Capital Regulation and Bank Failure Contagion: Daniel Mckeever
Capital Regulation and Bank Failure Contagion: Daniel Mckeever
Daniel McKeever*
Abstract
I provide simulation evidence that the complex systems framework is well-suited for explaining
the historical distribution of U.S. commercial bank failure cascades. I use the complex systems
framework to test a model of the efficacy of microprudential (bank-level) ratio-based capital
adequacy regulations. I find that these requirements generally have the adverse effect of
increasing the likelihood of large failure cascades. This adverse effect is especially pronounced
under simulation conditions that mimic economic downturns. If banks use more leverage in
response to decreased capital adequacy requirements, the likelihood of failure cascades increases
only minimally. These results suggest that existing microprudential capital adequacy
requirements might be counterproductive to the goal of mitigating bank failure cascades, and
provide theoretical support for a countercyclical capital buffer.
__________
Are microprudential (bank-level) capital regulations effective in reducing the overall rate
Regulatory efforts to reduce the likelihood of commercial bank failures suffer from an
apparent mismatch between the scope of the problem and the scope of the solution currently in
use. The financial health of large, interconnected banks is now widely understood to depend
directly on the financial health of the other large banks to which they are connected. Despite the
first-order importance of systemic risk in determining the likelihood of bank failures, however,
regulation.1
To date, most theoretical analyses of microprudential capital regulation have evaluated its
costs and benefits in the context of isolated, individual banks. 2 The costs and benefits of
largely unexamined.
Similarly, in the years since the financial crisis, most analyses of systemic risk have
naturally focused on measuring the contribution of network topology to the risks faced by
1
Basel III, codified in 2010 in response to the financial crisis, represents a shift in focus toward macroprudential
standards, designed to internalize the systemic externalities of individual institutions’ risk-taking. The innovation in
Basel III most relevant to this study is the countercyclical capital buffer, which is discussed in Section III.b.
2
There is no clear consensus in the theoretical literature as to the efficacy of microprudential capital regulations.
The theoretical costs of capital regulation include an increased cost of capital (Baker and Wurgler (2015)),
reductions in lending (Barajas et al. (2010)) and bank profitability (Osborne et al. (2012)), as well as the potential
creation of the perverse incentive for banks to rationally increase risk-taking and the expected return on their asset
portfolios in response to these constraints (Kahane (1977), Koehn and Santomero (1980), Calem and Rob (1999),
Berger et al. (1995), Blum (1999), and Diamond and Rajan (2000), among others). The theoretical benefits of capital
regulation are equally intuitive: a reduction in the number of insolvent banks and the size of banks’ losses (Furlong
and Keeley (1989), Berger and Bouwman (2013), Osborne et al. (2012)), and are most effective in conjunction with
complementary restrictions on overall leverage (Hugonnier and Morellec (2017)). These studies, many of which
predate the financial crisis, largely focus on the relationship between capital regulation and the costs or benefits to
an individual bank, rather than the banking system as a whole.
efficacy of the current microprudential regime for capital regulation (which was largely
engineered prior to the crisis) in mitigating risk which has a significant systemic component.
This paper links these two strands of literature by developing a theoretical framework for
interconnected financial institutions. Given the importance to the real economy of maintaining
the stability of the commercial banking system, understanding the nature of the relationship
between systemic risk and microprudential capital regulation is critical to designing an effective
regulatory regime.4
nodes of some kind, where each node has a value that depends in some way on its neighbors in
the network; and (b) a time-series of shocks that disturb these nodes in some way, with the added
requirement that the disturbance created by each shock persists until such time as a new shock
disturbs the same node again. Most shocks have little effect on the system; the effect on the
individual node being shocked is small, and the ripple effect to the nodes’ neighbors in the
network is minimal. On rarer occasions, however, the cumulative effect of past shocks causes the
network to reach a “critical state”, such that even a small shock to the right node in the network
3
Silva et al. (2017) identify 266 studies of systemic risk published prior to September 2016. Of these studies, about
one-fourth (71) investigate regulation, but only a few narrowly focus on the relationship between bank capital and
systemic risk. Acharya et al. (2012) propose a regulatory capital regime (“capital shortfall”) benchmarked to a
bank’s contribution to systemic risk. Similarly, Gauthier et al. (2012)) simulate bank failures under five different
candidate macroprudential capital regimes, and find that implementing a macroprudential capital regime could
substantially reduce both individual and systemic failure rates.
4
Hart and Zingales (2014) discuss the rationale for government intervention in the banking sector specifically:
because banks serve as stores of liquidity in the real economy, bank failures are disproportionately damaging to
agents in need of liquidity, reducing aggregate demand and creating a larger welfare loss than failures of other
corporate entities.
network (a “phase transition”). The resulting frequency distribution of the combined magnitudes
of disturbances follows a power-law: there are many small disturbances and few large ones, with
The complex systems framework lends itself naturally to the context of evaluating the
solvency of large commercial banks, the balance sheets of which are often heavily
asset and equity values resulting from fluctuations in asset markets. Widespread loss contagion
resulting from rare occurrences of small negative shocks propagating through the network
maintain compliance with capital regulations directly affect the balance sheets of the banks to
which it is connected in the interbank debt network. In this model, banks are required to maintain
a ratio of capital to risk-weighted assets above a threshold established by the regulator. The
efficacy of microprudential capital regulation is evaluated as the effect of varying the threshold
5
The canonical example of this phenomenon, called “self-organized criticality”, is the “sandpile” model of Bak,
Tang, and Wiesenfeld (1987). A simulated square grid of 1x1 cells forms the floor of a virtual sandbox. Grains of
sand with height 1 and base 1x1 fall, one at a time, on random locations on the grid. In this simple model, the nodes
are the cells of the grid, connected into a network by their spatial proximity, and the random shocks result from the
falling grains of sand. When the pile on a given square reaches a height of 4 grains, it becomes unstable and topples,
distributing one grain each to four of its neighbors. If any of those neighbors is of height 3, it too becomes unstable
and topples, and the process continues until the system is at rest. The distribution of “avalanche” sizes, measured as
the total distance fallen by all grains of sand in a given interval, follows a power-law. Intuitively, this distribution
obtains because most shocks to the grid occur before the pile reaches a critical state, and therefore have only a small
effect, and only a small number of shocks strike the right spot in the pile while the pile reaches a critical state,
causing a large avalanche.
simulation model.
The results of this simulation exercise are perhaps counterintuitive: increasing the
threshold capital ratio unambiguously results in larger cascades of insolvencies and higher
overall rates of bank insolvency. The primary insight that results from the simulation is that, in a
complex system of banks that are networked by bilateral debt exposures, microprudential capital
regulation that binds for a distressed bank has the effect of reducing that bank’s probability of
immediate insolvency, but increasing its counterparty banks’ probability of eventual insolvency.
This effect occurs as the result of the “fire sale” distribution of troubled assets from the
distressed banks to its counterparties as it sells risky assets to its creditor banks in order to reduce
the denominator of its risk-weighted capital ratio and comply with the capital regulation.
The simulation model has several free parameters, which correspond to the means and
volatilities of the returns on the banks’ risky asset portfolios, the severity of the discount applied
to troubled assets during a fire sale, and the average degree of the interbank debt network. The
adverse effects of microprudential capital regulations on the size on failure rates and the size of
failure cascades are more pronounced for parameter constellations that mimic economic
downturns (risky bank asset portfolios with low or negative means and high volatilities, more
severe fire sale discounts) and network fragility (intermediate average degree values that are
large enough to increase the likelihood of loss contagion in the interbank debt network, but too
small to reduce the risk of failure through debt portfolio diversification). These results provide
theoretical support for a countercyclical capital buffer (“CCyB”), a more recent innovation in
bank regulation that allows for microprudential capital regulations to be relaxed during periods
of widespread financial distress among banks, and enhanced during periods of growth when bank
extended so that banks respond to lower threshold capital ratios by increasing the volatility of the
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. I provide empirical evidence for the
suitability of the complex systems framework in explaining the distribution of U.S. commercial
bank failures in Section II. The simulation model that I implement is described in Section III. I
present the main results of the simulation exercises in Section IV, and conclude in Section V.
“cascades” of many failures in a short period of time requires a more nuanced understanding of
how these cascades arise. The post-crisis systemic risk literature offers ample evidence that
cascades are determined in large part by the topology of the network that links financial
institutions (Battiston et al. (2012), Glasserman and Young (2016)). The complexity of financial
networks is likely to hinder the abilities of regulators and individual banks to correctly price the
risk of failure cascades and take steps to mitigate their likelihood (Battiston et al. (2016)).
