Small States Security

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 291

Small States and International

Security

This book explains what ‘small’ states are and explores their current security chal-
lenges, in general terms and through specific examples. It reflects the shift from
traditional security definitions emphasizing defence and armaments, to new
security concerns such as economic, societal and environmental security where
institutional cooperation looms larger. These complex issues, linked with tradi-
tional power relations and new types of actors, need to be tackled with due regard
to democracy and good governance. Key policy challenges for small states are
examined and applied in the regional case studies.
The book deals mainly with the current experience and recent past of such
states but also offers insights for their future policies. Although many of the states
covered are European, the study also includes African, Caribbean and Asian small
states. Their particular interest and relevance is outlined, as is the connection
between their security challenges and their smallness. Policy lessons for other
states are then sought.
The book is the first in-depth, multi-continent study of security as an aspect of
small state governance today. It is novel in placing the security dilemmas of small
states in the context of wider ideas on international and institutional change, and in
dealing with non-European states and regions.

Clive Archer was, until 2009, Research Professor in International Relations at


Manchester Metropolitan University and was previously a Professor at Aberdeen
University. He has researched and published widely on the affairs of the Nordic
region, Arctic cooperation, international organizations and the European Union.

Alyson J.K. Bailes is a former British diplomat and Director of the Stockholm
International Peace Research Institute, now working as an Adjunct Professor at the
University of Iceland and a Visiting Professor at the College of Europe. Security
studies are her speciality.

Anders Wivel is an Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science,


University of Copenhagen. His most recent books are Explaining Foreign Policy:
International Diplomacy and the Russo-Georgian War (Lynne Rienner 2012, co-
author Hans Mouritzen) and Denmark and the European Union (Routledge 2013,
co-editor Lee Miles).
Routledge advances in international relations and global
politics

1 Foreign Policy and Discourse 8 Politics and Globalisation


Analysis Knowledge, ethics and agency
France, Britain and Europe Martin Shaw
Henrik Larsen
9 History and International
2 Agency, Structure and Relations
International Politics Thomas W. Smith
From ontology to empirical
enquiry 10 Idealism and Realism in
Gil Friedman and Harvey Starr International Relations
Robert M.A. Crawford
3 The Political Economy of
Regional Co-operation in the 11 National and International
Middle East Conflicts, 1945–1995
Ali Carkoglu, Mine Eder and New empirical and theoretical
Kemal Kirisci approaches.
Frank Pfetsch and
4 Peace Maintenance Christoph Rohloff
The evolution of international
political authority 12 Party Systems and Voter
Jarat Chopra Alignments Revisited
Edited by Lauri Karvonen and
5 International Relations and Stein Kuhnle
Historical Sociology
Breaking down boundaries 13 Ethics, Justice and International
Stephen Hobden Relations
Constructing an international
6 Equivalence in Comparative community
Politics Peter Sutch
Edited by Jan W. van Deth
14 Capturing Globalization
7 The Politics of Central Banks Edited by James H. Mittelman and
Robert Elgie and Helen Thompson Norani Othman
15 Uncertain Europe 24 Russian Foreign Policy and the
Building a new European security CIS
order? Theories, debates and actions
Edited by Martin A. Smith and Nicole J. Jackson
Graham Timmins
25 Asia and Europe
16 Power, Postcolonialism and
Development and different
International Relations
dimensions of ASEM
Reading race, gender and class
Yeo Lay Hwee
Edited by Geeta Chowdhry and
Sheila Nair
26 Global Instability and Strategic
17 Constituting Human Rights Crisis
Global civil society and the Neville Brown
society of democratic states
Mervyn Frost
27 Africa in International Politics
External involvement on the
18 US Economic Statecraft for
continent
Survival 1933–1991
Edited by Ian Taylor and
Of sanctions, embargoes and
Paul Williams
economic warfare
Alan P. Dobson
28 Global Governmentality
19 The EU and NATO Enlargement Governing international spaces
Richard McAllister and Edited by Wendy Larner and
Roland Dannreuther William Walters

20 Spatializing International Politics


Analysing activism on the internet 29 Political Learning and
Jayne Rodgers Citizenship Education Under
Conflict
21 Ethnonationalism in the The political socialization of
Contemporary World Israeli and Palestinian youngsters
Walker Connor and the study of Orit Ichilov
nationalism
Edited by Daniele Conversi 30 Gender and Civil Society
Transcending boundaries
22 Meaning and International Edited by Jude Howell and
Relations Diane Mulligan
Edited by Peter Mandaville and
Andrew Williams
31 State Crises, Globalisation and
23 Political Loyalty and the National Movements in
Nation-State North-East Africa
Edited by Michael Waller and The Horn’s dilemma
Andrew Linklater Edited by Asafa Jalata
32 Diplomacy and Developing 40 A Human Security Doctrine for
Nations Europe
Post-cold war foreign Project, principles, practicalities
policy-making structures and Edited by Marlies Glasius and
processes Mary Kaldor
Edited by Justin Robertson and
Maurice A. East 41 The History and Politics of UN
Security Council Reform
33 Autonomy, Self-governance and Dimitris Bourantonis
Conflict Resolution
Innovative approaches to 42 Russia and NATO Since 1991
institutional design in divided From cold war through cold peace
societies to partnership?
Edited by Marc Weller and Martin A. Smith
Stefan Wolff
43 The Politics of Protection
34 Mediating International Crises Sites of insecurity and political
Jonathan Wilkenfeld, agency
Kathleen J. Young, David M. Quinn Edited by Jef Huysmans,
and Victor Asal Andrew Dobson and
Raia Prokhovnik
35 Postcolonial Politics, the 44 International Relations in Europe
Internet and Everyday Life Traditions, perspectives and
Pacific traversals online destinations
M.I. Franklin Edited by Knud Erik Jørgensen
and Tonny Brems Knudsen
36 Reconstituting the Global
Liberal Order 45 The Empire of Security and the
Legitimacy and regulation Safety of the People
Kanishka Jayasuriya Edited by William Bain

37 International Relations, Security 46 Globalization and Religious


and Jeremy Bentham Nationalism in India
Gunhild Hoogensen The search for ontological security
Catrina Kinnvall
38 Interregionalism and 47 Culture and International
International Relations Relations
Edited by Heiner Hänggi, Narratives, natives and tourists
Ralf Roloff and Jürgen Rüland Julie Reeves

39 The International Criminal 48 Global Civil Society


Court Contested futures
A global civil society achievement Edited by Gideon Baker and
Marlies Glasius David Chandler
49 Rethinking Ethical Foreign 57 War, Peace and Hegemony in a
Policy Globalized World
Pitfalls, possibilities and The changing balance of power in
paradoxes the twenty-first century
Edited by David Chandler and Edited by Chandra Chari
Volker Heins
58 Economic Globalisation as
50 International Cooperation and Religious War
Arctic Governance Tragic convergence
Regime effectiveness and northern Michael McKinley
region building
Edited by Olav Schram Stokke and 59 Globalization, Prostitution and
Geir Hønneland Sex-trafficking
Corporeal politics
51 Human Security Elina Penttinen
Concepts and implications
Shahrbanou Tadjbakhsh and 60 Peacebuilding
Anuradha Chenoy Women in international perspective
Elisabeth Porter
52 International Relations and 61 Ethics, Liberalism and Realism
Security in the Digital Age in International Relations
Edited by Johan Eriksson and Mark D. Gismondi
Giampiero Giacomello
62 Law and Legalization in
53 State-Building Transnational Relations
Theory and practice Edited by Christian Brütsch and
Edited by Aidan Hehir and Dirk Lehmkuhl
Neil Robinson
63 Fighting Terrorism and Drugs
54 Violence and Non-Violence in Europe and international police
Africa cooperation
Edited by Pal Ahluwalia, Jörg Friedrichs
Louise Bethlehem and Ruth Ginio
64 Identity Politics in the Age of
Genocide
55 Developing Countries and The holocaust and historical
Global Trade Negotiations representation
Edited by Larry Crump and David B. MacDonald
S. Javed Maswood
65 Globalisation, Public Opinion
56 Civil Society, Religion and and the State
Global Governance Western Europe and East and
Paradigms of power and Southeast Asia
persuasion Edited by Takashi Inoguchi and
Edited by Helen James Ian Marsh
66 Urbicide 76 United Nations Reform
The politics of urban destruction Heading North or South?
Martin Coward Spencer Zifcak

67 Transnational Activism in the 77 New Norms and Knowledge in


UN and the EU World Politics
A comparative study Protecting people, intellectual
Jutta Joachim and Birgit Locher property and the environment
Preslava Stoeva
68 Gender Inclusive
Essays on violence, men and 78 Power, Resistance and Conflict
feminist international relations in the Contemporary World
Adam Jones Social movements, networks and
hierarchies
69 Capitalism, Democracy and the Athina Karatzogianni and
Prevention of War and Poverty Andrew Robinson
Edited by Peter Graeff and
Guido Mehlkop 79 World-Regional Social Policy
and Global Governance
70 Environmental Change and New research and policy agendas
Foreign Policy in Africa, Asia, Europe and Latin
Theory and practice America
Edited by Paul G. Harris Edited by Bob Deacon,
Maria Cristina Macovei,
71 Climate Change and Foreign Luk Van Langenhove and
Policy Nicola Yeates
Case studies from East to West
Edited by Paul G. Harris 80 International Relations Theory
and Philosophy
72 Securitizations of Citizenship Interpretive dialogues
Edited by Peter Nyers Edited by Cerwyn Moore and
Chris Farrands
73 The Power of Ideology
From the Roman Empire to 81 Superpower Rivalry and Conflict
Al-Qaeda The long shadow of the Cold War
Alex Roberto Hybel on the twenty-first century
Edited by Chandra Chari
74 The Securitization of
Humanitarian Migration 82 Coping and Conformity in
Digging moats and sinking boats World Politics
Scott D. Watson Hugh C. Dyer

75 Mediation in the Asia-Pacific 83 Defining and Defying Organized


Region Crime
Transforming conflicts and Discourse, perception and reality
building peace Edited by Felia Allum,
Edited by Dale Bagshaw and Francesca Longo, Daniela Irrera
Elisabeth Porter and Panos A. Kostakos
84 Federalism in Asia 93 Interrogating Democracy in
India, Pakistan and Malaysia World Politics
Harihar Bhattacharyya Edited by Joe Hoover,
Meera Sabaratnam and
85 The World Bank and HIV/AIDS Laust Schouenborg
Setting a global agenda
Sophie Harman 94 Globalizing Resistance against
War
86 The “War on Terror” and the Theories of resistance and the
Growth of Executive Power? new anti-war movement
A comparative analysis Tiina Seppälä
Edited by John E. Owens and
Riccardo Pelizzo 95 The Politics of
Self-Determination
87 The Contested Politics of Beyond the decolonisation process
Mobility Kristina Roepstorff
Borderzones and irregularity
Edited by Vicki Squires 96 Sovereignty and the
Responsibility to Protect
88 Human Security, Law and the The power of norms and the
Prevention of Terrorism norms of the powerful
Andrej Zwitter Theresa Reinold

89 Multilayered Migration 97 Anglo-American Relations


Governance Contemporary perspectives
The promise of partnership Edited by Alan P. Dobson and
Edited by Rahel Kunz, Steve Marsh
Sandra Lavenex and
98 The Emerging Politics of
Marion Panizzon
Antarctica
Edited by Anne-Marie Brady
90 Role Theory in International
Relations 99 Genocide, Ethnonationalism,
Approaches and analyses and the United Nations
Edited by Sebastian Harnisch, Exploring the causes of mass
Cornelia Frank and killing since 1945
Hanns W. Maull Hannibal Travis
91 Issue Salience in International 100 Caribbean Sovereignty,
Relations Development and Democracy
Edited by Kai Oppermann and in an Age of Globalization
Henrike Viehrig Edited by Linden Lewis

92 Corporate Risk and National 101 Rethinking Foreign Policy


Security Redefined Edited by Fredrik Bynander and
Karen Lund Petersen Stefano Guzzini
102 The Promise and Perils of 109 Politics and the Bomb
Transnationalization The role of experts in the
NGO activism and the creation of cooperative nuclear
socialization of women’s human non-proliferation agreements
rights in Egypt and Iran Sara Z. Kutchesfahani
Benjamin Stachursky
110 Interpreting Global Security
103 Peacebuilding and Mark Bevir, Oliver Daddow and
International Administration Ian Hall
The cases of Bosnia and
Herzegovina and Kosovo 111 Foreign Policy, Domestic
Niels van Willigen Politics and International
Relations
104 The Politics of the The case of Italy
Globalization of Law Elisabetta Brighi
Getting from rights to justice
Edited by Alison Brysk
112 The Scourge of Genocide
Essays and reflections
105 The Arctic in International
Adam Jones
Politics
Coming in from the cold
Peter Hough 113 Authority, Ascendancy, and
Supremacy
106 Understanding Transatlantic China, Russia, and the United
Relations States’ pursuit of relevancy and
Whither the West? power
Serena Simoni Gregory O. Hall

107 India in South Asia 114 The Politics of Arctic


Domestic identity politics and Sovereignty
foreign policy from Nehru to the Oil, ice and Inuit governance
BJP Jessica M. Shadian
Sinderpal Singh
115 Small States and International
108 A Strategic Understanding of Security
UN Economic Sanctions Europe and beyond
International relations, law and Edited by Clive Archer,
development Alyson J.K. Bailes and
Golnoosh Hakimdavar Anders Wivel
Small States and International
Security
Europe and beyond

Edited by Clive Archer,


Alyson J.K. Bailes and
Anders Wivel
First published 2014
by Routledge
2 Park Square, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon OX14 4RN
and by Routledge
711 Third Avenue, New York, NY 10017
Routledge is an imprint of the Taylor & Francis Group, an informa business
© 2014 selection and editorial matter, Clive Archer, Alyson J.K. Bailes
and Anders Wivel; contributors, their contributions
The right of Clive Archer, Alyson J.K. Bailes and Anders Wivel to be
identified as editors of this work has been asserted by them in accordance
with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reprinted or reproduced or
utilized in any form or by any electronic, mechanical, or other means, now
known or hereafter invented, including photocopying and recording, or in
any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing
from the publishers.
Trademark notice: Product or corporate names may be trademarks or
registered trademarks, and are used only for identification and explanation
without intent to infringe.
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Small states and international security: Europe and beyond / edited by
Clive Archer, Alyson J.K. Bailes, Anders Wivel.
pages cm. – (Routledge advances in international relations and global
politics)
Includes bibliographical references and index.
1. States, Small. 2. States, Small–Foreign relations. 3. Security,
International–Case studies. 4. States, Small–Economic conditions.
5. States, Small–Case studies. 6. National security. 7. States,
Small–Europe. I. Archer, Clive. II. Bailes, Alyson J. K.
III. Wivel, Anders.
JC365.S56 2014
355′.033–dc23
2013036132
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
A catalog record for this book has been requested
ISBN: 978-0-415-62998-0 (hbk)
ISBN: 978-1-315-79804-2 (ebk)
Typeset in Times New Roman
by Wearset Ltd, Boldon, Tyne and Wear
Contents

List of figures xiii


List of tables xiv
Notes on contributors xv
Preface xx
List of acronyms and abbreviations xxii

PART I
Small state security revisited: history, concepts, theory 1

1 Setting the scene: small states and international security 3


ANDERS WIVEL, ALYSON J.K. BAILES AND CLIVE ARCHER

2 Small states, survival and strategy 26


ALYSON J.K. BAILES, JEAN-MARC RICKLI AND
BALDUR THORHALLSSON

3 Economic security and size 46


RICHARD T. GRIFFITHS

4 Societal security and small states 66


ALYSON J.K. BAILES

5 Environmental security and small states 80


AUÐUR H. INGÓLFSDÓTTIR

PART II
Small state security in Europe 93

6 The Nordic states and security 95


CLIVE ARCHER
xii Contents
7 Security concerns of the Baltic States in the twenty-first
century 113
MINDAUGAS JURKYNAS

8 Security challenges in the Western Balkans: building ‘soft’


security after conflict 130
VIŠNJA SAMARDŽIJA AND SENADA ŠELO ŠABIĆ

9 Georgia and Moldova: caught in the outskirts of Europe? 149


RUXANDRA LUPU DINESEN AND ANDERS WIVEL

10 The security of the European micro-states 167


ARCHIE W. SIMPSON

PART III
Comparative insights 185

11 Botswana as a small developmental state 187


IAN TAYLOR

12 Small state security in Asia: political and temporal


constructions of vulnerability 202
ALAN CHONG

13 What Caribbean post-2015?: developmental and/or fragile?


Old versus new security? 223
TIMOTHY M. SHAW

14 The security concerns of designed spaces: size matters 241


GODFREY BALDACCHINO

Index 255
Figures

3.1 Commonwealth Vulnerability Index (1999) 50


3.2 Economic Vulnerability Index (2003) 51
3.3 Economic Vulnerability Index (2005) 51
3.4 UNDP Economic Vulnerability Index (2005–2008) 52
3.5 Revised Commonwealth Vulnerability Index (2010) 54
3.6 IMF Overall Vulnerability Index (2011) 55
3.7 Economic Resilience Index (2009) 57
Tables

2.1 A possible ‘comprehensive’ security agenda for small states 31


3.1 Comparison of most/least vulnerable states from four
international indexes (population sizes in millions) 53
3.2 Fifteen most and fifteen least vulnerable states in the
Economic Resilience Index 2009 (population size, thousands) 58
6.1 The Nordic states: some comparisons 95
8.1 Selected Western Balkan basic indicators 132
8.2 Population growth rate (%) in Western Balkan countries 133
8.3 Global corruption ranking of Western Balkan States
(2005–2011) 136
8.4 Percentage of unemployed workforce in the Western Balkans,
2005–2011 (%) 137
10.1 Size of micro-state parliaments in Europe 173
10.2 Selected economic data of the European micro-states 175
10.3 Membership of international organizations (with date of first
membership) 177
13.1 Caribbean incomes per capita, 2012 228
Contributors

Clive Archer was, until 2009, Director of the Manchester European Research
Institute at Manchester Metropolitan University. From 2009–2012, he was an
Emeritus Professor at MMU and an individual research member of the Oslo-
based Geopolitics of the High North research group; he remains part of a
brains-trust on the future of the Nordic region. His publications include
Norway Outside the European Union (Routledge 2005), ‘The Stoltenberg
Report and Nordic Security: Big Idea, Small Steps’, in Nanna Hvidt and Hans
Mouritzen (eds) Danish Foreign Policy Yearbook (Danish Institute of Inter-
national Affairs 2010, pp. 43–74) and ‘Norway and the United Kingdom in
the High North’, in Helge Pharo and Patrick Salmon (eds) Britain and
Norway: Special Relationships (Akademika Forlag 2012, pp. 309–334). He
has been granted honours by the King of Norway and the President of Fin-
land.
Alyson J.K. Bailes is an Adjunct Professor at the University of Iceland in Rey-
kjavik and a Visiting Professor at the College of Europe in Bruges, specializ-
ing in security studies. In her former career she was a UK diplomat and, from
2002–2007, served as Director of the Stockholm International Peace Research
Institute (SIPRI). She has published extensively on issues of European
security, regional security governance, arms control, and the roles of non-
state actors. Her recent work has focused more on the Arctic and on small
state issues and includes the monograph Does a Small State need a Strategy?
(University of Iceland 2009), as well as articles on Scotland’s choices as a
small state in the event of independence.
Godfrey Baldacchino (PhD Warwick) is Professor of Sociology at the Univer-
sity of Malta, Malta; Visiting Professor of Island Tourism at the Universita’
di Corsica Pascal Paoli, Corte, France; and the outgoing Canada Research
Chair (Island Studies) at the University of Prince Edward Island, Canada. He
is the Executive Editor of Island Studies Journal and the Vice-President of
the International Small Islands Studies Association (ISISA). His recent books
include Island Enclaves (McGill-Queen’s University Press 2010); Divided
Islands (Palgrave Macmillan 2012); and Independence Movements from Sub-
national Island Jurisdictions (Routledge 2013, co-author Eve Hepburn).
xvi Contributors
Alan Chong is Associate Professor at the S. Rajaratnam School of International
Studies based in Singapore, but he earned his doctorate at the London School
of Economics and Political Science. He has published widely on the notion of
soft power and the role of ideas in constructing the international relations of
Singapore and of Asia generally. His publications have appeared in The
Pacific Review; International Relations of the Asia-Pacific; Review of Inter-
national Studies; Politics, Religion and Ideology; Armed Forces and Society;
and Alternatives: Global, Local, Political.
Ruxandra Lupu Dinesen is a former research assistant at the Danish Institute
for International Studies and is now a PhD candidate at the Department of
Political Science in the University of Copenhagen, Denmark. Her research
focuses on how the European Union responds to mass protests in its neigh-
bourhood, in particular the Twitter revolution in Moldova and the Jasmine
revolution in Tunisia. She has conducted extensive fieldwork in both coun-
tries and has been a visiting scholar at the London School of Economics.
Richard T. Griffiths graduated in economic history from Swansea University
and obtained his doctorate from Cambridge University. He held the chair of
Economic and Social History at the Free University, Amsterdam, before
being appointed Professor of Contemporary History at the European Univer-
sity Institute, Florence. In 1995 he was appointed Professor of Economic and
Social History at Leiden University and in 2013, he became the first Professor
of International Studies at the same university. He has published widely in the
field of nineteenth- and twentieth-century economic history and the history of
European integration. His book, ‘Thank you M. Monnet’: Essays on the His-
tory of European Integration (Leiden University Press), appeared in 2013
Auður H. Ingólfsdóttir is an Assistant Professor at Bifröst University, Iceland,
teaching courses in the BA Programme in Philosophy, Politics and Eco-
nomics (PPE). She holds a BA degree in international studies from the Uni-
versity of Washington (Seattle), a postgraduate diploma in professional
journalism from the University of Iceland, and a Masters degree in inter-
national relations from the Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts
University (Boston). She has worked as a project manager for the University
of Iceland, as a special advisor in the Ministry for the Environment, and as a
private consultant on environmental policy. During the period 2006–2008 she
worked in Sri Lanka and in the Balkans for the Icelandic Crisis Response
Unit. Her main fields of interest within international relations are the environ-
ment and sustainable development, gender and security studies.
Mindaugas Jurkynas is Professor in Regional Studies at Vytautas Magnus
University in Kaunas and part-time Professor at Mykolas Romeris Univer-
sity in Vilnius, Lithuania, specializing in small state identity, patterns of
cooperation and conflict in Northern Europe and the transformation of new
democracies in Central and Eastern Europe. In his former career he served
as the Lithuanian Prime Minister’s advisor on foreign policy and national
Contributors xvii
security in 2006–2008 and worked at Vilnius University in 1998–2013.
Between December 2011 and January 2013, he launched and was editor-in-
chief of the first issue of the Baltic Journal of Political Science, and was
also head of the Northern European Study Centre at Vilnius University.
Since 2013 February, he has served as associate editor of the International
Journal of Area Studies at Vytautas Magnus University. Mindaugas Jurky-
nas has recently published on the issues of Lithuania’s democratization,
Lithuanian–Russian relations, the Europeanization of Lithuania and the
regional identity of the Baltic States in the periodicals Electoral Studies and
Journal of Baltic Studies, and in co-edited volumes published by Routledge,
Palgrave and Edward Elgar.
Jean-Marc Rickli is Assistant Professor at the Institute of International and
Civil Security at Khalifa University. He holds a PhD in international relations
from Oxford University, where he was a Berrow scholar, and has taught in
more than ten countries in North America, Europe, Asia and the Middle East.
His areas of expertise are small states’ security, risk analysis, and non-
traditional security issues. He has published several book chapters and articles
on small states’ security in Europe and in the Gulf, and a book titled Air
Power, Coercion and Crisis Management: The Use of Air Power in the Bal-
kans during the 1990s (Verlag 2009).
Senada Šelo Šabić is a Research Associate at the Institute for Development and
International Relations (IRMO) in Zagreb. Her research interests focus on
Croatian foreign policy, politics and relations among states in South-Eastern
Europe, EU enlargement, development assistance and migration. She holds a
PhD in political science from the European University Institute in Florence and
has two Masters degrees – in international relations and in peace studies – from
the University of Zagreb and the University of Notre Dame, USA, respectively.
She is editor-in-chief of the Croatian International Relations Review and is the
external teacher at the Faculty of Political Science, University of Zagreb. She
has authored a monograph on State Building under Foreign Supervision: Inter-
vention in Bosnia and Herzegovina 1996–2003 (Austrian Federal Ministry of
Defence 2005) as well as book chapters and articles.
Višnja Samardžija obtained her PhD at the Faculty of Economics, University
of Zagreb. She is Head of the Department for European Integration in the
Institute for Development and International Relations (IRMO) Zagreb. She
served as Assistant Minister in the Ministry for European Integration of
Croatia (2000–2004) and participated in working groups on Croatia’s negoti-
ations for EU membership. She lectures in postgraduate and doctoral Euro-
pean studies programmes at the universities of Zagreb and Osijek. She has
been a member of the Board of TEPSA (the Trans-European Policy Studies
Association), in Brussels, since 2010. She has coordinated a number of inter-
national projects and conferences, published articles in journals, books and
proceedings in Croatia and abroad and edited the IRMO Europe book series,
xviii Contributors
launched in 1994. Her area of interest includes EU enlargement, EU policy
towards South-Eastern Europe, regional cooperation, civil security, Europe
2020, and communication with citizens.
Timothy M. Shaw is Director of the PhD programme in Global Governance and
Human Security at the University of Massachusetts, Boston. He previously
directed graduate programmes in Commonwealth studies at the University of
London, and in international relations at the University of the West Indies,
after teaching for three decades at Dalhousie University in Nova Scotia. He
has just co-edited Comparative Regionalism for Development in the 21st Cen-
tury: Insights from the Global South (Ashgate 2013); while his co-edited col-
lection with Andrew Cooper on The Diplomacies of Small States: between
Vulnerability and Resilience (Palgrave 2009) was published in a revised
paperback edition in late 2012. Dr Shaw continues to edit an IPE book series
for Palgrave Macmillan and Ashgate. He is a Visiting Professor at Aalborg,
Mbarara, and Stellenbosch Universities.
Archie W. Simpson is a founding member of the Centre for Small State Stud-
ies, University of Iceland and has been a Teaching Fellow at the University of
Aberdeen and the University of St Andrews, and a Teaching Assistant at the
University of Stirling. His interests include small states, European politics,
British politics and international security. He is currently writing his first
book, Small States in International Politics, to be published by Routledge.
Ian Taylor is Professor in International Relations and African Politics at St
Andrews, and also holds a professorial chair in the School of International
Studies at China’s Renmin University. Further posts are Professor Extra-
ordinary in Political Science at the University of Stellenbosch, South Africa;
Honorary Professor at the Institute of African Studies, China; and Visiting
Scholar at Mbarara University of Science and Technology, Uganda. Focusing
largely on sub-Saharan Africa, he has authored seven academic books, edited
another eight, and has published well over 100 scholarly articles and chapters
in books.
Baldur Thorhallsson is Professor of Political Science and Jean Monnet Chair in
European Studies at the Faculty of Political Science at the University of Ice-
land. He holds a PhD (1999) and MA (1994) in Political Science from the
University of Essex in England. His research focus is primarily on small state
studies, European integration and Iceland’s domestic and foreign policy. He
has published extensively in international journals. He has contributed to sev-
eral academic books and written two books on small states in Europe: Iceland
and European Integration: On the Edge (Routledge 2004) and The Role of
Small States in the European Union (Routledge 2006). In 2002, Baldur estab-
lished a Centre for Small State Studies at the University of Iceland in associ-
ation with colleagues around the globe and re-established the Icelandic
Institute of International Affairs. He was Chair of the Board of the IIA/CSSS
until 2011 and is currently a Board member.
Contributors xix
Anders Wivel is an Associate Professor in the Department of Political Science,
University of Copenhagen. His current research focuses on small state foreign
policy and the realist perspective on international relations. He has published
on these topics in a number of international journals, including, for example,
Journal of Common Market Studies, Cooperation and Conflict, Security
Dialogue, Journal of European Integration and Cambridge Review of Inter-
national Affairs. His most recent books are Explaining Foreign Policy:
International Diplomacy and the Russo-Georgian War (Lynne Rienner 2012,
co-author Hans Mouritzen) and Denmark and the European Union (Routledge
2013, co-editor Lee Miles).
Preface

The study of security and the study of small states have always been closely
related. Twentieth-century scholars were puzzled as to how and why small states
survived in an anarchic international system dominated by great power politics.
More recently, a number of analysts have explored the behaviour and influence
of small states in an increasingly institutionalized security environment that
presents a more diverse range of security challenges to individuals, states and
societies. This volume explores small state security conceptually, theoretically
and empirically. It seeks to make an original and accessible contribution to our
understanding by unpacking the most important challenges to small state
security; identifying the central hypotheses emerging from the literature; and
discussing the importance and applicability of these hypotheses inside and
outside the European context for which they were typically constructed.
The study of small states is growing in popularity and sophistication around
the world, just as the numbers of such states have multiplied since the Cold War.
In consequence the number of academic publications and university courses on
small states has also increased over the past two decades. In Europe, in par-
ticular, there has been a growing interest in the challenges and opportunities of
small states in an increasingly globalized world. Since 2003, the Centre for
Small State Studies (CSSS) at the University of Iceland (UI) in Reykjavik has
held an annual two-week Summer School on Small States, with ERASMUS
funding and with help from a network currently of 17 partners (see http://ams.hi.
is/node/19). In 2009–2011, security for such states was the overarching topic of
the event, and it still features strongly within the 2012–2014 programme focus-
ing on ‘Small States, Integration and Globalization’. The co-editors of this
volume have worked together since the Centre’s earliest days, with Professor
Baldur Thorhallsson and Director Pia Hansson at UI, to help develop and teach
at the School; and the main inspiration for this volume was to bring into print –
for wider accessibility – the materials and deeper analysis developed for the
purpose. Most of the chapters were contributed, accordingly, by regular Summer
School lecturers and partners of the CSSS: a few more have been commissioned
from other qualified experts for the sake of coverage and balance.
We would like to thank all concerned at CSSS, including the Summer School
students who have been a permanent source of challenge and inspiration, and all
Preface xxi
who have played a part in preparing, reviewing, designing and producing this
volume. In particular, we would like to thank the contributors to this volume for
their professionalism, enthusiasm and willingness to engage in this project. We
are grateful to the editor of Copenhagen Political Studies Press, Professor Mikkel
Vedby Rasmussen, for a grant allowing for assistance in the final stages of the
editing process and to Vera Knutsdóttir for competently providing that assist-
ance. Last but not least, we thank Heidi Bagtazo, Alexander Quayle, Andrew
Taylor and their team at Routledge for their support and assistance throughout
the editorial process.
We trust that the results will be of help and profit to those engaged in
research, teaching and learning on small states, but also to all policy-makers and
actors – officials, businesspeople, civil society groups and media – who are
involved in managing such states, or who deal with them as partners and
neighbours.
Clive Archer
Alyson J.K. Bailes
Anders Wivel
(November 2013)
Acronyms and abbreviations

AA Association Agreement
ACCP Association of Caribbean Commissioners of Police
ACS Association of Caribbean States
AEI Alliance for European Integration (Moldova)
AOSIS Alliance of Small Island States
APEC Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation
ARF ASEAN Regional Forum
ASEAN Association of Southeast Asian Nations
ASEM Asia-Europe Meetings
AU African Union
BBC British Broadcasting Corporation
BDC Botswana Development Corporation Limited
BDP Botswana Democratic Party
BEDIA Botswana Export Development and Investment Authority
BiH Bosnia and Herzegovina
BRIC(s) Brazil, Russia, India, China
CAJO Caribbean Association of Judicial Officers
CANARI Caribbean Natural Resources Institute
CAP Common Agricultural Policy (EU)
CARICOM Caribbean Community
CARICOM- CARICOM Implementation Agency for Crime and Security
IMPACS
CARIFORUM Caribbean Forum
CCCC Caribbean Community Climate Change Centre
CDCC Caribbean Cooperation and Development Committee
CFSP Common Foreign and Security Policy (EU)
CIA Central Intelligence Agency
CLICO Colonial Life Insurance Company
CMS Constant Market Share
CoE Council of Europe
COP Conference of the Parties
CPDC Caribbean Development Policy Centre
CRIES Coordinadora Regional de Investigaciones Económicas y Sociales
Acronyms and abbreviations xxiii
CSA Caribbean Studies Association
CSDP Common Security and Defence Policy (EU)
CIS Commonwealth of Independent States
CSME Caribbean Single Market and Economy
CSTO Collective Security Treaty Organization
DCAF Geneva Centre for Democratic Control of Armed Forces
DCFTA Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Agreement
DEMA Danish Emergency Management Agency
DPPI SEE Disaster Preparedness and Prevention Initiative for South
Eastern Europe
EC European Commission
ECLAC Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean
EEA European Economic Area
EFTA European Free Trade Association
ENP European Neighbourhood Policy (EU)
EPA Economic Partnership Agreement
E-PINE Enhanced Partnership in Northern Europe
ESDP European Security and Defence Policy (EU)
EU European Union
EUROPOL EU Serious and Organized Crime Threat Assessment
SOCTA
EU-R-PSC European Union-Russia Political Security Committee
EUSR European Union’s Special Representative
EVI Economic Vulnerability Index
EVIAR Economic Vulnerability Index Augmented by Resilience
FAP Financial Assistance Programme
FATF Financial Action Task Force (OECD)
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FOSS Forum of Small States
FRY Former Republic of Yugoslavia
FYROM Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GIUK gap Greenland, Iceland, UK gap
GPS Global Positioning System
GR:EEN Global Re-ordering: Evolution through European Networks
GUAM Georgia, Ukraine, Azerbaijan, Moldova Organization for
Democracy and Economic Development
HDI Human Development Index
HIV/AIDS Human immunodeficiency virus infection/acquired
immunodeficiency syndrome
HLAD High-Level Accession Dialogue (EU and FYROM)
IBRD International Bank for Reconstruction and Development
ICBL International Campaign to Ban Landmines
ICRU Icelandic Crisis Response Unit
ICT Information and communications technology
xxiv Acronyms and abbreviations
ICTY International Criminal Tribunal for the Former Yugoslavia
IDB Inter-American Development Bank
IEA International Energy Agency
IFI International Financial Institution
IMF International Monetary Fund
IPCC Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
ISAF International Security Assistance Force (Afghanistan)
KFOR Kosovo Force (NATO-led)
LAC Latin America and the Caribbean
LTTE Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam (Sri Lanka)
MAP Membership Action Plan (NATO)
MDC Most Developed Countries
MDG Millennium Development Goals
MERCOSUR Southern Common Market
MFDP Ministry of Finance and Development Planning (Botswana)
MIST Mexico, Indonesia, South Korea, Turkey
MSB Civil Contingencies Agency (Sweden)
NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement
NATO North Atlantic Treaty Organization
NBC Nuclear, Biological, Chemical (weapons)
NDP National Development Plan
NETRIS Network of Regional Integration Studies
NGO Non-Governmental Organization
NORDAC Nordic Armaments Co-operation
NORDCAPS Nordic Coordinated Arrangement for Military Peace Support
NORDEFCO Nordic Defence Cooperation
NORDSUP Nordic Support Structure
NOST National Operative Staff (Denmark)
NTS Non-traditional security
OAS Organization of American States
OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
OECS Organization of Eastern Caribbean States
OIC Organization of Islamic Cooperation
OPEC Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries
OSCE Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe
PAP People’s Action Party (Singapore)
PCC SEE Police Cooperation Convention for South East Europe
PfP Partnership for Peace (NATO)
PIIGS Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, Spain
PPP Purchasing Power Parity
RACVIAC South East European Centre for Security Cooperation
RAI Regional Anti-corruption Initiative
RBC Royal Bank of Canada
RCC Regional Cooperation Council (Western Balkans)
Acronyms and abbreviations xxv
RECOM Regional Commission (on war crimes and other serious human
rights violations, Former Yugoslavia)
REVI Revised Economic Vulnerability Index
SAARC South Asian Association for Regional Cooperation
SADC Southern African Development Community
SAP Stabilization and Association Process (EU)
SAP Structural Adjustment Programme
SCO Shanghai Cooperation Organization
SEE South East Europe Transnational Cooperation Programme
SEECIC South East European Counter Intelligence Chiefs Forum
SEECP South East European Cooperation Process
SEEMIC South East European Military Intelligence Chiefs Conference
SEENSA South East European National Security Authorities
SEPCA South East European Police Chiefs Association
SFOR Stabilization Force (Bosnia and Herzegovina)
SIDS Small Island Developing States
SIPRI Stockholm International Peace Research Institute
TcFSSR Transcaucasian Federated Soviet Socialist Republic
TIEA Tax Information Exchange Agreements
TMR Transnistrian Moldovan Republic
TOC Transnational Organized Crime
UN United Nations
UNCED United Nations Conference on the Environment and
Development
UNCLOS United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea
UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development
UNDP United Nations Development Programme
UNEP United Nations Environment Programme
UNESCO United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural
Organization
UNFCCC United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
UNMIK United Nations Interim Administrative Mission in Kosovo
UNODC United Nations Office on Drugs and Crime
UNU-CRIS United Nations University’s Comparative Regional Integration
Studies
USSR Union of Soviet Socialist Republics
VAT Value Added Tax
WB Western Balkans
WIDER World Institute for Development Economics Research
WMD Weapons of Mass Destruction
WTO World Trade Organization
ZAVKO Transcaucasian Military District (Russia)
This page intentionally left blank
Part I
Small state security
revisited
History, concepts, theory
This page intentionally left blank
1 Setting the scene
Small states and international security
Anders Wivel, Alyson J.K. Bailes and Clive Archer

Introduction
Small states have traditionally played a marginal role in the construction and
maintenance of international security orders. Accepting the dictum formulated
by Thucydides in the fifth century BC, that ‘the strong do what they have the
power to do and the weak accept what they have to accept’ (Thucydides [1954]
1972: 302), small states have tended to pursue pragmatic and reactive security
policies adapting to the interests of nearby great powers and aiming primarily to
ensure their own survival. As noted by Browning:

[i]n the international relations literature and in world politics size has gener-
ally been connected to capability and influence. Whilst being big is corre-
lated with power, being small has been viewed as a handicap to state action,
and even state survival.
(Browning 2006: 669)

This was true even as international affairs began to institutionalize. In the nine-
teenth century, the Congress of Vienna recognized the special role of the United
Kingdom, Prussia, Austria, France and Russia, and for almost a century the great
powers set the rules of the game by meeting ‘in concert on a regular basis in order
to discuss questions of concern, and to draw up agreements and treaties’ (Neumann
and Gstöhl 2006: 5). Small states were those states that were not great powers, i.e.
the states left to obey the rules of the game, because they were too weak to be
taken seriously when the rules were negotiated. In the first half of the twentieth
century, conditions seemed to worsen for small states as the development of new
weapons technology widened the gap between them and the great powers. As
noted by Annette Baker Fox in her classic study of the power of small states:

[d]uring World War II it was widely asserted that the day of the small power
was over. Not only could such a state have no security under modern con-
ditions of war; it could have no future in the peace that presumably one day
would follow.
(Fox 2006 [1959]: 39)
4 A. Wivel et al.
Superpower rivalry between the US and the Soviet Union following the end
of the war simultaneously intensified and ameliorated the security predica-
ment of small states. On the one hand, the institutions of international society
were strengthened. On a global scale, the establishment and subsequent devel-
opment of the United Nations served as an important vehicle for decoloniza-
tion (supported by both superpowers), which helped to create a large number
of new small states. Subsequently the UN served as a platform for small states
voicing their concerns over international developments and cooperating on
promoting their values and interests. On a regional scale, a proliferation of
new regional trade agreements and organizations, most notably the precursors
to the European Union, helped small states to achieve some of the economies
of scale that had traditionally been the privilege of great powers. On the other
hand, a world with two superpowers of continental size and global reach was
also a world of even greater power disparity than had been the case before the
war, with a sharp delineation between the security- (and insecurity-)produc-
ing superpowers and small state security consumers unable to defend their
own territory against external (and sometimes internal) threats.
A transformed geopolitical environment after the Cold War, 9/11 and the
Iraq war have fundamentally altered the security challenges of small states in
Europe. Most importantly, the end of the Cold War reduced the traditional
military threat to most European small states significantly. In much of Europe
– at least – small states need not fear military invasion for the foreseeable
future. This has widened the foreign policy room of manoeuvre considerably
for these small states, as they need no longer fear that policies provoking or
irritating the strong will lead to military subjugation or extinction. In addi-
tion, from the 1990s onwards, intensified globalization and increased interde-
pendence reduced the importance of traditional military instruments in a way
that highlighted both the diplomatic and institutional competencies of small
states, and their possible non-state (business, intellectual, environmental)
assets.
However, new security challenges soon emerged. The Gulf War of
1990–1991 and the struggle over former Yugoslavia created new demands for
active conflict management, and small states were expected to contribute to their
solution even if their immediate security interests were not under threat. The
repercussions of the terrorist attacks on New York and Washington on
September 11, 2001, and the wars in Iraq and Afghanistan, emphasized the
global aspect of small state security. As the European experience has illustrated,
this does not necessarily mean the end of great power politics. The gradual
development of the EU as a security actor, and the frequent use of informal big
member state consultations in EU security policy making, illustrates that Euro-
peanization entails challenges as well as opportunities (Wivel 2005). At the same
time economic, societal and environmental security issues present all states with
a new set of challenges including financial crisis, increased competition over
markets, migration, terrorism and global warming.
Small states and international security 5
The aim of the book
The aim of this book is to conceptualize, map and explain the security challenges
of small states today. We specifically aim both to identify the challenges and the
opportunities of small states and to discuss the costs and benefits of the different
security strategies followed by small states inside and outside Europe. Through-
out the history of international security, small states’ relative lack of power has
given them less influence over international events and a smaller margin of time
and error (Jervis 1978: 172–173). As permanent security consumers they have
had little to offer the great powers and therefore, also, a limited room for man-
oeuvre when pursuing strategic goals beyond security and survival. As the stra-
tegic environment of small states is changing, so are their opportunities and
incentives to engage actively in the creation and maintenance of security orders.
Even though the literature on small state security has been growing rapidly
since the end of the Cold War, there have been few attempts to go beyond single
country studies and provide a comprehensive overview of the general pattern of
challenges, opportunities and strategies facing small states in the current security
order. Now, as in the past, the study of small states is plagued by a lack of cumu-
lative insights and coherent debate. This book aspires to fill this void by taking
three steps towards a more generally applicable understanding of small state
security. First, we discuss how the transformation of small state security necessi-
tates the development and application of new security concepts, and extends the
range of possible solutions. Second, we analyse a number of European cases in
order to describe and explain the security predicament of small European states
today and how they respond. Third, we explore examples of small state security
in Africa, Asia and the Caribbean to see how they compare or contrast with the
European experience. All this helps to produce comparative insights, drawn from
the conceptual discussions and empirical analyses, and reflected in the chapters
of Part III.
We do not seek to prove a certain theoretical school – realist, liberal or con-
structivist – right or wrong. Our research strategy is to start from a shared defini-
tion of small states, to focus on the security challenges and opportunities of
small states today and in the recent past, and to structure the analyses within
each part of the book with a set of questions to be answered by each chapter
within that part. Thus, our aim is not to construct and test a grand theory of small
states, but to offer a structured and focused analysis of small state security today.
We also acknowledge that different theories may shed light in different places,
and that variations in historical, geopolitical and institutional contexts will affect
the applicability of general theories to small state security over time and space.

