Zipf Plots and The Size Distribution of Firms: Economics Letters
Zipf Plots and The Size Distribution of Firms: Economics Letters
letters
ELSEVIER Economics Letters 49 (1995) 453-457
Abstract
We use a Zipf plot to demonstrate that the upper tail of the size distribution of firms is too thin relative to the log
normal rather than too fat, as had previously been believed.
This paper presents new evidence on the size distribution of firms. Like earlier studies, it
shows that the log-normal distribution fits the data well except for the upper tail. However, in
contrast to earlier studies, we find that there is too little mass in the upper tail, not too much.
We demonstrate this point with a statistical technique that has been used rarely in economics,
but is more c o m m o n in physics. 1 The technique, known as a Zipf plot, is a plot of the log of
the rank vs. the log of the variable being analyzed.
Let ( x l , . . . ,xN) be a set of N observations on a r a n d o m variable x for which the
cumulative distribution function is F ( x ) , and suppose that the observations are ordered from
largest to smallest so that the index i is the rank of x i. The Zipf plot of the sample is the graph
of In x i against In i. Because of the ranking, i / N = 1 - F ( x i ) , so
In i = In[1 - F ( x i ) ] + In N . (1)
Thus, the log of the rank is simply a transformation of the cumulative distribution function. It
accentuates the upper tail of the distribution and therefore makes it easier to detect deviations
* Corresponding author.
1 See Gell-Mann (1994, p. 93) for a discussion.
in the upper tail from the theoretical prediction of a particular distribution. Since there has
been interest in the upper tail of the size distribution of firms, the Zipf plot is particularly
useful for analyzing this question.
The Zipf plot for the log-normal distribution is characterized by
In i = I n [ 1 - ~ ( l n x i - +
- - tlz n) ] N C r , (2)
w h e r e / z and o- are the mean and standard deviation of In xi, and q~ is the standard normal
cumulative distribution function. Solving (2) for In x i as a function of In i gives
The data for this study are the 1993 sales of 4071 manufacturing firms (SIC codes
2000-3999) on Compustat. 2 Fig. 1 shows a histogram of the log of sales with bin sizes equal to
X/2. The curve is the normal density function with mean and standard deviation equal to the
sample mean and standard deviation of the log of sales. The graph seems to suggest that the
250 I
r
I
200 [
¢-
°
t
_
E 150
e i
lOO
E L
z i
50 ~
z Compustat is not, of course, the entire population of firms. In principle, though, it is the entire population of
publicly traded firms. While we only report results here for 1993, we have done the analysis for 1975, 1979, 1980,
and 1984 and obtained qualitatively similar results.
M.H.R. Stanley et al. I Economics Letters 49 (1995) 453-457 455
1012 .......
10 l°
10 8
m 06
10 4
0 , . . . . . . . i , , , , , , , , i , , . . . . . . t . . . . . . .
I0 I O0 1000 10000
Rank
Fig. 2. Zipf plot. The bottom curve is a Zipf plot (double logarithmic plot of sales vs. rank) for the same sample as
in Fig. 1. The top curve is a predicted Zipf plot obtained from the log-normal fit shown in Fig. 1.
distribution of the log of sales fits the log normal reasonably well. Fig. 2 shows the Zipf plot
along with the theoretical Zipf plot for the log normal. Like the histogram, the Zipf plot
suggests that the log normal fits the distribution of sales reasonably well. However, in contrast
to the histogram, the Zipf plot makes clear that the sales of the largest firms are smaller than
would be the case for a true log normal. The actual Zipf plot lies below the theoretical Zipf
plot for roughly the largest 100 firms.
With the aid of the Zipf plot, the deviations from the log normal can also be seen in Fig. 1.
First, the three points on the right lie slightly below the best fitting density function. The main
source of deviation is, however, that the upper tail should contain additional firms. The largest
firm in the sample, General Motors, has sales of $136 billion. The natural log of GM's sales is
25.63. The mean of the natural log of sales is 17.76 and the standard deviation is 2.72. Thus,
the natural log of GM's sales is 2.90 standard deviations above the mean. The probability that
an observation from a standard normal distribution exceeds 2.90 is 0.0019. Multiplying this
probability by the number of firms (other than GM) in the sample (4070) gives 7.73, which is
the expected number of firms with sales greater than $136 billion. If the distribution were log
normal, therefore, we would expect GM's level of sales to be the eighth or ninth largest, not
the first. All that would be needed for the size distribution of firms to be log normal would be
seven firms larger than GM!