The FDIC maintains a publicly available database of U.S. commercial bank failures
dating back to 19347. (Here, “failure” means that the bank ceases to exist as a going concern, and
its either liquidated or sold to another entity. In this case, the bank is either insolvent or in clear
danger of insolvency.) The data include the identifying characteristics of the failed bank, such as
6
These results build on the work of several recent papers that bridge the theoretical literatures in systemic risk and
prudential regulation. Notably, Gai et al. (2011), who implement a simulation model in which interconnections
between banks can foment a systemic liquidity crisis. My paper seeks to answer a similar question with respect to
system-wide insolvencies. Battiston et al. (2013) demonstrate the potential for minor reductions in the capitalization
of systemically important banks to initiate widespread failure cascades.
7
https://www.fdic.gov/bank/individual/failed/banklist.html
1986, two additional data points are also reported: the assets held by the bank during the quarter
prior to its reported failure, and the estimated losses resulting from the failure.8
To estimate the size of a “typical” bank failure, I use the FDIC data series from 1934 to
2019, inclusive. I adjust both of the variables pertaining to failure size (prior-quarter assets and
estimated losses) for inflation, assuming a rate of 3.5% per year to convert to year-2019 dollars,
and report the distributions in Figures I and II. Both variables are lognormally distributed. The
geometric mean of the prior-quarter assets of failed banks in the sample is $151.4 million in
2019 USD, and the geometric mean of the estimated equity value lost is $29.5 million in 2019
USD.
apparent only when analyzing the sizes of failure cascades, rather than the sizes of individual
failures. I analyze the distribution of failure cascades, measured as the number of failures
recorded in the FDIC data within a given interval of time (one month, one quarter, or one year).
The distribution of the sizes of failure cascades among U.S. commercial banks, measured
as the number of failures 𝑥 in a given period of time, follows a clear power-law distribution of
the form Pr(𝑥) ∝ 𝑥 −𝛾 ,, which obtains regardless of the interval of time used as the unit of
analysis (Figure III). The power-law distribution is evident in a wide variety of natural
phenomena, including the magnitudes of earthquakes, the diameters of craters on the moon, and
the intensity of solar flares (Newman, 2005), and strongly suggests (although by itself does not
prove) that the underlying mechanism that produces the distribution is a “complex system”.
8
Estimated losses are calculated as the value of deposits in the failed bank reimbursed by the FDIC, minus the asset
value recovered by the FDIC from the liquidation of the bank’s assets.
Bak et al. (1987), there is no “typical” failure cascade size. At an annual frequency, the exponent
of the power-law distribution is -1.52; in context, this means that doubling the size of a given
failure cascade being analyzed (for example, from ten failed banks per year to twenty) makes the
larger cascade about one-third as likely to occur as the smaller cascade.9 The persistence of the
Although the linear relationship between cascade size and frequency evident from the
log-log plots in Figure III, Panel A is not conclusive evidence of a power-law relationship
between the size and frequency of bank failure cascades, the Kolmogorov-Smirnov test statistics
reported in Figure III, Panel B support the validity of the fit of a power-law distribution. More
importantly, the simulation model that I implement in Section II shows that a similar power-law
distribution of bank failure cascade frequencies can be reproduced as the result of a complex
system of interconnected banks with plausible asset dynamics (Figure VII, VIII).
The two largest cascades of commercial bank failures in the data (the S&L crisis of the
1980s and the subprime mortgage crisis of 2007-2008) are mostly attributable to losses in banks’
risky asset portfolios, rather than loss contagion.10 The simulation model I implement in this
paper attempts to capture the mechanism by which losses on banks’ asset portfolios are
redistributed when banks are undercapitalized, including the extreme case of insolvency. The
large cascades of U.S. commercial bank failures were not caused by asset redistribution in
9
If Pr(𝑥) = 𝑥 −1.52 is the probability of a cascade of size x, then Pr(2𝑥) = (2𝑥)−1.52 = 2−1.52 Pr(𝑥) = 0.35 Pr(𝑥).
10
In explaining the bank failure cascade of 2007-2008, Jackson and Pernoud (2019) discuss the relative roles of
commonality in bank asset returns and contract-level contagion in the interbank debt network. They conclude that
the failure cascade represents a combination of both effects: failing banks had portfolios of high-risk,
underperforming mortgage loans, but were also exposed to each other’s debt losses.
during both waves were sold to other financial institutions, including other (larger) commercial
banks, at a discount (for example, in the wake of the recent financial crisis, Wachovia’s assets
were acquired by Wells Fargo, Colonial Bank’s assets by BB&T, and FBOP Corporation’s by
BBVA USA). Almost all of the 537 post-crisis bank failures in the FDIC’s database were
Acquisitions following insolvencies represent the most extreme and most visible case of
the redistribution of the troubled assets of commercial banks. The purpose of this study is to first
develop a tractable model for bank failure cascades that incorporates both a network of interbank
debt contracts and commonality in asset returns (Section III.a.). I then use that model to assess
the consequences for systemic risk of the less visible asset redistribution channel that obtains
through banks selling risky assets to one another to remain compliant with capital regulations
(Section III.b.)
interdependent bank values, two ingredients are necessary: (1) a model that captures the
interconnectedness of the values of items on banks’ balance sheet (the “adjacency” of the banks,
or nodes, in the network), and (2) a model for disturbances to the values of those balance sheet
my model of interconnected bank values, with a few minor modifications.11 The model consists
of a set of banks indexed bank 𝑖 = 1 … . 𝑛 and a set of risky bank assets indexed 𝑘 = 1 … 𝑚. The
𝐴
Where 0 ≤ 𝑄𝑖𝑘𝑡 ≤ 1 describes the fraction of a risky asset 𝑘 = 1 … 𝑚 that bank 𝑖 =
1 … . 𝑛 owns at time 𝑡 = 1 … 𝑇. At the beginning of each iteration of the simulation model, each
The risky assets represent the combined balance sheet assets of large financial
institutions, which could include personal and commercial loans, marketable investment
securities held in the bank’s portfolio, and any other tangible assets. For the sake of simplicity, I
abstract away from intangible assets in this model, and assume that all tangible balance sheet
items can be transferred, in part or in total, to other large financial institutions in the model.
identity matrix of size 𝑛 = 𝑚, so that each bank starts with ownership of a “proprietary”
representative risky asset, which can then be divided and resold as necessary throughout the
11
Namely, I introduce the matrix of “primitive liabilities” 𝑄𝐿 to complement the matrix of “primitive assets” 𝑄 𝐴 . I
also model changes in risky asset values as a discrete approximation of a continuous-time process, rather than as a
single-period failure with an exogenously determined failure cost. Finally, because banks’ positions in peer banks’
equity are trivially small in practice, I eliminate banks’ cross-holdings in equity positions by setting the matrix of
equity cross-holdings in Jackson and Pernoud (2019) to an n x n identity matrix.
12
In this model, banks are simply portfolio managers that seek to maximize shareholders’ utility over the mean and
volatility of the return on the banks’ assets. I abstract away from behavioral considerations: managerial incentives
are irrelevant and always comply with regulations. Strategic default is not an option, as banks are never bailed out,
and managers are junior claimants on banks’ assets, receiving nothing in the event of an insolvency.
method for “disturbing” or “shocking” the values of items on the balance sheet. Here, I use
standard asset pricing dynamics, with parameters estimated from publicly reported balance sheet
The price of the risky asset 𝑝𝑘 (𝑡) is time-varying, with dynamics given by the following
Δ𝑝𝑘
(2) = 𝜇𝑘𝐴 𝑑𝑡 + 𝜎𝑘𝐴 𝑑𝑊
𝑝𝑘
Where 𝜇𝑘𝐴 is the expected return of the 𝑘 𝑡ℎ risky asset over the short interval of time 𝑑𝑡,
and 𝜎𝑘𝐴 is the volatility of the 𝑘 𝑡ℎ risky asset’s returns, which multiplies 𝑑𝑊, an increment of a
To allow for correlations −1 ≤ 𝜌𝑘1,𝑘2 ≤ 1 between any two risky assets 𝑘1 and 𝑘2, I
Δ𝑝
(3) = 𝜇𝑝𝐴 𝑑𝑡 + Σ𝑝A 𝑑𝑊𝑚
𝑝
Where 𝜇𝑝𝐴 is the vector of expected returns on all risky assets in 𝑚, Σ𝑝A is the variance-
𝐴 𝐴 𝐴
covariance matrix of risky asset returns, with elements Σ𝑘1,𝑘2 = 𝜌𝑘1,𝑘2 𝜎𝑘1 𝜎𝑘2 , and 𝑑𝑊𝑚 is the
increment of an 𝑚-dimensional geometric Brownian motion. I assume that asset price dynamics
are unaffected by the profitability or solvency of any of the banks in the model.