Defining small states in international security


Students have not reached a consensus on how to define a small state or which
behavioural characteristics may be seen as typical for small states, beyond the
general tendency of such states to adapt to – rather than dominate – their external
6 A. Wivel et al.
environment, and (where applicable) to seek influence through membership of
international institutions (Amstrup 1976: 178; Antola and Lehtimäki 2001:
13–20; Archer and Nugent 2002: 2–5; Christmas-Møller 1983: 40; Hey 2003:
2–10; Knudsen 2002: 182–185; Panke 2010: 15; Steinmetz and Wivel 2010:
4–7).1 Thus, although most students would agree with Hey, that today ‘[s]mall
states [. . .] enjoy more international prestige and visibility than at any other time
in history’ (Hey 2003: 1), they would find it hard to agree upon what exactly
constitutes a small state.
Despite this lack of consensus, analyses of small state security tend to focus
on material power capabilities, i.e. the possession of – or rather the lack of –
power resources in absolute or relative terms; most often measured by proxies
such as population size, GDP (gross domestic product) or military expenditure.
Historically, this type of definition follows directly from the development of
international society in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries when the number
of small states rose sharply as a consequence of the break-up of empires and
decolonization. The class of small states was a ‘residual category’, referring to
those states that were not great powers and thus were defined by ‘their presumed
lack of power in a quantitative sense’ (Neumann and Gstöhl 2006: 4). Theoret-
ically, this type of definition typically follows from a starting point in the realist
school of international relations, which has historically been the dominant
approach to the analysis of international security, including the security prob-
lems of small states.2
Three benefits follow from defining small states in terms of capabilities. First,
if we are to analyse the opportunities, challenges and limitations of a specific
state, indications of absolute and relative capacity are important, because they
inform us of the absolute and relative limitations on these states’ capacity to
handle different types of challenges. Second, an absolute and universal threshold
between big and small states of, for example, a population size of 15 million
people, or a GDP of €500 billion, has the benefit of creating a clear and easily
applicable definition of small states. The same can be said of a relative definition
defining great powers as the ‘top ten’ in the world, or the ‘top five’ in a specific
region – measured in, for example, population size, GDP or military expenditure
– and the rest as small states. Also, the existing power indexes of the (realist) IR
literature, which seeks to combine a number of parameters in order to evaluate
the aggregate power of states, may be adapted to the analysis of small states
(Kennedy 1987; Schweller 1998; Wohlforth 1999).
Third, starting from a power possession definition allows us to draw on the
comprehensive literature on power and security in international relations in order
to identify why, when and how the security challenges of small states are distinct
from those faced by stronger states. For instance, Kenneth Waltz, the pre-
eminent scholar of relative capabilities, discusses the implications of power (and
the lack of it) and notes that: (1) ‘power provides the means of maintaining one’s
autonomy in the face of force that others wield’, (2) ‘greater power permits
wider ranges of action, while leaving the outcome of action uncertain’, (3) ‘the
more powerful enjoy wider margins of safety in dealing with the less powerful
Small states and international security 7
and have more to say about which games will be played and how’, and finally
(4) ‘great power gives its possessors a big stake in their system and the ability to
act for its sake’ (Waltz 1979: 194–195). Following this discussion, it could be
argued that small states: (1) are not able by themselves to preserve their own
autonomy in the face of force that others wield; (2) have a narrow range of
action; (3) have little to say about which games are being played, and how; (4)
have only a small stake in the system and are unable to act for its sake. These
four points correspond closely with a traditionalist view of small states in inter-
national security. Throughout the book, the authors of individual chapters use
these four assumptions as a starting point for discussing to which extent this
view is still relevant for the states analysed.
Yet despite the merits of the power possession definition of small states and
its prominence in security studies, we find that it has at least three important lim-
itations. First, it leads us to a focus on the military dimension of security. A
focus on material power resources naturally leads to a focus on military security,
because military capabilities are decisive for state survival in conventional
warfare. Even when human and economic resources are included in the defini-
tion of material power, these tend to be regarded as components of ‘latent power’
necessary for upholding and developing the military power capabilities that are
vital for survival in an anarchic international system (e.g. Mearsheimer 2001).
To be sure, military security threats continue to be important to the large major-
ity of small states, but, as argued in Chapter 2, an exclusive focus on military
threats is too restrictive if we are to understand small state security today. Most
importantly, we risk underestimating the opportunities and contributions of small
states if we focus on material, and in effect military, capabilities, because con-
ventional military power is the area where most small states are weakest.
Second, as argued by Rothstein, a focus on quantifiable objective criteria
logically leads to a ranking of powers and an understanding of international rela-
tions in terms of power hierarchy, which is of little use for identifying the real
challenges and opportunities of small states (Rothstein 1968). There are two
problems with this understanding in regard to analysing small state security.
First, security challenges to small states are rarely systemic but typically
originate in the geopolitical vicinity of the small state. Second, we cannot deduce
a state’s security challenges from its power rank in the international system, or
even in a given region. Security conflicts are typically the product of power as
well as a number of other factors, such as historical lessons learned by the polit-
ical elites and the electorate, religion, ideology, the personality of decision-
makers and political institutions. Thus, challenges to small state security often
make most sense within a specific spatio-temporal context, now including their
specific role in, and adjustment to, globalized features of the world scene. It
follows that no matter whether we focus on absolute or relative power, the cri-
teria for defining the cut-off line between small states and great powers will
always be arbitrary, and this problem is only aggravated if we introduce addi-
tional categories such as middle powers and micro-states.3 There is no reason
why a country with 20 million people should be a great power and a country
8 A. Wivel et al.
with 18 million should be a small state, or why number five in Europe – meas-
ured in military expenditure – should be characterized as a great power and
number six should not. Would numbers one to five face a different set of shared
problems than numbers six and seven? Would they follow a shared strategy dis-
tinguishable from that followed by numbers six and seven to solve these prob-
lems? So far, the evidence clearly suggests that they would not.
Finally, the power possession definition is based on the premise that we can
quantify and measure power. However, power is difficult to measure and its
effects are almost impossible to distinguish from the calculations and percep-
tions of policy makers. Thus, the cut-off point between big and small states is
rarely self-evident, and, accordingly, there is no consensus on what constitutes a
small state in term of power possession. Indeed, the notion ‘small state’ has
typically been used to denote at least three different types of states: micro-states,
small states in the developed world and small states in the Third World (Hey
2003: 2). Adding to the confusion, none of these categories is clear-cut and there
is agreement on how to define them. Micro-states are sometimes defined accord-
ing to the size of their population, typically with the threshold set somewhere
between 100,000 and 1.5 million inhabitants (cf. Anckar 2004: 208; Mohamed
2002: 1; Neumann and Gstöhl 2006: 6; Plischke 1977: 21), but at other times
micro-states are defined by having ‘a size so diminutive as to invite comment’
(Warrington 1998: 102). Likewise, small states in the developed world have
been defined using a number of different and often incompatible criteria, leading
to confusion over how to recognize a small state when we see one.
Thus Väyrynen, in a survey on the concept, identifies two axes for defining
small states (Väyrynen 1971). One axis focuses on whether the defining criteria
for small states are objective, e.g. size of GDP or population, or subjective, e.g.
perceptions of domestic or foreign elites. The other axis focuses on whether the
defining criteria are endogenous, i.e. internal characteristics of a country, or
exogenous, i.e. the country’s relations with other states.4 Adding to the complex-
ity, small states in the Third World usually have much larger populations than
what we term small states in the developed world, because ‘population size is
taken as a proxy of a range of other economic characteristics – all of which are
deemed to bestow particular vulnerabilities on small states’ (Heron 2008: 246).
Thus, in his now classical study The Inequality of States, David Vital studies
small states with, ‘. . . a) a population of 10–15 million in the case of economic-
ally advanced countries and b) a population of 20–30 million in the case of
underdeveloped countries’ (Vital 1967: 8).
Acknowledging this limitation, as well as the difficulties of measuring power
and its consequences, we have proposed to the authors in this book a move away
from the quantifiable power possession definition of small states to one that is
qualitative and relational (cf. Mouritzen and Wivel 2005b; Rothstein 1968; Toje
2010). We thereby accept the argument recently made by several scholars that,
rather than continue the search for universal characteristics of small states and
their behaviour, the ‘small state’ concept is best used as a ‘focusing device’ for
highlighting the characteristic security problems and foreign policy dilemmas of
Small states and international security 9
the weaker actors in asymmetric power relationships (Mouritzen and Wivel
2005b; Thorhallsson and Wivel 2006; Rickli 2008; Wivel 2005).5
Accordingly, we define a small state as the weaker part in an asymmetric rela-
tionship, which is unable to change the nature or functioning of the relationship
on its own (cf. Mouritzen and Wivel 2005a: 4; Grøn and Wivel 2011; Steinmetz
and Wivel 2010). Following this definition, small states ‘are stuck with the
power configuration and its institutional expression, no matter what their specific
relation to it is’ (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005a: 4). For instance, if the United
States chose to remove its troops from the European continent or to leave
NATO, or if China chose to abandon the Security Cooperation Organization
(SCO), this would radically change these institutions and therefore the nature,
magnitude and intensity of the security challenges for all other member states.
But if Denmark left NATO or Tajikistan left the SCO, the consequences would
mainly be felt by these small states themselves. Therefore, such states cannot
credibly threaten to leave, alter or destroy institutional structures: one important
way in which their strategic challenges and options differ from those of great
powers. However, today, a small state typically acts simultaneously in a number
of different power configurations with different sets of actors, and therefore a
state may be weak (‘small’) in one relation, but simultaneously powerful (a
‘great power’) in another. For instance, Romania is a great power in its relations
with Moldova but a small state in its relations with Russia, and Denmark is a
small state in NATO but a great power in relation to the Baltic countries. Thus,
we argue that being a small state is tied to a specific spatio-temporal context and
that this context – rather than general characteristics of the state defined by indi-
cators such as its absolute population size or its military expenditure relative to
other states – is decisive for both the nature of challenges and opportunities, and
the small states’ answer to these challenges and opportunities.
This definition shifts the analytical focus from the power that states possess to
the power that they exercise. From this point of departure the authors of this
book use the concept of small states as a ‘focusing device’, directing us towards
interesting research puzzles stemming from ‘the experience of power disparity
and the manner of coping with it’ (Knudsen 1996: 5; cf. Gärtner, 1993: 303;
Rickli 2008; Thorhallsson and Wivel 2006; Wivel 2005: 395). Thus, ‘[s]mall-
ness is, in this conception, a comparative and not an absolute idea’ (Hanf and
Soetendorp 1998: 4). It brings to our attention a particular set of security prob-
lems and foreign policy dilemmas, allowing us – among other things – to distin-
guish between issue areas where the notion of small state is relevant, and issue
areas where it is not.

Contents of the book and chapter summaries


This shared approach to the definition of small states helps to ensure the
analytical coherence of the book. Further, the chapters share a common time
frame. All chapters focus on the present and on the recent past (since the end of
the Cold War), although authors include references to the more distant past
10 A. Wivel et al.
whenever it is relevant for understanding the challenges, opportunities and pol-
itics of the present. Finally and crucially, coherence and comparability within
each section of the book is ensured by a single set of questions that all chapter
authors were asked to consider, as set out below.

Small state security revisited: history, concepts, theory


The book is organized into three parts. The first part, ‘Small state security revis-
ited: history, concepts, theory’, provides the conceptual and analytical frame-
work for the volume. This introductory chapter and the next chapter (which
discusses the security of small states) establish the general framework and shared
premises of the book. The three following chapters discuss new functional
approaches going beyond traditional, military notions of security: economic
security, societal security and environmental security. The authors of these three
chapters have sought to answer the following questions: (1) How do you define
this particular dimension of security? (2) Why is it important for small states?
(3) How has the understanding and impact of this dimension of security changed
over time for small states? and (4) What lessons and apparently useful tools for
small states’ internal and external governance have emerged?
In Chapter 2, Alyson Bailes, Jean-Marc Rickli and Baldur Thorhallsson
explain the practical and theoretical developments that have led to wider and
more diverse security concepts entering the realm of public policy since the late
twentieth century. More fields of life, such as economic management, energy
supply or health, have been brought within the scope of security or have been
recognized as including security dimensions. Security processes are understood
to operate not only between states, but also at trans-state and sub-state levels and
they increasingly involve non-state actors – businesses, terrorists, media or the
ordinary citizen – as agents, as well as objects or victims. A wider variety of
international organizations than before have competence to address at least some
part of the security spectrum, and security governance within the state is attract-
ing new attention as the importance of managing it both efficiently and in accord
with human rights and democratic norms is realized. The subjective nature of
many perceptions in the security field has further been acknowledged by the
concept of ‘securitization’, which asks who first defines a given issue as a
security challenge, and by what means public assent is acquired to tackle it with
suitably robust methods.
As a starting-point for considering how this affects small states, the authors
propose a four-line table of potential threats and risks, covering, respectively:
traditional military problems, non-state human threats, economic and social vul-
nerabilities and accidental and natural hazards. While each small state will have
a specific mix of such concerns – both objectively, and in terms of what is ‘secu-
ritized’ – some general assumptions can be made, starting with the permanent
disadvantages of a small administration facing traditional military threats at
home or abroad. For the other three categories of risks, small states’ limited
resources expose them to deeper damage from a single event, but their small
Small states and international security 11
scale may also make it easier to comprehend and solve some problems. At
bottom, a small polity must choose between a passive and neutralist orientation
in international society, or an active one. The latter choice is becoming more
typical as non-military threats can rarely be solved by inaction, and the peace-
keeping vogue calls for small states to contribute to global goods even in the
military mode. The widening of agendas also means that a single large-state pro-
tector is unlikely to be able to resolve all its protégé’s problems, so that the role
of the institution as shelter is becoming more central to small state strategies at
least in regions (and there are several) where this option exists. Multilateral
organizations, whose governance is reasonably pluralistic, can even offer a kind
of ‘escape from smallness’ by giving small states a theoretically equal say in
framing collective security policies. Though big–small dynamics still work to
their disadvantage within the structure, some small players – such as the Nordic
countries – have managed to edge whole institutional communities towards
giving, at least, lip-service to norms – such as peaceful resolution of disputes
and concern for the global commons – that are bound to profit the small. The
question is how much a small state opting for institutional integration has to
‘pay’ in return for such benefits, and whether the bargain may even be more
subtly erosive of the weaker party’s identity than traditional power relationships
have been – on which more below.
Chapter 3, by Richard Griffiths, deals with the economic and financial aspects
of the strategic plight of small states: an issue on which the literature, as noted,
has swung from pessimism to optimism and back since the beginning of the
twentieth century. He argues that (relative) economic success or vulnerability
can only be addressed today in a context of open international trade and interde-
pendence: it is not just about basic provision for one’s citizens, but about the
ability to survive the shocks that a volatile global system brings. In this context,
above all, a numerical measure of ‘smallness’ can tell us little, since a rich,
developed state will have different challenges, and solutions at its disposal, from
a poor developing one with the same size of population. In fact, the various
indices developed to try to measure vulnerability regularly show a preponder-
ance of small states in the most vulnerable class, but also position some nations,
like Luxembourg, Switzerland and the Netherlands, in the least vulnerable
group. In particular small, developed states have often been judged favourably in
terms of adaptability and resilience. As in other fields of security, what seems to
matter is less the common weaknesses of the small and more, the effectiveness
of different strategies used to counter them. The high import needs and limited
export potential of small economies can, for instance, be cushioned from the
worst shocks within a structure of long-term economic commitments and
common rules such those provided by regional organizations. While fiscal levers
may be less effective, volatile commodity prices could be evened out by creating
a national stabilization fund. Other aspects of internal organization may, in the
end, be even more crucial: social cohesion, a ‘corporatist’ system based on com-
promise among economic partners, and general good governance to avoid – inter
alia – waste through corruption. Such factors may explain the intriguing finding
12 A. Wivel et al.
that small independent states often weather crises better than neighbouring sub-
state regions of similar size and wealth. They are solutions available, in prin-
ciple, to the poorest of small states as well as the richest.
Chapter 4, by Alyson Bailes, returns to the issue of today’s wide, multi-
functional definitions of security and asks how a small state with limited finan-
cial and human resources can cope with such a potentially confusing agenda. A
solution adopted by most Nordic states (under one name or another) is the
concept of ‘societal security’, which views a functioning, peaceful society in
itself – distinct from the level of the state, or the isolated individual – as a
security good and a resource for security building. In practice, in these countries,
societal security policies have become focused on the handling of non-warlike
emergencies and on the best ways to bring state and non-state actors, including
the private sector and citizens’ volunteer groups, together for the purpose. This
focus on the event, rather than on creeping and dispersed risk factors such as
social or environmental change, may in itself be disputed; but the societal
security approach does have some prima facie generic advantages for small
states. Among other things, the recognition and prioritization of a wide range of
risks – from terrorist action to natural disasters – gives room for compromise
among different schools of thought and their securitizations, including those
who reject a military focus. Non-state actors in small nations may also have
strengths, including an understanding of the globalized environment, that the
state authorities lack. Nevertheless the societal vision has its own weaknesses,
starting with the question of how to define ‘society’ itself – rarely monolithic in
modern conditions, and not necessarily coinciding with state boundaries. Bailes
concludes that the use of a specific name or concept is immaterial, but small
states in any region might improve their security strategies and implementing
structures by asking themselves the same questions as those raised by the ‘soci-
etal’ agenda.
Chapter 5, by Auður Ingólfsdóttir, addresses one of the ‘softest’, if not genu-
inely the newest, sections of the modern security spectrum: the concern for
environmental security, currently deepened by an awareness of the multiple, and
probably severe, impacts of climate change. She explains that environmental
security itself can be addressed either in a more traditional light, focusing on the
links between environment and conflict dynamics, or in a broader context of
‘human security’ – a concept introduced in Chapter 2 – where implications for
health, the economy and other personal circumstances would be considered as
equally important. As with other non-military hazards, local environmental risks
can sometimes be easier for a small polity to handle, especially when well-
resourced, and climate change is putting states of all sizes in jeopardy. A small
state is, however, much less likely to be able directly to mitigate the process,
given its low carbon emissions, and it may have little room to adapt if – like
some small island states – the next decades could see its whole territory sub-
merged. In fact, these latter states have grouped together to achieve international
recognition of their plight: offering a further example of how multilateral, insti-
tutionalized approaches to common security problems may allow small actors to
Small states and international security 13
influence emerging norms even among far more powerful actors. Taking the
Nordic states as a test-case, Ingólfsdóttir suggests that the requisites of success
in such a tactic are a record of international activism and expertise, of setting a
good example by domestic action and of the coincidence of negotiating positions
with real national interests. If this conclusion helps to underline the importance
of national security governance as addressed in Chapter 2, Ingólfsdóttir also
stresses that small states do not necessarily get the equation right: even the
Nordic countries have sometimes bartered environmental norms for short-term
economic advantages or sectoral interests.

Small state security in Europe


The second part, ‘Small State Security in Europe’, covers illustrative groups of
small states and micro-states in the wider setting of Europe, moving from some
examples that have been extensively analysed in a ‘small states’ framework to
others that have not yet been addressed in this perspective, or are under-studied
in general. Each chapter addresses these four questions: (1) Why is/are this par-
ticular state/these particular states relevant/interesting? (2) What are the most
important security challenges faced by the state/s in question and how do the
challenges relate to their ‘smallness’? (3) What are the most important character-
istics of this state’s/these states’ security policy? (4) Does the analysis yield
important insights and/or lead to important policy advice for other states?
A general observation regarding Europe’s smaller states is that, with a few
exceptions (notably Luxembourg), they tend to be spread around the peripheries
of the continent and are more often strategically exposed than sheltered. The fact
that they have, in modern times, a rather good record of survival – and in many
cases also of wealth and wellbeing – says something about the range of solutions
that this macro-region offers for giving them shelter, ranging from national part-
nerships to the world’s most sophisticated and strong multilateral security organ-
izations. This set of states thus provides the obvious first place to look for the
benefits, costs and other implications of post-modern solutions to relational
asymmetry that go beyond traditional bandwaggoning and/or subjection.
The five Nordic states that are introduced in Chapter 6, by Clive Archer, are a
diverse group in every way: from their size (Iceland’s population numbering
one-third of a million and Sweden’s population approaching ten million) to their
formal strategic orientation (three being members of NATO and two being milit-
arily non-allied). The chapter rightly stresses these variations, as they make even
more interesting the question: Why has the Nordic region remained so stable
since 1945 while producing such a positive ‘surplus’ of high-minded inter-
national activism? The fact that the countries have no tensions, or damaging
competition, among themselves may be just as fundamental a part of the answer
as the de facto US strategic umbrella that, for now, remains in place over the
whole sub-region. Given these two basic features, the fact that the Nordics have
evaded a local defence pact among themselves and relied rather on NATO/EU
coverage to manage their asymmetrical position vis-à-vis Russia has actually
14 A. Wivel et al.
served the interests of stability and global freedom of action for all concerned in
the North. For dealing with modern, trans-frontier security problems, however,
and for ensuring that the norms promoted by such small players do in fact impact
on world governance, the non-legalistic and practical web of intra-Nordic
security cooperation is also very important – and is now growing in scope and
significance.
The Baltic States provide both parallels and contrasts with their Nordic neigh-
bours, and both aspects are well brought out in Chapter 7, by Mindaugas Jurky-
nas. Not only are Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania closer to Russia and thus
exposed to one of Europe’s most blatant strategic asymmetries, but, having been
more than once engulfed by Russian/Soviet power, their very identity includes
an apparently indelible anti-Russian streak. Consequently, ‘hard’ security con-
cerns have pushed them into a shared strategy of outright, maximal integration
with both the EU and NATO, combined with efforts to earn protection from the
US. They have also profited from several tiers of neighbourhood cooperation,
including many kinds of Nordic help, short of actual guarantees. Their particular
paradox is that while playing the post-modern integration game to the hilt, they
have remained stubbornly modern in the zero-sum aspects of their strategic
outlook. Even these states’ newer, non-military security challenges are still
largely seen through a Russia-related (energy, cyber-safety) or an identity-related
(migration, minorities) lens. Tellingly, also, in all three nations the level of con-
sensus experienced and the bureaucratic solutions used for ‘hard’ and ‘soft’
security issues, respectively, are quite different.
With the Western Balkan states covered in Chapter 8, by Višnja Samardžija
and Senada Šelo Šabić, even more dramatic security challenges come into the
picture. In the last two decades this region has witnessed bloody conflict among
states and entities qualifying as ‘small’, and their deconstruction into even
smaller entities (most recently, Kosovo and Montenegro). Today, peace is meas-
urably being consolidated – with the help of still-present international missions
– but serious challenges remain in non-military security, democracy, and the
general quality of governance. NATO and EU integration comes into play here,
not only as a way of building immunity against mutual and external attack, but
also as a force for transforming identity through conditional reforms receiving
targeted assistance. Cooperation and synergy among the region’s actors and their
medium-sized neighbours are also promoted in the process. The over-arching
question about the success of this strategy is the credibility of the ‘carrot’ of EU/
NATO membership if timetables become too extended. As our authors point out,
however, Croatia’s recent successful entry into the EU, and its presence with
Albania in NATO, have provided both encouragement to the others and a prac-
tical local model. Manifold as these nations’ problems may be, their smallness at
this point in history is perhaps more helpful than not: providing flexibility for
development, and the hope of – eventually – easy assimilation into the conti-
nent’s powerful institutions.
The cases of Moldova and Georgia, placed in the Western fringe of the
former Soviet Union, can make the Western Balkans’ position look almost
Small states and international security 15
fortunate. Both have seen parts of their territory fall under the de facto control of
Moscow and its friends; in Georgia’s case after an open, armed conflict in 2008.
Both are prone to transnational ills that damage both themselves and their neigh-
bours, and both have, at best, imperfect democracies and security systems. For
these two states, however, smallness as such, and the preservation of identity are
arguably not the key issues. Facing a strategic situation where the West cannot
do much to help them and may even be half-hearted over their inclusion, they
need to make fundamental national choices about what kind of shelter they can
realistically seek and what price they will pay for it. Even more than the former
Yugoslav states, they might need fundamental changes in their politics and
world outlook to be able both to achieve and accept organized Europe’s post-
modern solutions. For the present, at least, there are more signs of possible
acceptance of this bargain in Moldova’s cautious, defensive, drive towards the
EU than in Georgia’s more assertive tactics.
Micro-states are a sub-set of the world’s smallest states that share some basic
challenges and that have often found idiosyncratic solutions. Applying a cri-
terion of representation at the UN plus a population below one million, Archie
Simpson identifies 44 such states in the world and ten in Europe. Ranging from
Iceland to Montenegro and from Luxembourg to Malta by way of the Holy See,
the latter are very diverse in location, wealth and security predicaments. Most do
not maintain armed forces and are protected by a large neighbour, plus – in two
cases – NATO. Cyprus suffers, however, from a tense internal division and hosts
a UN peacekeeping mission. Micro-state economies have even more funda-
mental limitations, and in Europe have most often solved them by some combi-
nation of dependence on neighbours, sharing of currencies (now often the euro),
and joining of collective institutions like the EU. Several have also explored
profitable branches that are not size-dependent, such as casinos, banking services
and tax havens. As discussed further in the third part of this book, this is a post-
modern solution par excellence but also one that exposes small communities to
transnational crime, abuse, and serious reputational risk. Simpson correctly
stresses, therefore, the importance of good governance and points out that even
among European states in this class, it is not automatically forthcoming.

Comparative insights: beyond Europe


The third part, ‘Comparative Insights’, expands the book’s purview and seeks to
reveal parallels and contrasts by applying a similar analytical approach to three
regions outside Europe that contain a significant number of small states. The
regions are chosen because of their variety and because they have well-
developed traditions of scholarship on security, or small states, or both. Here, the
authors addressed the following key questions: (1) Why is this region and its
smaller states relevant/interesting? (2) What are the most important security
challenges faced by the state/s in question and how do the challenges relate to
its/their ‘smallness’? (3) What are the most important characteristics of this
state’s/these states’ security policy/policies? (4) Does the analysis yield
16 A. Wivel et al.
important insights and/or lead to important policy advice for other states? The
potential of regional integration in each relevant region is taken into account;
while the final chapter addresses some generic issues about small polities world-
wide, and the light they shed on an international system in rapid evolution.
In Chapter 11, by Ian Taylor, the first case-study takes Botswana as an
example of a small developmental state in Africa and focuses on the prima facie
riddle of its success. Together with a few others in its region, such as Mauritius,
it has attained soaring growth rates only exceeded by the ‘small tigers’ of Asia.
To understand the reasons for this growth, it is necessary to explore the typical
economic security challenges of a poorer, ex-colonial state; and what Botswana
seems to show is that the world community’s orthodox notions of promoting
development by reducing state power may be wrong-headed. Admittedly well
placed in other dimensions of security, Botswana has succeeded through its
efforts to keep control of its own strategic resources (diamonds) and to deploy
the proceeds through a strong government and a strong, competent bureaucracy
for interventionist development planning. In the process, the country has avoided
many of the pitfalls indicated by the analysis of small state vulnerabilities (cf.
Chapter 5). Botswana’s development trajectory has not been unproblematic: the
country still has immense levels of inequality and poverty. However, elements
within Botswana’s post-independence history could be useful for other poorer
small states to take on board, not just in Botswana’s African neighbourhood, but
elsewhere as well.
In Chapter 12, Alan Chong begins by analysing general traditions of state-
hood in Asia and shows that, historically, merit and authority depended on
factors quite unrelated to size. The present self-conceptions and threat percep-
tions of Asian small states reflect the way these longer traditions have been over-
laid by colonial influences – including the creation of new ethnic mixes as well
as boundaries – and the Manichaean culture of the Cold War. The contrasting
case-studies of Singapore and Sri Lanka both show how, as a result, external
worries driven by asymmetrical relationships are compounded by fears of
internal dissent, in what the author calls an ‘intermestic’ mix. For Sri Lanka, the
overriding internal issue is that of the conflict between the Sinhalese and the
Tamils, which not only prompted the recent bloody civil war, but has since
driven government attempts to balance with other large actors, such as China,
against the presumptively pro-Tamil Indian power. Singapore, for its part, had a
long struggle even to establish its permanent statehood vis-à-vis Malaysia and to
secure its territory against the even larger neighbour, Indonesia. Its rulers have
sought to suppress risks from internal ethnic diversity by a policy of strong gov-
ernment, underpinned by would-be distinct Singaporean values, and a corporatist
approach to working with non-state sectors. The price is a certain ‘strategic para-
noia’ that demands constant vigilance and effort – like pedalling to stay on a
bicycle. Externally, Singapore’s initial Cold War dependence on the US has
shifted towards an effort for multi-polar balance that includes acceptable forms
of engagement with China. Singaporean concerns about conflict risks and non-
military security are much eased by belonging to ASEAN, as well as to other
Small states and international security 17
competent multilateral groups. Chong concludes that intermestic issues of
identity-forming, including the question of who belongs as a citizen or ‘who
goes and who stays’, are typical of today’s security agendas and attempted solu-
tions by the region’s small states. The external framework in which such states
operate, however, starts with their sometimes ‘accidental construction’ during
the colonial period and remains strongly shaped and limited by the greater
powers.
Chapter 13, by Timothy Shaw, deals with the small island states of the Carib-
bean region: a collection of former (and some still present) colonies that have
evaded the world’s largest wars but are among those most heavily exposed to
non-military security hazards. His analysis dwells on, and richly illustrates, the
post-modern trends for which this region provides a prime laboratory. Regional
and trans-regional networking, the dynamics of human crime and violence, the
threat of climate change and the best-attuned governance responses, based on
transnational networking and regulation – all operate just as much, and are
equally decisive for good or bad security at the non-state as well as the tradi-
tional state level. Diasporas and ‘transnational families’, to give just one
example, provide crucial flows of remittances but also ‘export’ Caribbean-style
violence to other regions and facilitate the multi-billion dollar drugs trade. The
concept of ‘citizen security’, an interesting counterpoint to the Nordic ‘societal
security’ introduced in Chapter 4, has grown up to define the positive solutions
for which local and global, state and non-state actors can and should collaborate.
In terms of wealth, development and resilience, the Caribbean region (however
defined) is very diverse and will no doubt remain so. Clearly, for all its small
states, transnational threat factors and transnational solutions will determine
future fortunes as much as, and often more than, any traditional security
calculus.
In Chapter 14, Godfrey Baldacchino reverts to the generic theme of small ter-
ritories worldwide that are endowed with statehood while lacking some or all of
its traditional power characteristics. These face the starkest version of asym-
metry, both in their regional and global relations; yet, as the author shows with
rich examples drawn from all non-European regions, it is not impossible for
David to survive the contest with Goliath. The variety and intensity of their
experience is best understood if the nature of statehood can be re-framed in
Foucault’s terms as ‘the smart deployment of actual and potentially available
capacities to secure desirable fiscal, human, material, legal or geopolitical
resources’. In an interconnected world, a small actor can sometimes extend a
long way by such means, and can explore many niches that only make sense in
terms of relations with larger counterparts such as ‘offshore’ services. However,
intrinsic handicaps of smallness include the existential impact of quite small
natural, economic and other events; the lack of a hinterland and of diversity,
whereby a setback in one key sector may impose a total switch of profile or the
large-scale export of population; and the ease of ‘capture’ by commercial, crimi-
nal or other external interests. Baldacchino concludes that any really small polity
will go through a crisis sometime, the only question being when and of what
18 A. Wivel et al.
kind. Yet most such states, even when recently created, do survive; and the ‘cre-
ative political economy’ used by those who manage to prosper could offer
lessons even to larger players on how to cope with the globalized age. If this
finding echoes Griffiths’ remarks on small states’ economic adaptability, Bald-
acchino also recalls Archer’s chapter by ending with a case of ‘norm entrepre-
neurship’ at the UN, where European and non-European small states wielded
‘soft power’ together.

The lessons
As stressed above, the study of small states as we seek to use it is not a reduc-
tionist theory. It may be approached through and combined with any of the
dominant theories of International Relations (IR), from realism through to social
constructivism and beyond. It is at its best, however, when it is used to test such
theories through the exploration of outlying cases, and to challenge any over-
monolithic view of either statehood or the international system generally.
Preparing this volume has been an exercise both in enriching and in challeng-
ing the ‘small state’ concept itself. First and most obviously, when talking about
small states and security, the book’s different sections show the complex nature
of – and the need for a critical approach to – both terms involved. Small states
themselves are just as diverse as any other constructed category in international
society. They overlap variously with other categories, such as developing and
developed; ‘weak states’ (in the twenty-first century sense); and well-governed
states – modern and post-modern. Where they stand along these three axes – plus
the axis of economic vulnerability, as discussed in Griffiths’ chapter – provides
perhaps the best starting-point for assessing the character and manageability of
their security challenges.
Merely being small, or even very small, if a state enjoys external and internal
peace and wise governance, may be a factor that reduces rather than multiplies
security headaches. It eliminates the need to make a pretence of self-sufficient
defence or even to create military forces at all. It dampens expectations of a
significant outgoing contribution to global goods like peacekeeping and, rather,
creates a supposition of importing help in natural and accidental emergencies.
Such a state is arguably less ‘state-like’ than others in traditional IR terms, and
the micro-states covered in Chapter 10 are the most extreme and clear examples.
Add a modicum of flexibility and inventiveness to the mix, however, and small
actors may emerge – as shown by examples in Chapter 14 – as remarkably well-
attuned to the rules of survival both in today’s and tomorrow’s increasingly glo-
balized world.
When things go wrong in security terms, then like Tolstoy’s unhappy fam-
ilies, there are almost as many variants of trouble as there are small states them-
selves. Parts II and III of this book bear out the contention in Part I that newer,
broader definitions of security, including non-state threats and economic and
functional dimensions, can better capture the full spectrum of small state chal-
lenges than the post-World War II realist discourse, with its purely military and
Small states and international security 19
territorial focus. To be sure, geopolitical location continues to be of central
importance to small state security, but the case-studies in this volume illustrate
how many small states inside and outside Europe have a considerable action
space when deciding how to confront the challenges spurred by location and
power politics. Accordingly, within the four-way framework proposed in
Chapter 2, the small states covered in the geographical chapters emerge with
very diverse combinations of security priorities. Only a minority of those dis-
cussed, such as the Western Balkan states and Sri Lanka, have the consequences
of recent internal armed conflict near the top of their agendas, and this is in line
with the slowly decreasing frequency of such conflicts (or at least ‘major’ ones)
worldwide.6 A larger number, from the Baltic States through to Singapore, are
coping with prominent or residual threats from bigger neighbours of dubious
intent. Just about all face economic challenges that call for constant effort and
inventiveness to stay afloat, whether at a higher or lower level of wealth and
development. All, to some degree, are open to issues of security of supply, trans-
national human challenges like crime, and natural ones like pollution and climate
change, and various kinds of civil emergencies. A final variant in the mix is the
perception, whether justified or not, of ‘enemies within’, which may be triggered
either by long-standing ethnic divisions, or by concern over being swamped and
culturally diluted by immigration.
To be of any use, this book’s analysis cannot stop at documenting such issues
but needs to consider how small states can best grapple with them. It is here that
the ‘relational’ approach to small state identity, as proposed earlier in this intro-
ductory chapter, really proves its worth. Any small state in a region populated
mainly by states of similar and medium size (such as Europe, the Caribbean or
the Pacific) has different options from one whose only external relations – both
with potential problem states and protectors – are severely asymmetrical.
Further, both similarity and asymmetry vis-à-vis neighbours can make their mark
on national predicaments at several different levels of absolute size. The
common factors in the most problematic cases are quintessentially relational,
and often include subjective or constructed elements: lack of room for man-
oeuvre, de facto compromised sovereignty, but also a sense of smallness as help-
lessness and victimhood that, at worst, may lead the small actor itself into bad
choices. Hard though some may find it to accept, Chapter 9, on Georgia and
Moldova, correctly notes Georgia’s own contribution to the circumstances that
triggered war with Russia in 2008. Critical observers might also see instances of
counter-productive, provocative behaviour in the recent story of the Baltic
States. Few could claim that all the small Western Balkan states, or Sri Lanka,
are free of all responsibility for their own sufferings.
This only takes us as far, however, as concluding that small states in asym-
metric situations may or may not find improved solutions by means that include
their own wisdom and restraint. To explain more fully the differences reflected
in this volume’s chapters, another factor should be brought into the picture: the
presence, absence and relative effectiveness of multilateral regional or sub-
regional organizations. Chapter 2 proposes the hypothesis that small states
20 A. Wivel et al.
should have a better chance of moderating both their hard and soft security prob-
lems if one or more functional groupings of this kind are present. Such a thesis
is in line with recent directions in small state studies that explore the generic
relevance of institutions as ‘shelters’– capable of supplementing or even sup-
planting the more traditional state–protector relationship (e.g. Bailes and Thorh-
allsson 2013). How far do the case-studies in Parts II and III of this volume bear
this theory out?
The European cases covered in Part II actually fit it well. The Nordic and
Baltic nations are all living with an asymmetric, historically threatening and still
ambiguous neighbour, namely Russia. All have, however, gained high or very
high levels of wellbeing and an almost complete immunity (by now) from
military or political domination, with no crushing societal or economic costs in
terms of their own militarization. First and foremost, this is thanks to their region
being covered for hard security purposes by NATO (and by the US through
NATO), and for economic and functional security purposes by the EU. However,
the way that the two sets of states have worked together among themselves has
also been an important and arguably essential part of the mix. By establishing
strong and ostensibly de-securitized, inter-Nordic ties during the Cold War, the
Nordic states have built a kind of security community that surmounts persistent
divisions in institutional status and takes aggression or damaging competition
among themselves out of the equation. More recently, overt Nordic security and
defence cooperation has begun to address sub-regional challenges (including
Arctic ones) in an efficient mode of subsidiarity and has enhanced relative
Nordic standing in the European policy game. The Baltic States would not have
gained EU and NATO entry so fast, nor have been able to exploit these institu-
tions’ cover so well, had they not teamed up for local security purposes and also
drawn in Nordic advice and aid at crucial stages. These countries have added to
their security by enshrining their relations with Russia in regional multilateral
frameworks – the Barents Euro-Arctic Council and the Council for Baltic Sea
States – that allow an inclusive web of linkages to be established between all
neighbouring states and their societies.
The prospects of the Western Balkan states depend most obviously on their
integration into NATO and the EU, the only extant frameworks powerful enough
to overcome these states’ recent mutual enmity and still-existing internal ethnic
divisions. Sub-regional processes in this part of Europe were initially – and
understandably in post-war conditions – designed from outside.7 However, if one
goes through the motions long enough, even in imposed behaviours, they may
start to have a real transformative effect. Chapter 8 interestingly suggests that
not only have key local actors understood the need to ‘show willing’ in their
mutual relations for pragmatic purposes of accession strategy (hence the recent
Serbia-Kosovo agreement), but that cross-border and wider transnational flows
in the region are beginning to take positive effect both in concrete economic and
in attitudinal terms.
The situation of Moldova and Georgia makes an instructive contrast. Their
predicament can be put down first and foremost to ‘location, location, location’,
Small states and international security 21
with Moldova being on the borderline of the EU’s and NATO’s present strategic
reach and Georgia fatally beyond it. The Russia that has grudgingly accepted the
Baltic States’ full independence and Western integration is the same nation that
has managed to prise away parts of Moldovan and Georgian territory, and to
restrict (in practice) these states’ strategic options. The presence or absence of
Western – including US – ability and will to challenge Russia’s local dominance
is the most obvious variable in the two cases: but it is not the only one. The com-
plete failure of the independent states emerging from the Western part of the
former Soviet Union to create sub-regional groupings with real clout and mutual
loyalty8 is also important, especially when contrasted with Nordic, Baltic or non-
European (to be covered shortly) examples. It bears out the relativistic slant of
the relational hypothesis by showing that a small state may be effectively alone
in handling a dominant neighbour, even when it has other neighbours of a similar
smallness. Finally, and also to be discussed further in Chapter 9, Moldova’s and
Georgia’s own weaknesses of governance and security management have aggra-
vated their exposure to hostile interference, just as they have impeded their pro-
gress towards Western integrated standards.
It may be tempting to dismiss this analysis as Euro-centric. In fact, the chapters
in Part III suggest that factoring in the element of regional and sub-regional organ-
ization does have a wider explanatory value, so long as variations in the local
concept of statehood – and hence of inter-state relations – are taken into account.
In Southeast Asia, for example, older traditions separate the strength and influence
of states from their objective size, while modern approaches to multilateral cooper-
ation eschew the internally intrusive imposition of standards that is central to EU-
style integration. Yet the availability of the sub-regional ASEAN network to a
small actor like Singapore, and larger frames like the ASEAN Regional Forum
(ARF), where balancing tactics can be essayed towards China, has played a real
part in minimizing and containing physical conflicts in the neighbourhood and in
creating conditions for non-zero-sum regional growth. Chapter 13, on the Carib-
bean, explores in detail how the transnational and post-modern nature of most
security challenges for that cluster of small states has drawn solutions based on
regional and global network-building in its wake. This chapter, together with
Chapter 14, rightly reminds us that just as the new security challenges are often of
non-state origin, so the equivalent of regional institution-building in the business,
NGO and civil society spheres can also be an important part of solutions – and one
where notions of small state weakness under realist analysis become less and less
relevant. To the extent that such approaches succeed, they reduce the need and
scope for outside powers’ interference and divide-and-rule attempts, and thus rein-
force the need to rethink traditional realist logic if we are to understand the security
challenges and opportunities of small states.
What seems to need more study, and is just starting to be more deeply probed
in Europe, is the price that small states must pay for the multiple security bene-
fits of institutionalization. Aside from direct expenses and the impact of intrusive
standardization, serious burdens may be involved in shouldering the security
agendas of other, larger and/or more exposed integration partners, and in
22 A. Wivel et al.
contributing to collective institutional interventions outside the home area. The
normative hazard of having to espouse partners’ self-interested and possibly
aggressive policies is not wholly irrelevant here, though the risks are probably
less than when bandwaggoning with a single large protector, who may make
more arbitrary and extreme choices than an institution working by consensus.
Further, the intrusive regulatory impact of the more deep-reaching multilateral
structures may start to undermine national identity itself, in a way that traditional
empires often markedly failed to do. It would be good to see more work done on
investigating such benefit–cost equations of regionalization in non-European
cases, including Eurasian examples like the Russian-led groupings and the
Shanghai Cooperation Organization. Other areas not covered in this book, but
where interesting variations might be discovered, are the sub-regions of Africa,
Central America, and the cluster of small Arab states in the Gulf.
This discussion may appropriately end where Chapter 2 also ends: by noting the
importance of internal security governance. No state, however small, is entirely
without free will in this matter. The smallest states can be just as divided, corrupt,
incoherent and inconsistent in forming and executing security strategies as any
large state; they may even fall more readily into such traps when they discount the
need for formal structures. Yet good internal governance, including intra-
governmental and cross-sectoral coordination and a minimum of democratic
control, makes a real difference to success in any environment and under any ana-
lytical framework. Realistically, this implies maximizing national strength and
leaving no cracks for hostile forces to exploit (a point interestingly explored in
Chapter 12). In a more post-modern environment, where institutional shelters are
available, demonstrating good governance and ‘interoperable’ practices in this as
well as other spheres can make all the difference in the feasibility and speed of
integration, while at the same creating new challenges in the form of ‘goodwill
competition’ among small states vying for influence over institutional inclusion
and the attention of the great powers (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005b: 34–36).
As the Chapter 4, on ‘societal’ security will stress, this reasoning does not
imply that any single governance model or terminology – least of all a Euro-
centric one – should be imposed on all small states. It does mean that all of them
would do well to ask questions about their internal as well as external practices,
in the light of the analysis and empirical case-studies offered by this book.

