Journal of Accounting Research 27, 111-152.
14
Stigler, George J., 1963, Capital and Rates of Return in Manufacturing Industries, Princeton University Press,
Princeton, NJ.
Table 1 -- Regressions to Explain the Level of and Change in Profitability: 1964-95, 32 Years
The regressions are run for each year t, from 1964 to 1995, using NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ firms on
Compustat with data for the year on all variables in any regression and with total assets greater than $10 million and book
common equity greater than $5 million. The table shows means (across years) of regression intercepts (Int) and slopes, and
t-statistics for the means t(Mn), defined as the mean divided by its standard error [times-series standard deviation of the
coefficient divided by (32)½]. The table also shows averages (across years) of the means and standard deviations (Std) of
the regression variables.
The variables (and Compustat data items) are as follows. At is total book assets (6). Dt is dividends paid during
fiscal year t (21). DDt is a dummy that is 1.0 when dividends are zero and zero otherwise. Yt is earnings before
extraordinary items (18), plus interest expense (15), plus (when available) income statement deferred taxes (50) and
investment tax credit (51). Book common equity, BEt, is At minus liabilities (181) minus preferred stock [taken to be, in
order and as available, redemption value (56), liquidating value (10), or par value (130)], plus balance sheet deferred taxes
and investment tax credit (35). Vt, the total value of the firm, is its common stock price (199) times shares outstanding at
the end of fiscal year t (25), plus At minus BEt. E(Yt/At), the proxy for expected profitability, is the fitted value from the
profitability regression for year t, summarized in Part A. DFEt is Yt/At – E(Yt/At). NDFEt is DFEt when DFEt is negative
and zero otherwise. SNDFEt is the square of DFEt when DFEt is negative and zero otherwise. SPDFEt is the square of DFEt
when DFEt is positive and zero otherwise. CPt is Yt/At – Yt-1/At-1. NCPt is CPt when CPt is negative and zero otherwise.
SNCPt is the square of CPt when CPt is negative and zero otherwise. SPCPt is the square of CPt when CPt is positive and
zero otherwise.
Part A: Average Slopes for Regressions to Explain the Change in Earnings, dYt+1/At = (Yt+1-Yt)/At
Int Yt/At E(Yt/At) NDFEt SNDFEt SPDFEt CEt NCEt SNCEt SPCEt R2
Mean .011 -.14 .05
t(Mn) 6.886 -4.33 3.80
Mean -.015 .05 .17 -.30 1.14 -2.17 .18 -.25 .50 -.48 .20
t(Mn) -5.940 1.59 3.31 -4.91 4.00 -6.25 5.56 -5.94 1.53 -4.80 7.80
Mean .010 .076 .076 -.019 .004 .002 .012 -.015 .003 .004
Std .073 .074 .029 .049 .037 .030 .072 .041 .040 .053