For each iteration of the simulation model, I generate the means and volatilities of the
banks’ risky asset returns, as well as the correlations between each pair of returns, as random
draws. The means of these random draws are free parameters, 𝜇̅ 𝐴 and 𝜎̅𝐴 . In order to choose
plausible ranges of values for these parameters, I analyze the observed returns of the 25 largest
financial institutions for which the Federal Reserve conducted supervisory stress tests in 2018
The log asset returns of these 25 institutions (measured as 𝑟𝐴 (𝑡) = ln(𝐴(𝑡)/𝐴(𝑡 − 1))
were distributed approximately normally, with a mean of 3.3% and a standard deviation of 8.0%.
The 25 bank-level return asset return means are distributed approximately normally around the
mean of the means, 3.3%, with a standard deviation of means of 3.0%. Accordingly, I generate
the 25 risky asset return means 𝜇𝐴 for each iteration of the simulation as random draws from a
normal distribution centered at 𝜇̅𝐴 . Similarly, because the variances of a sample of normally-
distributed random variables follow a chi-square distribution, I generate the 25-bank-level return
variances as random draws from a chi-squared distribution centered at 𝜎̅𝐴2 . In each case, I choose
reasonable values for the distributional parameters so that the resulting set of risky asset return
Correlations are generated by first taking a draw from a normal distribution, 𝑧~𝑁(𝑧̅, 𝜎𝑍2 ),
and transforming the resulting value to a correlation coefficient using the method of Fisher
(1915):
e2z −1
(4) 𝜌 = 𝑒 2𝑧 +1
Among the 25 large financial institutions that make up the sample, the distribution of
above) is centered at 𝑧̅ = 0.03. Accordingly, I simulate correlations resulting from random draws
13
Of these, only 20 are registered as commercial banks, so the remaining five are therefore not subject to the FDIC’s
capital adequacy regulatory regime, or eligible for FDIC insurance on any deposit liabilities. I use these banks’ asset
dynamics to stand in for those of other large commercial banks with incomplete data. Because the simulation only
uses the dynamics of these banks’ assets as an input, and seeks to explain the failure distribution of a hypothetical
universe of banks with these asset dynamics and a given degree of interconnectedness via debt obligations, the
results of the simulation should be unaffected by this distinction.
the products of the simulated pairwise correlation coefficients 𝜌 and the simulated risky asset
The bank also holds some amount 𝑄𝑖𝑡0 of a risk-free “0th” asset, which has a price 𝑝0 (𝑡). I
treat this risk-free asset as a cash equivalent, such that its dynamics are given by 𝜇0𝐴 = 0 (so that
the “risk-free rate” in the system is normalized to 0) and 𝜎0𝐴 = 0, with a correlation equal to
𝜌0,𝑘 = 0∀𝑘 = 1 … 𝑚. I initialize the value of the risk-free asset to 𝑝0 (0) = 1 and the value of
The final category of assets is interbank debt obligations, where 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝐴 represents the face
value of debt owed by bank 𝑗 to bank 𝑖. These obligations could include short-term (overnight)
interbank loans, long-term unsecured interbank loans, reverse repurchase agreements, and any
other forms of fixed-term contracts between banks.16 I assume that all interbank debt assets and
liabilities on a bank’s balance sheet represent contracts with other commercial banks within the
model. This assumption is not intended to reflect empirical reality, but to allow for this model to
sketch the results of an edge case where losses are always contained and redistributed within the
14
Because the simulation method requires that the covariance matrix Σ𝐴 be positive definite, in some cases, it is
necessary to perform a Cholesky decomposition on the simulated covariance matrix, identify negative eigenvalues,
replace them with an arbitrarily small number, and recompose the matrix.
15
The model can be adjusted to allow for a non-zero risk-free rate; for simplicity, I assume away the role of inflation
over the short run and choose a cash equivalent risk-free asset with zero return.
16
For simplicity, I normalize the effective maturity of all debt items to 𝑇 = 12 months, the length of the simulation
period. Although shorter-term debt obligations with maturities less than 6 months make up the vast majority of
observed interbank loan transaction volume, these loans often represent continuing lending relationships with
repeated engagements between pairs of banks (Afonso et al, 2014), and can therefore plausibly be modeled as a
“revolving” short-term credit facility that extends over the period from 𝑡 = 1 … 𝑇. The simulation model can also be
estimated over shorter horizons (ex. 𝑇 = 30 days) without much difficulty; my approach in this study is to split the
difference between the frequencies with which interbank debt obligations mature (daily or monthly), bank capital
adequacy is assessed from SEC filings (quarterly), and the Fed conducts bank stress tests (annually).
financial institutions, such as investment banks, that are not subjected to capital adequacy
requirements. The opposite extreme edge case, a banking system with no internal interbank debt
distributions that varies with the severity of the fire-sale discount (Figure X). Empirical reality
lies somewhere between these two poles; the purpose of this model is to examine the relationship
between capital regulation and the distribution of bank failures under the assumption that the
network structure has the potential to differentially effect the size of failure cascades.
𝐿
Where 0 ≤ 𝑄𝑖𝑙𝑡 ≤ 1 describes the fraction of some liability 𝑙 = 1 … 𝑧 on the balance
sheet of bank 𝑖 at time 𝑡. These are “outside” liabilities due to an entity other than another bank
in the network, which could include deposits, loan obligations to be repaid to the Federal
Reserve, and nonbank debts (such as private loans or bond issues). I assume that these liabilities,
as well as the interbank debt obligations in 𝐷 𝐴 , return a uniform risk-free rate of 𝑟 = 0.17 The
dynamics of these outside liabilities 𝑑 are therefore identical to those of the risk-free asset 𝑝0
(i.e. zero mean and zero volatility), so that 𝑑𝑙 (𝑡) = 0.75 for all liabilities 𝑙 in 𝑧 at all times 𝑡 ≤ 𝑇.
𝐿
The debt obligations owed by bank 𝑖 to bank 𝑗 measured at time 𝑡 are given by 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝑡 , so
𝐿
that ∑𝑗 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝑡 represents the sum total of bank 𝑖’s interbank debt liabilities. I set the matrix 𝐷𝐿
17
This has been a reasonable approximation for much of the post-crisis period; the Fed’s discount rate, repo rates,
and the short-term T-bill rate all hovered close to zero from 2009 through 2016, and have returned to near-zero
levels in the early part of 2020. The unsecured interbank loans in 𝐷 𝐴 should earn a nonzero prime rate two to three
points above the discount rate in practice; in this model, I again implicitly assume that this rate is zero, simply
because the interesting variation in failure rates created by interconnectedness in bank values is driven by defaults
on delivery of the face values of these debts, not the rates of interest they could return.
bank 𝑗 to bank 𝑖 appears as an asset on the balance sheet of bank 𝑖 and as a liability on the
Taking the expressions for the values of the bank’s assets and liabilities together, I write
For simplicity, I use the value 𝑉𝑖𝑡𝐸 as bank i’s Tier 1 equity capital at time t, which forms
the numerator for the threshold capital ratio. The calculation of the threshold capital ratio is
b. Capital regulation
The focus of this study is the effect of microprudential capital regulation on the overall
rate of bank failure across the banking system. The financial crisis of 2007-2008 was a crisis of
insolvency, not illiquidity (Thakor (2018)); accordingly, the output variable of interest in this
simulation models pertain to the rate of insolvencies, rather than effects on asset prices or bank
profitability.
To operationalize the simulation, I begin by choosing values of four free parameters: the
average degree (number of counterparties) in the interbank debt network 𝛿; the required capital
adequacy ratio 𝑘̅, below which banks are required to enter a regime of “prompt corrective
action” through a “fire sale” of a fraction of its representative risky asset; the weight 𝑤𝐴 on the
bank’s representative risky asset in the calculation of the capital adequacy ratio 𝑘̅; and a “fire
sale” discount factor 𝛽. I also specify the capital ratio threshold for a “critically
undercapitalized” bank 𝑘, below which a bank must be liquidated; for tractability, I normalize
zero remaining equity value. (All simulation parameters are reported in Table V.)