Notes
1 ‘Should small states be categorized along geographic, demographic or economic lines,
or do institutions, resources, and power hold the key?’ ask Smith et al. in a discussion
of small states (Smith et al. 2005). Students of International Relations are unlikely to
deliver a uniform answer to this question, or even to agree on whether the question is
correctly posed for an understanding of the nature and challenges of small states.
2 Important contributions to the realist perspective on international relations include, for
example, Morgenthau (1948), Waltz (1979) and more recently Mearsheimer (2001).
For discussions on the contemporary state of realism, see Booth (2011) and Lobell et
al. (2009).
Small states and international security 23
3 ‘Micro-states’ in Europe are commonly defined to include Andorra, Liechtenstein,
Monaco, San Marino and the Vatican City. See Chapter 10 in this volume.
4 Following Väyrynen, Archer and Nugent suggest that we combine objective factors
such as ‘size of diplomatic corps’ and ‘size of GDP’ with subjective factors such as
‘foreign governments’ ’ view of a state’s size and capability’ and ‘domestic govern-
ments’ ’ view of its own state’s size and capability’ (Archer and Nugent 2002: 2–3).
5 See also the discussions by Knudsen (1996: 5) and Gärtner (1993: 303), which pre-
ceded the current development of the small state concept but introduced a similar crit-
ical approach to the power possession definition.
6 According to SIPRI (the Stockholm International Peace Research Institute), state-to-
state conflicts in 2002–2011 averaged 33 per year compared with 53 in 1992. Cases of
‘one-sided violence’ halved in 2002–2011, while non-state conflicts initially halved
during that period but then returned to 38 per year (Themnér and Wallensteen 2013:
52–57).
7 While the Western Balkans were covered by an earlier and larger Central European
Initiative, the first sub-region-specific framework – the Southeast European Coopera-
tion Initiative – was devised in 1996 under the guidance of the then Senior Director for
Eastern Europe in the United States National Security Council, Richard Schifter. Its
modern successor, the Regional Cooperation Council (RCC), is covered in Chapter 8
of this volume.
8 The problem has two levels. First, the states of the region are split as to their basic
strategic orientation: towards cooperation with Russia (Belarus, Armenia), or
towards the West and Turkey (Moldova, Georgia, Azerbaijan), with Ukraine often
oscillating in between. Second, both the GUAM (Georgia, Ukraine, Azerbaijan,
Moldova Organization for Democracy and Economic Development) grouping aimed
at balancing Russia, and the Russian-led Collective Security Treaty Organization
(CSTO), have severe institutional weaknesses including a failure to overcome the
basic bilateral dynamic in their respective members’ relations with Moscow (Bailes
et al. 2007).

Bibliography
Amstrup, N. (1976) ‘The Perennial Problem of Small States: A Survey of Research
Efforts’, Cooperation and Conflict, 11(3): 163–182.
Anckar, D. (2004) ‘Regime Choices in Microstates: The Cultural Constraint’, Common-
wealth and Comparative Politics, 42(2): 206–223.
Antola, E and Lehtimäki, M. (2001) Small States in the EU, Turku: Jean Monnet Centre
of Excellence.
Archer, C. and Nugent, N. (2002) ‘Introduction: Small States and the European Union’,
Current Politics and Economics of Europe, 11(1): 1–10.
Bailes, A.J.K., Baranovsky, V. and Dunay, P. (2007) ‘Regional security cooperation in
the former Soviet area’, in SIPRI Yearbook 2007: Armaments, Disarmament and Inter-
national Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bailes, A.J.K. and Thorhallsson, B. (2013) ‘Instrumentalizing the European Union in
Small State Strategies’, Journal of European Integration, 35(2): 99–115.
Booth, K. (ed.) (2011) Realism and World Politics, London: Routledge.
Browning, C. (2006) ‘Small, Smart and Salient? Rethinking Identity in the Small States
Literature’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 19(4): 669–684.
Christmas-Møller, W. (1983) ‘Some Thoughts on the Scientific Applicability of the Small
State Concept: A Research History and a Discussion’ in Otmar Höll (ed.) Small States
in Europe and Dependence, Vienna: Wilhelm Braumüller, pp. 35–53.
24 A. Wivel et al.
Fox, A. Baker (2006 [1959]) ‘The Power of Small States: Diplomacy in World War II’,
in Ingebritsen, C., Neumann, I., Gstöhl, S. and Beyer, J. (eds) Small States in Inter-
national Relations, Seattle: University of Washington Press, pp. 39–54.
Gärtner, H. (1993) ‘Small States and Security Integration’, Coexistence, 30: 303–312.
Grøn, C. and Wivel, A. ‘Maximizing Influence in the European Union after the Lisbon
Treaty: From Small State Policy to Smart State Strategy’, Journal of European Inte-
gration, 33(5): 523–539.
Hanf, K. and Soetendorp, B. (1998) ‘Small States and the Europeanisation of Public
Policy’, in Hanf, K. and Soetendorp, B. (eds) Adapting to European Integration: Small
States and the European Union, London and New York: Longman.
Heron, T. (2008) ‘Small States and the Politics of Multilateral Trade Liberalization’, The
Round Table, 97: 243–257.
Hey, J.A.K. (2003) ‘Introducing Small State Foreign Policy’, in Hey, J.A.K. (ed.) Small
States in World Politics, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner, pp. 1–11.
Jervis, R. (1978) ‘Cooperation under the Security Dilemma’, World Politics, 30(2):
172–173.
Kennedy, P. (1987) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and
Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000, New York: Random House.
Knudsen, O.F. (1996) ‘Analysing Small-State Security: The Role of External Factors’, in
Bauwens, W., Clesse, A. and Knudsen, O.F. (eds) Small States and the Security Chal-
lenge in the New Europe, London: Brassey’s, pp. 3–20.
Knudsen, O.F. (2002) ‘Small States, Latent and Extant: Towards a General Perspective’,
Journal of International Relations and Development, 5(2): 182–198.
Lobell, S., Ripsman, N.M. and Taliaferro, J.W. (2009) Neoclassical Realism, The State,
and Foreign Policy, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mearsheimer, J. (2001) The Tragedy of Great Power Politics, New York: W.W. Norton
& Company.
Mohamed, A.N. (2002) The Diplomacy of Micro-states, Discussion Paper in Diplomacy
78, The Hague: Netherlands Institute of International Relations.
Morgenthau, H. (1948) Politics among Nations, New York: Knopf.
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (eds) (2005a) ‘Introduction’, in Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A.
(eds) The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration, London: Routledge, pp. 1–11.
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (eds) (2005b) The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration.
London: Routledge, pp. 15–42.
Neumann, I.B. and Gstöhl, S. (2006) ‘Introduction: Lilliputians in Gulliver’s World?’, in
Ingebritsen, C., Neumann, I., Gstöhl, S. and Beyer, J. (eds) Small States in Inter-
national Relations, Seattle: University of Washington Press, pp. 3–36.
Panke, D. (2010) Small States in the European Union, Aldershot: Ashgate.
Plischke, E. (1977) Microstates in World Affairs, Washington, DC: American Enterprise
Institute for Public Policy Research.
Rickli, J.-M. (2008) ‘European Small States’ Military Policies after the Cold War: From
Territorial to Niche Strategies’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 21(3):
307–325.
Rothstein, R. (1968) Alliances and Small Powers, New York: Columbia University Press.
Schweller, R.L. (1998) Deadly Imbalances, New York: Columbia University Press.
Smith, N., Pace, M. and Lee, D. (2005) ‘Size Matters: Small States and International
Studies’, International Studies Perspectives, 6(3): 395–397.
Steinmetz, R. and Wivel, A. (2010) ‘Introduction’, in Steinmetz, R. and Wivel, A. (eds)
Small States in Europe: Challenges and Opportunities. Aldershot: Ashgate, pp. 1–14.
Small states and international security 25
Themnér, L. and Wallensteen, P. (2013) ‘Pattern of Organized Violence, 2002–11’, in
SIPRI Yearbook 2013: Armaments, Disarmament and International Security, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Thorhallsson, B. and Wivel, A. (2006) ‘Small States in the European Union: What Do
We Know and What Would We Like to Know’, Cambridge Review of International
Affairs, 19(4): 651–668.
Thucydides (1972 [1954]) History of the Peloponnesian War, London: Penguin Books.
Toje, A. (2010) The European Union as a Small Power, Hounslow: PalgraveMacmillan.
Väyrynen, R. (1971) ‘On the Definition and Measurement of Small Power Status’, Coop-
eration and Conflict, 6(1): 91–102.
Vital, D. (1967) The Inequality of States: A Study of the Small Power in International
Relations, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Waltz, K.N. (1979) Theory of International Politics, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Warrington, E. (1998) ‘Introduction: Gulliver and Lilliput in a New World Order: The
Impact of External Relations on the Domestic Policies and Institutions of Micro-states’,
Public Administration and Development, 18: 101–105.
Wivel, A. (2005) ‘The Security Challenge of Small EU Member States: Interests, Identity
and the Development of the EU as a Security Actor’, Journal of Common Market
Studies, 43(2): 393–412.
Wohlforth, W.C. (1999) ‘The Stability of a Unipolar World’, International Security,
24(1): 5–41.
2 Small states, survival and strategy
Alyson J.K. Bailes, Jean-Marc Rickli and
Baldur Thorhallsson

Introduction and aims


The study of small states has implied, from its earliest days, a concern with their
problems of survival. By definition, a small state – whether measured by abso-
lute or relative size – has limited assets, and probably limited competences, of
the kind that have traditionally brought power and influence in the international
system. At the same time, it may well have something that bigger states want:
natural resources, strategic location, or its allegiance, voice, and vote on the
international scene. A major focus of small state studies to date has been to
explore the predicament created by this combination of factors, and to discuss
how the small state can best hope to protect its territorial integrity, political
sovereignty, national identity and freedom of action. What can this book, and
this chapter, hope to add?
One answer is that definitions of security change over time, so that the ques-
tions previously addressed under this aspect of small state studies may now look
incomplete or wrongly balanced. The earliest literature was influenced by a
realist and/or geopolitical model that interpreted international relations as a self-
interested, zero-sum, ultimately anarchic competition among states. In such a
tough game, any smaller player was by definition endangered: facing not only
physical invasion and incorporation, but also the risk of political blackmail and
reduction to ‘satellite’ status (Keohane 1969; Vital 1967; Handel 1981). Small
states could in practice only protect themselves by seeking voluntary or semi-
voluntary ‘shelter’ from a larger state (also described as ‘bandwaggoning’), or
joining other more modest actors in ‘balancing’ the source of threat (Walt 1987;
Scheuerman 2009). Later, as liberal internationalist, institutionalist and social
constructivist perspectives were added,1 it became relevant to ask how far inter-
national organizations – military alliances and others, at the global and regional
level – might serve similar purposes for a small state, and what different cost-
benefit balances they would entail (Wivel 2005; Bailes and Thorhallsson 2012).
More recently, scholars have also addressed small state vulnerability and
the possible solutions in the field of economics, including international finance
and trade (Katzenstein 1984, 1985; Briguglio et al. 2006). This approach
gained an obvious boost with the global crash of autumn 2008, when small
Small states, survival and strategy 27
states were among those suffering most, and the wider strategic impact of eco-
nomic crisis was patent (Thorhallsson and Kirby 2012; Tranoy 2011). Finally,
studies on small states outside Europe, notably in the Caribbean and Pacific,
have recognized from the start a distinctive and less traditional security spec-
trum: vulnerability on the one hand to non-military violence and subversion –
internal insurrection, externally-driven coups, crime, and ‘capture’ by
drug-smuggling or other corrupt interests; and, on the other hand, to environ-
mental hazards such as water shortage, pollution, and natural disasters (e.g.
Cooper and Shaw 2009).
Combining all these aspects of security would produce quite a comprehen-
sive spectrum, even by today’s standards. The problem is that few, if any,
small state studies have yet integrated the military/strategic, economic and
other non-military dimensions into a comprehensive and balanced security
agenda, allowing the full profile of a nation’s challenges to be drawn and cor-
rectly related to its smallness. Without such a conspectus, statements cannot
safely be made about the range of solutions currently available for small
states, let alone about their relative merits. Moreover, the security agenda has
tended to be applied in a fragmented way to states in different regions of the
world. Mainstream literature on Northern-hemisphere small states has
highighted politico-military threats and economic vulnerabilities, while the
‘softer’ dimensions of security have been explored mainly for developing
regions. The modern discipline of (intra-state) conflict studies, meanwhile, has
yet to develop a distinct ‘small state’ branch, as its concepts of state ‘weak-
ness’ and ‘failure’ are not directly tied to size.2
Only by applying the whole range of potential security questions systemat-
ically to small states in different locations can it be possible to map the objective
variations in their strategic plights. Only by recognizing this diversity, in turn,
can differences in national security visions, priorities and the choice of remedies
be understood and respected. Prescriptions based on the Euro-Atlantic literature
risk seeming West-centric in other eyes, and doing less to help precisely those
with the most intractable problems. Finally, for small states of all kinds, internal
process in the security field – strategy-forming and decision-making systems,
inter-agency and public/private coordination impact of political culture and
public opinion – remains under-researched. One can hardly yet make com-
parative evalutions in this field, let alone detect features of security governance
specific to the small state.
This whole book is an attempt to bridge these gaps, and this chapter aims to
provide it with a common tool-box. First, we shall review current multi-
functional definitions of security, and suggest a spectrum of issues prima facie
relevant – in some combination – for all states covered in this volume. Second,
the implications of smallness itself for states confronting such security agendas
is discussed. Third, we explore the currently available range of policy responses
and coping mechanisms. Fourth, pointers are offered for probing security gov-
ernance within the small state. A final section sums up the questions addressed
to later chapters of this book, and speculates on possible findings.
28 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
Defining a security agenda
As already noted, security concepts and definitions evolve together with chang-
ing ideas on the appropriate frame of reference, on ‘actorness’ and on the nature
of the international system. The realist and Westphalian approaches in combina-
tion made the nation-state the key actor and saw security success or failure in
terms of territorial integrity and external influence, together resting on traditional
military and (under the mercantilist view) economic power. In the late twentieth
century, and especially since the end of the Cold War, an appetite for new
approaches was fuelled by such visible trends as a reduced military confronta-
tion among the greatest powers; an overall drop in numbers of armed conflicts,
and their predominantly intra-state character; the march of globalization; and the
linked realization of limits to the nation-state’s authority, including its monopoly
of violence (Bailes 2006; Guéhenno 1995). One result has been to broaden the
range of issues seen as belonging to security or having security aspects. No hard
line can now be drawn between external (international) security and ‘internal’
security issues such as crime, law enforcement and internal order. Non-state
violence by conflict actors, terrorists, pirates and other criminals offers its own
challenges to a state’s authority and integrity; while governments are called on
to protect their citizens in ‘softer’ dimensions, such as accident reponse and
infrastructure protection, natural disasters, pandemics, environmental security
and security of supply. Such an extended, heterogeneous version of security is
often called ‘comprehensive’ or, more neutrally, ‘multi-dimensional’ (Williams
2013).
Coinciding with this is an interest in exploring other frames of reference than
the nation-state, from the globally measured ‘state of the earth’ downwards.3
Influential concepts look below state level to assess security at the level of
society – ‘societal security’4 – or to make the individual the measure of both
problems and solutions (‘human security’).5 Broadly speaking, the language of
‘societal’ and also ‘comprehensive’ security has been used more often in the
Northern hemisphere and in other advanced countries, where it has a flavour of
seeking to conserve existing security benefits and civil rights. ‘Human security’,
which sees the individual in sore need of help to achieve both ‘freedom from
fear’ and ‘freedom from want’ (i.e. basic necessities), was first conceived to
tackle problems of development. It has since been used inter alia as a rationale
for ‘humanitarian’ intervention, typically by actors of the global North in the
global South.6
It is logical and timely that the last decades have also produced a theory about
security theories: the discourse of ‘securitization’ associated with Ole Wæver
and his ‘Copenhagen School’ (Buzan et al. 1998). Briefly, this posits that no per-
manent ‘true’ definition of security exists, and asks how the name of security
gets attached to different things over space and time. Its authors saw this hap-
pening through a ‘speech act’ addressed typically by those in power to a national
audience, indicating a manifest challenge of some new kind which – if the audi-
ence accepts its ‘securitization’ – can be tackled with the tough methods of
Small states, survival and strategy 29
traditional security governance. The classic case from the last decade is the way
George W. Bush’s US Administration re-labelled terrorism, after 11 September
2001, as an existential threat that justified a permanent ‘war’ against its perpetra-
tors and supporters, even at the cost of infringing certain laws and liberties. The
value of securitization theory lies not only in predicting such cases and warning
of their consequences, but providing a simple transferable model of how they
arise. However, subsequent writers have (among other things) queried the valid-
ity of the model in some non-Western settings, and noted that securitization may
happen from below if the authorities are not tough enough on something the
people – rightly or mistakenly – care about.7 Refusal to securitize, or what the
theory calls de-securitization, is not necessarily better for the human race as a
whole than over-securitizing (Emmers 2009).
With security concepts multiplying and shifting, where to find a workable
matrix for classifying and comparing small states’ actual concerns? We may
start by looking at agendas they have defined themselves, whether in universally
applicable UN statements (UN 2005), or documents from the Organization for
Security and Cooperation in Europe (OSCE 2003), NATO, the European Union
and corresponding security organizations in Africa, the Americas, Asia and the
Pacific.8 Such collective statements can also pinpoint areas for multilateral
security cooperation, give mandates to the organizations themselves and set
norms to be aimed at by any less evolved states within the group and candidates
seeking accession. Characteristics found in all of them, at least from the mid-
1990s onwards, include:

• a broad multi-functional approach, where traditional military threats are


supplemented or shifted from the centre by concerns about other forms of
violence – intra-state conflict, terrorism, internal oppression and genocide –
and human/societal hazards such as accidents and disasters, supply prob-
lems, climate change and pandemic disease, plus economic/social
weaknesses that both aggravate such risks and damage humans directly. The
concept of threats has thus given way to a wider class of risks, which give
‘more importance to perceived future consequencess than do threats’, and
may also be self-inflicted (Rickli 2008: 314; see also Bailes 2007);
• a recognition that many such challenges arise above the level of the indi-
vidual state or of local inter-state transactions, becoming transnational or
fully global, and thus demanding international approaches both to assess-
ment and remediation (Baylis et al. 2011);
• a growing understanding of the security roles for good and ill of various
non-state actors,9 who at worst may both undermine the state’s authority
from within (‘weak state’ syndrome), and exploit the transnational space to
move and multiply. When this allows apparently weaker players to damage
stronger states it produces asymmetrical violence, of which terrorism is a
prime example. Reversing the realist assumption, the conflict management
discourse thus now speaks of the need to restore a state monopoly of viol-
ence, while at the same time qualifying it by placing the state’s own agents
30 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
under the law and seeking security partnership and burden-sharing with
benign non-state actors;
• an ongoing multiplication of institutional roles in the security equation.
More international organizations (from UN agencies downwards) become
relevant as security definitions widen, while existing institutions are extend-
ing their agendas in response both to local needs and external urging. More
regional institutions are also undertaking direct security interventions
(military and civilian peace operations), while NATO and the European
Union have both claimed competence to intervene anywhere in the world
(Bailes 2006).

Added to all this is a growing tendency (at least in democratic and transitional
states) to challenge the self-justifying, self-regulating tendency of traditional
security establishments.10 When security is understood as protecting not just life
but the quality of life, security concepts and actions must be tested against the
political values that safeguard life’s quality, including equality under the law,
transparency, democratic accountability, respect for all kinds of rights and – not
least – affordability. A good conceptual example is the constitutive act of the
African Union (African Union 2002), which lays out three strongly interdepend-
ent goals of conflict resolution and security building, democracy building and
sustainable development. This may seem little more than an aspirational formula
for many parts of the world; but it finds a practical echo in the resources being
channelled by all main security institutions and aid donors into ‘Security Sector
Reform’ – an approach combining efficiency with law-based democratic
accountability across the whole security field – in post-conflict and transitional
environments.11 At the same time, all viable states, whether large or small, are
increasingly expected to contribute, more or less altruistically, to peace missions
and other forms of assistance for the less fortunate. Together, these trends are
expanding the conventional notion of state performance beyond what used to be
called ‘good security’, to include the expectation of ‘doing good’ in the security
dimension at home and abroad. Inevitably, these standards, set by the suppos-
edly most advanced states and organizations for others to follow, are sometimes
most flagrantly ignored by the most capable players – when it suits them.
Against this background, and drawing on relevant institutional and national
documents, Table 2.1 presents a matrix of security issues hopefully wide enough
to cover all regions featured in this book. It groups hazards by the type of action
involved, on a range from the ‘hardest’ to the ‘softest’, but also in terms of
agency. Thus package ‘A’ covers inter-state and state-targeted actions, including
classic ‘geopolitical’ threats, but also internal conflict. ‘B’ concerns non-state
and asymmetric damage of human origin, largely but not always intentional
(vide migration). In deference to the small-state literature, ‘C’ creates a separate
category for economic and social challenges arising from weakness, malfunction
or miscalculation in ‘normal’ aspects of community life; and finally, ‘D’ com-
bines events and processes of accidental or ‘natural’ origin. The listing within
each column also reflects a gradient of agency, moving from the more
Table 2.1 A possible ‘comprehensive’ security agenda for small states

A. Military,´hard’ security B. Non-state violence (conflict C. Economic security D. Accidents and natural
actors apart) hazards

State attack Terrorism General economic and financial viability, Major deadly accidents,
including problems of underdevelopment including NBC* release
Caught in crossfire Violent/organized crime Security of supply (food, energy, other Infrastructure breakdown
essentials)
Subversion, sabotage Smuggling of strategic goods Severe social weaknesses/divisions (including Pandemics
issues of demography)
Political or economic blackmail, Other ‘asymmetric’ attack, e.g. Natural disasters
forced clientage cyber-attack
Coup from outside Illegal migration, trafficking Environmental degradation,
resource exhaustion
Internal (armed) conflict, Climate change
including top-down violence
Severe civil disorder

Note
* Nuclear, biological or chemical.
32 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
‘traditional’, intentional and state-linked acts down to the more informal or unin-
tentional. It does not aim to quantify probability or seriousness of impact, which
can vary widely anyway within most categories – objectively, and in terms of
nations’ perceptions. This volume’s geographical experts will be invited pre-
cisely to explain how far, and why, these issues do or do not figure in the
security concepts and priorities of each state or region addressed.

Specific challenges for small states


In principle, for any given threat or risk, smallness could be a positive, a neutral
or a negative factor. It must always be a handicap in tackling the ‘hard’ threats
of package ‘A’ above, unless the small state is clearly harmless and lacking in
assets that others might want. (Even then, what other states want varies over
time; the relaxed environment for small Pacific islands today was different
during colonial expansion or the naval struggles of World War II.) The chances
that smallness will be at least a neutral factor grow as the spectrum shifts
towards categories ‘C’ and ‘D’, where a limited territory and simpler socio-
economic structure could also limit exposure and simplify risk management.
One constant, however, is the small scale of state resources, including human
resources – which in small bureaucracies may be under-professionalized, under-
specialized or skewed towards certain specializations. Combined with shortages
of cash, reserve stocks, equipment and related technologies, this narrows the
options available to a small state’s leaders both for mitigating risks and respond-
ing to crises. Facing an inevitable deficit of power – to coerce others and resist
coercion – they must choose between seeking either autonomy and detachment,
or alternative ways of controlling their interactions (Mouritzen 1997: 101–106).
This translates into two broad strategic options: a defensive posture focused on
autonomy and avoiding trouble, traditionally expressed as neutrality; or a proac-
tive posture using different cooperative schemes (national and international part-
nerships, organizations, regional and global activism) to seek both essential
protection and magnified influence (Rickli 2008). As will be seen in this and the
next section, current circumstances are pushing towards the second and more
proactive range of behaviours, at least for developed small states, and across all
security dimensions.
One basic reason is that in a security environment shaped by wider definitions
and growing international interdependence, the pursuit of neutrality, at least in tra-
ditional forms, risks leading to defensive isolationist positions that trap the small
state into marginalization (Rickli 2010b). To avoid this and make up for its own
limited capacity, a small state is prima facie more prone than the average to seek
solutions through external engagement and partnership. Yet this implies a degree
of more-or-less permanent dependency; while other costs may include a ‘quid pro
quo’ for the external provider, but also – in institutional contexts – the far-reaching
adaptation of national systems and policies (Bailes 2009, and see the next section).
More specific small state vulnerabilities are reviewed in what follows. Start-
ing with ‘A’, a small state is inherently vulnerable to military attack, especially
Small states, survival and strategy 33
if its territory is also small and accessible. If claiming neutrality, it is unlikely to
have the physical force to repel combatants who catch it in cross-fire or want to
exploit its facilities.12 An aggressor may be able to control the state through
political and economic leverage without firing a shot, as has often happened to
‘tributary’ nations on the frontiers of large states and empires. A small state
apparatus can also be more easily overmastered by an externally aided coup,13
by subversion and sabotage or by internal violence in the form of civil disobedi-
ence, rioting and breakdown of order.
When it comes to the currently prevalent form of intra-state conflict involving
an armed contestation over the organization of the state’s territory or nature of
its government,14 a small government’s authority can easily fall foul of external
meddling, inter alia, by diasporas. However, such conflicts can and do result
also from home-grown divisions, with or without aggravation by bad govern-
ment. Ethnic, religious and/or cultural diversity has prompted violence within
the small states of the former Soviet region, the Western Balkans, and Southeast
Asia among others – all examples to be covered in this volume. There are risks
also in the internal stratification of cosmopolitan small states (e.g. in the Gulf )
that attract foreign residents and often depend on migrant labour. Small state
politics can be vicious and polarized precisely because they are so easily person-
alized, and rival ideologies can generate violence as seen, for instance, in Central
America and the Caribbean in the past. Finally, the small state may be directly
born of conflict when it breaks out of a colonial empire or parent nation –
perhaps itself relatively small, as in the cases of Kosovo vs. Serbia, Transnistria
vs. Moldova and Abkhazia and South Ossetia seceding from Georgia in 2008. In
such cases both the ‘broken’ and the ‘breakaway’ state have to find a way of
consolidating their identity and healing the scars of conflict – with fewer assets,
and perhaps less intrinsic credibility, than an average-sized nation would enjoy.15
Continuing to category ‘B’, smallness remains an a priori handicap for con-
fronting less traditional forms of human violence. A few terrorists, other extrem-
ists or criminals can all too easily grab a small and exposed centre of power. A
single terrorist atrocity might cripple the national infrastructure, while scaring
off tourists and investors. Terrorists aiming at a third nation might strike at their
targets when transiting through a small state, counting on a lower level of pre-
paredness and protection. Smugglers of everything from drugs to weapons of
mass destruction take a similar interest in small state routes and hideaways.
Criminals may conserve the state structure while infiltrating and manipulating it
to their profit, as some observers have alleged in new small states like Monte-
negro (Naim 2012). The small state may suffer here also from a lack of investi-
gative media and civil society groups able to expose abuses. Finally, small states
are not intrinsically disadvantaged in cyber-warfare, as they may more easily
find working alternatives if ICT systems collapse. Indeed, the asymmetric nature
of cyber-weapons offers small states one of their few ways of making trouble –
if wished – for much larger ones. But they may be dangerously exposed if too
enthusiastically embracing ‘e-governance’ without adequate security expertise
and technical protection.16
34 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
The economic security complex – category ‘C’ above – is well documented, and
has its own chapter in this volume.17 Suffice it to say that smallness may bring
some benefits, implying less socio-economic complexity and hence simpler tasks
of economic management. It offers flexibility to seek new niches in international
competition, as shown by the many small states that have prospered as banking
centres, transport and communication hubs and tourist attractions. However, a
small economy is almost inescapably vulnerable at three levels: limited own
resources imposing high import dependence (for food, energy etc. and also capital
and technological knowhow); a narrow and specialized economic structure with
few wealth-producing pillars; and above-average ‘openness’ to external dependen-
cies, influences and market fluctuations – in turn mostly generated by larger players
(e.g. Katzenstein 1984, 1985). The attempt, in itself rational, to find a money-
making niche independent of size can lead to disproportionate damage if the
gamble fails – which can happen inter alia because small elites lack ability to
assess and insure against the risks (Schwartz 2011; Thorhallsson 2011). In a poorer
nation dragged down by under-development and struggling for international com-
petitiveness, economic dependency (in this case, on aid) can reach a point that ser-
iously calls in question the other attributes of sovereignty.
Physical smallness is no protection against the accidental and natural hazards
in category ‘D’. Haiti’s earthquake catastrophe of January 2010 was an extreme
case, but only one example of the disaster spectrum – including tropical storms,
tsunamis, internal floods and volcano eruptions – threatening small nations in the
Caribbean and worldwide. Some small island states in the Pacific and Indian
Ocean face total immersion by rising sea levels consequent upon global
warming. Short of that, extreme events and more gradual climate changes could
tip the balance against economic survival by destroying key habitat features and
polluting or exhausting natural resources. When pandemics hit, small states need
not suffer disproportionally as their defences (e.g. vaccination campaigns) are
easier to organize; but in small elites, even a few infections and deaths could
deprive the crisis management effort of crucial expertise. In cases of infrastruc-
ture failure and accidents, a lack of redundancy on the one hand and of special-
ized response assets and expertise on the other are the default aspects of small
state vulnerability. Island states lack neighbours to bring immediate aid, but
land-locked states relying on cross-border systems for energy, transport and
communications are doubly at risk: their own access is hostage to others’ actions,
but they also suffer the knock-on effects of neighbours’ disasters.
Across this whole threat/risk spectrum, it bears repeating that there is no
‘typical’ small state profile. The problems looming largest for each nation are
determined by objective factors of territory size, geography, climate and habitat;
but also by political features of the neighbourhood and larger region, the level
and direction of economic development, and human and societal factors includ-
ing population movements and tourism. As the next two sections will show,
moreover, knowing one’s threat/risk profile is only the first step towards a
security policy (or ‘strategy’) capable of averting threats, minimizing risks and
protecting the best interests of both nation and people.
Small states, survival and strategy 35
Small states’ strategic options
Few small states in the world today have problems simple enough to be managed
ad hoc. Most face complex challenges, opportunities and responsibilities that
demand a conscious effort of assessment and planning, often leading to a docu-
ment called a security ‘strategy’ (Bailes 2009). In a comprehensive security
context, where many different public authorities are involved, strategy design
needs to be a whole-government process. As argued above, it should ideally also
draw in (benign) non-state actors; be answerable to representative institutions
and the people; and allow for external activism – altruistic, or to meet defined
commitments. Assuming such a self-aware and rational approach to meeting a
given small state’s challenges (which cannot always be assumed, see next
section), what prima facie options are available?

‘Hard’ security and inter-state diplomacy


The literature provides its clearest answers for traditional ‘hard’ threats and geo-
political disadvantages. Military-strategic protection may be sought from the
nearest powerful state; from a remote large power, inter alia to protect against
the nearer one(s); or by grouping with larger variety of partners as a ‘balancing’
measure. The first two options can also be seen as types of ‘bandwaggoning’
(Walt 1987). Any of the three strategies may be formally expressed as a bilateral
or multilateral ‘alliance’, and they are not mutually exclusive. Lithuania, say,
may rely ultimately on US strategic protection against Russia, but qualifies its
bilateral dependence by entering the multilateral alliance, NATO – which in
some sense also constrains the exercise of US power – and seeks practical coop-
eration with Russia for added balance and risk reduction.
Few, if any, small states today can get by without some of these basic geopo-
litical devices, but all carry prices and penalties reflecting the ‘realist’ world of
interest-based calculations that they inhabit. Large protectors can abandon
smaller partners when their own cost-benefit balance changes. The ‘price’ they
charge may involve so much intrusion into the small state’s affairs, and pressure
for uncritical support, that it leaves the small actor hardly more freedom of play
than a hostile takeover would. These effects are softened but not eliminated
when the interaction takes place within a defence organization, as existing alli-
ances (even NATO) use an intergovernmental form of governance that barely
cloaks the underlying power-play and large-power dominance.18 At the extreme,
a small state may serve expressly or de facto as a ‘forward base’ of a remote
power in the flank of the nearest one, like Cuba or Taiwan, thus involving it in
strategic tensions and risks of an exceptionally high order (for both parties!) as
the price of its protection.
Small states suffering internal conflict, misrule or disorder also attract large
state interventions: Grenada and Panama are examples involving the US, and
there have been several such cases between the Russian Federation and its neigh-
bours since 1990.19 Another variant is intervention by a former imperial state:
36 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
the UK in Sierra Leone (2000) and France in Côte d’Ivoire (2002). Typically,
the intervener sponsors a new regime that may be a puppet or relatively inde-
pendent, and not necessarily dysfunctional, but which is not the small communi-
ty’s own choice and may thus sow further seeds of instability.
A less objectionable solution under current thinking is for the UN, or a multi-
national regional organization mandated by it, to take charge. In East Timor and
Kosovo, the UN even provided a temporary administration, offering time and
support for true self-government to develop. While avoiding the cruder forms of
big-power abuse, these methods have their own fragilities: the ‘multiple person-
ality’ of the responsible organization may weaken its vision and will, and
extended tutelage may sap rather than speed the growth of a self-sufficient
state.20 With its diplomacy effectively outsourced to a distant authority, the pro-
tected territory also risks being cut off from natural intercourse with its neigh-
bours. This problem is avoided, and practical results often improved, if a local
regional organization can take the lead in rehabilitation and offer the ‘carrot’ of
eventual membership in its ranks.21 Finally, a new small state created by ‘break-
away’ must normally find ways of protecting itself against its former mother-
land; but it can happen that a former colonial owner remains the chief defence
partner (e.g. for Pacific and Caribbean states). Some or all states born of a single
break-up may also try to bond together – cf. the sympathies among certain
Western Balkan successor states, or the post-Soviet GUAM organization, where
Moldova, Azerbaijan and Georgia cooperate with Ukraine.22
Small states’ own military policies have also undergone two fundamental
reassessments in recent decades in face of the broadening of security agendas
and the increasing institutionalization of security (Rickli 2010b). First, the tradi-
tional dichotomy whereby police forces guarantee domestic security, and armed
forces defend the borders and beyond, has been completely blurred. Today’s
post-conflict operations increasingly rely on international police forces drawn
from national contingents (Lutterbeck 2004). Similarly, the domestic role of the
armed forces can now extend to supporting counter-terrorist efforts, critical
infrastructure protection and disaster response and relief. Second, new-style
international operations are very often distant and involve close multinational
collaboration. To take part, even the smallest state needs interoperable expedi-
tionary capabilities.
Small-state armed forces thus face more varied missions requiring ever more
sophisticated materials and professional personnel. Small military forces with
limited assets, traditionally relying on conscripts, have obvious problems coping
and must be ready to change both their priorities and methods. For national
needs, the military must increase cooperation with civil forces, and consider
drawing on external (often, large-state) expertise for tasks such as counter-
terrorism, NBC protection, airspace policing or border control against illegal
immigration. At the international level, they must find capabilities useful for the
type of operations they would like to take part in (peacekeeping, peace enforce-
ment, stabilization, reconstruction), which often means finding ‘niche’ special-
izations (Rickli 2008). Focusing on such special tasks can endow small states
Small states, survival and strategy 37
with unique capabilities and expertise, tradeable as a bargaining chip in inter-
national partnerships; but it further undermines their ability to develop full-
spectrum capabilities. The overall result is to make small states even more
dependent on their stronger partners, both for addressing the full range of
security missions, and probably for their own basic territorial defence
Modern small states can try to mitigate ‘hard’ realist challenges one further
way: by directing their own influence towards changing the rules of the game.
Given sufficient capacity to act internationally, and understanding that consistent
international rules and norms are more reliable than any single protector, they
may leverage their ‘innocent’ and non-threatening nature to nudge larger powers
towards the ‘appropriate behaviour’ of non-zero-sum peaceful cooperation.
Ingebritsen (2002), for instance, shows the five Nordic states making a measur-
able impact on global norms and ambitions in the fields of sustainable develop-
ment, peaceful resolution of conflict and resource transfers from rich to poor.
Starting from a remote geographic location and with limited material powers, the
Nordics have sought multiplier effects for their ideas through institutions, espe-
cially those – UN and OSCE – where many members are small-to-medium states
and likely to sympathize. They have formed ‘coalitions’ for specific reform
agendas with like-minded but larger states, such as Canada and South Africa. As
Ingebritsen concludes, in the Nordic states ‘a group of military weak, economic-
ally dependent small states pursues “social power” by acting as a norm entrepre-
neur in the international community’ (Ingebritsen 2002). The same pattern could
be traced in the behaviour of a state like Costa Rica in South America, and some
smaller players in Africa and South-east Asia, as well as New Zealand.

Wider security and new institutional roles


This last remark makes a bridge to the handling of security issues from security
packages ‘B’, ‘C’ and ‘D’, where the traditional model of small-state options
starts to break down. Threats from non-state actors cannot be stopped at borders
nor conquered with purely military force, as recent events in Iraq and Afghan-
istan (or Somalia for that matter) have abundantly shown. Protection and tute-
lage from a capable larger state will certainly help, but the small state’s
360-degree exposure to transnational effects makes it extra-dependent upon a
coherent and helpful international community. Similarly in economics, if the
small state is not reduced to a de facto province of a neighbour’s economy (as
are micro-states such as San Marino in Italy, see Chapter 10), it must engage
with a variety of suppliers and customers and work to reduce risks both by
balancing between them, and sheltering under international rules and institutions.
For the hazards in group ‘D’, it is again unlikely that a single nation can offer
protection unless the small state is virtually absorbed in its own infrastructure –
thereby also sharing its own risks. More usually, the small player must supple-
ment its limited capacity by working with all its neighbours (as these issues often
cut across normal political divisions), and with international and institutional
partners from UN agencies downwards. In all these non-miltary fields, non-state
38 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
actors can positively reinforce small-state security governance when they are
strong, experienced and ethical; but their malign effects can rarely be mastered
without international help.
It is in these contexts that the institution as shelter moves to centre-stage,
thereby raising questions that challenge the classic realist analysis of small-state
options – together with their cost-benefit tallies. International and regional
organizations are increasingly important providers of ‘soft’ forms of security to
tackle new or newly prominent threats. Regional groupings everywhere in the
world23 have adopted joint approaches since 2001 to non-state transnational phe-
nomena like terrorism, smuggling and piracy, while many now also address
natural disasters, environmental security objectives and disease control. The EU,
with its unusually wide and deep competence, offers small states a new approach
to economic security; support for ‘homeland’ security through its Justice,
Liberty, Security programme and Schengen system; and regulatory and practical
support on every issue in category ‘D’ (Bailes and Thorhallsson 2012). In these
sectors, small states can draw variously on pooled assets (central EU funds), a
continent-wide regulatory framework, best practice lessons and emergency
assistance. For those sensing ‘hard’ security threats, like Finland and the Baltic
States, the EU provides a certain political and existential security; and its
enlargement offers the best hope of eventually ending conflict among and within
the Western Balkan candidates. It has many tools also to address small states’
problems beyond its borders, ranging from military deployments under the
Common Security and Defence Policy (CSDP) to instant humanitarian aid
(Giegerich 2010).
As seen all too plainly since 2008, the European Union cannot shelter small
states from economic crisis, nor spare them the pain of adjustment to fluctuations
in the neo-liberal international economy. Yet cases like Ireland’s also reveal a
two-way interdependence: the EU has not felt able simply to abandon its
problem children or leave them to the mercy of outside providers (like the Inter-
national monetary fund (IMF )) – as the non-EU member Iceland was left over
the same period (Thorhallsson and Kirby 2012). In any case, the ‘sheltering’
value of the EU for its smallest players does not rest only on its concrete record
of success in security provision, where the minuses are obvious. Given its prin-
ciple of members’ basic equality, which applies especially in its common foreign
and security policies,24 the EU offers small states a new context for asserting
their interests vis-à-vis larger neighbours and in global policy making. Its intan-
gible political and existential influences, as well as the constraints of formal joint
policies, go further than any old-style bilateral or multilateral alliance in restrain-
ing the biggest members from ‘throwing their weight around’.25 Last but not
least, small states can use non-traditional routes to influence through their deal-
ings with and inside the European Commission and European Parliament. In
sum, the EU:

can no longer be written off as a purely economic actor or dismissed as an


inefficient security provider, despite the fact, that its ‘hard’ security role
Small states, survival and strategy 39
remains minimal. The EU’s unique soft security features offer small Euro-
pean states a kind of ‘escape from smallness’ that no other known security
construct has been able to provide.
(Bailes and Thorhallsson 2012)

The EU is admittedly unique in its combination of post-realist, post-Westphalian


features. It may change the security calculus for a score of small or smallish
states (members and applicants) in Europe, but no other region offers the same
depth or variety of multilateral ‘shelters’ – including NATO and others.
However, there are several further parts of the world where the institutionaliza-
tion of security agendas is advancing, either replacing or supplementing small
players’ more basic strategic choices, and extending cooperation to new domains
of security, including internal and transnational ones. Nor should the United
Nations be underestimated as a security resource for the small, just because it
plays a more marginal role in European security.
This makes it important to acknowledge that institutional ‘shelters’ demand
their own price from small actors, and in ways partly more insidious than those of
national protectors. The small state that gains a larger voice in such a forum often
also attracts larger burdens: not just cash and in-kind contributions, but the need to
embrace all other members’ security agendas (Wivel 2005) and help carry the insti-
tution’s flag abroad (literally, in peace missions). The transformative, homogeniz-
ing processes described by social constructivism theory (Williams 2013) and the
‘Europeanization’ concept are prima facie likely to work faster on a small elite,
and a small society with a narrower set of traditions. On top of this, in the EU case,
comes a mass of directly applicable legislation that does not simply replace, but
adds major new outgrowths to, the home-grown legal/judicial system. In short,
small-state Euro-sceptics are not wrong to argue that serious modifications of
sovereignty are involved in such solutions, and to intuit that the ultimate effect on
identity will be deeper than that involved in simply courting or imitating a large
protector. Integration may be a potential ‘escape from smallness’, but the smallest
will arguably pay for it with the most lasting transformations, whatever second
thoughts they may later have about the bargain (Bailes 2011).