This deviation from log normality is statistically significant. Under the null hypothesis of log
normality, the number of firms with sales greater than $136 billion has a binomial distribution
with p = 0.0019 and N = 4070. The variance is, therefore, 4070 x 0.0019 x 0.9981 = 7.72; and
the standard deviation is 2.78. Thus, the actual number of firms with sales greater than
456 M.H.R. Stanley et al. / Economics Letters 49 (1995) 453-457
$136 billion, which is 0, is 2.78 standard deviations less than the expected n u m b e r , which is
7.73. 3 The probability that none of the 4070 firms other than G M would have sales greater
than $136 billion is ( 1 - 0.0019) 4070= 0.00043, which is substantially below any conventional
standard for significance. 4
These results are of interest because of their implications for the literature on the dynamics
of firm growth. Gibrat (1931) showed that if the distribution of growth rates is i n d e p e n d e n t of
firm size, the static distribution of firm size would approach the log normal. In an early
empirical test using British data, Hart and Prais (1956) found evidence b o t h that the log
normal fits the distribution of firm sizes reasonably well and that the growth rates of firms
were i n d e p e n d e n t of initial size. T h e y found, however, statistically significant deviations of the
distribution from the log normal by estimating the third and fourth m o m e n t s of the
distribution. The distributions were 'somewhat skewed to the right and slightly leptokurtotic. '5
Q u a n d t (1966) p r o p o s e d four tests of the distribution of firm size. H e was able to reject log
normality for the Fortune 500 in both 1955 and 1960 with each of the four tests he used.
A l t h o u g h he was able to reject every distribution he tested for the F o r t u n e 500 with at least
one test for at least one of the years, the two Pareto distributions and the C h a m p e r n o w n e
generally fit better than the log normal. In summarizing the literature, Hall (1987) wrote:
" T h e size distribution of firms conforms fairly well to the log normal, with possibly s o m e
skewness to the right" (p. 584). Thus, the results here may suggest a qualitative change in the
size distribution in firms from the earlier time periods used in those studies. 6
Acknowledgments
We have benefited from conversations with Glenn Loury, Jeff Miron, and M a r t h a Schary
and from a referee's comments.
References
Gell-Mann, M., 1994, The quark and the jaguar (W.H. Freeman, New York).
Gibrat, R., 1931, Les in6galit6s economiques (Sirey, Paris).
3 Because p is small, N is large, and Np is moderate, the distribution of the number of firms with sales greater
than $136 billion is approximately Poisson. The fact that the standard deviation and the number of standard
deviations from the mean are (approximately) equal is due to the well-known result that the variance of a Poisson
distribution equals the mean.
4 Even if there were one firm with sales larger than $136 billion, log normality could be rejected at the 1% level.
Log normality could be nearly rejected at the 5% level if there were three firms with sales above $136 billion. (The
p-value for three firms is 0.051.)
5 The skewness of the log of sales in our sample is -4.01. The kurtosis is 176.7, which is 3.22 times the square of
the variance. This ratio is only slightly above the theoretical value of 3 for a normal distribution.
6 An alternative explanation is that the earlier studies by Simon and Bonini (1958) and Quandt (1966) used the
Fortune 500 as their samples.
M.H.R. Stanley et al. / Economics Letters 49 (1995) 453-457 457
Hall, B.H., 1987, The relationship between firm size and firm growth in the U.S. manufacturing sector, The
Journal of Industrial Economics 35, 583-606.
Hart, P.E. and S.J. Prais, 1956, The analysis of business concentration: A statistical approach, Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series A, 119, 150-181.
Quandt, R., 1966, On the size distribution of firms, American Economic Review 56, 416-432.
Simon, H. and C.P. Bonini, 1958, The size distribution of business firms, American Economic Review 46, 607-617.