With 25 banks in the simulation, the number of possible interbank debt counterparties for
a given bank is in the range 𝛿̅ = {0, 1, … ,24}. I choose a value of 𝛿̅ for each simulation and then
𝑇
generate a random interbank debt matrix 𝐷 𝐴 = 𝐷𝐿 for each simulation with 𝛿̅ as its average
degree. This matrix stays fixed for each iteration of the simulation. This matrix, which contains
elements equal to 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝐴 = 1 if bank i is owed a debt by bank j, and 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝐴 = 0 otherwise, is scaled so
that its rows sum to 0.5 to initialize the simulation. These rescaled elements correspond to the
In all simulations with non-zero interbank debt obligations, the sum total of a bank’s
𝐴
interbank debt assets is normalized to ∑𝑖 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝑡 = 0.5, while the average total of a bank’s
𝐿
interbank debt liabilities ∑𝑗 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝑡 is also 0.5, although individual banks’ values vary.18 The total
value of each bank’s assets at the initiation of the simulation is 𝑉 𝐴 (0) = 1.0 + 0.5 = 1.5. The
average total value of each bank’s liabilities at the initiation of the simulation is 𝑉 𝐿 (0) = 0.75 +
0.5 = 1.25. Book equity value is therefore 𝑉 𝐸 (0) = 0.25. The simulation results are not
18
The distinction results from the method for operationalizing 𝐷𝐿 as the transpose of 𝐷 𝐴 , the rows of which are
normalized to sum to 0.5.
19
In my simulation, all banks are initialized with an identical asset value of 1.5 units. This abstraction facilitates the
implementation and interpretation of the model’s results, but does not match the empirical reality; even among the
large financial institutions I use to parameterize my simulation, the largest is 20 times the size of the 25 th-largest in
terms of balance sheet assets. Incorporating differential equity values into the simulation is an avenue for future
research.
̅ and 𝛽.20 If a bank’s Tier 1 capital ratio falls below 𝑘̅, it is considered “undercapitalized”,
𝑤𝐴 , 𝑘,
and must respond by taking what the FDIC calls “prompt corrective action” to improve its
capital position. It does this selling a fraction 1 − 𝛼 of its proprietary risky asset, 0 < 𝛼 ≤ 1. It
sells this fraction of its risky asset (in exchange for the riskless “cash-like” asset) to its creditor
banks, which are the banks to which the undercapitalized bank has outstanding debt obligations
(the non-zero elements of the row of 𝐷𝐿 corresponding to the undercapitalized bank).21 In this
model, all interbank loans are thus functionally collateralized by the bank’s proprietary risky
asset.
This asset sale is being conducted at a time of financial distress for the undercapitalized
bank; as a result, the creditor banks purchasing the asset may demand a “fire-sale” discount of
20
The regulatory regime I implement in this simulation is a stylized representation of the regime used by the FDIC.
The FDIC distinguishes between five categories of capitalization based on Tier 1 capital ratios, ranging from “well
capitalized” (Tier 1 ratio of 8% or greater) to “critically undercapitalized” (Tier 1 ratio of 2% or less). The
numerator of the ratio is “Tier 1” equity capital, which is the sum of the values of the bank’s common stock and
retained earnings. The denominator of the ratio is a risk-weighted average of the bank’s asset values. The risk
weights that I apply to the simulation banks’ assets are likewise simplified for the sake of tractability; in practice, the
risk weights assigned to balance sheet assets range from 0% (U.S. and OECD government bonds) to 1,250% or more
(structured or securitized products). Again for simplicity, I also abstract away from the additional restrictions on
bank balance sheets imposed by (a) fractional reserve ratio requirements for banks’ cash holdings relative to
deposits, (b) non risk-weighted leverage restrictions imposed under Basel III, and (c) additional “capital buffer”
requirements that are combined with the Tier 1 ratio. The model I develop is designed to capture the salient features
of the regulatory regime applied to commercial banks, while still being empirically tractable via simulation.
21
The bank could also respond by raising new equity capital to increase its Tier 1 capital ratio to exceed the required
threshold; FDIC guidance discusses both possibilities in terms of banks’ actions over time (“increased capital
formation” versus “reduced asset growth”). Some empirical evidence suggests that undercapitalized banks favor
shifting their payout policies away from dividends and toward earnings retention, as opposed to selling risky assets
(Cohen (2013)). In a version of the simulation model that allows for raising equity capital, resolving financial
distress is trivial, and the resulting effects on the distribution of bank failures are uninteresting; banks simply raise as
much equity capital as necessary each time they become “undercapitalized”. In this model, I assume that banks are
financially constrained, pay no dividends, and cannot raise new capital at an affordable rate of required return. This
has some intuitive appeal: undercapitalized banks have, by definition, experienced a negative rate of return on equity
over the simulation period, and are unlikely to be able to provide an adequate return on equity to compensate for
their current level of risk in the near future. The literature on troubled banks provides ample evidence of banks
responding to undercapitalization with asset fire sales (Campello et al. (2010); de Haan and van den End (2013);
Ramcharan (2020), Diamond and Rajan (2011)), which may be optimal when compared to issuing new equity
(Hyun and Rhee (2011)).
represent greater risk aversion on the part of creditor banks’ shareholders, an increased level of
desperation to remain solvent on the part of the troubled bank, greater negotiating leverage for
creditor banks, or some combination of the three. In implementing my simulation, I use values of
𝛽 ranging between 0.9 (an asset is sold for 90 cents on the dollar) and one (an asset is sold with
no fire-sale discount).22
Where 𝑤0 is the regulatory risk weight assigned to the bank’s position in the risk-free
(cash) asset, and 𝑤𝐴 is the regulatory risk weight assigned to both the bank’s proprietary risky
asset and its interbank debt assets. For the sake of simplicity, I set 𝑤0 = 0 and 𝑤𝐴 = 1 for all
simulations. The risk-free asset does not count against the denominator for the bank’s Tier 1
capital ratio, and so an asset fire sale has the effect of reducing the denominator of 𝑘𝑖𝑡 by
exchanging a risky asset for a risk-free one. For any fire-sale discount 𝛽 < 1, the asset sale also
reduces the bank’s equity value; accordingly, the bank identifies the smallest possible fraction
(1 − 𝛼) that it can sell in order to become compliant with 𝑘̅. After the asset sale, the bank’s
𝐴
∑𝑗 𝐷𝑖𝑗𝑡 )]
22
I present a representative balance sheet of an undercapitalized bank in my simulation during a fire sale in Figure
VI. Although each bank begins the simulation with zero units of the risk-free (cash) asset for the sake of simplifying
the model, the creditor banks to the undercapitalized bank nonetheless purchase a fraction of the undercapitalized
bank’s risky asset using cash. I record the cash used to finance this sale as a risk-free “outside” debt liability on the
creditor bank’s balance sheet, so the purchase of the troubled asset is effectively being financed with a zero-interest
loan from a non-network bank (which could include the Federal Reserve). This has an identical effect on the creditor
bank’s equity position and its capital adequacy as reducing some existing store of cash.
the risky asset sold and the cash received in the fire sale:
′
(9) 𝑉𝑖𝑡𝐸 = 𝑉𝑖𝑡𝐸 + (𝛽 − 1)[(1 − 𝛼) ∑𝑘 𝑄𝑖𝑘𝑡
𝐴
𝑝𝑘 (𝑡))]
If a bank is in such extreme distress that its Tier 1 capital ratio falls below 𝑘 ≤ 𝑘̅, it is
considered “critically undercapitalized”, and ceases to be a going concern. At this point, the
bank’s assets are distributed to its creditors according to an “orderly liquidation” regime, as in
Jackson and Pernoud (2019), such that each creditor bank 𝑗 ∈ 𝑐 receives a fraction of the
liquidated bank i’s assets (including cash, the representative risky asset, and interbank debt
assets) whose total value is in proportion to the creditor bank’s share of the liquidated bank’s
receive nothing.
The liquidated bank’s deposits must also be relocated. In my model, the deposits of the
liquidated bank i are divided proportionally among the liquidated bank’s debtors 𝑗 ∈ 𝑑,
failed bank being reimbursed in full by FDIC insurance, and then choosing to relocate their
deposits in proportion to their previous bank’s debt obligations.23 The liquidated bank’s
interbank debt liabilities are zeroed out on the asset side of the balance sheets of creditor banks.
To model the dynamics of the complex system, I simulate 1,000 iterations of the risky
asset price paths for each combination of values for a set of free parameters and observe the
23
While this solution does not map neatly to the real-world setting, it has some intuitive appeal: depositors with full
insurance should be indifferent between a set of identical commercial banks paying zero interest on deposits.
Furthermore, the bank’s debt to the depositor is functionally held by the bank’s own debtors: if Bank A owes a
dollar to Depositor X, but Bank B owes a dollar to Bank A, then Depositor X is ultimately a creditor to Bank B.