Inside the small state


The last section has shown the daunting challenges of designing a viable security
strategy for any small state. Putting it into practice is no easier. The task must be
tackled in a political, social and human context that is becoming more compli-
cated and confusing for everyone as the security agenda and range of relevant
actors grow wider. Facing an above-average gap between the security challenges
facing it and its own ability to master them, the small state needs a fortiori to
over-perform in this mode of strategy-making and execution. What are its
chances of doing so?
Only a few pointers can be offered here for our test-case studies.26 First, does
the small state have an explicit risk assessment process, and, if so, what quality of
40 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
information can it draw upon from home or abroad? Does it strive for objectivity
or are its calculations of urgency and priority affected by the typical biases: tradi-
tion and habit, over-generalization of latest experience, social anxieties and antago-
nisms, over-focus on more ‘acute’ and ‘shocking’ incidents? Does it include
informed non-state actors in order both to pick their brains and get a better picture
of their characteristic risks (e.g. corporate security concerns)? In more theoretical
terms, who ‘securitizes’ and are the right actors ‘securitizing’ the right things?
Second, how unitary are the nation’s perceptions, principles and values for
defence and security work? A small state can be as divided as any other on these
matters, along personal and political, ideological, ethnic, provincial, genera-
tional, gender, confessional and other lines. If not addressed, such rifts can result
in policy see-sawing, contradictions and unstable compromises, or no clear
strategy at all – as a way of dodging divisive debate. This is especially damaging
for a small state that has trouble in getting its voice heard to start with, and needs
to say something strong and consistent if it wants others to listen.
Third, what are the official structures for security policy assessment, decision-
making and execution? Do they include a clear centre and line of authority, inter
alia for dealing with external actors? Do they make enough provision for coordin-
ation across all the sectors now likely to be involved? Is there some kind of ‘situ-
ation centre’ where information can be pooled, fast decisions taken and resources
deployed in an emergency? Typical weaknesses of developed small states here are
to assume that no formal structures or plans are needed since so few people need to
interact; to keep things decentralized, matching a multi-polar political balance
among different parties or individualistic politicians; or to be generally too relaxed,
perhaps because of perceived lack of ‘real’ (hard, military) threats. Conversely,
power may be over-centralized and -personalized, neglecting grass-roots needs and
opinions and using ‘hard’ methods to excess; this can also reflecte a ‘fortress’ men-
tality that waits too long to seek needed help abroad. Finally, weak and conflict-
ridden administrations that struggle to keep minimal control of defence and internal
security challenges may have to leave ‘softer’ contingencies to a mixture of tradi-
tional social resilience and un-filtered foreign aid.
Fourth, how well does the national strategy identify and deal with external
influences and demands? We have seen that a small state must expect to ‘pay’
for full-spectrum security partnership and protection with an increasingly wide
and subtle set of adaptations to its own national starting-point. In extreme cases,
including newly-created states and those starting afresh after conflict, a foreign –
national or institutional – model of strategy may be implanted almost wholesale.
This has its merits, especially in palliating lack of expertise and bridging or
rising above internal divisions; it may trigger real transformations, notably when
the incentive of an accession process is present. But such situations can be dan-
gerous if they lead to changes in national behaviour whose rationale only the
elite understands, and that are not clearly explained to, let alone accepted and
internalized by, the people. An example would be tough laws brought in at US
(or other Western) behest against terrorism and WMD (weapons of mass destruc-
tion) proliferation in nations that have never been touched by these problems,
Small states, survival and strategy 41
and whose best experts may struggle to make sense of them. Another would be
sending people abroad on missions unrelated to national defence, which the elite
see as ‘payment’ for international sympathy and status, but which the public
revolts against when casualties occur. In highly integrated regions, as we have
seen, something slower but deeper goes on as states import agendas and norms,
are schooled in reciprocal solidarity, and acquire co-ownership of genuinely col-
lective interests emerging in the supranational space.
How to accommodate all this in national security strategy is something that
even today’s most advanced states are struggling with. For a small state where
the proportion of ‘imports’ will be prima facie higher, what matters above all is
that policy makers are aware of the process and – at least – try to make the
public see the instrumental logic of their new, constantly evolving activity
profile. If they can relate it to a strong unitary conception of underlying national
interests, their task is naturally much easier (Bailes 2009).

Summary and conclusions


The main argument of this chapter is quite simple. Security challenges for small,
as for all, states have diversified in the last decades partly as a result of new defi-
nitions. This implies a need also for new solutions and revised overall strategies.
To help in testing such propositions against individual states’ and regions’
everyday reality, we have offered a sketch of the evolution of security concepts;
a meta-analytical tool for probing them (securitization); a practical matrix for
classifying threats and risks; a discussion of small states’ particular vulnerabili-
ties and security options; and a set of questions on internal security governance.
The authors of both functional and geographical chapters in the rest of this
volume are invited to draw upon this tool-box, but also to challenge it if they
find it – despite the authors’ best efforts – too West-centric, ill-adapted or incom-
plete. At the least, we may expect small states in different regions to have differ-
ent security profiles and priorities, explicable inter alia by geopolitical
differences, state strength or weakness and the level of development. It will be
intriguing to see how far the intangibles of political/security ‘culture’, identity
and perception also come into play.
While this question remains open it would be presumptuous to suggest con-
clusions, but one hypothesis may be permitted. In the European region at least,
new and widening security challenges have been a factor pushing most small
states towards the deepest available forms of regional integration: a solution
apparently viable enough to have led many to make serious sacrifices for it. This
new approach does not necessarily replace more traditional manoeuvres to deal
with old-style, big-power challenges, but can either be combined with them or
transmute them into a new setting. If the model has wider relevance – as prima
facie suggested by parallels like ASEAN – should not small states in other
regions be putting their best energies into promoting voluntary multilateral
integration, and perhaps showing the way by experiments among themselves?
And even more interesting: if not, why not?
42 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
Notes
1 For summaries of these and other theoretical approaches the reader is directed to
(Williams 2013).
2 See, for example, the ‘Failed States Index’ published by Foreign Policy magazine at
www.foreignpolicy.com/failedstates (accessed 25 November 2013).
3 On the related concept of environmental security, see Chapter 5 in this book.
4 Developed by authors like Barry Buzan, and now official policy in several Nordic
states, this approach defines security priorities based on what damages society both
physically and in its established peaceful routines. As an executive doctrine it focuses
on handling civil emergencies of human or non-human origin (see Chapter 4 in this
book).
5 The United Nations Development Programme’s Human Development Report for
2004 (UNDP 2004) defined this concept as covering seven interlocking dimensions of
economic, food, health, environmental, personal, community, and political security.
For a recent assessment see (Acharya 2011).
6 A ‘humanitarian’ rationale for forceful intervention that could override normal con-
siderations of sovereignty has been discussed since the late twentieth century. In its
sixtieth anniversary Summit declaration (United Nations 2005) the UN defined a
‘responsibility to protect’ (R2P) allowing the international community to act, should
any government egregiously neglect or attack its own people. The UN mandate for
action against Libya in 2011 is often cited as a case in point.
7 A common example is popular concern about migration and multi-cultural tendencies
in society.
8 For a listing and comparative discussion of regional security institutions see (Bailes
and Cottey, 2006); and on regional security cultures, (Crocker et al. 2011).
9 Though lacking a universal definition, this expression normally covers the private
business sector; terrorists, criminals, and conflict actors not representing a state; non-
governmental organizations, civil society groupings and potentially all private
citizens. Non-state-owned media should logically be included and the status of polit-
ical parties (not in government) is moot.
10 This is also surely the underlying purpose of the ‘securitization’ school.
11 For a wide range of publications on this subject see the website of the Geneva Centre
for Democratic Control of Armed Forces: www.dcaf.ch. (accessed 25 November
2013).
12 See Chapter 10 in this book.
13 The Seychelles notoriously suffered multiple coups and coup attempts from both
inside and ouside in the first five years of their independence (from 1978).
14 This diagnostic vocabulary is used by the Uppsala Conflict Data Programme which
publishes well-respected data series, see: www.ucdp.uu.se. (accessed 25 November
2013).
15 As an illustration of the difficulties: by the time of writing, none of the break-away
entities mentioned here had secured formal recognition from all members of the EU
or UN.
16 For a case-study see Bailes and Ragnarsson (2011).
17 See Chapter 3 in this volume.
18 All decisions in NATO require the consensus of all governments and even the
Secretary-General has an essentially mediating role. In practice the US is the
dominant, if far from the only significant, player. On partial EU parallels, see p. 38.
19 Examples are the involvement of a Russian garrison in Transnistria and Russia’s
support for Armenia in its war with Azerbaijan, as well as the conflict with Georgia in
2008.
20 On the key importance of local ‘ownership’ in such cases see Hansen and Wiharta
(2007).
Small states, survival and strategy 43
21 The EU and NATO seek to play exactly this role for small Western Balkan states, and
the admissions of post-conflict Vietnam, Cambodia and Laos to ASEAN could be
seen as a parallel.
22 The ‘non-realist’ options in this paragraph all assume the willingness of multilateral
actors to act. In practice, interventions by the UN, NATO, EU and other regional
groups are selective, skirting ‘no-go’ areas of the globe, where conditions (includ-
ing possible reactions from local powers) appear too dangerous. A small state
caught inside such a zone only retains the options of realist bandwaggoning/
balancing.
23 Namely, the Shanghai Cooperation Organization, Collective Security Treaty Organ-
ization, and Commonwealth of Independent States.
24 There is no use of majority voting in these fields and it has been shown, e.g. by
Cyprus, that even the smallest states do have a veto.
25 One way to describe the process fostering such behavioural changes is ‘Europeaniza-
tion’, (see, for example, Ladrech 2010). Of course large states do still have dispropor-
tionate power to dictate EU policy moves, and may impose new risks/burdens on
small members in the process (Wivel 2005).
26 This section draws inter alia on Bailes (2009).

Bibliography
Acharya, A., (2011) ‘Human Security’, in Baylis, J., Smith, S. and Owens, P. The Glo-
balization of World Politics, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
African Union (2002) ‘The Constitutive Act’, available online at: www.africa-union.org/
root/au/aboutau/constitutive_act_en.htm (accessed 14 September 2012).
Bailes, A.J.K. (2006) ‘The World of Security and Peace Research in a 40-year Per-
spective’ in SIPRI Yearbook 2006: Armaments, Disarmament and International
Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bailes, A.J.K. (2007) ‘Introduction: A World of Risk’ in SIPRI Yearbook 2007: Arma-
ments, Disarmament and International Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bailes, A.J.K. (2009) ‘Does a Small State Need a Strategy?’, occasional paper of the
Institute for International Affairs/Centre for the Study of Small States, University of
Iceland, available online at: http:stofnanir.hi.is/ams/sites/files/ams/Bailes_Final_0.pdf
(accessed 13 May 2013).
Bailes, A.J.K. (2011) ‘Instrumentalizing the EU in Small State Strategies: Examples from
Norden’, paper presented at the International Studies Association, Montreal.
Bailes, A.J.K. and Cottey, A. (2006) ‘Regional Security Cooperation in the Early 21st
Century’ in SIPRI Yearbook 2006: Armaments, Disarmament and International
Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bailes, A.J.K. and Ragnarsson, J.K. (2011) ‘Iceland and Cyber-threats: Is it More Than
Fear of Fear?’, Stjórnmál og Stjórnsysla (University of Iceland), Summer 2011, pp.
185–202.
Bailes, A.J.K. and Thorhallsson, B. (2012) ‘Instrumentalizing the European Union in
Small State Strategies’, Journal of European Integration, 35(2): 99–115.
Baylis, J., Smith, S. and Owens, P. (2011) The Globalization of World Politics, Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Briguglio, L., Cordina, G. and Kisanga, E.J. (2006) ‘Introduction’, in Briguglio, L.,
Cordina, G. and Kisanga, E.J. (eds) Building the Economic Resilience of Small States,
Malta: Formatek for the Islands and Small States Institute of the University of Malta
and the Commonwealth Secretariat.
44 A.J.K. Bailes et al.
Buzan, B., de Wilde, J. and Wæver, O. (1998) Security: A New Framework for Analysis,
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner publishers.
Crocker, Chester A., Fen O. Hampson and Pamela Aall (2011) Rewiring Regional
Security in a Fragmented World, New York: US Institute of Peace.
Cooper, A.F. and Shaw T.M. (2009) (eds) The Diplomacies of Small States: Between Vul-
nerability and Resilience, The Centre for International Governance Innovation, Canada:
Palgrave Macmillan.
Emmers, R. (2009) ‘Securitization’, in Collins, A. (ed.) Contemporary Security Studies
(2nd edition), London: Oxford University Press.
Giegerich, B. (ed.) (2010) ‘Europe and Global Security’, Adelphi paper 414–415,
London: Institute of International Strategic Studies.
Guéhenno, J.-M. (1995) The End of the Nation-State, Minneapolis, MN: University of
Minnesota Press.
Handel, M. (1981) Weak States in the International System, London: Frank Cass.
Hansen, A. and Wiharta, S. (2007) ‘The Transition to a Just Order: Establish Local Own-
ership after Conflict, A Policy Report’, Stockholm: Folke Bernadotte Academy
Research Report no. 4.
Ingebritsen, C. (2002) ‘Norm Entrepreneurs: Scandinavia’s Role in World Politics’,
Cooperation and Conflict, 27(1): 11–23.
Katzenstein, P.J. (1984) Corporatism and Change: Austria, Switzerland, and the Politics
of Industry, Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.
Katzenstein, P.J. (1985) Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe,
Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.
Keohane, R.O. (1969) ‘Lilleputians’ Dilemmas: Small States in International Politics’,
International Organization, 23(2): 291–310.
Ladrech, R. (2010) Europeanization and National Politics, London: Macmillan.
Lutterbeck, D. (2004) ‘Between Police And Military: The New Security Agenda and the
Rise of Gendarmerie’, Cooperation and Conflict, 39:1: 45–68.
Mouritzen, H. (1997) External Danger and Democracy: Old Nordic Lessons and New
European Challenges, Aldershot and Brookfield: Dartmouth.
Naim, M. (2012). ‘Mafia States: Organized Crime Takes Off ’, Foreign Affairs, May/June
2012.
Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe (2003) Strategy to Address Threats
to Security and Stability in the Twenty-First Century, OECD.
Rickli, J.-M. (2008) ‘European Small States’ Military Policies after the Cold War: From
Territorial to Niche Strategies’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 21(3):
307–325.
Rickli, J.-M. (2010a) ‘Neutrality Inside and Outside the EU: A Comparison of the Aus-
trian and Swiss Security Policies after the Cold War’, in Steinmetz, R., Thorhallsson,
B. and Wivel, A. (eds) Small States in Europe: Challenges and Opportunities, Alder-
shot: Ashgate, pp. 181–198.
Rickli, J.-M. (2010b) The Military Policies of European Neutral and Non-Allied States
after the Cold War, PhD thesis, Oxford: University of Oxford.
Scheuerman, W.E. (2009) Hans Morgenthau: Realism and Beyond, Cambridge: Polity
Press.
Schwartz, H. (2011) ‘Iceland’s Financial Iceberg: Why Leveraging up is a Titanic
Mistake without a Reserve Currency’, European Political Science, 10(3): 292–300.
Tranoy, B.S. (2011) ‘Poor Governance in a Very Rich and Advanced (Micro)State:
Reflections from Political Science’, European Political Studies, 10(3): 277–291.
Small states, survival and strategy 45
Thorhallsson, B. (2011) ‘Domestic Buffer versus External Shelter: Viability of Small
States in the New Globalised Economy’, European Political Science, 10(3): 324–336.
Thorhallsson B. and Kirby, P. (2012) ‘Financial Crisis in Iceland and Ireland: Does EU
and Euro Membership Matter?’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 50(5): 801–818.
Vital, D. (1967) The Inequality of States: A Study of Small Powers in International Rela-
tions, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
United Nations (2005) ‘Summit Outcome’, available online at: www.un.org/summit2005/
documents.html (accessed 14 September 2012).
United Nations Development Programme (2004), ‘Human Development Report’, avail-
able online at: http://hdr.undp.org/en/reports/global/hdr1994/ (accessed 14 September
2012).
Walt, S.M. (1987) The Origins of Alliances, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Williams, P. (ed.) (2013) Security Studies: An Introduction (2nd edition), London:
Routledge.
Wivel, A. (2005) ‘The Security Challenge of Small EU Member States: Interests, Identity
and the Development of the EU as a Security Actor’, Journal of Common Market
Studies, 43(2): 393–412
3 Economic security and size
Richard T. Griffiths

Introduction
The concept of economic security has two dimensions – security at the level of
the household or citizen and security at the level of the state. Although the two
levels are obviously linked, since instability at the state level will percolate
through to its citizens, each level has its own distinct literature and the two levels
combined are too large to do justice to within the framework of a single chapter.
For this reason we will focus on the macro-economic dimensions of security.
No state can be completely secure, or should even aspire to be. Isolation and
self-sufficiency are options only available to the few, and states that have chosen
this path – such as the planned economy of the USSR and Communist China
before the reforms – have condemned themselves to wasteful and inefficient
growth strategies. The path of international development is not smooth, and it is
regularly punctuated by local, and sometimes global, setbacks. All states, large
and small, are exposed to such vicissitudes and no state can secure itself com-
pletely against them. The issue addressed in this chapter is whether smaller states
are more exposed, by virtue of their size, to such risks and whether they are more
constrained in their means of redress. Systemic insecurity of this nature can
impact on economies even when conditions seem favourable, since the percep-
tion of insecurity can shorten planning horizons, inhibit investment and dampen
growth perspectives (United Nations 2008: 4–5).
This chapter will start by reviewing the confusion that exists around the defi-
nition of a small state, before adopting the concept of relative size, as suggested
by the editors of this volume. It will then approach the question of economic
security by starting with the issues involved with insecurity. In the past decade
there has been a proliferation of composite indices covering almost all aspects of
economics, the environment and the social sciences, and the question of eco-
nomic vulnerability has not escaped this trend. Vulnerability is not simply a
function of size and therefore, after an examination of these indices – including
concrete examples of the states considered most and least vulnerable – the
chapter will focus on those aspects that may derive from the expectations of
small state literature. Having identified the source of security threats for smaller
economies, we shall turn to a discussion of factors that might mitigate their
Economic security and size 47
effects. This will start with the concept of resilience, or those structural factors
that may facilitate economic management under adverse conditions, before
examining some strategies available for overcoming the threats perceived.

The question of size


In the first chapter of this volume, the editors eschewed a cut-off point for defin-
ing a small state and clearly (and correctly) opted for a concept of relative size.
After all, if size is to be a useful explanatory factor in describing economies, it
should be applicable across the entire spectrum of the selected states when
ranked according to size. In other words ‘small’ should exhibit a certain charac-
teristic to a greater (or lesser) degree than ‘smaller still’ and ‘smaller still’
should, in its turn differ from ‘smallest’. We can always argue later whether it is
helpful to cluster states into any sub-categories as ‘small’, ‘middle’ or ‘large’.
That still leaves open the question of which indicator(s) to employ.
Since economists and political economists engaged in small state studies
commonly attempt to correlate size with economic performance, it is probably
better to avoid bringing gross domestic product (GDP) into the definition. Popu-
lation size is the most commonly used indicator, and the early literature settled
comfortably on a fairly arbitrary definition of around ten million (Sutton 2009:
142–146). More recently, however, there has been a shift in the focus of research
towards even smaller countries, with most literature settling on a cut-off point
around one and a half million (Commonwealth Advisory Group 1997; Common-
wealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force 2000; Liou and Ding 2002),
within a range from less than one million (Easterly and Kraay 2000) through to
three million (Armstrong and Read 1998). This new focus does not imply that
states beyond that cut-off point can be treated as an undifferentiated, relatively
homogeneous, contrasting bloc. Rather, it stems from a desire to concentrate on
the specific problems confronted by the ultra-small end of the spectrum, with a
high representation of developing isolated island economies.1 These countries
had also tended to be ignored in the empirical analysis and much recent work
has been devoted to recalibrating the focus of small state research.

Vulnerability
To determine what is meant by security, we need to know what exactly is meant
by insecurity. This is not to suggest that insecurity is the only paradigm from
which to approach the question of size, nor to insinuate that those structural ele-
ments that we identify as contributing to insecurity can only be resolved by
foreign aid or special concessions (Baldacchino and Bertram 2009: 141–142). It
is simply an attempt to define the potential problems before turning to possible
solutions. First, we should stress that insecurity is not synonymous with risk.
Every development that is not completely predictable is, by definition, risky, but
a risk can always have two outcomes – positive and negative. Insecurity implies
that there is a greater than average chance that, in a given situation, the outcomes
48 R.T. Griffiths
will be negative, and that it will be more than usually difficult to absorb the
effects. Thus insecurity implies a greater than otherwise risk of negative impact
of exogenous developments and a lack of mechanisms for coping with these
external shocks. Most authors opt for the term ‘vulnerability’ to capture this
mixture of elements (Combes and Guillaumont 2002; Seth and Ragab 2012).
For this chapter’s purposes, as already noted, we must confine ourselves to
macro-economic vulnerability and ignore the rich, interesting, and – in another
context – relevant literature on welfare impacts and household survival strategies
(Alwang et al. 2001). Further, we are interested in elements of vulnerability that
are functionally related to the size of a state – for instance, as relative smallness
exacerbates the impact of external shocks or diminishes the capacity to absorb
them. This qualification is important because many elements associated with
economic vulnerability are equally associated with poverty and under-
development. A small state that enjoys or attains more highly developed status
does not cease to be vulnerable, but the nature and degree of that vulnerability
may change. This distinction will also be important as we chart the various
attempts to construct tables of relative vulnerability.
The problems arising directly from size arise partly from the fact that produc-
tion is a function of available resources, whereas consumption is a function of
income levels (Snorrason 2012: 47–74). Thus the first expectation is that the
smaller the state, the more limited is likely to be its range of output. Small states
have supply constraints such as fewer resources (though strictly this is more a
function of area and geographical location than of size), less labour, a smaller
capital base and fewer entrepreneurs. They are also confronted by demand con-
straints, the most important of which is a domestic market too small to achieve
scale economies, and therefore less efficient (Kuznets 1960; Ward 1975; Roth-
schild 1993). But while a small state will not be producing a wide range of prod-
ucts, its consumption patterns will tend to reflect those of other economies with
a similar level of income. Thus the second expectation is that the smaller the size
of a state, the larger will be its propensity to import to meet its domestic con-
sumption and investment needs. This high level of import demand will force
smaller economies into export markets in order to earn the foreign exchange
necessary to meet the cost of imports (Kuznets 1960; Lloyd 1968; Väyrynen
1974; Alesina et al. 1997; Salvatore 1997; Armstrong and Read 1998; Common-
wealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force 2000; Armstrong 2002), but
here again, relative size can be expected to leave its mark on economic struc-
tures. Thus the third expectation is that the smaller the state, the more likely its
exports will be concentrated on a narrow range of export products, as the same
resource limitations that affected the diversity of output limit the diversity of
exports (Hirschman 1945; Kuznets, 1960; Commonwealth Secretariat/World
Bank Joint Task Force 2000; Jansen 2004).
Fourth and last, the smaller the state, the more likely that its exports will be
concentrated on a smaller group of countries, once again because of restrictions
in the amount of human capital available for international marketing. Despite
quibbles over one or two of these expectations (Väyrynen 1974; Damijan 1997),
Economic security and size 49
most studies conducted at various intervals, and with different samples of coun-
tries, have underlined their basic validity. Thus smaller countries tend to share
similar structural patterns deriving from their size and linked directly to their
trade dependence. However, these structural patterns do not necessarily translate
into factors of vulnerability (Baldacchino and Bertram 2009: 142). In many
cases, the factors that turn risk into vulnerability stem from under-development
rather than relative size.

Vulnerability indices
There has been a tendency, increasingly apparent in the last two decades, to try
to compress everything into compact, all-encompassing indexing systems.
Among the more famous are the United Nations Committee for Development
Policy’s Human Development Index and the World Bank’s Governance Indica-
tors. It would be disappointing if the discourse on vulnerability had not produced
a variant of its own: and indeed there are several ‘families’ of vulnerability
index, of which four will be compared and briefly analysed here. While the
present author is no enthusiast for experiments in quantitative data that yoke
heterogeneous ideas by violence together (to paraphrase Samuel Johnson’s
comment on metaphysical poetry), it is necessary and may be instructive to
understand why and how these attempts are made. What components are
included or omitted? What indicators are used and do they actually measure
what they claim to? And how are the components weighted to arrive at a single
index – arbitrarily, or by deriving the distribution endogenously? If the latter,
this is usually done by letting a multiple regression analysis loose on the data
and letting the outcome determine the weighting; but this then raises the ques-
tion of the representativity of the sample employed (Bishop 2012: 950–952).
The four sets of vulnerability indices covered here are: (1) a group concen-
trated on the Commonwealth; (2) a group concentrated on the University of
Malta; (3) a group associated with the UNDP; and (4) innovative approaches by
the Commonwealth and the IMF after the 2008 economic crash. For each, the
structure of the index is shown diagrammatically, while Table 3.1 compares the
sets of countries they identify as most and least vulnerable, looking at the com-
position of the ‘top’ and ‘bottom’ 15 in each case. The complete sets cannot be
listed here but full source directions will be given.
In the Commonwealth Family, a Small Island Developing States (SIDS)
meeting held in 1990 under the auspices of UNCTAD triggered the first serious
efforts towards developing a vulnerability index. The results, initially published
in 2001 (Atkins et al. 2001), assessed 111 developing countries, including 34
small states, under a composite index combining export dependence, lack of
diversification and proneness to natural disasters, with the emphasis on the first
(see Figure 3.1). Of the states judged most vulnerable, all but one would fall
below the Commonwealth’s cut-off line of 1.5 million inhabitants, and the
exception – Singapore – had only 2.8 million. No state with under 1.5 million
inhabitants finished among the least vulnerable. The final Commonwealth
50 R.T. Griffiths
Vulnerability Index took over the composite index in this form, but weighted it
further – without explaining the details – by ‘average gdp as a proxy for resil-
ience’ (Joint Task Force of the Commonwealth Secretariat and the World Bank
2000: 20). While some small states were more highly ranked this time and the
picture was blurred by including several states with over 1.5 million thought to
share typical ‘smallness’ problems, once more the great majority of ‘most vul-
nerable’ slots (26 out of 28) were occupied by small states, of which 18 were
small island developing states. Only two small states were in the top half of the
draw (ibid.: 20–23).
Meanwhile the Malta team, led by Lino Briguglio, were developing their own
Economic Vulnerability Index (EVI) (Brigulio 1995, 1997) and the results were
eventually published in 2003. The index was built up of indicators that shared
the openness and diversification concepts with the Commonwealth index, but
added proxies to represent peripherality and strategic import dependence whilst
omitting the disaster component. In contrast with the Commonwealth index,
which used raw data and model-determined weights, the Malta team first stand-
ardised the variables and then allocated equal weights in the index (see
Figure 3.2).
An adjusted index, EVIAR (EVI augmented by resilience), was also pro-
duced, which included resilience measured by per capita GDP and indeed gave
this 50 per cent of the weighting (Briguglio and Galea 2003). EVIAR’s 117
countries, of which 99 could be considered as developing countries, covered
only 18 of the 34 small developing states included in the Commonwealth list.
While the placing of medium/large countries changed considerably between EVI
and EVIAR – basically according to wealth – both had a clear preponderance of

Economic Exports goods and services


exposure percentage GDP
Weighed by
gdp to show
resilience

Export UNCTAD export


diversification diversification index

Vulnerability to Victims affected by


natural disasters natural disasters

1.4142 + 0.0096 vulnerability + 0.0322 export dependence + 3.3442 trade openness

Figure 3.1 Commonwealth Vulnerability Index (1999) (source: Atkins et al. 2000, 2001;
Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force 2000).
Economic security and size 51

Economic
Imports and exports
openness
as percentage GDP
1/4

Export Concentration
concentration exports goods
1/4 and services

Freight costs
Peripherality
and percentage
1/4
import value

Dependence Energy imports as


strategic imports percentage domestic
1/4 production

Figure 3.2 Economic Vulnerability Index (2003) (source: Briguglio and Galea 2003).

states with a population of under 1.5 million in the most vulnerable category: 9
and 10, respectively, in the bottom 15. The authors’ analysis (published only for
EVI) concluded that small developing island states (EVI 0.470) were more vul-
nerable than other small states (EVI 0.354), and both groups fared worse than
large developing states (EVI 0.220). The five small, developed states in the
sample (EVI 0.258) proved more vulnerable than large states, whether developed
(EVI 0.148) or developing (see Figure 3.3).

Export Mechandise 1/2


UNCTAD trade concentration
vulnerability
price instability indices
1/3 Services 1/2

FDI FDI potential 1/2 UNCTAD competitiveness index


vulnerability
1/3 Country of origin 1/2 Share of world FDI inflows

Mechandise 1/2
Import
UNCTAD trade concentration
vulnerability
price instability indices
1/3 Services 1/2

Figure 3.3 Economic Vulnerability Index (2005) (source: Cordina and Ferrugia 2005).
52 R.T. Griffiths
In 2005, the Malta team published a refined index (Cordina and Farrugia
2005) that improved on previous efforts by considering the impact of trade con-
centration in both exports and imports; by trying to capture exposure to price
volatility with a measure of product concentration in trade (distinguishing five
broad categories – food, agricultural raw materials, fuels, minerals and ores and
manufactures); and by attempting to capture the attraction of a country for
foreign direct investment (FDI). This was the first time that a financial variable
had appeared in an index. The results seemed to confirm the earlier studies’ find-
ings that vulnerability was inversely related to size, that small island states were
more vulnerable than any other category, and that vulnerability fell as countries
became richer (Cordina and Farrugia 2005: 17–18).2
In 1998 the United Nations Development Programme (henceforth UNDP)
also started work on an Economic Vulnerability Index (see Figure 3.4), designed
to let this variable be used – alongside per capita income and human capital
development – when deciding nations’ eligibility for aid. The version of this
index published in 2005 and re-used in 2008 is covered here; results of a 2011
update were not available at the time of writing.3 The index re-mixed many of
the elements present in the other indices we have examined, though the weights
attached differed. However, country size was directly built into the index, rather
than using openness, and no attempt was made to include resilience (Guillau-
mont 2010, 2011). The analysis of 112 developing countries suggested that
highly under-developed small country states are most vulnerable, followed by
other small island developing states (Guillaumont 2011: 839). No very large
states were considered vulnerable.
Up to this point, the logic of the various indices’ composition reflects their
origins in a community mainly concerned with development issues and their
impact on the smallest states. One striking feature, especially in the light of

Population
Size 1/2
Exposure
index Distance from main markets
Location 1/4
1/2
UNCTAD trade concentration
Specialization 1/4 index and percentage primary
products in GDP

Instability export earnings of


Trade shock
goods and services
1/2
Shock
index Homelessness after disasters
1/2
Natural shock
1/2 Instability agric. production

Figure 3.4 UNDP Economic Vulnerability Index (2005–2008) (source: Guillaumont 2009).
Table 3.1 Comparison of most/least vulnerable states from four international indexes (population sizes in millions)

Index name/abbreviation (see key) Commonwealth EVI/EVIAR REVI UNDP

Most vulnerable
Biggest Singapore (2.8) Rep. Congo (49.6)/Rep Congo Rep. Congo Zimbabwe (13)
Smallest Antigua + Barbuda (0.06) St Kitts Nevis (0.4)/Seychelles Reunion (0.7) Tuvalu (0.1)
Mode* Solomon Islands (0.3) Gambia (1.9)/Gambia Djibouti (0.7) Equatorial Guinea (0.5)
<1.5 million 14 of 15 9 of 15/10 out of 15 8 out of 15 7 out of 15
>15 million 0 of 15 1 of 15/1 out of 15 1 out of 15 0 out of 15
Least vulnerable
Biggest China (1,196) China/Indonesia (206) China China
Smallest Uruguay (3.1) Switzerland (7.1)/Luxembourg (0.436) Bhutan (0.5) Israel (0.7)
Mode* Myanmar (44.5) Turkey (63.6)/Netherlands (15.9) Nepal (24) Mexico (107.8)
<1.5 million 0 of 15 0 of 15/1 out of 15 1 out of 15 0 out of 15
>15 million 3 of 15 14 of 15/9 out of 15 8 out of 15 15 out of 15

Notes
* Mode – the middle observation, in this case the eighth country in terms of size.
Key: Commonwealth – Commonwealth Vulnerability Index for Developing Countries, calculated from Atkins et al. (2001).
EVIA/EVIAR – Economic Vulnerability Index/ditto Augmented by Resilience: calculated from Briguglio and Galea (2003); population for 2000 from World Bank
database.
REVI – Economic Vulnerability Index (2005), (Cordina and Farruglia 2005): calculated from country data supplied by authors; population for 2000 from World Bank
database.
UNDP – UNDP Economic Vulnerability Index 2005/8 (Guillaumont 2008).
54 R.T. Griffiths
events since 2008, is the absence of any financial dimension (Snieska et al.
2012). Although international monetary crises were hardly unknown before, the
Lehmann crisis and the financial meltdown that it signalled have finally con-
vinced major institutions of the need to re-assess vulnerability on a broader
basis. Since 2010, the Commonwealth has worked on a new index of which only
the outline is so far known, but which will add at least some new economic com-
ponents, e.g. inflation rates and the weight of debt service (see Figure 3.5). A
logistic performance index, which is more a measure of efficiency in trading
than of the actual costs of trade, is a further interesting addition, if somewhat
misplaced (Goto 2010).
A far more radical approach is evident in the new index Overall Vulnerability
Index being prepared by the IMF (see Figure 3.6). The contours of the index, but
no country results, have been published and reflect sweeping changes – only
trade exposure survives from earlier versions, and it accounts for hardly more
than one-eighth of the final index. Yet foreign indebtedness in the private sector,
as opposed to the government’s borrowing, is still absent from the calculation.
The country results will be very interesting to see, especially when matched
against the relative size of countries.

Components of vulnerability
Moving on from statistical depictions, the various factors determining vulner-
ability will now be discussed in substance to see how they contribute towards
undermining economic security – and what needs to be added for a satisfactory
framework of analysis.
Starting with the classics: trade dependence, of course, forces states onto
markets over which they have little or no control. In addition, smaller states are

Openness
Economic
Inflation
index Food import
Debt service

Environmental Natural disaster


index victim

Logistic performance
index
Insularity
Population size

Figure 3.5 Revised Commonwealth Vulnerability Index (2010) (source: Goto 2012).
Economic security and size 55

Government
Public sector balance 0.33
index Public debt 0.19
Real government
0.31
revenue 0.48

External
Reserves 0.58
sector index
0.25 Exports goods and
services 0.42

Real GDP growth


Overall 0.64
economy 0.55 Country policy and
institutional
assessment index 0.36

Figure 3.6 IMF Overall Vulnerability Index (2011) (source: Moghadam et al. 2011;
Dabla-Norrise and Gündüz 2012).

likely to be price-takers, although the threshold of exercising price leadership is


probably outside the capacity of most exporting nations acting alone. On the
other hand, a considerable empirical literature tends to emphasise the positive
relationship between openness and economic growth. Other authors stress the
role of openness in accentuating volatility, though the causal link usually runs
through adjustment costs aggravated by various dimensions of under-
development, rather than by openness per se (Montalbano 2011).
A second expectation deriving from small state literature is that there is a con-
centration on markets. However, the impact on vulnerability depends on which
countries trade is focused upon. In the 1930s, for example, it mattered a lot
whether a European state’s trade was directed primarily towards Germany or
towards the UK. Similarly, a Latin American country, reliant on the US market,
would have suffered when demand there slumped and tariffs increased. Now-
adays, exposure to other countries’ trade policies is less relevant, but it still
matters whether an economy is oriented towards faster or towards slower
growing markets. So, for a smaller country, the focus on/in Western Europe in
the 1950s and 1960s would have been better than a similar focus in the 1990s
and 2000s, whereas the reverse would be true for a focus on South Asia. This is
not a merely anecdotal observation: a ‘constant market share’ (CMS) analysis
allows a prediction of export growth rates based on an observed geographical
pattern, assuming that the share in each of those markets remains unchanged
(Finicelli et al. 2008)
The lack of a diversified production structure is also reflected in a product
concentration in exports. Export composition concentration is a standard expec-
tation in small state literature, but as such it need not be a source of vulnerability,
56 R.T. Griffiths
and certainly not an undifferentiated one. The link to vulnerability is twofold. In
the first place, one could expect that countries with a concentration in goods for
which world demand was growing slowly would be penalized through slower
growth than experienced by those countries with a more favourable export com-
position. This factor would penalize countries by sluggish demand, lack of dyna-
mism and semi-stagnant status, especially when combined with a high export
reliance as a component in final demand. Such an impact could be calculated
using the CMS techniques described above. However, it is not just the trend rate
of growth that is affected in this way: the product composition of exports also
affects the stability or volatility of export earnings because price swings are
more common in some commodities than in others. This is especially true if
exports are concentrated in primary products – agricultural goods and minerals –
which are more susceptible to price fluctuations than manufactured goods (UN
2008: 15–16, 24–25). Most of the vulnerability indices use the UNCTAD export
concentration index, sometimes broadened to embrace services (Briguglio and
Galea), but without any differentiation.
Cordina and Ferrugia go a step further and also use the UNCTAD commodity
volatility index, which gives a statistical measure of the degree of price fluctu-
ation. Commodity prices after World War II were in relative decline until the
1970s and 1980s, when they began a slow climb before exploding since the turn
of the century. But not all prices underwent the same development and therefore
not all countries experienced the same impact (Erten and Ocampo 2012; Spata-
fora and Tytell 2009). What Cordina and Ferrugia have done is to break exports
into five main export groups (food, agricultural raw materials, fuels, ores and
metals, manufactures) and to calculate an overall index by weighting each cat-
egory by its share in exports (Cordina and Ferrugia 2005). This is an excellent
innovation because it means, for example, that based on 2002–2011 data, a
country with all its exports in ores and metals would have had volatility index of
21.65, whereas those focused in food would have experienced a volatility index
of only 7.03. However, to really operationalize the concept, one could have gone
further and looked at the differences in price volatility experienced by individual
commodities.4 This would have revealed important differences and would have
had a major impact on any vulnerability index, especially when applied to less
developed countries whose export concentration usually lies outside
manufactures.5
If one looks at issues that do not appear in the traditional small state liter-
ature, susceptibility to disasters and isolation appear in some of the indices. Vul-
nerability to disasters is a factor in the Commonwealth index and, slightly more
prominently, in the UNDP index. Although with any given disaster, a small
polity will be left with a smaller area unaffected and therefore able to facilitate
recovery, susceptibility to disaster is in itself much more a factor of geography.
It depends on whether the state is situated in a typhoon or hurricane zone or
along an earthquake line. For small island states lying in the tropics, it is prob-
ably a factor to consider and it might make sense to include it in an index of vul-
nerability. For a global consideration of vulnerability, it is less important.
Economic security and size 57
Isolation also appears in vulnerability indices but, again, this is more a question
of geography than size. Once more, small states that are islands tend to be dis-
proportionately represented, but larger states, too, can be confronted by market
remoteness. One need only to look at Australia to see, within a large country in
terms of area or a medium country in terms of population, the distances separat-
ing major cities, and therefore markets, from each other.
A final factor that appears in some of the indices is per capita income. It is
used in the early Commonwealth index and in the Malta index as a proxy for
resilience. Richer states are supposed to have more resources and more capacity
to cope with the impact of negative shocks. By itself, however, it is a crude
indicator of state capacity. There are many more nuanced indicators available to
identify resilience and it should come as no surprise that, here too, there are
efforts to capture it in an index of its own.

Resilience
Resilience as a concept has been taken to embrace two associated issues, namely
the ability to withstand an exogenous shock should one occur, and the ability to
respond to a crisis should it develop. The first depends on mechanisms of flex-
ibility and adaptability and the second depends on the quality of governance and
the policy options available (Briguglio et al. 2009: 233–234) The Malta group
has constructed a resilience index based around four elements, macro-economic
stability, market efficiency, good governance and social development (see
Figure 3.7).

Fiscal deficit
Macroeconomic
stability Unemployment rate
1/4 Inflation rate
External debt

Market efficiency Economic Freedom Index


1/4 component on credit, labour
and business

Good Economic Freedom Index


governance component on legal structure
1/4 and security property rights

Social Human Development Index


development Education and health
1/4

Figure 3.7 Economic Resilience Index (2009) (source: Briguglio et al. 2009).
58 R.T. Griffiths
The index represents a brave attempt to push research further forward, but one
can still pose some questions about both the components isolated and the indica-
tors chosen to represent them. For a start, the items chosen to represent macro-
economic stability (fiscal deficit, unemployment and inflation and the weight of
external debt) all appear in the IMF Vulnerability Index as factors to be taken
into account in a state’s initial risk assessment. Second, the indices chosen to
represent good governance seem unnecessarily restrictive, especially when the
more famous and more authoritative World Bank Governance Indicators are
available. Similarly, to describe social development solely in terms of education
and health, derived from the UN’s Human Development Index, seems unneces-
sarily parsimonious when it must surely have been possible to employ other
indicators, such as income inequality or social welfare expenditure. The Malta
index was constructed for 86 countries, both developing and advanced, but
covered none of the small island developing states with populations of less than
1.5 million, as defined by the UNDP (see Table 3.2).
If one looks at the most vulnerable countries, it is obvious that very small
countries are notable by their absence. The smallest country to appear has a
population a little above five million. The obverse is almost true of the most
resilient list where all but four of the top 15 have populations below ten million,
and all the countries in the top portion of the list can be classified as advanced
economies.

Security strategies
Thus our analysis so far suggests that small states are more vulnerable than large
states, but developed small states seem often to be more resilient than large
developed states. The irony of Iceland and Ireland appearing in the top of the
resilience index at the very moment that their economies were collapsing is not
an indication that the index is at fault, but of the fact that these states were vul-
nerable in a way that was not adequately captured by the existing indices – nor,
to be honest, in economic analyses preceding the Lehmann crash of 2007.
Small(er) states were quickly drawn into the vortex of the financial crisis. A
recent OECD study suggests that their inability to control monetary policy

Table 3.2 Fifteen most and fifteen least vulnerable states in the Economic Resilience
Index 2009 (population size, thousands)

Least resilient Most resilient

Biggest Indonesia (277,303) Canada (32,312)


Smallest Nicaragua (5,424) Iceland (297)
Mode Uganda (28,431) Hong Kong (107,801)
<1.5 million 1 out of 15 1 out of 15
>15 million 13 out of 15 2 out of 15

Source: (Briguglio 2009). Population for 2005 from World Bank database, available online at: http://
data.worldbank.org/indicator/SP.POP.TOTL?page=2 (accessed 25 November 2013).
Economic security and size 59
(especially in a monetary union) meant that asset prices outstripped interest rates
and fuelled the construction bubbles in Ireland, Spain and Portugal. Moreover,
even if they did have recourse to monetary instruments, raising interest rates
would most probably have sucked in capital and negated the intended effect
(Sutherland et al. 2010: 15, 28). A further problem is that the traditional fiscal
policy instruments available to larger countries are likely to be muted in their
effect when applied in smaller economies. This is because much of the multiplier
effect of an injection of state spending is likely to be lost to leakages through
imports (ibid.: 26). One way out is to practise fiscal prudence and use ‘automatic
stabilizers’ to absorb the initial impact of the shock (Buti and Van den Noord
2004: 13, 16), and the OECD study specifically compliments Denmark, the
Netherlands and Switzerland for a successful policy of combining ‘initial cush-
ioning with a quick adjustment’ (Sutherland et al. 2010: 44).
The small state literature suggests that (richer) smaller states have developed
successful security strategies that may not shield them from powerful economic
forces emanating from abroad, but which allow them successfully to adapt. In
his classic study of small European economies, Peter Katzenstein argued that the
paramount need for small countries to remain competitive contributed directly to
their development of high welfare expenditure and neo-corporatist governance
structures. Potentially damaging private wage demands were bought off with
public goods, including a voice in policy making, and welfare payments eased
the risk to citizens in making structural adjustments to the economy. Consensus
was more easily achieved around policy measures and inefficient, rent-seeking
sectors were more readily sacrificed as industrial policy targeted potential growth
areas (Katzenstein 1985; see also Midttun et al. 2006). Criticised by those who
interpreted this as prescriptive rather than descriptive, Katzenstein later modified
this position to stress that the main advantage available to small states lay in
their ability to adapt quickly to changing circumstances, which was itself a
reflection of the social cohesion that they had been able to engineer (Katzenstein
2003).
Another insight was afforded by comparing (European) small countries with
neighbouring regions of larger countries. This is made possible by the regional
counting procedures adopted by the European Union. In almost every case and
in almost every measure of performance, the small state did better than the
neighbouring region, despite having all the apparent disadvantages of market
size and none of the fall-back options of transfer payments and support from
central government. The compensatory advantage, it was suggested, was to be
found in the independence of a small state in defining its own sectoral and other
meso-economic policies (Armstrong and Read 1998).
Thus, smaller richer states have the advantages of possessing economic
resources to sustain good governance structures and to support strong social
cohesion around policies of adjustment and adaptation. Their position is a far cry
from the picture of the small island developing states in the Pacific and the
Caribbean that is painted by the Commonwealth, World Bank and UNDP.
Indeed, there is no barrier to their adopting the same governance practices and
60 R.T. Griffiths
encouraging the same strategic adaptability as demonstrated by the states with
the main success stories in Western Europe and elsewhere. In a challenge to the
institutional pessimism of the vulnerability school, Baldacchino and Bertram
(2009) suggest that this is exactly what many of them are already doing. They
thus do not lack strategies for economic security and, without being exhaustive,
in the rest of this chapter we will attempt to cover some of these, starting with
vulnerabilities stemming from the classical ‘small state’ literature.
Most literature stresses that foreign trade dependence is more of an advantage
than a structural disadvantage; but it is, per se, unpredictable and leaves coun-
tries especially vulnerable to policy changes by major trading partners. One solu-
tion is to tie oneself as closely as possible to one major trading partner, if
possible through a customs union or else through another form of preferential
trading arrangement (Mansfield and Reinhardt 2008). This was a prime motiva-
tion of the Benelux countries in the early stages of European integration. What-
ever loss of independence this entails in trade policy is outweighed by
constraining the possibly damaging autonomous decisions of the other (often
larger) party. Small states love international agreements, the more complex and
more binding the better.
This brings us to the volatility in export earnings caused by an extreme reli-
ance on particular primary products. This has been referred to in the literature as
a ‘resource curse’, but recent research on the period since 1970 (when the price
trend was upwards) has suggested that the long-term effects of abundant
resources on growth have been positive. It is the short-term instability that
creates the problem (Cavalcanti et al. 2012). One answer would be to combine
with similar producers and form an international commodity agreement cartel,
but past experience suggests that this is rarely a permanent solution. In some
cases, prices are stabilised at too high a level, and this attracts outside competi-
tors, as has been the case with OPEC. In others, the high prices stimulated over-
production and the agreement collapsed because it could not bear the costs of
maintain ever-growing stockpiles – coffee and tin are good examples. Another
danger is that individual members start ‘cheating’ by increasing their own output
to take full benefit of high prices maintained by everyone else restricting theirs,
as proved the case in the international steel cartel between the world wars.
If an international solution is not an option for the problem of price volatility,
then a stabilization fund offers another option. In this case, one puts (part of ) the
government’s income in good years into a savings account upon which it can
draw when prices are low. This does mean sacrificing the option to employ the
same resources for investment, for example in economic diversification (UN
2008: 45–48). Moreover, if the idea is simple, the implementation is fraught with
difficulties. Politicians being what they are, there will inevitably be a temptation
to use the account to reward party allies and to buy votes in the build-up to elec-
tions. And dictators being who they are, there is always a temptation to add a
wing to a palace, to buy yet another pair of shoes or to add a few more noughts
to a Swiss bank account. But a greater temptation is to assume that an upward
trend is permanent, and to abandon the programme prematurely.6
Economic security and size 61
The solutions described for the volatility issue are really ‘coping’ mechan-
isms. The way to obtain greater security in the longer term is to diversify output
and sources of export earnings. A recent review explained that ‘for most devel-
oping countries, economic insecurity is first and foremost a development chal-
lenge (that) calls for economic diversification and policies that foster productive
investment’ (UN 2008: 7). This does not necessarily mean developing a whole
new range of commodity exports or even commercializing some colourful local
custom to attract the odd cruise ship for a stop-over. Rather, attracting some
foreign direct investment to allow the development of a link or component in an
international supply chain may be sufficient to stimulate the economy and estab-
lish the beginnings of a niche sector. Of course, for that to happen, the invest-
ment climate must be favourable: namely, stable, transparent, well regulated and
predictable. And this is often where the problems really start.
There is a large body of literature associating good governance with growth.
In this respect, the relatively small high-tax, high-spend welfare-ist economies of
Western Europe appear to offer affirmation of this relationship. The World Bank
is among the leading advocates of improved governance structures as a route out
of under-development. The amount of investment capital slushing round the
international system dwarfs the sums available in development aid. Moreover,
private capital not only helps close the investment gap, but it often comes
accompanied by the latest technology and the human capital to make it all work.
The problem is that although there is a strong statistical relationship between
governance and growth, there is far more debate about the direction of the cau-
sality. A society that can afford to pay its officials enough to stop them being
pulled into corruption, and that can staff its services so that they function well,
can afford good governance. Meanwhile, endemic corruption, capricious
decision-making, cronyism and nepotism are a blight over almost all developing
economies, large or small. And, as long as that state of affairs is allowed to
prevail, economic security will remain a distant dream for small developing
states.

Reflections
Small states, despite their inherent vulnerability, still tend to perform relatively
well in economic terms. Armstrong and Read (1998) have demonstrated that
small states in Western Europe outperform the neighbouring regions in larger
states. Baldacchino and Bertram (2009: 147–150) raid the library of available
statistical indicators to demonstrate the robustness of small state performance.
Most recently, in an up-to-date literature review, Bishop (2012: 949) summar-
ized the state of play by declaring that ‘almost all small states are doing “better”
developmentally than the least-developed countries in the world, some spectacu-
larly so’.
In looking at the economic security of small states, the nature of the vulner-
ability makes it difficult to predict the direction and timing of a threat. The con-
sciousness of potential vulnerability, if it fosters the ability to isolate a security
62 R.T. Griffiths
challenge, is in fact a precondition for the preparation of strategies to mitigate its
impact or preferably avoid it altogether. In this respect, one can question the use-
fulness of a composite index and even the relevance of some of the proxy indica-
tors it contains.
Another reflection is that the nature of security threats, or rather the perception
of them, has changed. There has been a remarkable shift in the last decade from
trade-related to finance-related crises, and this is being incorporated into the new
indices being conceived. However, it is rather unsettling to see the IMF abandon-
ing all the earlier trade-related features and employing exclusively financial and
monetary variables – unless it is intended simply to reflect that particular threat dir-
ection. Composite indices tend to be better when they are not too dispersed and the
IMF index might be an ideal instrument for a more restricted goal.
Small state studies today are thus waking up to the new threats inherent in
globalization, and seeing that ‘casino capitalism’ (Strange 1986) is not a place
for players with small pockets. The next time a financial crisis occurs, we will be
able to test our indices against it, but it is less certain whether having such an
index will help us avoid it. More to the point, however, is that we should stop
becoming mesmerized by yesterday’s threats. Other chapters in this book point,
for example, to environmental threats arising from climate shifts, and other
natural hazards such as pandemics, that have yet to make an appearance in the
economics-oriented vulnerability/resilience debate. There are further risks, such
as the potential threat to the world’s critical cyber-infrastructure or the exposure
of the world’s GPS systems to the incidence of sun-flares, that will have untold
economic consequences. Here again, the size and sophistication of economies
will be determinants in the construction of adequate defences and the capacity
for restoration. These areas, too, still need to penetrate the literature. . . . But in
separate indices, please.

Notes
1 In 1992 the UN Conference on Environment and Development, held in Rio de Janeiro,
acknowledged the particular problems faced by small island developing states (SIDS)
and two years later the first Global Conference on the Sustainable Development of
Small Island States was held in Barbados. The conference set up a permanent frame-
work for research and cooperation among the SIDS and also established criteria for
membership. It recommended a maximum size for inclusion in the group of 1.5 million,
and linked this to a threshold of per capita income (Commonwealth Advisory Group
1997). A group of countries also pressed within the World Trade Organization (WTO)
for recognition of their special status and the need for new trade rules to accommodate
their problems. This need was recognized at the Doha Ministerial meeting in 2001,
which opened the way for special treatment. However, difficulty in agreeing either on
the exact criteria needed to qualify for special treatment or on the nature of such con-
cessions kept the issue on the agenda for the next decade – and has kept the research
agenda alive ever since (Corrales-Leal et al. 2007).
2 The Malta team have also produced an ‘Economic Resilience’ index, which is dis-
cussed separately later and which gives interestingly different results.
3 Details of the methodological changes in 2011 are available online at: www.un.org/en/
development/desa/policy/cdp/ldc/ldc_criteria_timeline.pdf (accessed 15 January 2013).
Economic security and size 63
4 It is obviously not good to be concentrated in ores and metals, but if the output was
gold, the index would have been only 6.11. Equally, food might have been compara-
tively stable but if exports comprised sugar, the volatility would have been 17.24. Sim-
ilarly, agricultural raw materials might have been a tranquil 8.31, but a focus on cotton
would have pushed the index up to 19.47. Data derived from http://unctadstat.unctad.
org/ReportFolders/reportFolders.aspx (accessed 25 November 2013).
5 For manufactures it is difficult to determine prices, since goods are rarely homogeneous.
They usually fluctuate less in price and any changes, if they are calculated, are measured
through the terms-of-trade, which capture price changes of imports relative to exports;
this is much less refined and suitable for incorporation into a vulnerability index.
6 The Commonwealth/World Bank was particularly supine in this context. While
acknowledging the problem and the availability of the solution (which has been around
since the 1930s), it hides behind costs and lack of experience, and leaves recommenda-
tions to yet another task-force (Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task
Force 2000, pp. 26–27).

Bibliography
Alesina, A., Spolaore, E. and Wacziarg, R. (1997) ‘Economic Integration and Political
Disintegration’, NBER working paper no. 6163, Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Alwang, J., Siegel, P.B. and Jorgensen, S.L. (2001) Vulnerability: A View from Different
Disciplines, Social Protection Discussion Paper Series, 0155, Washington, DC.
Armstrong, H. (2002) ‘The Phantom of Liberty? Economic Growth and the Vulnerability
of Small States’, Journal of International Development, 14: 435–458.
Armstrong, H. and Read, R. (1998) ‘Trade and Growth in Small States: The Impact of
Global Trade Liberalisation’, The World Economy, 21(4): 563–585.
Atkins, J.P., Mazzi, S.A. and Easter, C.D. (2000) ‘Commonwealth Vulnerability Index for
Developing Countries’, economic paper no. 40, London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Baldacchino, G. and Bertram, G. (2009) ‘The Beak of the Finch: Insights into the Eco-
nomic Development of Small Economies’, The Round Table: Commonwealth Journal
of International Affairs, 98(401): 141–160.
Bishop, M.L. (2012) ‘The Political Economy of Small States: Enduring Vulnerability’,
Review of International Political Economy, 19(5): 942–990.
Briguglio, L. (1995) ‘Small Island States and their Economic Vulnerabilities’, World
Development, 23(9): 1615–1632.
Briguglio, L. (1997) ‘Alternative Economic Vulnerability Indices for Developing Coun-
tries’, report prepared for the Expert Group on Vulnerability Index, United Nations
Department of Economic and Social Affairs-UN(DESA), December 1997.
Briguglio, L. and Galea, W. (2003) ‘Updating and Augmenting the Economic Vulner-
ability Index’, occasional paper by the Islands and Small States Institute of the Univer-
sity of Malta.
Briguglio, L., Cordina, G., Farrugia, N. and Vella, S. (2009) ‘Economic Vulnerability and
Resilience: Concepts and Measurements’, Oxford Development Studies, 37(3):
229–247.
Buti, M. and Van den Noord, P. (2004) ‘Fiscal Policy in the EMU. Rules, Discretion and
Political Incentives’, European Commission, DG for Economic and Financial Affairs,
economic paper, no. 206.
Cavalcanti, T.V., Mohaddes, K and Raissi, M. (2012) ‘Commodity Price Volatility and
the Sources of Growth’, IMF working paper WP/12/12.
64 R.T. Griffiths
Combes, J.-L. and Guillaumont, P. (2002) ‘Commodity Price Volatility, Vulnerability
and Development’, Development Policy Review, 20(1): 25–39.
Commonwealth Advisory Group (1997) A Future for Small States: Overcoming Vulner-
ability, London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Commonwealth Secretariat/World Bank Joint Task Force on Small States (2000) Small
States: Meeting Challenges in the Global Economy, Washington, DC.
Cordina, G. and Ferrugia, N. (2005) ‘Measuring Vulnerability: A Methodological Review
and refinement Based on Partner Country and Price Volatility Issues’, Occasional
papers on islands and small states, 2/2005, University of Malta.
Corrales-Leal, W., Baritto, F. and Mohan, S.A. (2007) ‘Special and Differential Treat-
ment for Small and Vulnerable Countries based on the Situational Approach’, ICTSD
issue paper no. 2, Geneva.
Dabla-Norris, E. and Gündüz, Y.B. (2012) ‘Exogenous Shocks and Growth Crises in
Low-Income Countries: A Vulnerability Index’, IMF working paper WP/12/264.
Damijan, J.P. (1997) ‘Main Economic Characteristics of Small Countries: Some Empiri-
cal Evidence’, Development and International Cooperation, 13(24/25): 43–84.
Easterly, W. and Kraay, A. (2000) ‘Small states, Small Problems? Income, Growth, and
Volatility in Small States’, World Development, 28(11): 2013–2027, available online at:
www.worldbank.org/research/growth/pdfiles/kraay1.pdf (accessed 15 January 2013).
Erten, B. and Ocampo, J.A. (2012) ‘Super-cycles of Commodity Prices Since the mid-
nineteenth Century’, DESA working paper no. 112.
Finicelli, A., Sbracia, M. and Zaghini, A. (2008) ‘A Disaggregated Analysis of the Export
performance of some Industrial and Emerging Countries’, MPRA discussion paper, 92.
Goto, M. (2010) ‘Commonwealth Composite Vulnerability Index’, presentation at Bien-
nial Small States Meeting, Marlborough House, London, 28–29 July 2010.
Guillaumont, P. (2008) ‘An Economic Vulnerability Index: Its Design and Use for Inter-
national Development Policy’, Helsinki: UNU-WIDER research paper.
Guillaumont, P. (2010) ‘Assessing the Economic Vulnerability of Small island Develop-
ing States and the Least Developed Countries’, Journal of Development Studies, 46(5):
828–854.
Guillaumont, P. (2011) ‘The Concept of Structural Economic Vulnerability and its Relev-
ance for the Identification of Least Developed Countries and other Purposes (Nature,
Measurement and Evolution)’, CDP background paper 12, ST/ESA/2011/CDP/1.
Hirschman, A.O. (1945) National power and the Structure of Foreign Trade, Berkeley:
University of California Press.
Jansen, M. (2004) ‘Income Volatility in Small and Developing Economies: Export Con-
centration Matters’, WTO discussion paper no. 3.
Katzenstein P.J. (1985) Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe,
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Katzenstein, P.J. (2003) ‘ “Small States” and Small States Revisited’, New Political
Economy, 8(1): 9–30.
Kuznets, S. (1960) ‘Economic Growth of Small Nations’, in Robinson, E.A.G. (ed.) Eco-
nomic Consequences of the Size of Nations, London: Macmillan.
Liou, F.M. and Ding, C.G. (2002) ‘Subgrouping Small States Based on Socio-Economic
Characteristics’, World Development, 30(7):1289–1306.
Lloyd, P.J. (1968) International Trade Problems of Small Nations, Durham, NC: Duke
University Press.
Mansfield, E.D. and Reinhardt, E. (2008) ‘International Institutions and the Volatility of
International Trade’, International Organization, 46(4): 621–652.
Economic security and size 65
Midttun, A., Gautesen, K. and Gjolberg, M. (2006) ‘The Political Economy of Corporate
Social Responsibility in Western Europe’, Corporate Governance, 6(4): 369–385.
Moghadam, R., Cottarelli, C. and and Ostry, J. (2011) ‘Managing Volatility: A Vulner-
ability Exercise for Low-Income Countries’, paper prepared by the Strategy, Policy,
and Review, Fiscal Affairs, and Research Departments, Washington, available online
at: www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/030911.pdf (accessed 25 November 2013).
Montalbano, P. (2011) ‘Trade Openness and Developing Countries’ Vulnerability: Con-
cepts, Misconceptions and Directions for Research’, World Development, 39(9):
1489–1502.
Rothschild, K.W. (1993) ‘Kleinstaat und Interdependenz. Anmerkungen zur Klienstaaten-
theorie aus oekonomischer Sicht’ in Waschkuhn, A. (ed.) Kleinstaat: Grundsätzliche
und aktuelle Probleme, Vaduz: 71–87.
Salvatore, D. (1997) ‘The Economic Performance of Small versus Large Nations’, Devel-
opment and International Cooperation, 13(24–25): 21–42.
Seth, A. and Ragab, A. (2012) ‘Macroeconomic Vulnerability in Developing Countries:
Approaches and Issues’, IPC-IP working paper no. 94.
Snieska, V., Draksaite, A. and Zaburaite, D. (2012) ‘The Peculiarities of Contemporary
Management of Foreign Debt in a Small Open Economy’, Economics and Manage-
ment, 17(3): 1042–1048.
Snorrason, S.T. (2012) Asymmetric Economic Integration: Contributions to Economics,
Berlin and Heidelberg: Springer-Verlag.
Spatafora, N. and Tytell, I (2009) ‘Commodity Terms of trade: The History of Booms
and Busts’, IMF working paper WP/09/205.
Strange, S. (1986) Casino Capitalism, Oxford: Blackwell.
Sutherland, D., Hoeller, D., Égert, B and Röhn, O. (2010) ‘Counter-cyclical Economic
Policy’, OECD Economics Department working paper no. 760.
Väyrynen, R. (1974) ‘The Position of Small Powers in the West European Network of
Economic Relations’, European Journal of Political Research, 2: 143–178.
United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs (2008) World Economic and
Social Survey, Overcoming Economic Insecurity, New York: United Nations.
Ward, M (1975) ‘Dependent Development – Problems of Economic Planning in Small
Developing Countries’ in Selwyn, P. (ed.) Development Policy in Small Countries,
London: Croom Helm Ltd, pp. 115–133.
4 Societal security and small states
Alyson J.K. Bailes

Introduction and outline


Other chapters in this section have stressed that security today is a multi-faceted
affair, with an equally complex range of possible solutions. For small states,1
these solutions will almost always mean ‘importing’ or ‘buying’ support and
assistance, but they need not always shop in the same place. As Chapter 2 points
out, earlier discussions of small state security focused on challenges of military
or ‘hard’ security, of a sort that actually confront rather few small states – at
least in Europe – today.2 When a small state looks instead for economic, environ-
mental, energy or health security (for example), its judgements on the range of
potential shelters and helpers, and the best potential bargains in partnership, will
diverge from the old answers and probably also vary from case to case. Yet a
small state still has just one government, one budget and one limited store of
political capital to expend on securing its needs. Are there any ‘package’
approaches to security that might help such a state systematize its analysis, and
make good choices on priorities, synergies and resource allocation, across the
whole strategic spectrum?
One answer explored in this chapter is the concept of ‘societal security’, first
developed by academics in the late twentieth century, and now used as a policy
doctrine by states in Northern Europe. The next section explains what it means
in theory and practice, including how it differs from other major security con-
cepts. The third section asks why the societal security approach might suit small
states and how it could help them. To balance this, the fourth discusses some
conceptual and practical challenges inherent in such a policy, and the final
section has the brief conclusions.

Societal security: what and why?

Theoretical origins and comparisons


The seminal work behind recent academic debates on societal security is Barry
Buzan’s People, States and Fear, first published in 1991 and re-issued in 2008
(Buzan 1991; see also Buzan et al. 1998). In this book, Buzan adopted ‘societal’
Societal security and small states 67
security as one of five large sub-divisions of modern security, the others being
political, military, economic and environmental. He was especially interested in
the often tangled relations between security actors, where the state may prosper
at its citizens’ expense and vice versa. In this context, the ‘societal’ category
allowed Buzan to probe security transactions lying somewhere between the
national/governmental and the individual level. For most states today, society
has become a complex construct with values, security concerns and also capabil-
ities of its own. When under challenge, it may also mobilize its own members
and sub-groups such as private businesses, non-governmental organizations,
churches, or the media. This latter point is central to the distinction between
societal security, where society is both the referent body and potential actor, and
social security, which denotes state support for the individual.
The societal approach also differs in important ways from other established
frameworks of security analysis. It diverges most clearly from the traditional
realist view inasmuch as it focuses elsewhere than the state, qualifies the lat-
ter’s supposed monopoly of security actorness and takes rather little interest in
inter-state power transactions (though it may stimulate non-zero-sum inter-
state cooperation). To protect society, a state needs as a minimum to control
its territory; but its prowess in zero-sum international competition does not
necessarily help its citizens and may even penalize them. By extension,
military issues feature, if at all, only in a contingent and limited way in soci-
etal security. Except where an internal conflict needs to be resolved, national
forces will contribute mainly by their support in non-warlike civil disasters.
Societal concerns will then focus more on non-warlike forms of violence
(crime, street disturbances, terrorism where applicable); and on accidents,
natural disasters, epidemics, and social/economic stresses and weaknesses,
including the vulnerability of infrastructure.3
The same non-military topics could of course be gathered under the heading
of ‘Homeland Security’ in the USA, or ‘internal security’ and ‘home affairs’ in
Europe. But these terms have often signalled a technical or managerial approach
based on executive and expert authority. The societal approach gives more
weight to subjective factors including both society’s positive norms and hopes,
and the protection of citizens against oppression or disruption from whatever
source. While zeal for ‘homeland’ security can demonstrably lead to curbs on
popular rights and freedoms, in societal security the ‘normal’, peaceful function-
ing of society becomes an end in itself. A societal approach thus includes the
fine-tuning of protective measures to avoid damaging the social fabric more than
strengthening it.
The doctrine of human security that has spread in popularity after featuring in
a UNDP report of 1994 (UNDP 1994) also consciously rejects the realist
approach, taking instead the human being as the object and measure of good or
bad security. It covers much the same potential range of hazards to human life
and quality of life as societal security does: but by focusing on the isolated indi-
vidual, it tends to highlight human exposure and vulnerability. Its policy conclu-
sions accordingly call for international help – including forceful intervention if
68 A.J.K. Bailes
necessary4 – rather than asking how people can help themselves and each other.
Societal security, by contrast, assumes that most individuals are embedded in
(possibly, multiple) groups within and beyond their own states, the functions of
which include protecting them against undue interference from any quarter.
Against this background it is interesting that developed Western states typic-
ally reserve the discourse of ‘human security’ for poor and weak states rather
than applying it to themselves. The cynical explanation is that it provides a
further rationale for interventions they may want to undertake for less pure
reasons. Probably, however, there is an unconscious double standard, whereby
Westerners elevate the value of their own social forms, while underplaying the
risks of high development and complexity itself (Bailes 2007). An urbanized,
materialistic Western society may actually leave the individual more exposed
and alienated than a poorer one where family and tribal links, as well as basic
survival skills, are stronger. It might thus be revealing to experiment with ‘soci-
etal’ analysis of non-Western systems, while opening eyes to ‘human’ security
problems persisting in the West itself.

Concept development5
In the 1990s, Buzan quickly updated his own concept to recognize that societal
security included, rather than contrasted with, other dimensions like the eco-
nomic and environmental: the true dichotomy was between society and the state.
But what was concretely different about societal agendas? In a European climate
of thought dominated by war in the Balkans, attention naturally focused on the
needs of societal communities not co-terminous with the state, such as ethnic
(and/or religious) groups that stretched across borders and sometimes challenged
the state they were supposed to belong to. Conversely, an established more
homogenous society could feel threatened by migration and cultural dilution
(Wæver et al. 1993). These emphases led to expert debates over how to judge
the reality of self-claimed ‘communities’, and how to cope with possibly plural
‘identities’. More seriously, it was pointed out that ethnic nationalism and fear of
the cultural ‘other’ were often forces for insecurity, and not necessarily an ethi-
cally superior yardstick6 (McSweeney 1996).
Buzan’s other seminal notion of ‘securitization’ may help in rising above this
confusion. As explained in Chapter 2,7 securitization theory asks how and by
whom a security challenge is defined. Often, it is national leaders who put such
labels on new developments in hopes of gaining permission to handle them by
tougher-than-normal methods. But the same process can work bottom-up, if
society demands tough official action on a popular concern such as the cultural,
economic, or other impacts of immigration – which the government may have its
own reasons for tolerating, or at least, may prefer to handle by non-securitized
means (Huysmans 2000; Ibryamova 2002). Such societal demands are not neces-
sarily more objective, wise or reasonable than top-down security ‘labelling’.
Indeed, they may obscure other objectively valid security concerns, such as the
threats and risks that immigrants themselves are exposed to.
Societal security and small states 69
Setting a practical agenda
What is clear is that, if only on practical grounds, a state wanting a sustainable
security policy cannot define the threat simply as whatever society imagines at
the time (which also begs the question, Who speaks for society?). It must resist
unreasonable or transient bottom-up demands: including those that discriminate
between or damage other components in society,8 but also those exceeding a
government’s power (e.g. an expectation of total protection for all citizens trav-
elling abroad). At the same time, it must induce taxpayers to fund things
(military and other) that the experts consider necessary, but which bring no
obvious benefit to citizens in their daily lives.
For these and other reasons, the ‘societal security’ used as a policy denomina-
tor by such states as Norway and Sweden has come to differ greatly from the
conceptual topic of Buzan’s, Wæver’s, and related writings. Typically, govern-
ments have evaded the pitfalls of societal ‘identity’ by trying to frame the agenda
in more precise, concrete, administratively and financially feasible terms. In turn,
a separate scholarly literature has grown up on the challenges and implications
of this official approach, as seen notably in the large Norwegian SAMRISK
cooperative research programme.9 We shall now look at Nordic examples of
how the concept has been re-framed in practice.
Norway’s central government website defines societal security as comprising
‘events that threaten central societal institutions, our common security or indi-
viduals’ sense of safety’.10 In a working report from 2007–2008, the Ministry of
Justice and Police (which in Norway holds the main responsibility emergency
management) further defines the policy as resting on a:

risk, threat and vulnerability analysis that includes natural disasters and
climate change, pandemics, collapse of critical infrastructure, accidents
involving dangerous substances, terror and other activities threatening
public security, and challenges in the High North.11

The Defence Ministry’s definition is also interesting, given that emergency hand-
ling may call both upon civil defence and – if necessary – regular military forces.
As the Defence Report of 2008 puts it,

. . . a range of risk of factors such as the danger from infectious diseases,


natural disasters and major accidents have attained heightened significance
in the context of national emergency planning. The security of society
[= societal security] is about ensuring the safety of the civilian population
and protecting important infrastructure and the main public sector func-
tions12 against attack or other forms of subversion in situations where the
existence of the state as such is not threatened.
(Norwegian Ministry of Defence 2008)

Finally, at the central government website, Norway’s societal security policy is


presented as focusing mainly on prevention, but:
70 A.J.K. Bailes
When events nevertheless occur, the government’s aim is to have them
handled effectively. Crises must be met with the use of the nation’s total
resources, based on clear structures, lines of responsibility and lines of
command between civil and military actors, and on adequate capabilities at
all levels.13

What we see here is that societal security in government parlance has come to
focus overwhelmingly on the event (the emergency, the crisis), and on the
coordination efforts and resource-building needed for response to ad hoc contin-
gencies (Sundelius 2005). As the SAMRISK website mentioned above plainly
states: ‘The point of departure of societal security efforts is that crises can and
must be prevented’. Such a focus shifts the whole societal discourse towards
terms and spheres like ‘risk assessment’, ‘crisis management’, ‘preparedness’,
‘robustness’ and ‘resilience’ – concepts that carry recognizable and rather
precise meanings in modern security work, independently of societal theory as
such. This approach does not have to mean ‘securitizing’ societal endeavours in
over-hard and traditional terms, as the Norwegian central government website
extends its scope as far as (among others) national health, road accident preven-
tion and search and rescue at sea.14 Indeed, hardly any department of government
is exempt from the coverage of the policy and the associated demands for
coordination (Burgess and Mouhleb 2007).
What the event-based focus does allow is to set limits both to central inter-
vention and to securitization itself. Thus, if a problem arises in a non-military
field – say, public health – that the normally responsible authority (here, health
ministry) is capable of handling, it will be left in that authority’s hands. Only if a
health crisis (like a major pandemic) disrupts broader aspects of national life,
and needs exceptional means to control it, will higher-level inter-departmental
mechanisms be activated.15 This method, taking ‘peacetime’ departmental
responsibility as the default, is typical of all Nordic government systems practis-
ing societal security or an analogous approach.16 Most obviously, it aims to
avoid creeping ‘militarization’, excessive securitization or over-centralization of
the workings of society and government. But it also offers the authorities some
protection against having to convert each new public neurosis into security
action. If an issue cannot be shown to produce potential large-scale emergencies,
it will in principle remain a ‘peacetime’ responsibility of the appropriate agency,
or – if the government declines to handle it at all – a focus for voluntary efforts.
There are, of course, risks in this pragmatic solution, starting with the danger
that ‘creeping’ processes undermining society’s safety and resilience may be
neglected until too late; and event-related ‘preparedness’ will overshadow the
scope for prophylaxis and positive security-building. Further, thwarting bottom-
up attempts at securitization risks leaving the most concerned groups and indi-
viduals to find their own, potentially violent, means of exorcizing their fears.
Given the transnational nature of many societal security challenges –
epidemic control, supply and infrastructure safety, combating climate change
and human threats like terrorism and smuggling – the Nordic states also
Societal security and small states 71
acknowledge the need for extensive external cooperation for handling them.
Possible partners start with the responsible UN agencies and, for economic/fin-
ancial issues, the international financial institutions (IFIs). Many issues are
appropriate for regional and sub-regional collaboration, where Europe has a
plethora of institutions involved. NATO has long had plans to assist in major
civil emergencies, and the European Union (EU) has developed mechanisms for
deploying financial, professional and mechanical aid to member states. The EU’s
Lisbon Treaty, entering into force on 1 December 2009, introduces a provision
(Article 222) obliging both member states and the Brussels organs to provide
joint assistance for any member suffering a severe natural emergency or similar
damage from a terrorist strike (European Union 2007).17 This legal obligation
gives new force to the debate over whether a common level of societal security
could, and should, be defined for the whole of ‘European society’ (Boin et al.
2007). All EU members, after all, share a common market and a common space
for movement of people and funds; while even neighbouring non-members find
themselves increasingly looking to the EU for partnership and guidance across
the non-military security field.18

Relevance for small states


Norway and Sweden, the states most explicitly using societal security as a policy
framework, are both relatively small with less than ten million people each. This
is hardly their sole reason for choosing the concept, as many historical, cultural
and practical motives come into play; but at least it shows that societal security
can work in a small state environment. How well it would fit a poor, developing
state with little hope of effective regional cooperation is another question, to be
taken up later. Here, two normative and three practical arguments will be offered
on why the societal approach might suit generic small state requirements and
particularities.

Concepts and principles


First, shifting the focus from military power and traditional defence moves the
idea of security away from the area where such states are at the greatest dis-
advantage. The core of societal security lies within the country, where the
scale of problems should be more proportionate to local capacities, and where
local experience and expertise can mean more for success than the scale of
resources or even the level of technology. Iceland is extremely good at pro-
tecting its people in volcanic events and earthquakes, and Finland at keeping
society functioning comfortably in temperatures down to minus 50 Celsius.
Both these countries find it rather easy to spot and track ill-intentioned outsid-
ers like traffickers and terrorists. In short, a small state that prioritizes goals in
this sphere has a hope of finding that many solutions lie in its own hands. This
in itself should help bolster the confidence and claims to ‘statehood’ of even
the smallest player.
72 A.J.K. Bailes
Second, the interactive and bottom-up aspects of societal security throw into
relief the importance of society itself. The concept puts a premium on close
synergy between the national centre and local authorities, businesses, NGOs, social
bodies and the general public. National size does not automatically multiply effec-
tiveness in this regard and will often be a handicap, if the social and environmental
conditions vary between provinces and local communities have different, perhaps
contradictory, demands. Further, the qualities of society that matter for societal
security are not dependent on and may even be antithetical to the typical ‘strengths’
of a state defence establishment. A strong military nation may have a weak, drained
and divided society, precisely because the authorities monopolize the ‘securitiza-
tion’ process and give citizens neither a voice nor a role.

Practical implications
The practicalities start with intra-governmental and cross-sectoral cooperation. In
principle, designing this both for ‘peacetime’ policy making and emergency hand-
ling should be simpler in a small administration. The role of the ‘centre’ is clearer
in a small territory lacking part-autonomous sub-divisions (like US states or
German Länder); centre–local communications should be easier with fewer players
involved, even when physical distances are great. Ministries and agencies should
be fewer in number and will combine more functions than in a larger, more sub-
divided and specialized system. There should be fewer officials overall, increasing
the odds that they will know each other personally. Cross-sectoral cooperation
should also be easier mutatis mutandis; not just because fewer social, business,
media etc. leaders come into the game, but because a small elite tends to be more
homogenous with many cross-cutting family and personal bonds.
Thus far the ideal narrative; in fact, one need not look very far to see that small
states can have chronic internal divisions of their own for all the same reasons that
apply elsewhere. Ethnic minorities linked to neighbouring countries and immigrant
communities alike can reduce social homogeneity, introduce territorial differences
that complicate planning19 and even lead to security tensions and antagonisms in
their own right.20 Politics may be highly polarized and/or ideologized, and in the
smallest states it tends to become also extremely personal. Closeness in private life
does not necessarily stop people playing aggressive, zero-sum games with each
other in political life; it may rather give them an exaggerated sense of security in
doing so. Another effect of closeness can be to blur notions of ethics and public
service and facilitate the more subtle (sometimes not so subtle) forms of nepotism,
corruption and general abuse of power. Conversely, the gulf in personnel and
philosophy between politics (and the public service) and private business may be
too wide for comfort even in a nation of a few million.
Governmental machines are not exempt from such factionalism. Ministries
and agencies may resist coordination and quibble on demarcation for reasons of
partisanship as well as empire-building, because their few, overburdened
officials see it as a last straw breaking their backs, or just because they fail to see
the point in such a small administration. Local elites may resist a centrally
Societal security and small states 73
framed and coordinated security plan because they do not trust the centre’s
understanding of their distinctive needs; while in certain cultures (including the
Scandinavian culture), centralization in itself is suspect as a threat to freedom
and diversity. All these factors can discourage the adoption of a societal security
concept – with its stress on comprehensiveness, mutual dependence and shared
discipline – in the first place, but also undermine its translation into practice.21
The same small state failings would vitiate almost any modern system of
security, however. The real question is whether societal security may ease and/or
circumvent such internal differences better than the alternative concepts. Some
arguments can be made in its favour:

• in not a few small states including Nordic ones, the most basic security dis-
agreement is between pro-defence and anti-military views, including
opposite attitudes to outside ‘protectors’. The societal approach avoids and
may bridge such divisions by focusing on ‘softer’ and ‘newer’ fields of
security, including natural and accidental risks, whose meaning for a small
society is hardly contestable. It also shifts external military protection from
centre-stage and can foster greater self-confidence in international partner-
ships thanks to greater (if still finite) self-sufficiency;
• the wide range of topics covered by an official societal security concept
allows different actors’ priorities to be balanced and potentially reconciled,
while leaving room to ‘securitize’ new issues as needed;
• it militates for better coordination at the highest (Prime Ministerial) level,
which might help overcome inter-agency vendettas;
• by emphasizing bottom-up action, it promotes a rational degree of decen-
tralization that may accommodate genuine internal differences;
• the positive slant that it gives to using non-state (business, NGO) capacities,
if properly followed through, could help to overcome both former rifts
between these constituencies and government, and ill-defined ‘underhand’
relationships leading to corruption.22

One final advantage of societal security lies in its ability to move the management
of external partnerships away from the ‘realist’ and ‘asymmetric’ process of bar-
gaining for military support. Against transnational hazards like terrorism, disease or
climate change, big states have a positive interest in helping small ones to avoid
becoming weak links in the chain. Further, for effective responses, states of all sizes
need to accept and obey universal regulations and standardized norms, creating a
more level playing-field. The flexibility and transparency of small communities
may, indeed, allow such states to find faster solutions for emerging hazards, revers-
ing the usual security ‘food chain’. It remains true that big states have more power
to impose their own preferred solutions, regardless of quality – as when the US
hyper-securitized the issues of terrorism and nuclear proliferation after September
2001 – with results that can be both normatively offensive and burdensome for
smaller partners. But a small state that only thinks of security as a military calculus
is more likely to be caught off-balance by such pressures than one practising a
74 A.J.K. Bailes
multi-dimensional approach, with a variety of partners, and with awareness of the
need to maintain basic societal values as well as political consensus at home.
How much of this applies to states that are not just small but poor, isolated
and lacking effective regional integration, or those struggling to create a new
security system after conflict? Clearly, societal security would not help them
much if it had to be applied always, everywhere, following Norwegian and
Swedish models. Yet there is no reason why it should be. Its main benefits could
be replicated with quite different functional priorities – starting for instance with
internal armed violence and/or hunger – and perhaps also shifting from the
dominant ‘event’ focus to steadily improving the societal experience in ‘peace-
time’. Admittedly, much the same could be attempted under the flag of a ‘human
security’ rather than ‘societal’ policy. But the latter could help highlight the pos-
itive potential of different social structures, including the remarkable resilience
shown by many non-Western communities in far worse than Western conditions.
It would demand a full-spectrum approach including economic, financial and
functional security, aspects now admitted to be under-played in most established
concepts both of humanitarian aid and post-conflict peacebuilding.23 By promot-
ing rational analysis of ways to mitigate transational threats, it might create new
impetus for neighbourhood cooperation and help overcome former divisions
based on ‘hard’ military differences. Of course, none of these possible benefits
depends on the name: a policy that is ‘societal’ in substance should work just as
well under any label that chimes with local attitudes and traditions.