The power-law distribution is immediately apparent in the log-log plot the distribution of
failures from a typical simulation (Figures VII, VIII). The consistency between the power-law
distribution produced by the simple simulation model and the observed power-law distribution of
commercial bank failures strongly suggests that the complex systems framework is the right lens
IV. Results
a. Capital thresholds
should be a negative relationship between capital ratio thresholds for prompt corrective action
and the overall failure rate in the banking system. Under this hypothesis, there would also be a
positive relationship between the prompt corrective action threshold and the value of the power-
law exponent in the distribution of failures (where a larger exponent value corresponds to a
requirements have unintended, adverse consequences, it may be that the opposite results (a
higher frequency of failures and of large failure cascades) are associated with higher capital
Implementing the simulation algorithm described in Section III over a range of capital
thresholds 𝑘̅ = {0, … , 0.15}, I find that higher required capital ratios 𝑘̅ are associated with a
greater likelihood of large failure cascades, as measured by both the total failure rate per
simulation and by the exponent of the power-law distribution of failure frequencies estimated
complex systems. The prompt corrective action regime serves to temporarily reduce the
When a bank removes a troubled asset from its books through a fire sale, the risk
associated with the asset is not eliminated, but displaced elsewhere within the banking system.
Comparing the characteristics of the assets of surviving and failing banks from the simulation
model results, failed banks’ risky assets are significantly more likely to have a low (or negative)
mean return and/or a high volatility when compared with surviving banks (Figure XIV). As a
result of the asset sale necessitated by the individual troubled bank breaching the capital
threshold, shares of this troubled asset have now been distributed to the undercapitalized bank’s
creditor institutions, in exchange for some (possibly discounted) amount of the safe asset. With a
troubled asset making up some portion of their balance sheets, the creditor banks are now each
more likely to see a further reduction in the asset’s value and become insolvent.
Failure cascades are also more likely with lower values of 𝛽, which represent steeper
discounts for the fire sale of the undercapitalized bank’s risky asset (Figure XI). Receiving a
lower fire sale price for its risky asset means that the undercapitalized bank receives a smaller
infusion of cash, and its book values of assets and equity are correspondingly lower than in the
case with no discounting. This puts the bank at greater risk of falling below the threshold for
prompt corrective action again in the near future, which in turn results in further fire sales and
further redistribution of the undercapitalized bank’s toxic asset throughout the system.
The adverse consequences of higher capital thresholds with even a small fire sale
discount are also evident in the frequency of large cascades, not just the overall failure rate
the simulation environment under 𝛿̅ = 0, the effect of transitioning from no capital threshold
(top left panel) to a capital threshold of 𝑘̅ = 0.075 is minimal; the slope of the log-log plot is
basically unchanged (-2.9065 in the top left panel to 2.8533 in the bottom left panel). The top
right and bottom right panels correspond to a fragile network topology (𝛿̅ = 12) with a modest
fire sale discount (𝛽 = 0.95). Here, the adverse effect of introducing capital thresholds is
apparent from the shift in the slope of the log-log plot (-2.0097 in the top right, -1.4767 in the
bottom right panel).24 Larger cascades are much more frequent as losses are redistributed within
b. Network structure
financial system, which obscures the importance of network topology and the role of
diversification.
the average network degree. Using a single-period model with random, exogenous negative
shocks to individual institutions’ solvency, Elliott et al. (2014) identify a “sweet spot” for
network degree. In this “sweet spot”, institutions are sufficiently interconnected to allow for
contagion of losses through defaults on debt, but insufficiently interconnected to reap the
benefits of debt portfolio diversification. I obtain the same “sweet spot” using a multi-period
24
Note that a value of gamma closer to zero corresponds to a higher probability of large failure cascades.
diversification and the likelihood of insolvency is true at both the level of the individual bank as
well as at the level of the banking system. For any given value of the average interbank debt
network degree 𝛿̅, the random allocation of the distribution of the number of counterparties for
an individual bank’s debt obligations (both as a creditor and a debtor) within the model produces
variation in the extent to which banks are diversified against counterparty risk. Banks with few
debtors in the interbank debt network are poorly diversified against the risk that a given debtor
becomes insolvent and is unable to repay some or all of its debt, while banks with many debtors
are relatively well diversified against this risk. I find that less-diversified banks are also more
likely to fail in this simulation model than their better-diversified counterparts (Figure XIV).
The effect of network topology is also apparent in the exponent of the power-law
distributions of failures produced by the simulation (Figure VIII). Comparing the top left and top
right panels of Figure VIII demonstrates the effect of introducing a fragile network topology on
the likelihood of large failure cascades in the absence of capital regulations. Increasing the
average network degree from 𝛿̅ = 0 to 𝛿̅ = 12 causes the slope of the log-log plot to shift from
-2.9065 to -2.0097, corresponding to a greater frequency of large failure cascades. The same
effect appears in the presence of capital thresholds (bottom left and bottom right panels).
Unsurprisingly, decreasing the mean return on the risky asset for an average bank in the
simulation 𝜇̅𝐴 increases the likelihood of failure cascades (Figure XII). Because bank-level risky
asset return means are a draw from a normal distribution centered at 𝜇̅ 𝐴 , a lower mean leads to a
larger proportion of banks with low or negative means. Assets with low or negative means are
likely to drive a bank below the capital threshold and trigger a fire sale, and are correspondingly
banks. Similarly, increasing the volatility of the risky asset for an average bank in the simulation
𝜎̅𝐴 also increases the likelihood of failure cascades (Figure XIII). More volatile assets naturally
produce more extreme negative returns, and so are more likely to cause a bank to breach the
capital threshold and trigger a fire sale, which in turn increases the likelihood that a creditor bank
that purchases the asset experiences extreme negative returns and is itself pushed below the
capital threshold.
Taken together, these conditions (low or negative mean returns on risky assets, increased
volatility of risky assets, and a steeper fire sale discount) are representative of the banking
environment during economic downturns.25 Ideally, these are precisely the conditions under
which microprudential regulations such as capital thresholds should fulfill their intended purpose
The results of this simulation model suggest that exactly the opposite result is possible:
microprudential capital regulations have a positive effect on the probability of bank solvency
when asset liquidations are conducted at full price (Figure XI) and when banks operate without
interbank debt (Figure X), and have a smaller negative effect on the probability of bank solvency
when asset returns are larger and less volatile (Figure XII, XIII). Under less-ideal conditions,
however, the distribution of risky assets throughout the system that results from prompt
corrective action is counterproductive to the goal of mitigating bank failure cascades over the
25
The effects on banks’ risk of insolvency from changes to variables including the Dow Jones Total Stock Market
Index, the yield on U.S. BBB corporate bonds, and the U.S. Market Volatility Index (VIX), the growth rate in real
GDP, and the unemployment rate are used in the annual stress tests of systemically important financial institutions
conducted by the Federal Reserve as a requirement of the Dodd-Frank Act.
buffer (“CCyB”) established as a part of Basel III. The CCyB allows for the central banks that
voluntarily agree to comply with the Basel accords to require that banks retain an additional
percentage of equity capital during leverage expansions, reserving the ability to turn the buffer
requirement back off in the event of a downturn. The primary rationale for the CCyB is that
turning the buffer on during economic expansions allows system banks to reap the accumulated
benefits of additional risk-weighted capital once a downturn occurs. The results of this study
suggest a complementary rationale for turning the CCyB switch back off during contractions: the
adverse consequences of prompt corrective action are most severe under conditions
approximating a downturn. The costs and benefits of the CCyB in the U.S. banking system are
still purely theoretical: the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors has left countercyclical capital
buffers at zero percent in each of its annual votes since the implementation of the CCyB under
Basel III.
The basic model described in II.b. and the analysis of the effect of capital adequacy
requirements discussed so far in this section both treat the dynamics of banks’ asset values as
the financial health of the lending bank. It should be noted, however, that these parameters were
estimated from historical data that reflect the choices made by banks with respect to leverage and
asset portfolio volatility under a given set of capital requirements. The observed distribution of
reported Tier 1 capital ratios among solvent banks is therefore truncated from below at a ratio
greater than the minimum of 6 percent required under Basel III (see Figure IV).26
26
Another explanation is that risk-weighted capital ratios are incorrectly specified, and do not form a binding
constraint on banks’ asset portfolio selection (Cathcart et al. (2015)). U.S. commercial banks keep capital in excess
constraint on the banks’ optimization problem when selecting portfolio assets. 27 Under less-
stringent capital requirements, the likelihood of decreasing asset values causing a bank to drop
below the threshold for regulatory action is lower, and so a given bank might choose a larger
weight on higher-volatility loans in its asset portfolio. More volatile asset portfolios would
requirements could also result in more failure cascades. This stands in direct opposition to the
simulation results discussed so far., which suggest that the prompt corrective action mechanism
serves to spread toxic assets more broadly throughout the system, temporarily saving an
individual troubled bank, but increasing the likelihood that many other banks will fail in the near
future. Accordingly, I use my simulation model to test whether one of these two effects of
of required regulatory minimums, and empirical evidence suggests that they manage these ratios toward
predetermined targets (Berger et al. (2008)).The bank capital literature offers several explanations for this behavior,
including reducing the expected costs of bankruptcy (Allen et al. (2015)), reducing agency problems with respect to
loan monitoring (Allen et al. (2011)), and loss aversion induced by the bank’s experiences during previous crises
(Bouwman & Malmendier (2015)).
27
The concern raised in this section is only of first-order importance if the leverage constraint imposed by the Tier 1
capital requirement is binding with respect to the bank’s portfolio optimization problem. The distribution in Figure
IV is truncated from below at 6%, and has a mean of 13.02% and a standard deviation of 2.59%. Assuming
normality and adjusting for this truncation to find the “true” moments of the distribution yields a mean of 12.99%
and a standard deviation of 2.63%. If banks’ optimal choices over asset portfolios are reflected by a non-truncated
normal distribution with these moments, the probability of a bank choosing a portfolio that results in a Tier 1 capital
rat io of less than 6% is approximately 0.4%, indicating that the constraint on asset selection posed by the Tier 1
capital adequacy requirements under Basel III is generally non-binding. The early years of the sample period (2010
to 2019) correspond to the Basel II regime and the phase-in of Basel III implementation; under Basel II, the
minimum Tier 1 ratio was even lower, at 4.5%, which provides further evidence that required Tier 1 capital ratios do
not represent a binding constraint with respect to banks’ portfolio optimization strategies.
28
Consider the edge case where every bank held only the risk-free asset. In this version of the model, the failure rate
would be zero by definition. For each bank, the rate of return on assets would be 𝜇 𝐴 = 𝑟 = 0, the rate of return on
equity would be 𝜇 𝐴 ∗ (𝑉 𝐴 /𝑉 𝐸 ) = 𝑟 = 0, and the risk-weighted Tier 1 capital ratio would be undefined.
required capital ratios. I begin by assuming that each bank has chosen a set of portfolio weights
on all of the potential individual assets (mortgages, commercial loans, student loans, credit cards,
and so on) within its investment opportunity set, such the weighted-average mean and volatility
I next assume that each bank in the sample is currently choosing an optimal set of
weights on assets that maximizes a utility function over 𝜇 𝐴 and 𝜎 𝐴 belonging to a representative
bank shareholder, subject to a given tolerance for falling below 𝑘̅, the capital threshold for
prompt corrective action.29 This representative bank shareholder desires the maximum attainable
Sharpe ratio with respect to the bank’s asset returns, (𝜇 𝐴 − 𝑟)/𝜎 𝐴 , subject to the means and
covariances of the available assets and the constraint on leverage imposed by 𝑘̅. I therefore
assume that the observed moments of the bank’s asset return distribution correspond to this
Assume that the leverage constraint imposed by 𝑘̅ on the bank’s portfolio selection
∗
problem is binding, so that the observed level of asset portfolio risk 𝜎 𝐴 is below the level 𝜎 𝐴
that the bank would optimally choose in the absence of the constraint. Further assume that, in the
familiar CAPM setting (Sharpe, 1964), this unconstrained optimum corresponds to a point on the
∗
capital allocation line with 𝜇 𝐴 > 𝜇 𝐴 . Conceptually, the bank is increasing its leverage to invest
more in the maximally efficient portfolio corresponding to (𝜇 𝐴 , 𝜎 𝐴 ). Because the Sharpe ratio
gives the slope of the capital allocation line, this new optimal portfolio must have the same
29
This tolerance corresponds to a value-at-risk probability. For example, if a given bank is willing to tolerate a 5%
chance of dropping below the threshold for prompt corrective action in one year, it would choose a set of individual
asset weights over the set of feasible “representative” asset return distribution parameters (𝜇 𝐴 , 𝜎 𝐴 ) such that 𝑍 =
(𝑥 𝐴 − 𝜇 𝐴 )/𝜎 𝐴 ≤ -1.645, where 𝑥 𝐴 = −(𝑘̅ − 𝑘)/(𝑘̅ − 1) is the return on the bank’s assets that results in 𝑘 ≤ 𝑘̅ .
the risk-free rate is assumed to be zero, then the ratio of the mean and volatility of each portfolio
is identical, and the mean and volatility of the unconstrained portfolio’s asset returns can be
I evaluate the effect of increasing the bank leverage parameter 𝜆 on the failure cascade
distribution parameter 𝛾 in the edge case where capital requirements are non-existent above and
beyond the bank remaining solvent, 𝑘̅ = 𝑘 = 0, using the simulation approach described in
Section II.b. I run the simulation over a set of leverage parameters 𝜆 = {1 … 1.2}, keeping all
other model simulation inputs unchanged. This allows for the cleanest test of whether additional
risk-taking induced by weaker capital adequacy requirements dominates the systemic risk-
mitigating effect.
I find that increased bank leverage induced by lower required minimum capital ratios
indeed accelerates the rate of failures in the banking system, although the incremental effect of
leverage is relatively small (Figure XV). For an average interbank debt network degree of 𝛿̅ =
12, a ten percent increase in leverage (𝜆 = 1.1) corresponds to an increase in the predicted
failure rate from 13.8% to 15.2%, and a twenty percent increase in leverage (𝜆 = 1.2)
corresponds to a predicted failure rate of 16.3%. These estimated increases are comparable to the
effects of introducing capital thresholds of 𝑘̅ = 0.045 and 𝑘̅ = 0.75, respectively, in the base
case with 𝛽 = 0.95 and 𝛿̅ = 12. In this simulation model, the additional failures resulting from
increased risk-taking induced by setting 𝑘̅ = 0 are minimal compared to the failures resulting
from contagion generated by asset fire sales under prompt corrective action.
I find that bank failure cascades can plausibly be modeled as the result of a complex
system reaching a critical state that depends heavily on the interconnectedness between the
balance sheets of the banks in the system. As a result, bank-level measures that seek to predict
large failure cascades are prone to sizable errors, especially when the diversification of the
The complex origins of failure cascades also limit the efficacy of ratio-based capital
adequacy requirements, which can have unintended, adverse consequences for the frequency of
large cascades of failures. These risk-weighted ratios, designed to maintain an adequate store of
equity capital on banks’ balance sheets relative to the volatility of their assets’ market values,
actually increase the likelihood of bank failures and failure cascades when banks’ troubled assets
are sold at even a small fire sale discount, or when the interbank debt network is only moderately
diversified. These effects are attenuated if banks are induced by decreased capital adequacy
requirements to take greater risks in their asset portfolios, but the likelihood of capital adequacy
to be very low. Taken together, these results provide a new avenue of theoretical support for the
The complex systems framework for analyzing bank failures is ripe with opportunities for
future research. For the sake of tractability, this paper assumes equally-sized banks, a simplified
ratios), leaving considerable room for further inquiries into the effects on the distribution of
failures from altering these and other assumptions. Given the societal and economic importance
Acemoglu, D., Ozdaglar, A., & Tahbaz-Salehi, A. (2015). Systemic Risk and Stability in
Financial Networks. American Economic Review, 105(2), 564-608.
Acharya, V., Engle, R., & Richardson, M. (2012). Capital Shortfall: A New Approach to
Ranking and Regulating Systemic Risks. American Economic Review, 102(3), 59-64.
Afonso, G., Kovner, A., & Schoar, A. (2014). Trading Partners in the Interbank Lending Market.
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports, 620, 1-52.
Allen, F., Carletti, E., & Marquez, R. (2011). Credit Market Competition and Capital Regulation.
The Review of Financial Studies, 24(4), 983-1018.
Allen, F., Carletti, E., & Marquez, R. (2015). Deposits and Bank Capital Structure. Journal of
Financial Economics, 118(3), 601-619.
Bak, P., Tang, C., & Wiesenfeld, K. (1987). Self-Organized Criticality: An Explanation of 1/f
Noise. Physical Review Letters, 59(4), 381-384.
Baker, M., & Wurgler, J. (2015). Do Strict Capital Requirements Raise the Cost of Capital?
Bank Regulation, Capital Structure, and the Low-Risk Anomaly. American Economic Review:
Papers & Proceedings, 105(5), 315-320.
Barajas, A., Chami, R., Cosimano, T., & Hakura, D. (2010). U.S. Bank Behavior in the Wake of
the 2007-2009 Financial Crisis. Working paper.
Battiston, S., Caldarelli, G., May, R., Roukny, T., & Stiglitz, J. (2016). The Price of Complexity
in Financial Networks. PNAS – Proceedings of the National Academy of Science, 113(36),
10031-10036.