A final critique
As foreseen above, this analysis needs to be completed with further conceptual
and practical snags of a societal approach. A small state must be especially
careful not to waste energy (and credibility) on half-baked ideas, or on solutions
that come with intolerable side-effects.
The most basic conceptual question is, what is ‘society’? Only under the sim-
plest model of the nation-state does this have a self-evident answer. Aside from
the ethno-religious divisions recognized by Buzan and Wæver, most states today
must accommodate new immigrants and asylum seekers, migrant workers and
tourists – the last potentially multiplying the seasonal population in scenic loca-
tions. Are all these humans part of the ‘society’ that the country’s leadership
aims to protect? Could they also have active roles in emergency handling? In
either case, how to brief and prepare them, taking account of their probably dif-
ferent security needs, competences and attitudes in a crisis? Can government do
anything, and if so what, to improve the subjective sense of solidarity and mutual
responsibility among such disparate groups?
Conversely, what to do about national citizens who live and work abroad or
go abroad as tourists and run into a war or civil emergency? Do they remain part
of the ‘society’ that the mother-state must protect, if necessary by repatriating
them? Does that responsibility extend to their material property and investments?
How to help them without risking interference and distorting aid priorities for
Societal security and small states 75
the (possibly worse-hit) local population? All these issues faced Nordic govern-
ments whose citizens were hit by the Indian Ocean tsunami of December 2004,
and their varying responses had such political resonance that in Sweden they
ultimately hastened the fall of a government (Nord et al. 2006). By the time the
same countries faced an evacuation of their nationals from Lebanon in 2006, all
had learned some lessons and reacted more consistently, including an approach
that – tellingly – focused on their passport-carrying citizens regardless of ethni-
city. For real efficiency, however, small and medium states must always cosider
teaming up with like-minded ones and/or working through an institution, such as
the European Union, with its long-standing efforts for reciprocal and joint con-
sular assistance.24 This is one external aspect of the point made above about an
incipient ‘societal’ community for the whole European space.
A second general issue is whether the concentration on exceptional and dra-
matic ‘civil emergencies’ really makes sense. Is there not a risk of over-
securitizing the single event, risking over-reaction and panic on the one hand,
and inattention to the hazards of ‘normal’ life on the other? If citizens are given
to believe they need only follow security disciplines in exceptional cases, not
only may (as already argued) ‘creeping’ dangers like climate change or ageing
populations be taken too lightly, but bad security habits and selfishness may
aggravate losses from everyday hazards like traffic and industrial accidents,
interpersonal violence, substance abuse, street brawls and hooliganism. True,
these latter issues are hard to tackle with traditional security-policy tools; but a
wise government could try to develop its ‘societal’ concept in a way that fos-
tered awareness and responsibility at the micro- as well as the macro-level. A
futher good idea would be to make provision for regularly reviewing the given
threat/risk spectrum, including possible ‘new horizon’ issues.
A related challenge, especially for states with a high quality of life, is to
motivate the individual citizen to have any sense of security responsibility and
ownership at all. When a Nordic state, for instance, offers everyone ‘social’
security against the effects of all socio-economic mishaps and personal life
choices, how can it explain that the same individuals must help shoulder the
burden in apparently tougher, life-threatening emergencies? The Nordic notion
of ‘trygghet’ (safeness, protectedness) as the aim of social policy can too easily
‘leak’ its statist, top-down assumptions into the realm of security proper, casting
society as a flock to be shepherded rather than a self-aware, self-protecting
entity. This happens more easily when past security discourse has been over-
whelmingly military-focused and/or when personal security duties are seen as
limited to military service. Attitudes in different nations vary so much that it is
hard to see a single solution, but arguably the change of approach needed is
largely in the hands of the state. As found in a recent Icelandic study,25 individu-
als even in the richest societies can possess security skills, awareness, and a
readiness to help that they simply do not ‘securitize’ in their own discourse, and
that the official machine too often fails to notice or respect.
Various practical difficulties in setting up and pursuing a societal security
concept can be noted more briefly:
76 A.J.K. Bailes
• Should the word ‘societal’ itself be the official denominator of policy, or
some other term with better local resonance (and more obvious meaning)?
• Should there be a single all-embracing societal security concept covering all
uses of military forces and assets (also for traditional defence), or does the
Swedish/Norwegian model, keeping a separate ‘total’ defence concept for
the forces but emphasizing civil–military cooperation, have merits?
• What are the best models of horizontal and vertical coordination among
government actors, including the centre/province division of roles? What
are the respective merits of giving strong coordinating powers to one minis-
try or coordination agency, and of spreading responsibilities more equally?
What is the correct role for the head of government and his/her office? How
should external partnerships and communications be factored in?
• What resources should be spent on societal security overall and how should
they be prioritized, inter alia, between military and non-military spending?
• What is the optimum small state design for prevention, planning (including
exercises and training), incident response, reconstruction and integration of
lessons learned?
• How should government cooperate with private business actors, NGOs, the
media, and relevant social actors? Should active partnerships be legally
defined, or based on commercial contracts, or should they remain ad hoc
and voluntary? How much is it acceptable to delegate to non-governmental
actors? At what level(s) should coordination with them take place?
• What should be the approach to informing and mobilizing the public? How
to strike the balance between proper preparedness and resilience, and avoid-
ing over-securitization or panic? How should security be defined in a way
that is not itself divisive between different social groups and cultures, and
soothes rather than aggravating their self-constructed divisions? How to
should a large permanent or seasonal tourist population be dealt with?

In conclusion
No security model yet devised is without its faults, and the societal approach is
surely no exception. It is very much a child of its time, reflecting the shift from
military to other preoccupations towards the end of the twentieth century, and
the high-water-mark of social development and peace achieved in the Nordic
nations that first introduced it. It also, however, responds rationally to some
trends that are unlikely to disappear any time soon: notably the growing power
of non-state actors everywhere, for good or ill. Thus, even if a better overall
solution is found for comprehensive security in a democratic state, some
building-blocks of the societal approach are likely to survive.
We have argued that the societal approach has some features that are especially
helpful to small states, with their limited resources, sometimes atypical security
profiles and exposure to transnational trends. At the least, almost any small state
could benefit by asking itself the questions necessary to formulate and test a soci-
etal policy framework. For some governments, the extension to multiple
Societal security and small states 77
non-military dimensions of security may prove most liberating. For others, concep-
tualizing the three-way dependence between state, business and society could be
the breakthrough. For those deciding to go ahead with a full-fledged societal
approach, it must be stressed again that neither the name used nor the copying of
any particular model is crucial. Societal security should emerge from the society it
belongs to: tailor-making it to the locality means not just greater efficiency, but a
better chance of broad social acceptance and ownership.
Last and most obviously, no societal security policy can stand still and no
implementing machinery should be designed for permanence. One of the truths
behind the securitization concept is that security is what leaders and people think
it is at any given time – and there is ample room for second thoughts. A good
policy will be designed from the outset not only to allow frequent reviews, but to
use the same inclusive, cross-sectoral, transnational methods in that process as
those that underpin the strategy itself.

Notes
1 This chapter accepts the definition of small statehood proposed in Chapter 1, and
takes its test-cases from states with less than ten million inhabitants.
2 In particular, traditional military threats have receded from the Caribbean and Pacific
regions since 1945 and Western and Central Europe since 1990. Most European small
states that still feel strategically vulnerable have already gained or are seeking the
shelter of NATO and EU membership; on the more exposed cases of Moldova and
Georgia, see Chapter 9 in this volume.
3 This military/non-military distinction is particularly clear in Norway and Sweden,
where the state maintains a policy of military (‘total’) defence alongside an official
‘societal security’ doctrine covering just about everything else.
4 The related principle of Responsibility to Protect empowers international society to
intervene without the local powers’ consent in cases of extreme abuse (genocide) or
neglect of a people. A corresponding statement was adopted by the UN Summit in
September 2005 (UN 2005: para. 139).
5 This section owes much to Roe (2010).
6 Arguably, a restatement in other terms of the long-standing dilemma over ‘self-
determination’.
7 See p. 28.
8 Difficulties arising in this context are further explored in the section ‘A final critique’,
on p. 74.
9 See www.forskningsradet.no/prognett-samrisk/Home_page/1228296552859 (accessed
20 September 2012), including the text ‘Results from the programme: What we know
about societal security’. Another good source of research materials is the website
www.societalsecurity.eu/ (accessed 20 September 2012). In 2013 the Nordic states
agreed to launch a new, joint research programme to create centres of excellence on
societal security throughout the region: see www.nordforsk.org/en/programs/program-
mer/samfunnssikkerhet (accessed 20 September 2012).
10 Author’s translation from the Norwegian: ‘hendelser som truer sentrale samfunnsin-
stitusjoner, vår felles sikkerhet eller den enkeltes trygghetsfølelse’. Taken from the
official website at: www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/jd/tema/samfunnssikkerhet-og-
beredskap.html?id=87075 (accessed 20 September 2012).
11 Author’s translation from Royal Norwegian Ministry of Justice and Police, St.
melding (state report) nr 22 2007–8, text at: www.regjeringen.no/pages/2073310/
PDFS/STM200720080022000DDDPDFS.pdf (accessed 20 September 2012), p. 6.
78 A.J.K. Bailes
12 ‘Main public sector functions’ is a standard phrase in Norwegian security planning
and refers to major utilities like energy, food and water supplies, transport and com-
munications, plus basic financial services.
13 Author’s translation, from the official website at: www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/jd/tema/
samfunnssikkerhet-og-beredskap.html?id=87075 (accessed 25 October 2012).
14 Ibid.
15 In the Swedish and Finnish systems, control of complex emergencies would pass
directly to the Prime Ministerial level where the key resources (24/7 situation centre
etc.) are located, but this is somewhat less clear in Norway and Denmark.
16 Aside from Norway and Sweden, which expressly use the societal term (samfunns-
sikkerhet and samhallssäkerhet respectively), Finland has formulated a ‘comprehen-
sive’ approach to national security that means much the same in practice. Denmark
sets similar goals for emergency preparedness and management in a ‘robust society’,
with perhaps greater emphasis on international human threats. Iceland has a coord-
inating institution under the Ministry of Justice with the title of ‘Almannavarnir’, offi-
cially translated as civil defence or (more recently) civil protection.
17 On the significance of Article 223 and its precursors, see Rhinard and Myrdal (2010).
18 For instance, Iceland’s independent risk assessment of March 2009 cited the EU as a
key partner in numerous areas of civil security (Icelandic Ministry of Foreign Affairs
2009).
19 The problem is of course aggravated when different ethnic, religious etc. groups are
clustered in the different regions.
20 This last point hardly needs to be laboured in the case of the Western Balkan small
states, Cyprus or Georgia.
21 Insights into variations and limitations of Nordic ‘societal’ practice are given in Britz
(2008). For a critical review of Icelandic internal emergency handling see Bern-
hardsdóttir and Svedin (2004).
22 A study of elite reactions to the idea of ‘societal’ security carried out in Iceland in
2008 gave some credence to all these points, but also showed what misapprehensions
and fears any new proposal could evoke in a traditionally polarized sphere. See Bailes
and Gylfason (2008).
23 A good start is made on remedying this weakness in (World Bank 2011).
24 For current information on EU policy see www.travel-voyage.consilium.europa.eu/
file.asp?thepath={5D28E317–0BC5–435A-BCA7-FAFE6CAD6A58}.pdf and http://
ec.europa.eu/echo/civil_protection/civil/prote/perspectives_en.htm (both accessed 25
October 2012).
25 See note 22.

Bibliography
Bailes, A.J.K. (2007) ‘A World of Risk’, in SIPRI Yearbook 2007: Armaments, Disarma-
ment and International Security, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Bailes, A.J.K. and Gylfason, Th.F. (2008) ‘ “Societal Security” and Iceland’ in Stjórn-
mála og Stjórnsysla 2008/1, University of Iceland, available online at: www.
stjornmalogstjornsysla.is/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=368
(accessed 20 September 2012).
Bernhardsdóttir, Á.E. and Svedin, L. (eds) (2004) Small-state Crisis Management: The
Icelandic Way, Stockholm: CRISMART (Swedish Defence College).
Boin, A., Ekengren, M., Missiroli, A., Rhinhard, M. and Sundelius, B. (2007) ‘Building
Societal Security: The EU’s Role in Managing Emergencies’, Brussels: EPC working
paper no. 27, available online at: www.epc.eu/en/pb.asp?TYP=TEWN&LV=187&see=
y&t=7&PG=TEWN/EN/detailpub&l=12&AI=846 (accessed 20 September 2012).
Societal security and small states 79
Britz, M. (2008) Lost in Translation? EU’s Solidarity Declaration in Practice: A Nordic
Perspective on Civil Protection, Acta B 37, Stockholm: Swedish National Defence
College.
Burgess, P. and Mouhleb, N. (2007) ‘Societal Security: Definitions and Scope for the
Norwegian Setting’, PRIO Policy brief, 2/2007.
Buzan, B. (1991) Peoples, States and Fear: An Agenda for International Security Studies
in the Post-Cold War Era, Boulder CO: Lynn Rienner Publishers.
Buzan, B., de Wilde, J. and Wæver, O. (1998) Security, A New Framework for Analysis,
Boulder, CO and London: Lynn Rienner Publishers.
European Union (2007) ‘Treaty of Lisbon’, available online at: http://europa.eu/lisbon_
treaty/full_text/index_en.htm (accessed 20 August 2013).
Huysmans, J. (2000) ‘The European Union and the Securitization of Migration’, Journal
of Common Market Studies, 38(5): 751–777.
Ibryamova, N. (2002) ‘Migration from Central and Eastern Europe and Societal Security
in the European Union’, University of Miami: 2002, available online at: http://aei.pitt.
edu/8088/ (accessed 15 September 2012).
Icelandic Ministry of Foreign Affairs (2009) ‘Risk Assessment for Iceland’, text available
online at: www.mfa.is/news-and-publications/nr/4823 (accessed 20 September 2012).
McSweeney, B. (1996) ‘Identity and Security: Buzan and the Copenhagen School’,
Review of International Studies, 22(1): 81–93.
Nord, L., Strömbäck, J., Grandien, C. and Ottestig, A.C. (2006) ‘When a Natural Disaster
Becomes a Political Crisis: A Swedish Case Study’, paper presented to the Inter-
national Communication Association at Dresden, available online at: www.allaca-
demic.com/meta/p_mla_apa_research_citation/0/9/2/0/4/p92041_index.html (accessed
20 February 2013).
Norwegian Ministry of Defence (2008) Norwegian Defence 2008, available online at: www.
regjeringen.no/upload/FD/Dokumenter/Fakta2008_eng.pdf (accessed 20 September
2012).
Rhinard, M. and Myrdal, S. (2010) ‘The European Union’s Solidarity Clause: Empty Letter
or Effective Tool?’, Swedish Institute of International Affairs occasional paper no. 2,
available online at: www.ui.se/news.aspx?r_id=24311 (accessed 20 September 2012).
Roe, P. (2010) ‘Societal Security’, in Collins, A. (ed.) Contemporary Security Studies
(2nd edition), Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Sundelius, B. (2005) ‘A Brief on Embedded Societal Security’, Information & Security,
17: 23–37.
United Nations (2005) ‘Summit Outcome’ (of the 60th anniversary UN Summit), avail-
able online at: http://daccess-dds-ny.un.org/doc/UNDOC/GEN/N05/487/60/PDF/
N0548760.pdf?OpenElement (accessed 20 September 2012).
United Nations Development Programme (1994) ‘Human Development Report 1994:
New Dimensions of Human Security’, available online at: http://hdr.undp.org/en/
reports/global/hdr1994/ (accessed 20 September 2012).
Wæver, O. (1993) Identity, Migration and the New Security Agenda in Europe, London:
Pinter.
World Bank (2011) ‘World Development Report, Conflict, Security and Development’,
available online at: http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWDRS/Resources/WDR2011_
Full_Text.pdf (accessed 29 August 2013).
5 Environmental security and small
states
Auður H. Ingólfsdóttir

Introduction
Without nature humans would not exist. The natural world is not only a provider
of food, water, energy and other necessities vital for our survival, but also a
place where we seek joy and inspiration. All human communities are shaped by
their natural environment and rely on natural resources in order to flourish. The
nurturing element of nature, however, only tells part of the story. The environ-
ment is also a source of multiple threats that can endanger the security of indi-
viduals and communities. In some instances, environmental hazards can also
threaten the national security of states or even global security. While certain
environmental hazards, like natural disasters, have always existed, the ways
humans have over-exploited resources and polluted the environment in modern
times have created new threats. In other words, man-made environmental
degradation is causing multiple security threats that call for our attention.
The topic of this chapter is environmental security and it focuses on why this
type of security should be of any relevance for small states. After discussing the
different understandings of environmental security, the link to small states will
be established and the importance of this particular dimension of security for
them will be explored. Finally, the opportunities small states have to influence
discourses on security and the environment at the international level will be dis-
cussed. A key argument presented in the chapter is that although small states are
vulnerable to environmental threats, especially when such threats originate
outside their borders, they also have opportunities to influence policy at the inter-
national level by acting as ‘norm entrepreneurs’.1 The power to shape norms,
however, will be weakened if domestic policies are in conflict with the ideals
that small states are advocating in international forums.
The theoretical underpinning of this argument is drawn from social construc-
tivism. Constructivists emphasize the social dimensions of international rela-
tions, including the importance of norms, rules and language, and the possibility
of change. Unlike the neo-realists and neo-liberalists, whose main focus is on
structure, constructivists believe that although states are influenced by structure,
they also have agency and can facilitate changes through a process of interaction
with other states (Fierke 2010: 179–180).
Environmental security and small states 81
Throughout the chapter, climate change will be used as an example of an
environmental issue that threatens security. Climate change serves as an interest-
ing case since it is a truly global issue that demands the cooperation of all states.
No single state, large or small, can tackle problems related to climate change
with domestic policies alone, since the threat originates both outside and inside
the borders of each state.

Environmental security: what is it?


The United Nations Conference on the Human Environment, held in Stockholm
in 1972, firmly placed environmental issues on the agenda of international pol-
itics. Concerns about the vulnerability of human communities to the degradation
of the environment continued to grow during the 1980s, spurred by events like
the Exxon Valdes oil spill and the Chernobyl disaster. Debates about whether
and how environmental degradation should be linked to security are, however, a
more recent phenomena that can be traced back to the early 1990s (Haldén 2011:
406–407). This is in line with the general trend since the end of the Cold War to
broaden the range of issues defined and addressed as belonging to security, at
national, regional and global levels.2
The most dominant discourses on environmental security can be roughly
divided into two camps. On the one hand, we have the view that environmental
degradation will increase the number of violent conflicts in the world, which will
be a threat to the national security of the relevant states. On the other hand, there
are those who prefer to understand environmental security in the context of
human security, where the degradation of the environment poses a variety of
threats – not necessarily involving open violence – to the daily lives of peoples
around the world.
‘The 1990s will demand a redefinition of what constitutes national security’
wrote Jessica Tuchman Mathew in a call for more attention to be given to
environmental and resource issues (Mathew 1989: 162). Her paper was pub-
lished in Foreign Affairs, a US foreign policy journal widely read in policy
circles. Thus, the article was clearly aimed at influencing policy makers by ele-
vating environmental concerns to the level of security issues. In other words,
environmental problems were ‘securitized’ in the hope that this would give them
higher priority on the policy agenda (Barnett 2001a: 42). Calling for a redefini-
tion of national security, however, was problematic for many of those used to
working with a more traditional meaning of security. Deudney, for example,
argues against linking environmental degradation and national security. Security,
in his view, is first and foremost related to violence, and most of the causes and
cures of environmental degradation will be found outside the domain of the tra-
ditional national security system focused upon violent risks (Deudney 1990).
Barnett (2001a) uses the same premises as Deudney to conclude that so long
as national security continues to be the domain of the military, then national
security logic will be incapable of grasping environmental issues and dealing
with them effectively. This is not, however, the point that most writers who link
82 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
environmental issues with security are actually aiming at. As Barnett acknow-
ledges, most of them are also calling for a redefinition of the security concept
and criticizing the realist understanding of security, with its narrow focus on
military security and its assumption that the military is the most relevant actor
(Barnett 2001a: 45).
One consequence of linking environmental issues with the traditional under-
standing of national security is that the focus remains on the question of whether
environmental degradation triggers violent conflict. This emphasis is what
Detraz and Betsill (2009) label as the environmental conflict discourse. This dis-
course focuses on the potential for humans to engage in violent conflict over
resources, which in turn threatens the security of the state. Much has been
written about the potential link between environmental degradation and violent
conflict, but so far this research has failed to establish clear links between the
two. Thus, it seems that the literature has been theoretically driven rather than
based on empirical evidence (see, e.g. Haldén 2011: 409 and Salehyan
2008: 316).
As a better alternative to treating the environment as a sub-theme of tradi-
tional national security, Barnett proposes the following definition of environ-
mental security:

The process of peacefully reducing human vulnerability to human-induced


environmental degradation by addressing the root causes of environmental
degradation and human insecurity.
(Barnett 2001a: 129)

This definition implies that rather than linking environmental degradation


directly to national security, it should be viewed as one dimension of human
security.
When environmental security is nested in the human security framework, as
Barnett suggests, it shifts the emphasis from national security and the armed pro-
tection of territories towards a focus on the security of individuals and sustain-
able human development. The concept of human security can be traced back to a
UNDP report, published in 1994, where the traditional concept of security is
questioned:

The concept of security has for too long been interpreted narrowly: as
security of territory from external aggression, or as protection of national
interest in foreign policy or as global security from the threat of a nuclear
holocaust. It has been related more to nation-states than to people.
(United Nations Development Programme 1994: 22)

The report then goes on to discuss a long list of threats to human security and
groups them into the seven following categories: Economic security, food
security, health security, environmental security, personal security, community
security and political security.
Environmental security and small states 83
An important feature of the human security approach is the possibility for
analysing security threats as they apply to different groups in society, rather than
only focusing on the state as the unit of analysis. In this context, identifying vul-
nerable groups might be more important than looking at environmental security
through the lens of state security, regardless of whether the states are small or
large. That said, there are still some issues that require the cooperation of states.
This applies in particular to environmental issues that are global in scope, such
as climate change.
As an environmental problem, climate change is on a different scale from
anything else the international system has previously encountered. Increasing
temperatures will not only drastically alter natural environments, but can also
lead to huge changes in living conditions for humans (Vogler 2008). These
changes will provide a number of new security challenges, some of which can
only be dealt with at the international level. Examples of new security challenges
include the increasing risks of coastal erosion and more frequent floods in low
lying coastal areas (due to rising sea levels), an increase in the number and
intensity of extreme weather events, and the risk that millions of people will be
exposed to increased stress from water shortage in the future (International Panel
on Climate Change 2007: 48).
In this light, it should not come as a surprise that the debate on environmental
security has been revitalized in recent years due to the increasing spotlight on
climate change as a security issue. In the 1990s, climate change was discussed as
part of the environmental security discourse, but by the beginning of the twenty-
first century it had emerged as a separate issue. It was quickly connected to
human security, although the possibility of linking climate change with future
conflict causation was also raised (Haldén 2011: 410).
The publication, in 2007, of the fourth assessment report of the Intergovern-
mental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC) (International Panel on Climate Change
2007) brought a turning point in the securitization of climate change. The report
repeated the earlier message about human-induced climate change, but with
much more scientific certainty than before. Also in 2007, Al Gore and the IPCC
received the Nobel Peace Prize for their work in drawing attention to the danger
of climate change, and in April that year the UN Security Council held its first
debate on climate change and global security. Although predictions about
climate change causing future conflicts were prominent, especially in the media,
an analysis of these developments by Detraz and Betsill (2009) indicates that in
international forums the main focus has been on the environmental security dis-
course, rather than the environmental conflict discourse. Their research is based
on reviewing a number of UNFCCC3-related documents as well as the debate in
the Security Council. Using content and discourse analysis, they demonstrate
that both the historical climate change debate and the Security Council debate of
2007 were drawing from the environmental security discourse, rather than focus-
ing on the linkages between environment and conflict.
Whether the focus is on environmental conflict related to climate change, or the
broader environmental security discourse, it is clear that security threats caused by
84 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
climate change are on the agenda in international forums today. As already argued,
climate change cannot be addressed by one state alone. It calls for cooperation, not
only between states, but also between states and non-state actors, such as multi-
national corporations and international environmental NGOs.
Furthermore, climate change cannot be dealt with in isolation from other issues.
Other types of environmental threats also demand attention, e.g. pollution, soil
erosion and over-exploitation of renewable resources. While climate change might
intensify problems related to those threats, preventing or minimizing it will not
necessarily address the root causes of those particular problems. Additionally,
threats related to climate change must be weighed against other types of security
issues and the links between the different types of security threats must be kept in
mind. For example, in some cases climate change could add to economic insecurity
but, on other occasions, efforts to mitigate climate change might be more of a
threat to economic security than climate change itself.
To sum up, climate change provides the international community with a huge
task: it must simultaneously find ways to reduce climate-related security threats,
and coordinate those efforts with other pressing security issues also calling for
attention. International agreements will clearly play an important role in this
task. In spite of the importance of other actors, states still play a key role in
negotiating binding international agreements that provide the basis for establish-
ing new norms and defining legitimate behaviour. In this context, the relative
size of a state matters. For example, large states have more power to influence
the overall global greenhouse gas emissions through direct action, either by
cutting emissions domestically, or using their economic power to put pressure on
other states to cut their emissions. This does not mean that small states are com-
pletely powerless; but they might need to be more creative in their diplomacy to
have any real impact on the climate debate and large state behaviour. This
thought leads us into the next section, where the relevance of environmental
security for small states will be discussed.

Relevance for small states


Are small states more vulnerable to environmental threats than larger powers?
The short answer would be: it depends. In many cases, the strength of domestic
institutions might be more important when dealing with environmental threats
than the actual size of the state. Small states should not be confused with weak
states, as Neumann and Gstöhl emphasize (2004: 4). A small state with strong
democratic institutions, high GDP per capita, and a highly educated population
is likely to have more resources to tackle environmental threats than a poor,
developing country with a fragile political system, even if the latter is much
larger in size. This logic applies when dealing with the consequences of environ-
mental degradation, but is also relevant when addressing the root causes to the
extent that those can be dealt with domestically – as is the case with local
pollution, or the overuse of a resource located within the boundaries of one state.
When the environmental threat is regional, e.g. acid rain, or global, like the
Environmental security and small states 85
thinning of the ozone layer or climate change, small states become more vulner-
able to consequences beyond their own control.
Geography is another factor that might be more relevant than the size of a
state when it comes to vulnerability to environmental threats. Sea level rise due
to climate change is a good example. Small island states are especially vulner-
able to sea level rise, but cities along the coast of big states like China, India and
the US are also threatened. The German Advisory Council on Global Change
(2007) has labeled ten regions of the world as ‘hotspots of climate change’,
arguing that climate change will present particularly severe challenges in these
regions in the next decades. The ten hotspots are the following:

1 The Arctic and subarctic


2 Southern Europe and North Africa
3 The Sahel zone
4 Southern Africa
5 Central Asia
6 India, Pakistan and Bangladesh
7 China
8 The Caribbean and Gulf of Mexico
9 The Andes region
10 The Amazon region.

As can be seen from this list, regions at special risk include states of all shapes
and sizes. Barnett has summarized the situation by stating that: ‘Climate change
is a security issue for some nation-states, communities and individuals’ (Barnett
2001b: 2). Among those especially vulnerable, he mentions small island states
(threatened by sea level rise), Inuit communities in the Arctic (threatened by
thinner ice and less predictable snow cover), people living in the deltas of Bang-
ladesh (where floods will be more common) and communities in the highlands
of Papua New Guinea (increasingly prone to diseases spread by mosquitos)
(Barnett 2001b: 2).
Climate change does not only pose threats to individual regions of the world
but can also threaten international security. One example would be when climate
change triggers or intensifies migration within and between countries; another
would be if climate change leads to a growing international distributional con-
flict between the main drivers of climate change (industrialized countries) and
those most affected (developing countries). If climate change exceeds the
adaptation capacity of many states, this could also increase the number of weak
and fragile states, which can threaten stability in the world (German Advisory
Council on Global Change 2007).
There are two key methods to minimize threats presented by climate change:
mitigation and adaptation. Mitigation aims at preventing or limiting change and
involves implementing policies to reduce greenhouse gas emissions. Adaptation
refers to initiatives and measures to reduce the vulnerability of natural and
human systems to climate changes that are already happening or are expected to
86 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
happen. Earlier efforts focused almost exclusively on mitigation, but as time has
passed and attempts to reduce overall global emissions have failed, the need to
focus on adaptation has increased. As stated earlier, weak and fragile states –
located in geographical areas that will be hit hard by climate change – are the
most vulnerable, and will have the hardest time adapting to the changes. Many
of those countries, especially the smaller ones, have also contributed little to
overall greenhouse gas emissions, and thus are unable to offer their help by
taking relevant mitigation measures domestically. Small island developing states
are a good example. Their contribution to global greenhouse gas emissions is
minimal but they may experience the most serious impact, and some even face
the threat of going completely under water. This leaves these states in the vul-
nerable position of having a vital stake in the international effort to combat
climate change and enhance climate security, but without the means to con-
tribute significantly to mitigation or adaptation measures (Betzold 2010: 131).
Smaller states in Northern Europe are in a different position. Most of them
have the resources to defend their population against moderate climate changes
through adaptation. In some cases, the changes might even bring new economic
opportunities, especially for those located in the Arctic. The melting of the
Arctic ice cap will increase accessibility to the region, which will bring both new
opportunities and risks. New opportunities could include more shipping (both
from transport and tourism), oil and gas development and the opening up of new
fishing grounds. A warmer climate might also benefit agriculture in certain
Arctic regions. A recent report by the Nordic Council of Ministers lists
‘Increased accessibility that will provide opportunities as well as new risks’, as
one of nine mega-trends currently characterizing the Arctic (Nordic Council of
Ministers 2011: 13). The small state of Iceland, with a population of only
300,000 people, can be taken as an example. Planning authorities have already
adopted policies aimed at taking future climate changes into account. Since
1992, harbours have been designed with rising sea levels in mind and the
National Power Company (Landvirkjun) has done some work on estimating the
influence that warmer temperatures will have on renewable energy sources,
especially hydropower (Ministry for the Environment 2010: 78).
If climate impacts become even more dramatic, however, the adaptation capa-
city of even the more favourably placed states might be exceeded. Thus, mitiga-
tion is a vital component of enhancing climate security in the long run. When it
comes to mitigation, however, small states have very little direct power to influ-
ence overall global emissions. Going back to the case of Iceland, greenhouse gas
emissions from Iceland are only a tiny fraction of global emissions. Even if
emissions there could be cut down to zero, this would not make a noticeable dent
in the overall output. This fact creates a great temptation for small states to act as
‘free riders’ when it comes to contributing towards solving the climate crisis.
This is exactly what Iceland did during the negotiations for the Kyoto Protocol,
where the Icelandic negotiating team managed to get a special exemption from
greenhouse gas emission limits for Iceland’s new large-scale industries using
renewable energy.4 This negotiating tactic was, in turn, driven by special
Environmental security and small states 87
interests, leaving little room for Iceland to contribute to the discussion on how to
reduce global emissions, even though this was a common interest for all states
(Ingólfsdóttir 2008).
Another, more recent example of a small actor flirting with the free rider
approach is provided by Greenland.5 Greenland is frequently taken as an
example of a place where the impacts of climate change are particularly severe.
Prior to the 2009 Copenhagen climate conference, Denmark used Greenland as a
meeting site for high-level policy makers, so they could observe the effects of
climate change at first hand (Degeorges 2010: 3). Today, however, with increas-
ingly easy access to resources in the Arctic, foreign investors are standing in line
for oil and gas explorations off the coast of Greenland and for mapping out sites
for potential mineral mining on land (Rosenthal 2012). In sum, the impact of
climate change is creating new economic opportunities, but taking advantage of
those opportunities means a large increase in emissions from this region, further
adding to the climate problem.
A closer look reveals that the tension between trying to implement an ambi-
tious climate policy and the pressure to continue with economic development,
often leading to an increase in emissions, can be found in most places that have
committed to the task of keeping greenhouse gas emissions in check. Norway,
another small state in Northern Europe, is yet another example. The Norwegian
government has announced its ambition to become ‘carbon neutral’ by 2030. At
the same time, there are plans to start offshore oil and gas activities in new loca-
tions, just south of the Barents Sea. The Norwegian Minister of Foreign Affairs,
Jonas Gahr Støre, addressed this dilemma in a speech to the Norwegian Parlia-
ment in 2008: ‘Norway has to find a balance between the superior climate target
and safeguarding Norwegian interests in the north’, he said (quoted in Kristof-
fersen and Young 2009: 577).
This issue can also serve as an example of how tension can arise between the
demands of different security dimensions. Economic, financial and societal
security at home is likely to have more weight in domestic policy making than
concern for global environmental security.
Given the small impact that any reduction in emissions from small states can
have on global emissions, it is understandable that economic interests tend to be
prioritized over an ambitious climate mitigation policy. This approach, however,
could weaken the power of small states to act as norm entrepreneurs in inter-
national forums, which is generally their best opportunity to influence the beha-
viour of larger states. The role of a norm entrepreneur is a challenging one,
because it requires a long-term vision and the willingness to take a higher moral
ground, advocating policies that aim at supporting the common interests of all
states rather than the special interests of a few.

How can small states have influence?


Large and powerful states have more options than small states to influence world
politics. They can exercise direct power using their military capabilities or use
88 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
economic power to put pressure on other states. A hegemonic power can even
unilaterally take a decision that has a ‘ripple’ effect throughout the world.
Smaller states have more limited options. They can enter into bilateral partner-
ship with stronger states, or reach agreements through multilateral, including
institutional, methods. Another option is to rely on the power of ideas (Ingebrit-
sen 2006: 1–2). It is through this last approach that small states might be able to
exercise their power to positively influence the climate agenda most effectively.
This brings us back to the option of acting as norm entrepreneurs.
Scholars of international relations have studied the role that norms play in
international politics. Norms generally have to go through three phases before
they are institutionalized as legitimate behaviour: norm emergence, norm accept-
ance and norm internalization. Norms do not emerge by coincidence, they are
actively pursued by agents with strong opinions about a desirable behaviour in a
community (Ingebritsen 2002: 12). With the rise of social constructivism in
international relations studies, the power of norms has been receiving increasing
attention. There are several examples where small states have acted as norm
entrepreneurs in international politics.
Ingebritsen argues that the five Nordic countries (Sweden, Norway, Finland,
Denmark and Iceland) have acted as norm entrepreneurs in international politics
in three policy areas: the environment, international security and global welfare.
She points to the reputation of those states as trustworthy and effective negotiat-
ing partners, their role as neutral mediators in international conflicts, and their
strong democratic institutions as reasons for their effectiveness in this area
(Ingebritsen 2002: 13). All of the Nordic states would be considered small states
by any definition,6 but they are strong in the sense of having well-functioning
domestic institutions and their populations enjoy high living standards.
Sweden’s hosting of the UN Conference on the Environment in 1972, and
Norwegian leadership in promoting the norms of sustainable development within
the UN,7 are named as examples of the Nordics acting as environmental entre-
preneurs (Ingebritsen 2002: 14). Denmark’s hosting of the COP 15 climate
meeting in Copenhagen in 2009 could also be interpreted as an attempt to show
leadership in dealing with the climate crisis. The failure of states to reach any
meaningful agreement in Copenhagen, however, serves as a reminder that not all
such attempts are successful.
Other scholars have tested Ingebritsen’s theses by examining the influence of
small states in the European Union. One study from 2002 evaluates the effec-
tiveness of Sweden’s pressure for environmental norms within the EU. For a
long time, Sweden has been active in putting environmental issues on the inter-
national agenda and, when the country joined the EU in 1995, the Swedish gov-
ernment promised it would not compromise domestic environmental norms
(Kronsell 2002: 287). As in other international forums, the economic and
military power of large states gives them more power within the EU than small
states. Yet voting strength is not the only way to influence policy outcomes,
since much of the work takes place in venues and modes where representatives
of all states have the opportunity to shape the discussion. Kronsell concludes that
Environmental security and small states 89
Swedish policy makers have clearly had some success in pursuing their goals in
the area of environmental policy. She takes the adoption of an EU acidification
strategy and the revision of chemical industry policy as an example.
Kronsell identifies four factors as important for small states if they want to be
effective as norm setters. The first one is reputation. In the Swedish case, the fact
that Sweden had previously been known as an advocate for the environment
meant that others in the EU expected it to be in the forefront when discussing
environmental issues. The second factor is expertise and knowledge. Having
good access to scientific knowledge helps a small state to establish credibility.
Third, having already implemented progressive national policies domestically
can give small states an advantage, first and foremost as credible actors, but also
because successful national policies can serve as an inspiration. Finally, to be
effective, the negotiating strategy must be in alignment with national interests of
the state. In this case smallness can be an advantage, since forming a clear and
unified national position should be easier in smaller settings (Kronsell 2002).
Small island developing states (SIDS) are another example of a group of
states that have managed to influence international discourses in spite of their
small size. The Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS) has been one of the
most vocal participants in the climate negotiations from the start. Betzold con-
ducted an analysis of the influence of the AOSIS in international climate negoti-
ations for the period 1990–1997 (the negotiation period for both the UNFCCC
and the Kyoto Protocol). Her conclusion was that although the small island states
did not have enough power to facilitate the creation of a climate regime strong
enough to prevent climate change, their participation still had more influence
than would be expected given their small size.
Betzold explains that although the AOSIS lacked traditional sources of power,
they were able to draw on external sources (Betzold 2010: 143). The AOSIS
appealed to norms and principles in their interventions. They spoke from the
position of the ‘innocent victim’ of the actions of others, particularly developed
countries, and argued that those responsible for historical emissions had a moral
duty to act. With the four factors identified by Kronsell in mind, it can be argued
that the AOSIS had a clear and unified message about the national interests of
their member states (i.e. their very existence is threatened by climate change).
The AOSIS have been active participants in the climate negotiations from the
beginning, and with time earned the role of a credible player. One method they
used to give their message more weight was strong reliance on scientific evid-
ence. This was possible because the AOSIS negotiating bloc was supported by a
number of NGOs that provided both technical information and legal advice
(Betzold 2010).
Another factor that Kronsell identified as important in the Swedish case was
having implemented progressive policies domestically. This factor does not
seem to have played a role in the negotiation strategy of the AOSIS, partly
because their greenhouse gas emissions were, in most cases, rather low to start
with, and partly because developed countries were generally expected to show
leadership in mitigation efforts. Thus, while the AOSIS have played a role in
90 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
creating the understanding that all states have a moral duty to mitigate climate
change, they have not been able to inspire other states with policy models of
their own – demonstrating that cuts in emissions are not only desirable, but also
possible.
What about the Nordic states? Do they have the potential to play the role of
norm entrepreneurs in the climate crisis by setting examples with progressive
domestic climate policies? The Nordics states have already established them-
selves as states that are serious about environmental issues, and all of them have
put forward ambitious targets aimed at decarbonizing their economies by 2050.
The International Energy Agency (IEA) sees the Nordic states, with their pro-
gressive policies, as leaders in the global transition to a low-carbon energy
system (International Energy Agency 2012). Setting policies, however, is only
the first step: the true test comes with implementation. The IEA analysis also
suggests that while Nordic national targets should be achievable, there are a
number of critical challenges standing in the way. The nations’ track records are
in fact mixed, with only Sweden and Denmark making noticeable reductions in
greenhouse gas emissions in the period from 1990 to 2010 (Nordic Energy
Research 2012). The examples given earlier from Iceland, Greenland and
Norway also demonstrate that implementing policies that reduce emissions is not
a simple task when those policies conflict with economic interests. Thus, a key
factor in deciding whether the Nordics can act as norm entrepreneurs in the
climate debate will be how successful those states are in implementing their own
climate targets.

Conclusion
Human-induced environmental degradation is a growing problem that threatens
both the human security of individuals and groups and the national security of
selected states. Additionally, some environmental issues are global in scope, and
have the potential to threaten international security as well. Climate change is
one such example begging for the attention of the international community.
Smallness is not the only factor of relevance when evaluating the environ-
mental security of states. Geography, standard of living and human capital are,
in some cases, more relevant factors. When it comes to global problems like
climate change, however, small states are more vulnerable than large ones in the
sense that they have less power to take direct action that will have any real
impact on mitigating climate change. Their smallness also limits their options
for effective adaptation and if the latter fails, they are liable to become an early
source of climate-driven migration.
Although small states are unable to use their military or economic power to
change the behaviour of large states, they have the opportunity to influence inter-
national discourses and act as norm entrepreneurs. In the long run, this will help
enhance their environmental security. The role of a norm entrepreneur, however,
requires a clear vision and a long-term commitment. It calls on states to focus on
common global interests and to provide leadership in implementing progressive
Environmental security and small states 91
domestic policies. The Nordic states have often acted as norm entrepreneurs in
environmental policy, both internationally and within the EU. They are viewed
by many as leaders in the climate policy field as well, but domestic economic
policies in conflict with their climate goals might weaken their power to act as
inspiration for other states.

Notes
1 The term ‘norm entrepreneur’ is borrowed from Christine Ingebritsen who has written
much about the role of the Nordic countries in world politics (Ingebritsen 2002, 2006).
2 See Chapter 2 in this book.
3 UNFCCC stands for the United Nations Framework Convention for Climate Change.
Among the documents reviewed were summaries from COP (Conference of the
Parties) meetings that are held every year.
4 The agreement about this exemption was reached at COP 7, and is listed as Decision
14/CP.7. The decision is only relevant for small economies, emitting less than 0.05 per
cent of the total Annex I carbon dioxide emissions in 1990. What this means in prac-
tical terms is that Iceland is the only state that benefits from the exemption.
5 Greenland is a self-ruled territory that is part of the Kingdom of Denmark. With only
57,000 inhabitants it can definitely be considered small (although it is not yet an inde-
pendent state).
6 See Chapter 6 in this book.
7 Gro Harlem Brundtland, the former Prime Minister of Norway, led the work of the
World Commission on Environment and Development that authored the famous report
‘Our Common Future’ (1987), where the idea of sustainable development was
presented.