Battiston, S., Delli Gatti, D., Gallegati, M., Greenwald, B., Stiglitz, J. (2012). Default Cascades:
When Does Risk Diversification Increase Stability? Journal of Financial Stability, 8(3), 138-
149.
Battiston, S., di Iasio, G., Infante, L., & Pierobon, F. (2013). Capital and Contagion in Financial
Networks. Working paper.
Berger, A., & Bouwman, C.H.S. (2013). How Does Capital Affect Bank Performance During
Financial Crises? Journal of Financial Economics, 109(1), 146-176.
Berger, A., DeYoung, R., Flannery, M.J., Lee, D., & Oztekin, O. (2008). How Do Large
Banking Organizations Manage Their Capital Ratios? Journal of Financial Services Research,
34(2-3), 123-149.
Bouwman, C.H.S., & Malmendier, U. (2015). Does a Bank’s History Affect Its Risk-Taking?
American Economic Review, 105(5), 321-25.
Calem, P., & Rob, R. (1999). The Impact of Capital-Based Regulation on Bank Risk-Taking.
Journal of Financial Intermediation, 8(4), 317-352.
Campello, M., Graham, J., & Harvey, C. (2010). The Real Effects of Financial Constraints:
Evidence From a Financial Crisis. Journal of Financial Economics, 97(3) 470-487
Cathcart, L., El-Jahel, L., & Jabbour, R. (2015). Can Regulators Allow Banks to Set Their Own
Capital Ratios? Journal of Banking & Finance, 53, 112-123.
Clauset, A., Shalizi, C., & Newman, M. (2009). Power-Law Distributions in Empirical
Data. SIAM Review, 51(4), 661-703.
Cohen, B. (2013). How Have Banks Adjusted to Higher Capital Requirements? BIS Quarterly
Review: September 2013, 25-41.
de Haan, L., & van den End, J.W. (2013). Banks’ Responses to Funding Liquidity Shocks:
Lending Adjustments, Liquidity Hoarding and Fire Sales. Journal of International Financial
Markets, Institutions & Money, 26, 152-174.
Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2000). A Theory of Bank Capital. The Journal of Finance, 55(6),
2431-2465.
Diamond, D., & Rajan, R. (2011). Fear of Fire Sales, Illiquidity Seeking, and Credit Freezes. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 126(2), 557-591.
Elliott, M., Golub, B., & Jackson, M. (2014). Financial Networks and Contagion. The American
Economic Review, 104(10), 3115-3153.
Fisher, R.A. (1915). Frequency Distribution of the Values of the Correlation Coefficient in
Samples from an Indefinitely Large Population. Biometrika, 10(4), 507-521.
Furlong, F., & Keeley, M. (1989). Capital Regulation and Bank Risk-Taking: A Note. Journal of
Banking & Finance, 13(6), 883-891.
Gai, P., Haldane, A., & Kapadia, S. (2011). Complexity, Concentration & Contagion. Journal of
Monetary Economics, 58, 453-470.
Gauthier, C., Lehar, A., & Souissi, M. (2012). Macroprudential Capital Requirements and
Systemic Risk. Working paper.
Glasserman, P., & Young, H.P. (2016). Contagion in Financial Networks. Journal of Economic
Literature, 54(3), 779-831.
Hart, O., & Zingales, L. (2014). Banks Are Where the Liquidity Is. Working paper.
Hugonnier, J., & Morellec, E. (2017). Bank Capital, Liquid Reserves, and Insolvency Risk.
Journal of Financial Economics, 125(2), 266-285.
Hyun, J-S., & Rhee, B-K. (2011). Bank Capital Regulation and Credit Supply. Journal of
Banking & Finance, 35(2), 323-330.
Jackson, M., & Pernoud, A. (2019). What Makes Financial Markets Special? Distorted
Investment Incentives, Regulation, and Systemic Risk Measurement. Working paper.
Newman, M. (2005). Power Laws, Pareto Distributions and Zipf’s Law. Contemporary Physics,
46(5), 323-351.
Osborne, M., Fuertes, A-M., & Milne, A. (2012). Capital and Profitability in Banking: Evidence
from U.S. Banks. Working paper.
Ramcharan, R. (2020). Bank Balance Sheets and Liquidation Values. Working Paper.
Sharpe, W.F. (1964). Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions of
Risk. Journal of Finance. 19(3), 425-442.
Silva, W., Kimura, H., & Sobreiro, V.A. (2017). An Analysis of the Literature on Systemic
Financial Risk: A Survey. Journal of Financial Stability, 28, 91-114.
Thakor, A. (2018). Post-Crisis Regulatory Reform in Banking: Address Insolvency Risk, Not
Illiquidity! Journal of Financial Stability, 37, 107-111.
VanHoose, D. (2007). Theories of Bank Behavior Under Capital Regulation. Journal of Banking
& Finance, 31, 3680-3697.
The assets of N = 3,943 failed U.S. commercial banks, measured as of the quarter prior to failure, are collected from
the FDIC’s public database. The banks’ assets are reported as of the date of failure, and so are converted to 2019
USD using an assumed 3.5% annual inflation rate to facilitate comparison. Because the data are lognormally
distributed, the frequency distribution is presented using the base-10 logarithms of the inflation-adjusted asset value.
The sample mean is 108.18 = 151.4 million inflation-adjusted dollars.
The estimated losses resulting from N = 2,573 U.S. commercial bank failures, measured as of the difference between
the value of the failed banks’ deposits reimbursed by the FDIC and the asset value recovered by the FDIC via
liquidation of the failed bank, are collected from the FDIC’s public database. The banks’ estimated losses are
reported as of the date of failure, and so are converted to 2019 USD using an assumed 3.5% annual inflation rate to
facilitate comparison. Because the data are lognormally distributed, the frequency distribution is presented using the
base-10 logarithms of the inflation-adjusted asset value. The sample mean is 107.47 = 29.5 million inflation-
adjusted dollars.
The plots show the log number of bank failures in a given period against the log of the frequency of that failure count in the FDIC’s public bank failure database.
Annual, quarterly, and monthly frequencies are reported in order from left to right. The best-fit line is given by Pr(𝑥) ∝ 𝑥 −𝛾 over the domain 𝑥 ≥ 𝑥𝑚𝑖𝑛 , where
the parameter estimate 𝛾̂ for values greater than or equal to 𝑥𝑚𝑖𝑛 are estimated via maximum likelihood, using the method of Clauset et al. (2009). Taken
together, the plots demonstrate “scale invariance” (i.e., similar power-law distributions at varying measurement frequencies) characteristic of the output of
complex systems.
The Kolmogorov-Smirnov (KS) test statistic describes the likelihood of rejecting the null hypothesis that an observed data sample was drawn from some
candidate population distribution. A p-value of 0.1 or smaller would suggest rejecting the null and concluding that the sample was not drawn from the candidate
distribution. In this case, the K-S p-values for all estimation frequencies are well in excess of traditional critical values (0.01, 0.05, 0.1) when estimated using a
power-law distribution parameterized with identical values of 𝛾 and 𝑥𝑚𝑖𝑛 , suggesting that they fit a power-law fairly closely.
This figure shows the quarterly Tier 1 capital ratios for solvent institutions among the 25 largest commercial banks
in the U.S., collected from Fed reports from 2010 to 2019 (N = 897). Because the Fed’s reporting requirements for
Tier 1 capital ratios vary slightly during the sample period, I report the largest of the available numbers in the event
of a conflict between multiple reports for the same bank and quarter.
Banks begin with an average of 1.5 units of assets, comprised of 0 units of the risk-free asset (cash), 1 unit of the
representative risky asset, and 0.5 units of debt obligations owed by other banks. Each bank also begins with 0.75
units of outside debts (deposits and debts to other creditors), and an average of 0.5 units of debt obligations owed to
other banks. The average starting equity value for a bank in the simulation is therefore 0.25 units.
The bank chooses the minimum fraction (1 − 𝛼), 0 ≤ 𝛼 ≤ 1, of its risky asset portfolio 𝑄𝑖𝐴 to sell to other banks so
that it comes back into compliance with the capital adequacy requirement 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡) ≥ 𝑘̅ . The sale occurs at a “fire sale”
discount 𝛽, 0 ≤ 𝛽 ≤ 1. Liabilities are unaffected, so that a full-price sale (𝛽 = 1) has no immediate effect on the
book value of the bank’s assets or equity (the loss in risky asset value is replaced dollar-for-dollar in cash), while
any fire sale with 𝛽 < 1 will result in a reduction in the risk-weighted value of the bank’s assets and a smaller
reduction in the book values of the bank’s assets and equity. If there is no 𝛼 in 0 ≤ 𝛼 ≤ 1 that can satisfy 𝑘𝑖 (𝑡) ≥ 𝑘̅ ,
the bank is considered “critically undercapitalized” and is liquidated according to the “orderly liquidation” regime
for insolvent banks, ceasing to continue as a going concern.
The number of simulated failures per year is plotted against the observed frequency of that number of failures per
year, again on a log scale, collected from 10,000 iterations of the simulation model (100 loops of a simulated
distribution from 100 years of bank data). Parameter constellations are as follows: 𝛿̅ = 0, 𝑘̅ = 0 (top left); 𝛿̅ = 12,
𝑘̅ = 0 (top right); 𝛿̅ = 0, 𝑘̅ = 0.075 (bottom left); 𝛿̅ = 12, 𝑘̅ = 0.075 (bottom right). All simulations use a fire sale
discount 𝛽 = 0.95 where applicable.
The number of simulated failures per year is plotted against the observed frequency of that number of failures per
year, again on a log scale, collected from 10,000 iterations of the simulation model (100 loops of a simulated
distribution from 100 years of bank data). Parameter constellations are as follows: 𝛿̅ = 0, 𝑘̅ = 0 (top left); 𝛿̅ = 12,
𝑘̅ = 0 (top right); 𝛿̅ = 0, 𝑘̅ = 0.075 (bottom left); 𝛿̅ = 12, 𝑘̅ = 0.075 (bottom right). All simulations use a fire sale
discount 𝛽 = 0.95 where applicable. The best-fit lines in Panel A correspond to Pr(𝑥) = 𝐶𝑥 𝛾̂ , estimated via
ordinary least-squares using log transformed variables: ln(Pr(𝑥)) = ln(𝐶 ) + 𝛾̂ ∗ ln(𝑥).
The realized bank failure rates from the simulation model are reported as a function of the average degree of the
interbank debt network, which takes values of 𝛿̅ = 1 (very low diversification in interbank debt obligations) to 𝛿̅ =
24 (very high diversification in interbank debt obligations). In all simulations, capital regulations are given by 𝑘 =
𝑘̅ = 0 (i.e., so long as a bank is solvent, it can maintain any level of capitalization without facing the requirement for
prompt corrective action). The fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 is therefore irrelevant. The average mean and volatility
of banks’ representative risky assets are 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all simulations. Each panel reports the
simulated bank failure rate for each value of 𝛿̅; a rate of 0.2 indicates that out of 1,000 simulations for 25 banks,
5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed. The failure rates produced by the simulation model are highly consistent
with those resulting from a single-period version of the model (Elliott, Jackson, and Golub (2014)).
The plot shows the results of 1,000 iterations of the simulation model with a solvency condition given by 𝑘 = 0, and
prompt corrective action threshold values of 𝑘̅ = {0,0.015, 0.03, 0.045, 0.06, 0.075, 0.09, 0.105, 0.12, 0.135, 0.15}..
The average mean and volatility of banks’ representative risky assets are 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all
simulations. In these simulations, there is no interbank debt network, so the average degree of the interbank debt
network 𝛿̅ is irrelevant. In the event of a bank’s insolvency, its deposit liabilities and shares in its proprietary asset
are equally redistributed among half of the remaining banks at random. OLS best-fit lines connect results for
simulations using values of the fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 = {0.9, 0.95, 1.00}. Each point in the plot reports the
simulated bank failure rate for each combination of parameter inputs 𝜆 and 𝛿̅; a rate of 0.2 indicates that out of 1,000
simulations for 25 banks, 5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed.
All figures represent the results of simulations with a solvency condition given by 𝑘 = 0, and prompt corrective action threshold values of 𝑘̅ =
{0,0.015, 0.03, 0.045, 0.06, 0.075, 0.09, 0.105, 0.12, 0.135, 0.15}. OLS best-fit lines connect results for simulations over average interbank debt network degree
values of 𝛿̅ = {9, 12, 15, 18, 21, 24}. The average mean and volatility of banks’ representative risky assets are 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all simulations.
Each panel reports the simulated bank failure rate for each combination of parameter inputs 𝑘̅ and 𝛿̅; a rate of 0.2 indicates that out of 1,000 simulations for 25
banks, 5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed. From left to right, the panels correspond to a fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 equal to 0.9 (assets are sold at 90
percent of book value), 0.95 (assets are sold at 95 percent of book value), and 1 (no fire-sale discount), respectively.
All figures represent the results of simulations with a solvency condition given by 𝑘 = 0, and prompt corrective action threshold values of 𝑘̅ =
{0,0.015, 0.03, 0.045, 0.06, 0.075, 0.09, 0.105, 0.12, 0.135, 0.15}. OLS best-fit lines connect results for simulations over average interbank debt network degree
values of 𝛿̅ = {9, 12, 15, 18, 21, 24}. The fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 is equal to 0.95 (assets are sold at 95 percent of book value) in all simulations. From left
to right, the panels correspond to a distribution of banks’ representative risky assets means with an average of 𝜇̅𝐴 = 1.5% (high likelihood of negative asset
returns), 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% (base case), and 𝜇̅𝐴 = 5.5% (low likelihood of negative asset returns), respectively. The average volatility of banks’ representative risky
asset returns is 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all simulations. Each panel reports the simulated bank failure rate for each combination of parameter inputs 𝑘̅ and 𝛿̅; a rate of 0.2
indicates that out of 1,000 simulations for 25 banks, 5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed.
All figures represent the results of simulations with a solvency condition given by 𝑘 = 0, and prompt corrective action threshold values of 𝑘̅ =
{0,0.015, 0.03, 0.045, 0.06, 0.075, 0.09, 0.105, 0.12, 0.135, 0.15}. OLS best-fit lines connect results for simulations over average interbank debt network degree
values of 𝛿̅ = {9, 12, 15, 18, 21, 24}. The fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 is equal to 0.95 (assets are sold at 95 percent of book value) in all simulations. The
average of banks’ representative risky asset mean returns is 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% in all simulations. From left to right, the panels correspond to a distribution of banks’
representative risky assets volatilities with an average of 𝜎̅𝐴 = 6.0% (low likelihood of negative asset returns), 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% (base case), and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 10.0% (high
likelihood of negative asset returns), respectively. Each panel reports the simulated bank failure rate for each combination of parameter inputs 𝑘̅ and 𝛿̅; a rate of
0.2 indicates that out of 1,000 simulations for 25 banks, 5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed.
The plots show the frequency distributions of selected balance-sheet parameters of 25 banks over 10,000 iterations of the simulation model, with 𝑘̅ = 0.075, 𝛿̅ =
12, 𝛽 = 0.95, 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5%, and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all iterations. These balance-sheet parameters are measured at the beginning of the iteration (and so are expected,
rather than realized, values). The frequency distributions are separated by the solvency status of the bank at the end of the iteration (“failed” or “survived”). The
leftmost panel shows the means of individual banks’ risky asset returns 𝜇𝐴 . The average failed bank had an expected mean risky asset return of 2.95%, compared
with an expected mean risky asset return of 3.63% for the average surviving bank. The difference between the means is significant at the 1% level using
Student’s t-test. The central panel shows the volatilities of individual banks’ risky asset returns 𝜎𝐴 . The average failed bank had an expected risky asset return
volatility of 10.55%, compared with an expected risky asset return volatility of 7.65% for the average surviving bank. The difference between the distributions is
significant at the 1% level using both a Kolmogorov-Smirnov two-sample test and a Chi-squared two-sample test. The rightmost panel shows the number of bank
counterparties with debt obligations to the individual bank (i.e., the bank’s debtors in the interbank network). The average failed bank had 10.39 debtors in the
interbank network, compared with 12.32 debtors for the average surviving bank. The difference between the means is significant at the 1% level using Student’s
t-test.
The plot shows the results of 1,000 iterations of the simulation model over varying levels of “induced leverage”, as
measured by the free parameter 𝜆. For all iterations, capital regulations are given by 𝑘 = 𝑘̅ = 0 (i.e., so long as a
bank is solvent, it can maintain any level of capitalization without facing the requirement for prompt corrective
action). The fire-sale discount parameter 𝛽 is therefore irrelevant. The average mean and volatility of banks’
representative risky assets are 𝜇̅𝐴 = 3.5% and 𝜎̅𝐴 = 8.0% in all simulations. OLS best-fit lines connect results for
simulations over average interbank debt network degree values of 𝛿̅ = {9, 12, 15, 18, 21, 24}. Each point in the plot
reports the simulated bank failure rate for each combination of parameter inputs 𝜆 and 𝛿̅; a rate of 0.2 indicates that
out of 1,000 simulations for 25 banks, 5,000/(1,000*25) = 20% of banks failed.