Bibliography
Barnett, J. (2001a) The Meaning of Environmental Security, London: Zed Books.
Barnett, J. (2001b) ‘Security and Climate Change’, working paper no. 7, Tyndall Centre
for Climate Change Research.
Betzold, C. (2010) ‘Borrowing Power to Influence International Negotiations: AOSIS in
the Climate Change Regime, 1990–1997’, Politics, 30(3): 131–148.
Degeorges, D. (2010) ‘Greenland’s State-building in a Changing Arctic: Climate, Energy
and Geopolitics’ – Our Ice Dependent World, conference proceedings from the Sixth
Open Assembly of the Northern Research Forum. Akureyri: Northern Research Forum,
available online at www.nrf.is/images/stories/Damien_Deogeorges_final.pdf (accessed
29 November 2013).
Detraz, N. and Betsill, M.M. (2009) ‘Climate Change and Environmental Security: For
Whom the Discourse Shifts’, International Studies Perspectives, 10: 303–330.
Deudney, D. (1990) ‘The Case Against Linking Environmental Degradation and National
Security’, Millennium: Journal of International Studies, 19(3): 461–476.
Fierke, K.M. (2010) ‘Constructivism’, in Dunne, T., Kurki, D. and Smith, S. (eds) Inter-
national Relations Theories. Discipline and Diversity (2nd edition) New York: Oxford
University Press.
German Advisory Council on Global Change (2008) Climate Change as a Security Risk,
London and Sterling: Earth Scan.
Haldén, P. (2011) ‘The Past, Present and Future(s) of Environmental Security Studies’,
Cooperation and Conflict, 46(3): 406–414.
92 A.H. Ingólfsdóttir
Ingebritsen, C. (2002) ‘Norm Entreprenaurs: Scandinavia’s Role in World Politics’,
Cooperation and Conflict, 37(1): 11–23.
Ingebritsen, C. (2006) Scandinavia in World Politics, New York: Rowman & Littlefield
Publishers.
Ingólfsdóttir, A.H. (2008) ‘Umhverfismál og utanríkisstefna: Stefna Íslands í samningum
um loftslagsbreytingar’ [Environmental Issues and Foreign Policy: Iceland’s Strategy in
Negotiations about Climate Treaties] in Ingimundarson, V. (ed.) Uppbrot hugmynda-
kerfis. Endurmótun íslenskrar utanríkisstefnu 1991–2007 [a book about Icelandic foreign
policy after the cold war] Reykjavík: Hið íslenska bókmenntafélag, pp. 253–278.
International Energy Agency (2012) ‘Nordic Energy Technology Perspective. At a
glance’, available online at: www.iea.org/etp/nordic/ (accessed 25 November 2013).
International Panel on Climate Change (2007) ‘Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report’,
Geneva: IPCC. Available online at: www.ipcc.ch/pdf/assessment-report/ar4/syr/ar4_
syr.pdf (accessed 29 November).
Kronsell, A. (2002) ‘Can Small States Influence EU Norms? Insights From Sweden´s
Participation in the Field of Environmental Politics’, Scandinavian Studies, 74(3):
287–304.
Kristoffersen, B. and Young, S. (2010) ‘Geographies of Security and Statehood in Nor-
way’s “Battle of the North” ’, Geoforum, 41: 577–584.
Mathew, J.T. (1989) ‘Redefining Security’, Foreign Affairs, 68(2):162–177.
Ministry for the Environment (2010) ‘Iceland’s Fifth National Communication on
Climate Change Under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate
Change’, Reykjavík: Icelandic Ministry for the Environment.
Nordic Council of Ministers (2011) Megatrends, Nordic council of Ministers, Copen-
hagen: ThemaNord, p. 525.
Nordic Energy Research (2012) ‘Nordic Greenhouse Gas Emissions and Targets’, avail-
able online at: www.nordicenergy.org/thenordicway/topic/policies/ (accessed 30
October 2012).
Neumann, I.B and Gstöhl, S. (2004) ‘Lilliputians in Gulliver´s World? Small States in
International Relations’, working paper, Reykjavík: Centre for Small State Studies,
University of Iceland.
Rosenthal, E. (2012) ‘Race is on as Ice Melt Reveals Arctic Treasures’, The New York
Times, 12 September 2012, available onlinat at: www.nytimes.com/2012/09/19/science/
earth/arctic-resources-exposed-by-warming-set-off-competition.html?pagewanted=al
(accessed 30 October 2012).
Salehyan, I. (2008) ‘Climate Change and Conflict’, Journal of Peace Research, 45(3):
315–326.
Vogler, J. (2008) ‘Environmental Issues’, Chapter 20 in Baylis, J., Smith, S. and Owens,
P. (eds) The Globalization of World Politics. An Introduction to International Rela-
tions, New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 350–366.
United Nations Development Programme (1994) Human Development Report 1994,
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Part II
Small state security in
Europe
This page intentionally left blank
6 The Nordic states and security
Clive Archer

Introduction
Since the end of the Cold War, the five Nordic states have reacted to their new
security environment in ways that demonstrate an awareness of the opportunities
provided for small states. They have also tried to adapt to new circumstances by
showing the strengths and weaknesses of small states of varying sizes in differ-
ing contexts.
The five Nordic states – Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway and Sweden –
are often placed together in international relations and frequently consider them-
selves as a Nordic group with much in common. However, their closeness in
areas such as culture, social welfare, justice and even economic matters has not
been matched by a common approach to security policy, or indeed in their land
size and population size (see Table 6.1).
The disappearance of the Cold War ended many outside restraints on the
security of the Nordic region and also brought in new security concepts, many of
which have been embraced by Nordic security decision-makers. Furthermore,

Table 6.1 The Nordic states: some comparisons

Area Population NATO/EU Defence expenditure Troops


member/link
km2 million US$2007 2008

Denmark 43,094 5.5 NATO, EU 4.2 billion 29,550


Finland 338,145 5.3 PfP, EU 3.2 billion 29,300
Iceland 103,000 0.3 NATO, EEA – –
Norway 323,802 4.7 NATO, EEA 5.6 billion 19,100
Sweden 450,295 9.1 PfP, EU 6.8 billion 16,900

Notes
Area and population statistics from The Central Intelligence Agency, The World Factbook, at www.
cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/wfbExt/region_eur.html (accessed 4 August 2012);
population figures for 2013, area for Denmark excludes Greenland and Faroes.
Defence expenditure and troop statistics from IISS (2009); manpower – army, navy and air force,
plus central support in Norway and joint force personnel (including civilians) in Denmark.
PfP: Partnership for Peace agreement with NATO.
EEA: European Economic Area agreement with the EU.
96 C. Archer
the five states made an effort in the Stoltenberg Report (Stoltenberg 2009) to find
the basis for common action on security matters. This combination of closeness
and divisions in security matters makes the responses of the five Nordic states
interesting in terms of defence and security analysis in the post-Cold War
period.

The background
Some elements of history already distinguish certain Nordic states from others.
They may all now be regarded as ‘small states’: but Denmark and, especially,
Sweden were great powers in their time that became ‘small’ – in the sense of
this volume – over the years. Norway, Finland and Iceland were born as small
states in the twentieth century, thus having their expectations already trimmed.
After World War II, in the 1948 attempt to establish a Nordic Defence Union,
Denmark, Norway and Sweden agreed on a high level of defence cooperation;
but negotiations broke down because Denmark and Norway wished to sign the
North Atlantic Treaty and Sweden did not. Indeed, military cooperation based
on these talks continued between the three states, often on a secret basis, well
into the Cold War.
NATO membership meant that Denmark, Norway and Iceland – especially the
first two – had increasingly close cooperation within NATO’s command structures.
Nevertheless the defence and security orientations of the three states were some-
what different. Denmark looked to NATO’s central front, but had residual interests
in the Atlantic through the defence of the Faroe Islands and Greenland. Norway’s
concerns were increasingly with the Kola Peninsula (where forces of the neigh-
bouring Soviet Union were massed) and the North Atlantic; while Iceland’s rela-
tions were mainly with the US, its defence protector.
The Cold War implanted deep defence and security differences between the
Nordic states, based on their strategic positions and alliance choices. Denmark
and Norway had decided to balance against the Soviet Union, rather than
bandwaggon with it – which was broadly the choice that Finland felt it had to
make. Iceland bandwaggoned with the US and Sweden found its own way of
balancing against the perceived power of the Soviet Union. However, the Nordic
governments chose to maintain a certain internal dynamic in the security field
that helped shape the Nordic region overall as ‘a low-tension area’, where the
Nordic states ‘chose to take into account the position and interests of their neigh-
bours when making decisions about security.’ This was less ‘the product of
deliberate design but rather the aggregated result of incremental decisions and
adjustment’ (Holst 1990: 8). The result was sometimes characterized as the
‘Nordic balance’.
During the Cold War, the Nordic governments saw the concept of security in
wide terms. The notion of ‘total defence’ was accepted, whereby society was pre-
pared to defend the state against attack by utilizing economic and social resources.
Similar ideas were seen in ‘civil defence’ in other states (such as the US and UK),
but the small homogenous Nordic countries were able to implement them more
The Nordic states and security 97
easily. In the Nordic states, security policy meant defence policy plus diplomacy,
economic policy and social policy.
The five Nordic states had the advantage of being a security community as
they conducted their mutual relations without expecting the use of force and
intra-Nordic policies were conducted almost as if they were domestic policies.
This meant that, in dealing with wider aspects of East–West relations (e.g. disar-
mament), North–South relations in the UN and international peacekeeping, the
Nordic states stressed non-zero-sum solutions and the wider acceptance of law-
based norms in international relations.
The diversification of the five Nordic states’ core security policies accord-
ing to the demands of the Cold War partly continued the domination of those
policies by Great Power considerations seen before 1945. Nevertheless, there
was some commonality within Nordic security policy and culture, and where
the governments could act together – for example in training for peacekeeping
– they did.

National challenges and responses


The end of the Cold War opened up new policy options for the security decision-
makers in the Nordic states, but also provided new security challenges. Nordic
decision-makers made different choices over time and by country in dealing with
these opportunities and challenges. The greatest variations can best be explained
by the perceived strategic position and culture of each state and the decision-
makers’ perceptions of the new international environment. There were increased
chances to pursue values and identity issues through autonomous actions, but
also heightened opportunities to enter into agreements and alliances with each
other and with other states.
While common security challenges have faced the Nordic states since 1989,
there are important differences, both in type and range, over time. The Nordic
region has seen a sizeable improvement in its traditional security situation.
The source of such security concerns has shifted from being Central Europe to
the High North above the Arctic Circle, where the Nordic states are important
actors. Also the Nordic states have defined military security concerns outside
the Atlantic area as being their business. The five states have varied in their
approach to non-traditional security concerns (see pp. 66–79). Generally
speaking and excepting Iceland and its economic security, no Nordic state is
in the front line of ‘new’ security challenges, though some are in the second
echelon of concern over terrorist matters and there are growing longer-term
issues about societal security.
In terms of policy responses, the five Nordic states have been ‘stuck with the
power configuration and its institutional expression’ (Mouritzen and Wivel
2005: 4). However, internal political, societal or economic factors have fed into
security responses, often as restraints. For example, public opinion has swayed
Sweden and Finland’s approach to NATO membership and also Icelandic
governments’ responses to economic challenges.
98 C. Archer
Finland
The end of the Soviet Union changed Finland’s security environment. However,
Russia’s military capability in the region endured, and the security intentions of
the Russian governments under Yeltsin and Putin were somewhat uncertain.
Thus Finland proceeded with caution when responding to the changes of 1989–
1991; but once free of the 1948 Treaty of Friendship, Cooperation and Mutual
Assistance with the Soviet Union, it directed its strategic aim towards becoming
fully integrated into the European Union (EU). Finland emphasized the security
community side of the EU and a ‘narrow notion of military non-alignment’
(Ojanen 2008: 56–58). Finland was active in bringing ‘the Petersberg Tasks’–
with their broad approach to security – into the ESDP, and by the end of 2004
Finland was committed to joining two EU battlegroups and became fully
involved in EU, UN and other international peace operations. It is now fully
engaged in international crisis management.
The core of Finland’s defence posture remained fairly untouched by the sur-
rounding strategic changes, reflecting the feeling that, locally, these might mean
less to Finland than to other states. The emphasis was on territorial defence
against an enemy that might seize Finnish territory, and conscription under-
pinned the doctrine of a ‘credible national defence’ (Ojanen 2008: 61). Further-
more engagement with NATO – though not full membership – has allowed
Finland greater interoperability of forces in the case of peacekeeping operations,
and has helped to strengthen Finland’s defence forces and the ability to receive
outside assistance (Government Report 2001: 26, 57–58).
The main challenge to Finland’s military defence has come through internal
factors. The 2012 Defence Forces Reform Concept identified a shrinking con-
scription age group, rising defence materiel prices and other cost increases as
being the stimuli for reform (Finnish Defence Forces 2012: 3). As a result, the
wartime forces will be further reduced from an earlier 450,000 and 350,000 in
2011 to about 230,000 in 2015 (Finnish Defence Forces 2012: 14): still a size-
able strength for a country of less than 5.5million people.
Finland has widened its concept of security since 1989. Traditionally, ‘total
defence’ has linked the public and private sectors and individual citizens and has
encompassed territorial defence, economic and civil defence, public safety, tech-
nical systems and health care (Government Resolution 2003). More generally,
key threats were seen in 2004 as including:

Terrorism, the threat of the proliferation and use of weapons of mass


destruction, regional conflicts and the use of military force, organized crime,
drugs and human trafficking, economic and technological risks, environ-
mental problems, population growth, population migrations and epidemics.
(Prime Minister’s Office 2004: 5)

An important moment in the Finnish response to global security challenges was


its response to the Asian tsunami of 26 December 2004, when 178 Finns were
The Nordic states and security 99
killed, but 3,300 were evacuated in five days after a Heads of Preparedness Com-
mittee – existing as part of the traditional total defence structure – was convened
to coordinate state, commercial and civil society action (T. Archer 2011: 187).
This fed into the 2006 report on Strategy Securing the Functions Vital to Society,
which identified a range of non-military threats – terrorism, pandemics, environ-
mental catastrophes and non-defence crises (Security and Defence Committee
2006: 48–58) – where a coordinated response was needed. In 2011, a report on
Preparedness and Comprehensive Security by the high-powered Hallberg Com-
mittee recommended that ‘preparedness must be based on the broadest security
thinking possible, that of comprehensive security, and on harnessing the
resources of the whole of society’; it concluded that no major reform of the
Finnish system of preparedness was needed, but did suggest some organizational
reforms. It declared that, ‘The strengths of Finnish society and the characteristics
of its administration form the foundation of preparedness’ (Prime Minister’s
Office 2011: 67) – a reasonable assumption for a relatively homogenous society.
As these security threats and challenges were ‘increasingly cross-border in
nature’ (ibid.), Finland’s response became more international. The European
Security and Defence Policy (ESDP) became an important element in Finnish
security solutions but saw Finland moving ‘obliquely forward’, putting ‘the
brakes on more doctrinal issues and accelerating on tangible commitments’
(Ojanen 2008: 74). Finland has not taken up the option of NATO membership,
an issue that still divides Finnish society. Nordic cooperation on security matters
is more pragmatic and less controversial (see pp. 105–6), as is the country’s con-
tribution to UN operations. More broadly, Finland has used the institutions in its
region – the Council for Baltic Sea States and the EU’s Northern Dimension – to
spread notions of security community to the Baltic Sea area and build inclusive
networks.
Nevertheless, among the Nordic states, Finland remains the one that often
sees its main challenges as being ‘Russia, Russia, Russia’1 and has a strongly
territorial, defence-led response. The wider security agenda is recognized, espe-
cially in Finland’s engagement with the EU and in internal administrative
changes. Most importantly, Finland has, since 1990, bandwaggoned with the
West, but has also tried to ameliorate the Russian presence in the region by using
‘soft security’ institutions.

Sweden
Sweden has seen a considerable change in its strategic position since 1989, and a
variety of governments have altered its defence posture and policy away from its
previous position of being well armed and free from peacetime alliances. For
Sweden, EU membership was a response to the Swedish economic model falter-
ing in the early 1990s. Nevertheless, the country responded to the ESDP’s evolu-
tion and Balkan events in the 1990s by Europeanizing its security policy. It
became engaged in peace operations in the former Yugoslavia and was closely
associated with NATO’s Partnership for Peace. Sweden accepted a broad
100 C. Archer
security concept – familiar from its Cold War practice – widening it to include
terrorism, natural disasters and links to development and human rights (Regerin-
gen 2007: 1).
After 1991, in military defence, Sweden concluded that threats to its territory
had broadly disappeared, and during the 2000s the basis of Swedish security
shifted from territorial defence to international crisis management (Regeringen
2004: 6–7, 13–14). However, after the Russo-Georgian War of 2008, a slight
move back to territorial defence was made.
The longer-term trend suggests a physical widening of Sweden’s security
scope to encompass possible regional and global adverse affects on Sweden’s
security. Sweden always considered world security to be indivisible – thus its
participation in UN operations – but after the Cold War, its military posture
became more specifically aimed at responding to outside threats. This repres-
ented a ‘first-order change’ from deterrence by denial (attacking Sweden being
made not worth the cost) to active defence of Swedish interests by international
crisis management, with the first line of defence being abroad (Wedin 2008: 53).
Close to home, Sweden agreed not to be passive if other Nordic or EU states
were attacked, accepting that it should ‘have the capability to provide and
receive military support’ (Regeringskansliet 2011).
These policy developments were reflected in the provision for Sweden’s
armed forces: they were cut from 600,000 by 1999 (IISS 1999: 98–99) to 91,000
in 2009 (Försvarsmakten 2010: 11–13). Furthermore, male conscription was
replaced in 2010 by contracted personnel. The 2008 Russo-Georgian War led the
government to adjust the required mobilization time for most of the armed forces
from a year to a week; the defence minister also proposed to end the distinction
between Sweden’s national effort and its international duties, and placed an
emphasis on the ability to act – individually or with others – in response to
threats in the region ‘at short notice’ (Regeringskansliet 2009).
Sweden also developed its capabilities in the soft security area. Together with
Finland, Sweden pressed for the Petersberg tasks – with their emphasis on soft
security – to be the basis for the ESDP, and led in proposing the development of
EU civil intervention capabilities. Again, the Asian tsunami in 2004 was a key
moment for Sweden, but the country’s response was seen as wanting (T. Archer
2011: 187). Since then, Swedish civil preparedness has been improved with the
Swedish Civil Contingencies Agency (MSB), with 850 staff, coordinating Swe-
den’s response and cooperating with the EU. This covers all forms of emergen-
cies (Swedish Civil Contingencies Agency 2009).
In 2010, the government recommended a comprehensive approach to crisis
management. Defence and societal crisis preparedness were later given a
common budget line, leading to crisis management becoming more integrated
with the defence structure. The MSB now ‘holds the mandate for a holistic and
all hazards approach to emergency management . . . from everyday accidents up
to major disasters’ (Swedish Civil Contingencies Agency 2009).
The military and civilians work closely in dealing with a variety of events:
the spring floods in Sweden in 2010, the cyber-attack against official sites in
The Nordic states and security 101
Estonia in April 2007, the oil clean-up in the Baltic in May 2003, mass vaccina-
tion against swine influenza in April 2008, help to Haiti after an earthquake and
evacuation of Swedes from the Lebanon in July 2006 (Försvarsdepartementet
2010). These scenarios would all come under category ‘D’, (‘Accidents and
Natural Hazards’), in Table 2.1 modelling a typical small-state agenda in Chapter
2 of this book (p. 31), with a touch of categories ‘B’ (‘Non-state Violence –
Cyber-attacks’) and ‘C’ (‘Economic Security’, albeit abroad). The authorities
also work together with civil society (with a section headed ‘All Responsible’),
NGOs such as the Red Cross and Save the Children, as well as with international
authorities such as the Nordic ‘Haga’ cooperation group (see p. 106), the EU and
the UN. All this demonstrates a Swedish commitment to the comprehensive
model of security.

Norway
Norway proceeded with caution after the Cold War, as it still had a sizeable –
and unpredictable – nuclear power on its northern doorstep.
Norway was already locked into NATO, and subsequent Norwegian govern-
ments have aimed at enhancing this link in order to keep the US and/or major
EU powers by its side. The worst danger was neglect by both, and throughout
the 1990s Norway sought to prevent this marginalization. First, its multilateral-
ism aimed at enveloping itself in regional cooperative institutions to counter
international anarchy and stabilize northern Europe. Second, it became more
involved in ESDP, though it was not an EU member. Norway offered personnel
to serve in ESDP operations, hoping to raise its status amongst EU states – what
Græger called ‘troops for influence’ (2002: 35) – and ensure promises of rein-
forcement for Norway. However, the expected influence did not arrive and,
anyhow, Norwegian troops available for peacekeeping were used in UN, OSCE
and NATO operations, with few being left for ESDP actions.
By the mid-2000s, Norwegian armed forces were more flexible. The Tele-
mark battalion contributed to ISAF in Afghanistan where, for the first time since
1945, Norwegian aircraft were used to attack enemy positions. Norwegian forces
contributed to the NATO standing maritime force in the Mediterranean and to
NATO’s Kosovo operation. Norwegian aircraft were some of the first to bomb
positions of Gaddafi’s forces in Libya in 2011.
After the Russian-Georgian War, Norway re-emphasized that ‘NATO’s role
as the primary guarantor for the security of its members, embodied in Article V,
collective defence and security consultations, should continue to be the bedrock
of alliance activity’ (Barth Eide 2009). Norway saw the NATO strategy adopted
at the November 2010 Lisbon Summit as showing the Allies’ continued interest
in areas such as the High North (Faremo 2010), despite further substantial with-
drawal of US troops from Europe. Indeed, this led to a closer Norwegian military
relationship with its old ally, the United Kingdom.
As well as widening its security horizon since 1989 – while keeping one eye
firmly on the High North – Norway has also expanded its official understanding
102 C. Archer
of security. The Norwegian Defence Minister noted in 2000 that ‘Society at large
has also become more vulnerable’ with increased vulnerability to sabotage being
of importance for an oil and gas producer such as Norway (Løwer 2000: 2). By
2008, this had become a wider range of societal threats requiring the kinds of
responses identified by Alyson Bailes in Chapter 4. More recently, both the Nor-
wegian Ministry of Defence and the Ministry of Justice and Police have adopted
a wide definition of societal security. The bombing of central Oslo and shooting
of civilians on 22 July 2011, by one person, caused the Norwegian government
to re-examine both the governmental and societal response to those events; this
has both strengthened the agents of government dealing with crises, and
entrenched their place in society.
All this has meant that Norway has an extensive range of security commit-
ments for a small state. Its oil and gas wealth has necessitated some of those, but
has also provided greater resources to help respond to them. However, it is
notable that Norway still pursues alliance strategies to bring military security to
its shores, and its diplomacy is clearly based on a view of international relations
whereby any strengthening of international norms and institutions benefits relat-
ively less powerful states such as Norway. These two tracks – one more Realist,
the other more Liberal Institutionalist – are woven into Norway’s security now,
as they were before.

Denmark
Denmark was the Nordic country that benefited most from the strategic changes
after the Cold War, and policies since adopted have shown a willingness to re-
think the country’s security policy, though still within the context of the Atlantic
Alliance. Its post-Cold War security policy thus reflects not just international
developments but also the debate within Denmark.
Even before the end of the Cold War, the Danish Foriegn Minister and leader
of the key Social Liberal party agreed the broad outlines of a post-Cold War
Danish foreign and security policy that brought to an end the period of Denmark
being a ‘footnote country’ in NATO.2 By early 1992, Denmark was no longer
faced with the prospect of a massive attack; the main threats to European
security were seen as arms proliferation, Islamic fundamentalism, the population
explosion, wealth differences between North and South, the pressure of immi-
gration and environmental threats. Security policy was ‘more widely defined’,
with economic aspects, among others, playing a greater role (Rapport . . . 1992:
27, 32–33, author’s translation).
Danish decision-makers sought a more ambitious security policy than the
mostly responsive attitudes of the Cold War. This new policy of ‘active interna-
tionalism’ was ‘a fundamental break with the past and with traditional Danish
foreign policy [which was] to be less conditioned by geopolitical realities and
more focussed on actively contributing to the creation of new rules of co-
operation and co-existence’. The Foriegn Minister, Niels Helveg Petersen, said
that Denmark had grown out of its small state role and was in the lead in areas
The Nordic states and security 103
such as peacekeeping and aid policy (Holm 2002: 21). Indeed, it was in the latter
area vis-à-vis the Baltic States, that Denmark was most proactive in the 1990s,
providing materiel assistance to Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania, and promoting
their quest for NATO and EU membership. Activist Baltic policies led Denmark
to see itself as ‘a pioneer state’ in East and Central Europe (Archer 1999: 49–52,
64–65).
With Denmark opting out of the defence aspects of the EU’s Common
Security and Defence Policy,3 its security policy was NATO-oriented. Early in
the 1990s, Denmark restructured its armed forces by organizing an international
brigade, and supported NATO’s reaction forces and multinational divisions. It
was active in the Balkans in peace operations (Rynning 2003: 27). However, the
Danish response to 9/11 was of a different order – for the first time, Denmark
was prepared to send its troops ‘out of area’ to fight for a cause, first in Afghan-
istan and then in Iraq. The new foreign policy doctrine of the centre-right gov-
ernment in November 2002 talked about full engagement in institutions such as
NATO and the EU, activism and a proactive search for partners, promotion of
the rule of international law and niche activities that allow a small country to
make a difference (cited in Rynning 2003: 29–30). The Danish Prime Minister,
Anders Fogh Rasmussen, clearly closing the chapter of Denmark’s footnote
policy, stated in 2003 that ‘my Government wishes to depart from this tradition
of reluctance. We feel we have a role to play and we wish to play it’ (Rasmussen
2003: 198). The view was that, after 9/11, ‘Denmark had direct enemies and
needed to deploy and use military force to defeat them’ (Ringsmose and Rynning
2008: 55). According to the multi-party 2004 defence agreement, Danish forces
would focus on ‘high-intensity operations’, fighting wars rather than peacekeep-
ing, and would be rapidly deployable. Conscription was to be phased out (Ras-
mussen 2005: 46). This line was followed by the centre-left government that
came into power in 2011 and sent soldiers to Senegal and Mali to ‘stand for
international law and order as opposed to the anarchy of militant Islam’
(Hækkerup 2013: 8).
Danish politicians embraced wide definitions of security after the Cold War.
The Foreign Minister, Niels Helveg Petersen (1997: 273), differentiated between
hard security – ‘mainly the territorial defence against an outside aggressor’ – and
soft security, which encompassed the non-military, civic aspects of security,
though he noted that soft security instruments were more effective when under-
pinned by a hard security framework (ibid.: 277). Denmark has developed a
crisis management capability whereby the Danish Emergency Management
Agency (DEMA) coordinates action. In a crisis abroad, the Ministry of Foreign
Affairs, together with DEMA and the Ministry of Defence – which together
make up Denmark’s international alarm centre – decide on responses to requests
for assistance (Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Denmark 2010: 13).
Nationally, legislation was introduced after the Asian tsunami to bring the fire
and rescue authorities under the Ministry of Defence acting through DEMA
(Danish Emergency Management Agency 2011a). National incidents that cannot
be dealt with regionally are the concern of the National Operative staff (NOST),
104 C. Archer
chaired by the National Danish Police. Incidents of political importance can be
dealt with by one or more of three organizations: the Government Security Com-
mittee, consisting of the Prime Minister and key ministers; the Senior Officials
Security Committee, with the permanent secretaries of those ministries and the
heads of the Defence Intelligence Service and the Security Intelligence Service;
and the Crisis Management Group, made up of the under-secretaries of the above
authorities together with the Defence Command Denmark, the National Danish
Police and DEMA (Danish Emergency Management Agency 2011b). Among
the tasks listed for the armed forces are civilian ones such as maritime and
environmental surveillance, the fight against pollution, fisheries inspection,
rescue services, ice-breaking and participation in emergency preparation (Fors-
varet 2012).
Denmark’s active security policy has shown that a small state can make a dif-
ference, especially within an alliance, but has also demonstrated the political and
economic constraints on such extrovert policies.

Iceland
Iceland’s security has developed in two stages since 1989: first, following the
downfall of the Soviet Union, and then when US forces left Iceland in 2006. A
new set of parallel uncertainties came with the economic downturn of 2008,
which left Iceland particularly exposed.
In the immediate post-Cold War period, Iceland’s main security task became
the defence and control of Icelandic airspace – previously undertaken by the US
– after the US military left the Keflavik air base in 2006. Other NATO states,
such as Norway and France, have provided air patrols and ship visits on a rota
basis, but this provides neither the size nor the consistency of the previous US
force. An Icelandic Defence Agency established in 2008, took over some
defence and security tasks; it operated Iceland’s air defence system, prepared
defence exercises, supervised host nation support and represented Iceland in
NATO defence meetings. However, it was disbanded by 2010 with its activities
being divided mainly between the Foreign Ministry, the Icelandic Coastguard
and the Ministry of the Interior (Ministry for Foreign Affairs (Iceland) 2010).
Another issue was how Iceland might contribute to non-military aspects of
international peace operations. From 1994, Iceland provided civilian personnel
to UN operations in the Balkans and, in September 2001, established an Icelan-
dic Crisis Response Unit (ICRU) consisting mainly of police, medical staff,
lawyers and air traffic controllers. The latter deployed to Priština airport under
NATO supervision from 2002 to 2004 and to Kabul International Airport until
2005. ICRU members were also engaged in missions in Iraq, Morocco, Turkey,
Sri Lanka, Kosovo, Bosnia-Herzegovina and Algeria. Iceland worked mainly
through NATO, the EU, the UN and the OSCE (Bailes and Thorhallsson 2006:
331–340).
The work of ICRU became controversial within Iceland, as some regarded it
as becoming militarized (ibid.: 337). By 2009, a commission had undertaken a
The Nordic states and security 105
risk assessment for Iceland after the departure of the US forces. It took ‘a broad
and inclusive definition of security, encompassing “new threats” posed by
global/transnational, societal, and human factors’ (Ministry for Foreign Affairs
(Iceland) 2009: 1). It concentrated on three categories: national security and
state-centred threats, societal and civil security threats that target ‘social groups,
identities, values and civil infrastructure’ and ‘globally-induced risks to individ-
uals and society by transnational factors such as environmental disasters, pan-
demics, climate change, terrorism, human trafficking, and weapons of mass
destruction’ (ibid.: 1–2). Reporting after the full impact of the 2008 economic
crash on Icelandic banks and society, the commission considered this had
‘revealed the vulnerability of Icelandic society to a systemic breakdown’
(ibid.: 3). It did not see a direct short or medium-term military threat, but saw
long-term uncertainties with the increasing importance of the High North. It
mentioned greater threats in pandemics, natural disasters and organized crime,
and potential problems with the social exclusion of immigrants, the opening of
new shipping routes and organized cyber-attacks (ibid.: 5–12). The commission
made 25 recommendations, but governments have thus far not taken steps to
develop them into an official security strategy and/or action programme.
Iceland is a typical small state that finds its security environment buffeted by
outside events such as the US exodus from military bases and the global reces-
sion. Yet Icelandic policy on security matters has depended much on the
outcome of internal political debate, and Iceland has shown itself willing to con-
front the IMF and the UK over ‘Icesave’. A country used to natural disasters –
on land and at sea – is well-placed to face the challenges that come under the
broader definition of security, though its citizens’ independence of mind may
lead to continued disagreements over security policy and a rejection of EU
membership.

Nordic challenges and responses


As a collective response to events in the Baltic region, the Nordic countries
pressed the case of the Baltic States’ membership of NATO and of the European
Union. Denmark, in particular, helped to establish the Council of the Baltic Sea
States with the help of Germany and the other Nordic states. Elsewhere, Norwe-
gian, Finnish and Swedish troops contributed to a Nordic peacekeeping battalion
in Macedonia in the mid-1990s.
Cooperation in practical security aspects became more institutionalized in the
2000s. The Nordic institutions started to discuss security, and Nordic ministers
of defence met, claiming by 2005 that ‘Nordic countries have had a comprehen-
sive cooperation in defence and security policies’ (Ministry of Defence, Finland,
2005). This consisted, inter alia, of NORDCAPS (the Nordic Coordinated
Arrangement for Military Peace Support), NORDAC (Nordic Armaments Co-
operation) and NORDSUP (the Nordic support structure), all of which were
unified into NORDEFCO – Nordic Defence Co-operation – in December 2009
(Archer 2010: 46–48).
106 C. Archer
The Nordic and Baltic States have taken on a wide selection of ‘soft security’
tasks in the Baltic region, ranging from tackling cyber-attacks and reinforcing
maritime accident response to common action on cross-border crime and miti-
gating the effects of climate change. From 2009, the five Nordic ministers
responsible for civil emergencies have developed the so-called ‘Haga’ coopera-
tion on community preparedness for withstanding and managing social crises
(Regeringskansliet 2013). Institutions used include the EU, the Council for
Baltic Sea States and Nordic organizations.
Practical security cooperation by the Nordic countries has become more pos-
sible and desirable in the post-Cold War period. The independent Stoltenberg
Report on strengthening security cooperation among the Nordic states drew
official responses from all the Nordic governments, broadly welcoming its ideas
on potential cooperation in disaster response, maritime monitoring, air surveil-
lance over Iceland and search and rescue in the Arctic region (Archer, 2010:
51). By April 2011, the five Nordic Foreign Ministers had agreed a common
‘solidarity clause’ guaranteeing mutual help for non-warlike threats and emer-
gencies (Den nordiske solidaritetserklæringen 2011). The membership of all
five states in the Arctic Council, and the opening up of the Arctic region, offer
another opportunity for the Nordic states to define common interests. The five
Nordic states, with Russia, the US and Canada, agreed a legally binding docu-
ment on aeronautical and maritime search and rescue at an Arctic Council
meeting in May 2011 (Arctic Council 2011) and another on cooperation on
marine oil pollution preparedness and response at their 2013 Kiruna meeting
(Arctic Council Secretariat 2013).
Why have the Nordic states not yet decided to have a common security
system? While some of the weight of history has been washed away after 1989,
differences remain in the states’ deeper strategic cultures. They have developed
very different behaviours and attitudes in terms of military doctrines, civil-
military relations, procurement and grand strategy. Over the last decade there
have been differences over how best to ‘cause’ security and what instruments to
use. Denmark has considered its international position to be enhanced by partici-
pating in wars, including those in Afghanistan, Libya and Iraq, whereas Norway
– despite its deployment in Afghanistan and Libya – has been seen as emphasis-
ing peace brokering in Indonesia, Sri Lanka and Sudan. Norway and Finland
have emphasized security through defence of the homeland more than Sweden
and Denmark. Since the 2009 economic downturn, Iceland has almost exclu-
sively seen the causes of security/insecurity in economic and societal terms.
Over the decades, the four armed countries have restructured their defences dif-
ferently, with Denmark moving away from a volunteer army to a lighter, more
mobile force than that in Finland. Furthermore, the European Union has had a
differential effect on the strategies of the five states, partly because they have
differing relations with the EU and partly because they have responded differ-
ently to what the EU has on offer.
The Nordic states and security 107
An evaluation
The Nordic states are generally regarded as ‘small states’, though Sweden has
had sizeable military strength and a large arms industry. Defining states as being
‘small’ in relational terms brings out the fact that Sweden and, to some extent
Denmark, had a certain regional strength in the post-Cold War Baltic area.
During the Cold War period, all five states were ‘small’ in relation to the two
superpowers and states such as the United Kingdom and Germany. The main
understanding of security was in military-diplomatic terms, and the weighting
given to states in the security field was primarily in terms of armaments, armed
forces and, partly, diplomatic ability. The Cold War defined the security policies
of the Nordic states, dividing them in terms of alliance. This partly constrained
these small states, but also encouraged them to find shelter with larger allies
against threats they could not manage alone. However, some space was left for
individual and collective activity in the security field that was less compelling
for the more powerful countries. Sweden could advance disarmament initiatives
such as the Undén Plan. Finland hosted the Conference on Security and Cooper-
ation in Europe and advanced ideas for a Nordic nuclear-weapon-free zone.
Norway and Denmark instituted their non-nuclear ‘base and ban’ policies. Col-
lectively, the Nordic states – whether consciously or not – promoted the area as
one of low tension and also cooperated in the field of United Nations
peacekeeping.
The end of the Cold War led to a radical change in the power calculations in
the Nordic region. For some, especially Norway, the relative deliquescence of
power in the North was not enough to free them totally from traditional military
concerns. For Finland, the power vacuum in the East in the early 1990s was an
opportunity for a strategic shift to join the European Union. Sweden also had an
opportunity to act as a regional power and to be active with other Western
powers in the wider world. Denmark saw the most radical change, with its active
internationalism and its high alliance-loyalty in terms of the US, contrasting with
its footnote-strewn reservations within NATO in the 1980s.
Understanding defence in wide terms was already common in the Cold War
Nordic region, but the broadening out of the security concept since 1989
allowed the Nordic states a wider menu for choice than before. The Nordic
states have been in the van of small states generally in emphasizing economic,
resource-related, human and environmental security. Despite their size, they
could play to relative strengths and could find niches outside the military field.
In fields such as environmental policy, the treatment of refugees and the man-
agement of disasters, their comparative strengths showed. With the exception
of Iceland, the Nordic economies demonstrated robustness in the face of eco-
nomic perils from 2008 onwards. Icelandic society, with its high social cohe-
sion, did survive some of the worst economic storms of the period, and while
its centre-left government decided that the longer-term answer was to shelter
within the EU, the successor centre-right government felt confident enough in
2013 to abandon this route.
108 C. Archer
The ending of Cold War constraints and the widening of the security concept
provided extra opportunities for Nordic cooperation. Within the Baltic region,
the Nordic countries individually and collectively shepherded the Baltic States in
a Liberal Institutionalist direction. This emphasis on common values – liberal
democratic ones plus elements of the Nordic social welfare society – as under-
pinning Nordic or national identities, was matched by practical cooperation in
Nordic and other settings, but is occasionally at odds with working together in
forums such as the EU. The Nordic states have continued to pick and choose the
elements of European integration that suited them, though a commitment, once
made, was whole-hearted. By the end of the 2000s, all Nordic states – or combi-
nations of two or three of them – were cooperating on defence and security
issues, especially at the practical level, leading to Stoltenberg’s suggestion of
more formalized coordination. This has further increased the relative importance
of collective action by the states when meeting both their own and outside needs,
though we are unlikely to witness a grand scheme similar to that of the 1948
Nordic Defence Union.
The five Nordic states – as small countries – still have unanswered security
dilemmas. Their own power shrinks by the side of Russian or US military might.
They are more evenly balanced when non-military security is being considered
and when they act regionally, as in the Baltic Sea. Furthermore, they find their
positions less at a disadvantage when dealing through international organiza-
tions, such as the Arctic Council, or using international law, as with the Law of
the Sea. Nevertheless, there is still a residue of uneven power. For Iceland, there
is the question of who patrols its airspace; for Norway, the issue of continued
Russian military strength on its borders. Denmark has to decide whether to join
an EU defence system and also how to manage the security implications of a
Greenlandic and/or Faroese move to independence. For Finland, the conscription
question arises. For both Sweden and Finland, the issue of full membership of
NATO awaits. Even together, the Nordic area is still a small region of small
states.
Does the Nordic example have anything to show other small states in their
security policies? First, even the small Nordic states during the harshest years of
the Cold War were not without choice: wise policies and national cohesion made
a difference. Second, wider strategic differences can trump common cultural and
political affinities. Third, the widening of the security agenda since the end of
the Cold War has meant increased opportunities for small states. These can be
effectively exploited when countries have a speciality (such as Iceland in the
case of energy security) or are prepared to spend resources on creating a niche
(such as Norway in environmental security). In these cases, values can be pro-
moted and identities entrenched. Furthermore, the reflection outwards of
domestic values – for example, the role of women in governance in all the
Nordic states – provides an enduring source of strength. Finally, collective action
can act as a force multiplier. Bringing together the small, like-minded Nordic
states can produce effective action in areas such as peacekeeping or Swedish–
Finnish cooperation on an amphibious unit. Calculations have to be made as to
The Nordic states and security 109
how much autonomy to give up in decision-making in order to gain greater
control through influence within joint arrangements. The experience of the
Nordic states has been that, while each state has its red lines of autonomy, the
gains from collective action are there to be collected.

Notes
1 In 2007, the then Minister of Defence said that ‘the three main security challenges for
Finland today are Russia, Russia, and Russia’ (Häkämies 2007: 6).
2 Previously, the Social Liberals had supported the Social Democrat-led policy of enter-
ing reservations (footnotes) against NATO’s nuclear policies.
3 The opt-outs obtained at the Edinburgh European Council meeting encouraged Danish
voters to accept the Maastricht Treaty, which they had previously rejected in a
referendum.

Bibliography
Archer, C. (1999) ‘Nordic Swans and Baltic Cygnets’, Cooperation and Conflict, 34(1):
47–71.
Archer, C. (2010) ‘The Stoltenberg Report and Nordic Security: Big Idea, Small Steps’,
in Hvidt, N. and Mouritzen. H. (eds) Danish Foreign Policy Yearbook 2010, Copen-
hagen: Danish Institute for International Studies, pp. 43–74.
Archer, T. (2011) Between Kant and Hobbes. Finnish Security Policy after European
Integration, Manchester: Manchester Metropolitan University, PhD.
Arctic Council (2011) ‘Task Force on Search and Rescue’, available online at: www.
arctic-council.org/index.php/en/about-us/task-forces/282-task-force-on-search-and-
rescue (accessed 27 August 2012).
Arctic Council Secretariat (2013) ‘Kiruna Declaration’, available online at: www.arctic-
council.org/index.php/en/document- archive/category/425-main- documents-from-
kiruna-ministerial-meeting (accessed 29 June 2013).
Bailes, A.J.K. and Thorhallsson, B. (2006) ‘Iceland and the European Security and
Defence Policy’, in Bailes, A.J.K., Herolf, G. and Sundelius, B. (eds) The Nordic
Countries and the European Security and Defence Policy, Oxford: Oxford University
Press, pp. 328–348.
Barth Eide, E. (2009) ‘Collective Defence in Today’s Security Environment’, available
online at: www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/fd/aktuelt/taler_artikler/politisk_ledelse/statssekre-
taer_espen_barth_eide/2009/collective-defence-in-todays-security-en.html?id=582015
(accessed 2 October 2011).
Danish Emergency Management Agency (2011a) ‘The Emergency Management Act’,
available online at: brs.dk/eng/legislation/act/Pages/the_emergency_management_act.
aspx (accessed 25 August 2012).
Danish Emergency Management Agency (2011b) ‘National Crisis Management’, avail-
able online at: brs.dk/eng/emergency_management/national_emergency_management_
organisation/Pages/national_emergency_management_organisation.aspx (accessed 25
August 2012).
Den nordiske solidaritetserklæringen (2011) Available online at: www.regjeringen.no/
upload/UD/Vedlegg/Nordisk%20samarbeid/Den_nordiske_solidaritetserklaeringen.pdf
(accessed 6 October 2011).
110 C. Archer
Faremo, G. (2010) ‘NATO retter nå oppmerksomheten hjemover’, available online at:
www.regjeringen.no/nb/dep/fd/aktuelt/taler_artikler/ministeren/taler-og-artikler-av-
forsvarsminister-gr/2010/nato-retter-na-oppmerksomheten-hjemover.html?id=625243
(accessed 2 October 2011).
Finnish Defence Forces (2012) ‘Defence Forces Reform Concept’, available online at: www.
defmin.fi/files/2054/Defence_Forces_reform_concept_8212.pdf (accessed 9 August 2012).
Forsvaret (2012) ‘Opgaver’, available online at: www2.forsvaret.dk/omos/opgaver/Pages/
opgaver.aspx (accessed 25 August 2012).
Försvarsdepartementet (2010) ‘Trygg tillsammans’, available online at: www.sakerhet-
spolitik.se/Global/PDF/PDF%20Elever/Trygg%20tillsammans_Webb.pdf (accessed 25
August 2012).
Försvarsmakten (2010) ‘Försvarsmaktens Årsredovisning 2009 Resultatredovisning, resul-
taträkning, balansräkning, anslagsredovisning,finansieringsanalys och noter’, available
online at: www.forsvarsmakten.se/upload/dokumentfiler/%C3%85rsredovisningar/%C3
%85rsredovisning%202009/%C3%85R%2009%20.pdf (accessed 17 August 2012).
Government Report (2001) Finnish Security and Defence Policy 2001, UaVL 6/2001 vp
– VNS 2/2001 vp.
Government Resolution (2003) ‘Government Resolution on Securing the Functions Vital to
Society’, available online at: www.defmin.fi/files/168/2587_2047_Government_Resolu-
tion_On_Securing_The_Functions_Vital_To_Society_1_.pdf (accessed 3 December 2008).
Græger, N. (2002) ‘Norway and the EU’s Defence Dimension: A “Troops for Influence”
Strategy’, in Græger, N., Larsen, H. and Ojanen, H. (eds) The ESDP and the Nordic
Countries. Four Variations on a Theme, Helsinki: UPI, pp. 33–89.
Hækkerup, N. (2013) ‘En ny realisme – principper for en aktiv forsvars- og sikkerheds-
politik’, available online at: www.fmn.dk/forsvarsministeren/talerogartikler/Docu-
ments/FM-tale-ved-CMS-seminar-5marts2013.pdf (accessed 29 June 2013).
Häkämies, J. (2007) ‘Finland: Similar but Different’, Speech by Minister of Defence
Häkämies at CSIS Washington, DC 6 September 2007, available online at: www.
defmin.fi/index.phtml?663_m=3335&l=en&s=270 (accessed 1 July 2008).
Holm, H.-H. (2002) ‘Danish Foreign Policy Activism. The Rise and Decline’, Danish
Foreign Policy Yearbook 2002, Copenhagen: Danish Institute of International Affairs,
pp. 19–45.
Holst, J.J. (1990) ‘Foreword. Nordic Security: Past Mirrors and Future Faces’, The Annals
of the Academy of Political and Social Sciences, November: 8–15.
IISS (1999) The Military Balance 1999–2000, International Institute for Strategic Studies,
London: Oxford University Press.
IISS (2009) The Military Balance 2009, International Institute for Strategic Studies,
London: IISS.
Løwer, E. (2000) ‘Our Defence in an International Perspective’, Address to Oslo Military
Society, 10 January 2000, Oslo: mimeo.
Ministry of Defence, Finland (2005) ‘Press Release from Nordic-Baltic Ministers
meeting’, available online at: www.defmin.fi (accessed 1 October 2011).
Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Denmark (2010) ‘When disaster strikes – Denmark will
help’, available online at: www.netpublikationer.dk/um/10504/pdf/when_disaster_
strikes.pdf (accessed 25 August 2012).
Ministry for Foreign Affairs (Iceland) (2009) ‘A Risk Assessment for Iceland: Global,
Societal, and Military Factors. Summary of the Findings of an Interdisciplinary
Commission’, available online at: www.mfa.is/media/Skyrslur/A_Risk_Assessment_
for_Iceland_-_English_Summary.pdf.
The Nordic states and security 111
Ministry for Foreign Affairs (Iceland) (2010) ‘Report of the Working Group on Security
and Administrative Reorganisation’, available online at: www.mfa.is/media/MFA_pdf/
Skyrsla-starfshopsins_ENS.pdf (accessed 25 August 2012).
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (2005) The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration,
London: Routledge.
Ojanen, H. (2008) ‘Finland and the ESDP: “Obliquely forwards”?’ in Archer, C. (ed.)
New Security Issues in Northern Europe The Nordic and Baltic States and the ESDP,
Abingdon and New York: Routledge, pp. 56–77.
Petersen, N.H. (1997) ‘Security Cooperation and Integration in the Baltic Region. The
Role of the European Union: Soft security?’ in Christensen, S.A. and Wæver, O. (eds)
DUPIDOK 1996. Dansk udenrigspolitisk dokumentation, Copenhagen: Dansk Uden-
rigspolitisk Institut, pp. 273–278.
Prime Minister’s Office (2004) Finnish Security and Defence Policy 2004 Helsinki: Prime
Minister’s Office Publications 18/2004.
Prime Minister’s Office (2011) ‘Preparedness and Comprehensive Security. Committee
Report’, Helsinki: Prime Minister’s Office Publications 18/2011, available online at:
www.vnk.fi/julkaisukansio/2010/j21-varautuminen- j1511-beredskap- j1811-
preparedness/PDF/en.pdf (accessed 9 August 2012).
Rapport om Forsvarets fremtidige struktur og størrelse. Rapport fra det af Forsvarsmin-
isteren den 11. april 1991 nedsatte Udvalg vedrørende forsvarets udvikling mv. 2 marts
1992 (1992), Copenhagen: Ministry of Defence.
Rasmussen, A.F. (2003) ‘Speech by Prime Minister Anders Fogh Rasmussen at the
Woodrow Wilson Center, Washington, DC, 9 May 2003’, Danish Foreign Policy Year-
book 2004, Copenhagen: Danish Institute for International Studies, pp. 190–198.
Rasmussen, M.V. (2005) ‘Camp Eden: The 2004 Defence Agreement, Military Power
and Danish Values’, Danish Foreign Policy Yearbook 2005, Copenhagen: Danish Insti-
tute for International Studies, pp. 41–64.
Regeringen (2004) ‘Swedish Government Bill 2004/05:5. Our Future Defence. The focus
of Swedish Defence Policy 2005–2007’, available online at: www.regeringen.se/
content/1/c6/05/57/44/224a4b3c.pdf (accessed 9 August 2012).
Regeringen (2007) ‘Statement of Government Policy in the Parliamentary Debate on
Foreign Affairs, Wednesday 14 February 2007’, available online at: www.regeringen.
se/content/1/c6/03/95/92/fa8a1932.pdf (accessed 9 August 2012).
Regeringskansliet (2009) ‘Ett användbart försvar – med kraftigt stärkt försvarsförmåga’,
available online at: www.regeringen.se/sb/d/11431/a/122883 (accessed 9 August 2012).
Regeringskansliet (2011) ‘Sweden’s Security Policy’, available online at: www.sweden.
gov.se/sb/d/3103/a/116839 (accessed 9 August 2012).
Regeringskansliet (2013) ‘Försvarsministern värd för det nordiska Hagamötet’, (Defence
Minister hosted the Nordic Haga meeting), available online at: www.regeringen.se/
sb/d/17021/a/218686 (accessed 29 June 2013).
Ringsmose, J. and Rynning, S. (2008) ‘The Impeccable Ally? Denmark, NATO and the
Uncertain Future of Top Tier membership’, Danish Foreign Policy Yearbook 2008,
Copenhagen: Danish Institute for International Studies, pp. 55–84.
Rynning, S. (2003) ‘Denmark as a Strategic Actor? Danish Security Policy after 11
September,’ Danish Foreign Policy Yearbook 2003, Copenhagen: Danish Institute of
International Studies, pp. 23–46.
Security and Defence Committee (2006) ‘The Strategy for Securing the Functions Vital
to Society’, Government Resolution, 23 September, available online at www.defmin.fi/
files/858/06_12_12_YETTS__in_english.pdf (accessed 5 December 2007).
Stoltenberg, T. (2009) ‘Nordic Cooperation on Foreign and Security Policy proposals
112 C. Archer
Presented to the Extraordinary Meeting of Nordic Foriegn Ministers in Oslo on 9
February 2009’, available online at: www.regjeringen.no (accessed 1 October 2011).
Swedish Civil Contingencies Agency (2009) ‘Emergency Planning. Crisis Management
in Sweden’, available online at: www.msb.se/en/About-MSB/Crisis-Management-in-
Sweden/ (accessed 21 August 2012).
Wedin, L. (2008) ‘Northern Europe and the ESDP: The Case of Sweden’, in Archer, C.
(ed.) New Security Issues in Northern Europe. The Nordic and Baltic States and the
ESDP, Abingdon and New York: Routledge, pp. 38–55.
7 Security concerns of the Baltic
States in the twenty-first century
Mindaugas Jurkynas

Distrust and caution are the parents of security.


(Benjamin Franklin 1914)

Introduction
The security of the three small states of Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia (the Baltic
States),1 has, perhaps unsurprisingly, never been off the political agenda in these
countries. Arguably, their membership in NATO and the EU since 2004 should
have somewhat – at least, de jure – reduced their concerns; but it would be naïve
to think that security issues ceased to be part of Baltic political discourse as a
result. With the end of the Cold War, the theoretical conceptualization of
security has broadened from the politico-military to other fields, embracing
society, energy, the economy, cyber-space, the environment and other dimen-
sions. As explained in Chapter 2, processes of globalization, Europeanization
and others have blurred the line between domestic and foreign policies and thus
between endogenous and exogenous aspects of security. The range of security
worries in Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia has rapidly proliferated accordingly:
issues of identity, emigration, interdependence, the integration of minorities and
the like have entered into domestic debates on the state’s duty to provide security
and welfare and to foster the national culture and identity. Real-life events in the
Baltics have also fuelled security concerns, including the broad-range cyber-
attacks against Estonian cyber-space in 2007 and against Lithuania’s major inter-
net media outlets in 2013; disruptions of fossil fuel supplies to Lithuania since
2006; and the general status of the Baltics as an ‘energy island’, with few links
to the rest of the European Union (EU). The disquieting Russian military exer-
cises in 2009, which simulated the invasion of the Baltic States, not only under-
pinned the call for NATO to draw up contingency plans for the Baltic States’
defence, but brought security narratives back into these countries’ own academic
and political discussions.
A well-worn joke circulates from time to time in diplomatic circles: the Baltic
States are preoccupied only with three issues: Russia, Russia and . . . we forgot
the third one – must be Russia. Those writing foreign audience-oriented speeches
for high-ranking Baltic officials have a similarly limited menu to choose from,
114 M. Jurkynas
including perceptions of state smallness, relations with neighbours in a sensitive
North European geopolitical milieu and notorious historical legacies. Actual
foreign policy statements made by Baltic politicians in recent years rest on three
pillars: energy security, the EU’s Eastern neighbourhood and Russia, and
Europe–US relations. All are linked to post-Soviet states’ relations with Russia
and find echoes in present politics. For example, Lithuania’s 2013 EU Presid-
ency priorities focused on the EU’s Eastern partnership, energy sustainability,
EU external borders and the EU Baltic Sea Strategy.2 In July of that year the
Lithuanian President, Ms. Dalia Grybauskaitė, drew attention to Russia’s
increasing grip on the Eastern European states.3 Estonia’s President, Toomas
Hendrik Ilves, similarly emphasizes the EU’s financial stability and external
borders, energy issues, the Eastern Partnership, the Baltic Sea Strategy and
cyber-security as key security issues for small states.4 The Latvian foreign min-
istry publicly cites defence and security as top priorities.5 All these recurring
issues reflect the way that living memories, smallness and relational insecurity,
as well as geopolitical realities, circumscribe foreign and security policies in the
Baltics: ‘Old legacies continue to dog the states formerly under Soviet domina-
tion, whilst new opportunities may undermine the fragile sense of regional com-
munity’ (Kirby 1999).
At the same time, in historical perspective, Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia may
have never felt as secure as today. European and trans-Atlantic reunification, to
use Bernard-Henri Lévy’s term (2013),6 have brought substantial institutional
and operational security guarantees for member states’ hard (strategic, military)
and soft (energy-related, virtual, economic, environmental, etc.) security needs.
Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia, in their successful quest to join the new West,
were seeking historical justice and fulfilment of their socio-economic and hard
security requirements; but they also embraced the Europeanization7 of their
political, legal and economic modi operandi, participation in collective decision-
making, and the ability to upload national interests, values, norms and concerns
into EU and NATO agendas (Jurkynas 2012a; Ozoliņa 2012; Veebel and Loik
2012). As noted, however, EU and NATO membership have not eliminated
security concerns. The Baltic States still view their place in the West and rela-
tions with Russia in terms of existential politics (Mälksoo 2006). Baltic regional
identities are largely framed by security concerns about Russia, Soviet legacies,
and the experiences of post-Communist transformation (Jurkynas 2007).
Prior to the NATO and EU enlargements of 2004, Baltic States’ security was
an almost over-researched topic (Jurkynas 2007: 20), but attention has since
dwindled. This chapter aims to discuss the most important and acute security
challenges faced by the Baltic States after 2004, together with current or planned
security solutions. Country size; power, identity and subsequent national inter-
ests; integration and cooperation; and the roles of the NATO and the EU will
appear as key factors. The nations’ main structures and procedures for security
policy making will also be covered. Normatively, the Baltic case suggests certain
lessons for the empirical aspects of security studies. The factors of size and
related lack of concrete resources are shown to sharpen the Baltic States’
Security concerns of the Baltic States 115
anxieties and to prompt them constantly to remind the EU and NATO of their
concerns. Neighbourhood, history and identity, but also national size and power,
do matter for the security of the Baltics today.

Security’s relation to size, identity and relationships


Sustaining security, welfare and culture for its citizens is the first duty of a state,
but is easier said than done. The demise of bipolarity in world politics at the end
of the second millennium paved the way for the emergence of multi-polarity
with the decline of US military and economic dominance, and also heralded a
vast array of new security problems transcending both state borders and tradi-
tional, material capabilities. In the Baltic States, as elsewhere, issues such as the
global economic crisis, emigration and integration of minorities, challenges of
cyber-space, and participation in international efforts against terrorism and
global warming have made their mark on debates about the costs, benefits and
perspectives of security solutions.
The size of a country and its relative material power are far from being the
only determinants of its identity, interests, capacities and subsequent domestic or
foreign actions. Small states in a less troubled neighbourhood, like Luxembourg,
may have fewer worries about hard security though they are no strangers to soft
security concerns. Historical and geographical contexts are relevant, especially if
they happen to define asymmetries between local powers and their legacies that
remain vivid in living memories.
Baldur Thorhallsson (2006) has helped to guide the paradigm change from a
Rationalist to a Reflectivist one in small state research. Rationalists, and Realists
in particular, saw small states as by definition less able than large powers to
protect their sovereignty and territories and to exercise choice in their inter-
national action. Thorhallsson argues, however, that traditional criteria such as
population, territory, economic output and military strength should be comple-
mented by considering factors of competence for action and vulnerability, and
noting the relevance of a state’s values, ideas, norms, perceptions and, not least,
ambitions. A similar constructivist approach is endorsed in Chapter 1 of this
volume, which stresses the importance – and variability – of relational aspects: a
state may be smaller in particular relations than in others. However, the material
consequences of smallness also affect constructed visions. A history of limited
options and restraints on action in the shape of conflicts, wars, occupations and
annexations can be ingrained in the mind-mapping and ‘Othering’ of political
elites in smaller and weaker states, thereby constituting part of their identity.
Perceptual and preference sizes in the investigation of small states go hand-
in-hand with regional identity studies. Collective identity is a self-perception
based on commonalities of ‘We’ and differences from the ‘Other’. ‘We’ refers to
like-minded and similar countries, while the role of the ‘Other’ is linked with
vulnerability, bitter memories, or both combined. States sharing the same vision
of the ‘Other’ can more easily develop a vision of themselves as a regional com-
munity with a collective identity and potential for cooperation (Neumann 1994);
116 M. Jurkynas
and such regional relations – as also argued in Chapter 2 – may be proportion-
ally more important as a strategic solution for smaller than for larger states.
Effective neighbourly cooperation can both change a country’s (self-) image and
palliate the effects of smallness (Jurkynas 2007). Small states may benefit both
from joining larger cooperative formats like the EU – which offer shelter from
diverse external challenges, though paradoxically also erode state sovereignty –
and from allying with smaller like-minded groups (often starting with neigh-
bours) within these large fora, to ensure their special interests are not ignored.

Autonomy? Neutrality? No – Western engagement!


Geopolitical and memory-related sensitivities have guided Baltic post-
Communist policies in searching for enhanced security. The role of Russia has
been crucial for the regional identity and very existence of the Baltic States. All
three countries, like Finland, broke free from the Tsarist Empire at the end of, or
after, World War I. A brief inter-war independence was nipped in the bud by
Soviet annexation just before the outbreak of World War II. The fight for the re-
establishment of Baltic statehood in 1990–1991 crystallized bitter memories of
the three nations’ 50-year long incorporation into the USSR. Behind the historic
Baltic–Russian antipathy can be seen both a massive power asymmetry and an
identity clash. Russia’s national identity has been built on the victorious and
expansive Soviet legacy, which is seen as a political chimera in Lithuania, Latvia
and Estonia (Morozov 2004, 2009). Russia regarded the Baltics as the ‘black
sheep’ in Europe, who had failed to meet European standards in fighting the
Nazi heritage. For their part, the Baltic States have remained (consistently over
eight years) among the top five countries considered most unfriendly towards
Russia,8 and Baltic media and political rhetoric is spiced with negative Russian
images.9 Even if direct Russian threats seem decreasingly relevant, Russia
remains the main source of concern.10 The Baltic case thus fits well with Ahto
Lobjakas’ (2012: 4) summation, whereby four factors – proximity, history, size/
global reach and trade – are key determinants in virtually all European countries’
modern-day relations with Russia.
With the rebirth of independence in 1990–1991, Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia
set out to rid themselves of the Soviet legacy and the political, economic and cul-
tural influence of Russia.11 A break-out from the Soviet matrix and integration into
Western institutional, economic and socio-political structures was the prescription
for augmented security. Recognizing that the security of small states depends
heavily on their cooperative engagements, in the 1990s the Baltic countries created
or joined several dozens of regional and global collaborative organizations: among
others the Baltic Council, the Council of Baltic Sea States, the United Nations and
the Organization for Security and Cooperation in Europe, the European Bank for
Reconstruction and Development, the Council of Europe, the World Trade Organ-
ization and, finally, the EU and NATO. In the process, Lithuania, Latvia and
Estonia developed a well-institutionalized collaboration12 among themselves and
with the Nordic countries, which has persisted to the present.
Security concerns of the Baltic States 117
Hard security was among the top priorities for the Baltics before their NATO
entry in 2004. Baltic neutrality in the late 1930s had brought no safety – follow-
ing the 1939 Ribbentrop–Molotov Pact, the Baltic States were invaded by both
the Nazis and the Soviet troops. Naturally, Baltic policy makers noted this lesson
when seeking NATO and EU membership, and also strong national support and
sympathy from the US superpower, in the early 1990s.13 The Western skies
cleared after Soviet troops pulled out from Lithuania in 1993, and Estonia and
Latvia in 1994. Baltic security hopes were pinned on growing self-defence capa-
cities, integration into NATO and broader military cooperation. In 1994, the
Baltic States joined the Partnership for Peace programme, which facilitated inter-
Baltic and Baltic–Nordic military collaboration as well as preparation for NATO
membership, talks on which started in 1997. All three states signed the US-
Baltic Charter in 1998 and NATO Membership Action Plans in 1999, before
entering NATO as part of its second post-Cold War expansion in 2004. NATO
and the US did help to allay major Baltic military and strategic security con-
cerns, especially with the new contingency plans approved in 2009.14 As US
President, George W. Bush put it in 2002, ‘Our alliance has made a solemn
pledge of protection, and anyone who would choose Lithuania as an enemy has
also made an enemy of the United States’.15
The security guarantees provided by the EU are of a different kind. Despite
the EU’s manifest weaknesses in developing a common European defence, the
joint decision-making framework grants soft security16 and offers manifold
opportunities for bottom-up Europeanization, thereby helping to offset ‘small-
ness’17 and lessen relational power asymmetries. The Baltic States’ route towards
the EU started in the early 1990s18 and peaked at the end of 2002, when all three
Baltic countries finally qualified for membership by meeting the Copenhagen
criteria of democracy, market economy, rule of law, market strength and state
ability to implement membership requirements.19 Europeanization during the
membership negotiations involved wide-ranging institutional and legal changes
to meet EU standards, and the Baltic States went to great lengths to accelerate
the required reforms; yet EU conditionality had its price too.20 Following EU
entry in 2004, benefits continued as economic growth increased substantially,
living standards rose and so did the influx of foreign direct investment. People
enjoyed the common market and free movement. At the same time, the outward
migration of labour forces, social disparities and the lingering absence of energy
security provided jarring notes.
With security in mind, the Baltic States set out to play their part in ‘custom-
izing’ EU policies by importing national interests, as Finland had done before
them, e.g. with the Northern Dimension Initiative of 1997 (Ojanen 1999). The
Baltic States, with support from Northern and Central European partners, kept
the EU alert to two chief issues: the Eastern neighbourhood and energy security.
On the former, the Baltics saw themselves as exporting the model of successful
post-Communist transformation to the EU’s Eastern neighbourhood. Fostering
democracy, human rights and the rule of law in the adjacent countries of
Armenia, Azerbaijan, Belarus, Georgia, Moldova and Ukraine was seen as a way
118 M. Jurkynas
to cushion the Baltics’ own security while promoting a domino effect of
European-style reforms that could spread not only to Eastern Europe, but too
Russia itself. The Baltic States have accordingly been staunch supporters of the
EU’s Eastern Partnership programme, launched in 2009,21 a posture that can also
be seen as an example of Nordic-style norm entrepreneurship (Ingebritsen 2002).
Well aware that their power, resources and action capacity lag well behind many
larger EU states, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania have sought a niche of ‘special-
ization’ as ex-USSR countries that have successfully transformed themselves
into Western states – even if not yet the wealthiest. This makes the Baltic model
‘sexier’ in Eastern Partnership countries, and raises the Baltic profile of East
European expertise in the EU. ‘The more of the West in Eastern Europe, the less
Russia’ is a tacit motto that many Baltic policy makers subscribe to.
The energy security issues of Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia were also uploaded
onto the EU agenda,22 but membership did not bring immediate benefits in this
sector. On the contrary, the Baltic States remain ‘energy islands’ that are heavily
dependent on imports of electricity and fossil fuels from Russia. To boost their
energy security, they seek diversification of energy imports and reliable local sup-
plies. The EU has stepped into the picture by co-financing and politically support-
ing two trans-frontier electricity grids.23 The NordBalt Link will connect the Baltic
and the Nordic states via Lithuania and Sweden, and the LitPol Link will join the
Baltics and the Western European Electricity System through Poland – both to be
operational by the end of 2015. The EU also supports a regional liquefied natural
gas terminal being built on the Baltic coast. Due to intra-Baltic disagreements, this
project will most likely be developed closer to Finland, but Lithuania will also
build its own terminal to be ready by 2014.
The Baltic States took an even higher profile in EU debates on the Nord-
stream, a gas pipeline connecting Russia and Germany along the bed of the
Baltic Sea. While the project was given a green light by the EU, the Baltic States
plus Poland were strongly opposed because of their own exclusion from it, its
implications for energy dependence on Russia, and ecological concerns. When
the EU decided to cap CO2 emissions in the member states, to improve the effi-
ciency of energy usage and increase the share of renewable energy, the Baltic
States argued that such measures should not be allowed to damage the competit-
iveness of ‘catching-up’ economies and all EU states should equally share the
burden of the emissions.
One soft security success for Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia – as EU members
– was joining the Schengen Treaty in 2007. Accessing the Eurozone has been
another key issue. Despite current Eurozone troubles, the Baltic States have seen
the adoption of the euro as an economic benefit that would reduce transaction
costs and display sound public finances, but also contribute to economic security.
Estonian Prime Minister, Andrus Ansip, stated that ‘the Euro predominantly
means security’24 and the Chairwoman of the Latvian Parliament, Solvita
Āboltiņa, described the Euro as a strategic goal of Latvia and a symbol of
security.25 Estonia became the seventeenth Eurozone member state in 2011,
Latvia is set to join in January 2014 and Lithuania plans to follow suit in 2015.
Security concerns of the Baltic States 119
Despite emerging Eurosceptic trends in Greece, the Nordic countries, the
Netherlands and France, the EU is not (yet) a polarizing issue in Baltic politics.
Mainstream parties in the region, apart from Russian-minority-oriented politi-
cians, back EU membership for various soft security reasons and as a way to
help the Baltics amplify their relative power and welfare through engagement.
There are, however, exceptions: for instance the EU’s perceived moral liberal-
ism on the rights of various minorities vexes socially conservative parties and
voters, especially in Catholic Lithuania. If EU integration (and even more, glo-
balization) is perceived as an attack on tradition and identity and does not
increase security in the long run, the myth of a ‘good Europe’ in the Baltics
might eventually be laid to rest.

Identity and neighbourhood: Russia and the Nordic states


The importance of regional identity for small states, especially in the era of glo-
balization and growing interdependence, has been noted above. Lithuania, Latvia
and Estonia have limited choices for regional affiliations, with four overlapping
frameworks: their own trilateral relationship, the Baltic–Nordic (Baltoscandian),
the post-Communist (Central and Eastern Europe), and the riparian Baltic Sea
region. Constructivist, quantitative and qualitative analysis of regional identities
in Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia reveals the dominance of a common Baltic
identity and sense of fate, underlining that Soviet legacies have not lost their
relevance yet (Jurkynas 2007). Miniotaitė (2003) argued that political identity in
the Baltics is founded in an East–West opposition, and present-day discourse has
not moved far from this, even though the level of securitization has dwindled
(see speech by Grybauskaitė, The Financial Times 2013). As recently as 2007,
an EU academic study described the Lithuanians as ‘new Cold-warriors’, while
Estonia and Latvia were seen as ‘frosty pragmatists’ who never missed a chance
to criticize Russia.26 The image is reinforced by specific Baltic actions, such as
Lithuania’s efforts in 2012 to urge the European Commission into launching an
anti-monopoly case against Russia’s gas company, Gazprom, claiming that it
bullied Central and Eastern Europe with unfairly high gas prices.
After the tri-Baltic cooperation that was so prominent during the EU/NATO
accession phase, the Baltic States’ next most prominent regional alignment has
become the Nordic–Baltic one. This ‘Baltoscandian’ idea is powerfully promoted
in the Baltic States for a reason. The Baltic States do not want to be seen as ex-
Soviet Union or Eastern European countries associated with under-development,
corruption and Russia’s influence. The Nordic world, by contrast, excels in many
areas and is attractive to many, including the Baltic States who see the Nordics as
close cousins due to geography, similar security challenges, smallness and close
links both in history and the present.27 The Nordic countries were among the first to
recognize the Baltics’ re-established independence and generously assisted the
Baltic resurrection in the early 1990s (Bergmann 2004). Leaders of the Nordic and
Baltic EU member nations regularly hold NB6 meetings on the margins of EU
summits; NB8 meetings with all five Nordics are organized annually; and the
120 M. Jurkynas
inter-parliamentary bodies – the Nordic Council and Baltic Assembly – hold joint
sessions too. The Baltics are the only shareholders along with the Nordic states in
the Nordic Investment Bank, and Nordic investments provide the largest share of
the stock in Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia. With the development of electricity
grids like NordBalt, Estlink and the Estlink2, the Baltic countries will anchor them-
selves to the North European electric energy market, the Nordpool spot. Baltic
leaders also emphasize affinities of sound public finance policy and political coop-
eration within the regular US-Nordic-Baltic E-PINE (Enhanced Partnership in
Northern Europe) and nascent UK-Nordic-Baltic frameworks.
Yet the Nordic states, for their part, do not see the Baltics as an inherent part of
the Nordic community (Norden). First of all, they have chosen different strategies
of security management: Finland and Sweden remain outside NATO and Norway
and Iceland outside the EU’s soft security community. There is still a prosperity
chasm between the fast-developing Baltic countries and their well-heeled Nordic
neighbours.28 The redistributive social-democratic welfare state model, part of the
Nordic identity, has not taken root in the economically far more liberal Baltic
States. Human rights including de facto minority rights, let alone corruption
indices, in the Baltics are well behind the top-notch Nordic standards. The Baltic
States are not consensus democracies and gender equality there is still on the rise.
Further, the Balts are not such ‘reluctant Europeans’ as the Nordics and have not
witnessed a similar emergence of Eurosceptic, anti-immigration and xenophobic
parties. Finally, Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia, despite being good examples of
Europeanization in general, still tend to think of security in very ‘modern’ terms
when they worry about sovereignty, security and borders.29
Despite such differences, the Baltic and Nordic countries are intensifying
levels of cooperation and region-building in many areas. The Nordics’ role in
Baltic military security has been patchy: they have supported the Baltic march to
the West and have provided aid for civil society, rebuilding democratic and
military structures, yet Nordic security guarantees have been out of the question,
above all because of Finnish and Swedish non-alignment policies. The Nordic
states have often been wary about the Baltic proclivity to lambast Russia’s bel-
ligerence. Nonetheless, new initiatives for closer Nordic–Baltic collaboration
have surfaced recently: the Birkavs–Gade report of 2010 produced a series of
recommendations for intra-regional collaboration, starting with foreign policy
dialogue and defence cooperation, and ending with the NB8 brand.30 The first
Lithuanian head of state, Vytautas Landsbergis, was perhaps too optimistic when
stating in 201131 that for all their differences, the Nordic and Baltic States consti-
tute a spiritual community. Yet Nordic–Baltic region-building and the gradual
pooling of resources is accelerating32 and is important in avoiding marginaliza-
tion for both these sets of small states.

New security challenges for the Baltic States


Being small and not disguising this fact, Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia are
unlikely to forget the regional realities that made them seek strategic shelter in
Security concerns of the Baltic States 121
the EU and the NATO. Electoral turnovers in Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia have
not altered hard security attitudes among political elites. While policy rifts may
appear on socio-economic or even environmental issues, Baltic governments
have not faltered in their determination to strengthen their military capacities,
cooperation and interdependence within the NATO and EU structures. Even if
feeling better protected than ever before, the Baltic States have neither become
freed from anxiety nor turned into free riders. Today, small states are expected
to contribute to international security responsibilities, and Lithuania, Latvia and
Estonia have actively engaged in US/NATO-led international operations. Baltic
inputs to the missions in Iraq and Afghanistan signalled a readiness to support
wider security interests but were also calculated to earn US and NATO favour in
the interests of the countries’ own security. At the same time and on parallel
reasoning, all three states have contributed extensively to the EU’s ‘softer’,
civilian-manned missions.
At the rebirth of independence, Baltic security dilemmas were rather similar
and embraced the protection of territorial integrity and society. Since then,
national security strategies and concepts have identified multiplying security
concerns. As these documents33 show, Baltic security horizons have broadened
to include not only defence and foreign policy, but also economic, ecological,
crisis management, energy and cyber security, information technology and other
facets (Kaljurand et al. 2012).
Economic security is a complex issue, ranging from macro-economic vulner-
ability to micro-economic sustainability (Briguglio et al. 2006). Being small,
open, export-oriented and competitive economies, the Baltic States are vulner-
able and cannot hope to dictate external trends. Those now in the Eurozone, like
Estonia, must share common currency-related troubles. Facing challenges of this
nature requires either leftist or rightist political solutions: pundits disagree on
whether austerity-driven or Keynesian policies suit best for an economic crisis
management. Earlier, the Baltic States were called economic tigers due to their
fast economic growth.34 The economic crisis in 2009–2010 hit hard on the Baltic
economies, whose outputs shrank by around 20 per cent in two years. The
Latvian and Lithuanian budgets shrivelled and public debts soared; only Estonia
managed to absorb external shocks by having accumulated financial reserves
(Veebel and Loik 2012). Socially regressive austerity measures, cutting budget
deficits, heavy international borrowing and internal devaluation put the Baltics
back on the track of recovery and, by 2012, had made them again the fastest
growing economies in the EU. However, economic hardship hit all public spend-
ing, including military expenditure, which fell to levels ranging from 1 per cent
of GDP in Latvia and Lithuania to 1.7 per cent in Estonia.35 From a social point
of view, social disparities and income inequalities – reflected in the Gini coeffi-
cient36 – and relatively high levels of poverty remain among the gravest political
problems to be solved. Government programmes in the Baltics are unequivocal
about steering economies towards growth and job creation. The right-of-centre
Estonian and the Latvian cabinets rely more on market economy and prudent
spending, whereas the Lithuanian left-of-centre government is more open to
122 M. Jurkynas
increasing the role of the public sector, especially in fighting unemployment.
The logic of security via participation and membership has been applied in the
economic dimension as well: Estonia joined the OECD in 2010, the OECD
decided to start membership talks with Latvia in 2013, and has signalled its read-
iness to do likewise with Lithuania pretty soon.37
The lack of sustainable and diversified energy supplies affects not only Baltic
security and political vulnerability but the competitiveness of small Baltic eco-
nomies and social life.38 Due to an abundance of shale oil, Estonia’s energy
dependency on foreign sources is the lowest in the Baltics, with barely 21.2 per
cent of energy needs39 (Kaljurand et al. 2012), whereas Lithuania and Latvia
import almost 100 per cent of their oil40 and gas from Russia,41 and 60 per cent
of Lithuanian electricity needs come from their big neighbour (Jurkynas 2012b).
Given EU plans for ‘green’ economies with increased energy efficiency, shares
of renewable sources of energy and reduced usage of fossil fuels by 2020, the
Baltic States have started considering different options to enhance their energy
security. Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia have been considering the joint construc-
tion of a new nuclear power plant in Lithuania for nearly a decade.42 However,
Lithuanian governments have dragged their feet as political parties disagree on
the project, while Russian and Belorussian plans (or bluffs) to construct their
own nuclear power plants raise questions about the Lithuanian idea’s commer-
cial viability. Moreover, a 2012 consultative referendum in Lithuania rejected a
nuclear project. As of 2013, the Lithuanian government is leaving the initiative
to regional partners and strategic investors, while Poland and Estonia do not rule
out developing their own nuclear power plants. Although politicians reiterate
that energy issues are market- and company-driven, in practice such projects do
not proceed without a political will; and that is currently lacking. Coordination
of energy security matters in the Baltics is also problematic as the energy sector
is divided according to sources, e.g. nuclear energy, with different bodies taking
responsibility for each sub-sector.43
Cyber-space has recently found its place in security considerations world-
wide. A fast-growing reliance on e-communication, the internet, tablets and
smart-phones makes people’s lives inseparable from various e-services and thus
vulnerable to their malfunction or absence. The malicious e-worm, Stuxnet, in
2010 and glitches experienced by BlackBerry in 2012, illustrate the problems of
security and operability. Cyber-space can become a zone of information warfare,
espionage or electronic attack. Being IT-adept, among the top countries in terms
of the numbers of e-communication users and with correspondingly developed
infrastructures, Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia have already encountered security
challenges in this field. A number of public and commercial services are being
uploaded into cloud computing, thus becoming targets for malevolent activities.
Estonia fell victim to a well-orchestrated cyber-attack in 2007, after the author-
ities decided to remove a commemorative statue for fallen Soviet troops, the
‘Bronze Soldier’, from the city centre. Many believed Russia stood behind those
attacks. Events in Estonia catalyzed the country’s specialization in cyber-security
in much the same way as Lithuania found a niche in energy security.44 Estonia
Security concerns of the Baltic States 123
has hosted the NATO Cooperative Cyber Defence Centre of Excellence since
2008.45 Lithuania, responding to attacks on electronic media in 2013, has estab-
lished a consultative Cybersecurity Council under the Ministry of the Interior.46
Since 2011, Latvia has had an Information Technology Security Incident
Response Institution, initially under the Ministry of Defence and, since 2012,
under the Ministry of Transportation.47
Societal issues, among others, offer perhaps no less significant security chal-
lenges. As explained in Chapter 4, societal security aims to maintain well-
functioning foundations for a society free of violent, non-military calamities
ranging from terrorism and crime to natural and man-made disasters and infra-
structure disruptions. Non-state actors, such as NGOs and voluntary associ-
ations, play significant roles. Identity is a further important aspect of societal
security that deserves special attention in the Baltic case. During the post-
Communist transition, a key focus was ‘nation- and state-building’, but ‘society-
building’ might have been a more appropriate term. Consolidation of the societal
fabric was among the most acute issues, especially in Estonia and Latvia where
large Russian-speaking minorities – a legacy of colonization during the Soviet
years – make up nearly one-third of the aggregate population. This enables
Russia to adopt a ‘compatriots abroad’ policy and to highlight ostensible ‘human
rights violations’ of Russian speakers. At times, ethnic tensions can catch wider
attention as with the violent street riots by Estonian Russians, not without insti-
gation from Moscow, over removal of the aforementioned war monument in
2007. Russia sponsors different interest groups in the Baltic States, such as the
Russkiy Mir Foundation and Russkiy Dom network, and promotes political parties
sharing Russia’s political views, such as the Harmony Centre in Latvia and
Centre Party in Estonia. Quite a few Baltic politicians perceive this as a Russian
tool to interfere in Baltic national politics. Latvian Russian minority rights have
similarly been defended by Moscow: preparations for a referendum on introduc-
ing Russian as the second official state language were mostly understood as a
clear Russian bid to increase influence in Latvia by electorally mobilizing
Russian speakers (Bukovskis 2012). Moscow’s blatant reactions to commemora-
tive marches by Latvian war veterans, who fought against the Soviets, further
illustrate the scope both for interpretative disagreements on recent history, and
for a clash of identities between small states and the regional power.
Security governance involves the conceptualization of security threats at the
political level and the preventive or reactive implementation of security policies.
In the Baltics, institutions dealing with new security threats have most often
been created in reaction to externally triggered events, as with cyber-attacks or
disruptions of energy supplies. Security management in the Baltic States can be
broadly divided into hard and soft security. The primary issues of military and
strategic security draw constant high political attention48 and are frequently dis-
cussed and coordinated by the Presidents, government leaders and/or respons-
ible, usually Defence and Foreign, Ministries. Respective parliamentary
committees and national security bodies are also active. In all three states, cen-
tralization of security governance is clearest in hard security, while soft security
124 M. Jurkynas
governance is more decentralized across different governmental bodies and even
public–private partnership arrangements, especially in the area of information
technology. Nevertheless, increasing awareness of new types of trans-border
threats is attracting more thorough political scrutiny and coordination, with the
government increasingly becoming the highest security governance authority
that integrates information, adopts decisions and deploys resources. On the other
hand, governments still rely on a relatively high number of different institutions
to supervise different security challenges.

Conclusions
Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia constitute an interesting case in the context of
small state security. They show how the ‘post-traumatic stress disorder’ of
nations – once occupied, annexed and rather recently independent – seeps into
identity and drives the search for security against a former ruling power and its
legacies. The review of Baltic security challenges and responses confirms that
Lithuanian, Latvian and Estonian policy makers tend to base their security
assessments on a well-established, ‘anti-Russia’ habit as part of their identity.
While the Baltic States have made considerable efforts to become part of the
West, little has changed in Baltic security considerations following membership
of NATO and the EU. Soviet legacies and Russia’s neighbourhood may at times
lead to over-generalizations about the ‘big neighbour’; yet recent experience of
incidents in the fields of energy and cyber-security (among others) keeps Russia
on the Baltic political mind. Both traditional ‘hard’ and new, post-Cold War
‘soft’ security concerns have nudged the Baltic States towards more regional
integration, primarily within the EU and NATO – even though these qualify the
much-cherished sovereignty regained after the collapse of the USSR. Seeking a
strategic shelter was the primary raison d’être for the Western integration that
has increased the Baltics’ security, making them part of decision-making coali-
tions and uploading Baltic concerns onto the agendas of political organizations.
Aside from NATO’s contingency Baltic defence plans and active military
cooperation, the introduction of the euro, diversification of energy imports,
deeper involvement in EU external actions and avoidance of a two-speed Europe
are among top Baltic security priorities today. Identity and security concerns,
among others, remain important variables driving Lithuanian, Latvian and Esto-
nian choices within the EU. Calls for Europeanization of the EU’s Eastern neigh-
bours and enhanced energy security for the Baltics, let alone specific tensions
with Russia and the integration of national minorities, are generated not least by
identity constructions and living memories in the Baltic region. Smallness
appears as a factor, as one might expect, yet is not particularly dominant. Espe-
cially within the EU, the Baltics’ activism and regional cooperation, notably
with the Nordic states, allows them to partly escape their smallness in terms of a
traditional understanding of power and resources. The EU forum has served
Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia well in dispelling power asymmetries, especially
vis-à-vis Russia. The small Baltic States so far fall among the chief enthusiasts
Security concerns of the Baltic States 125
for Westernization and Europeanization, which, directly or indirectly, have
enhanced their security and welfare. Mushrooming security challenges like inter-
national terrorism, nuclear safety, or energy, environmental and cyber-security
issues, have called for new responses, new evaluations and corresponding pol-
icies. The Baltic States have responded by adopting new national security strat-
egies and concepts within the last three years. The pattern of security
governance, however, remains complex: all Baltic States know the drill when it
comes to hard security issues, while the management of soft security problems
remains dispersed within government.
The analysis of the Baltic case poses an interesting, but probably unanswer-
able, question about small state security: What if the recent history of these
states had been far less painful and without Soviet legacies? Perhaps the Baltic
identity would be less imbued with victimization, and in the absence of identity
clashes, relations with Russia would be seen in a light of desecuritization. As
things stand, living next to the assertive regional power has taught these small
states to accommodate their national identity and even sovereignty to Western
values and institutions, and to elaborate different modes of cooperative engage-
ment and contribution.

Notes
1 The total population of the Baltic States is barely over six million people and the ter-
ritory of the largest country, Lithuania, is just 65,302 km2.
2 Nutarimas dėl Lietuvos Respublikos Pirmininkavimo ES Tarybai 2013 m., Lithuanian
Parliament, available online at: www3.lrs.lt/pls/inter3/dokpaieska.showdoc_l?p_
id=410980&p_query=&p_tr2=2 (accessed 10 July 2013).
3 ‘Lithuania’s President Warns of Russia’s Rising Influence in the East’, Financial
Times 2 July 2013, available online at: www.ft.com/cms/s/0/4eb04500-e32b-11e2-
bd87–00144feabdc0.html#axzz2Y4HMQggO (accessed 15 July 2013).
4 President Toomas Hendrik Ilves at the State Dinner in Vilnius, 27 May 2013, available
online at: www.President.ee/en/official-duties/speeches/9092-President-toomas-hendrik-
ilves-at-the-state-dinner-in-vilnius-27-may-2013/index.html (accessed 15 July 2013).
5 Speech by the Minister of Foreign Affairs of the Republic of Latvia, Mr. Edgars
Rinkēvičs at the Foreign Policy Debate in the Saeima, 24 January 2013, available
online at: www.mfa.gov.lv/en/news/speeches/2013/24–3/ (accessed 19 July 2013).
6 Bernard-Henri Lévy: ‘I Don’t Care Much about my Image’, Financial Times 14 June
2013, available online at: www.ft.com/cms/s/2/080ad66c-d2ee-11e2-aac2–00144
feab7de.html#axzz2Y4wkKUS1 (accessed 20 July 2013).
7 Europeanization is a process of cultural, political and organizational change along
European lines, within and beyond the borders of Europe. It has top-down (‘down-
load’ of EU norms and practices), bottom-up (‘upload’ of member states’ interests)
and horizontal (sharing good practices and learning) vectors (Flockhart 2006: 86).
8 Внешнеполитические враги и друзья России, Levada Center, 18 June 2013,
The Levada Institute, available online at: www.levada.ru/18–06–2013/vneshne
politicheskie-vragi-i-druzya-rossii (accessed 15 July 2013).
9 These include Russia’s embargoes of energy and food products for a number of coun-
tries (Lithuania, Georgia, Moldova, Ukraine, etc.), the 2007 cyber-attacks against
Estonia, the 2008 war with Georgia, Alexander Litvinenko’s and Anna Politko-
vskaya’s homicides, control of the media, rigged elections, violation of human rights,
the destruction, persecution and intimidation of political opponents and businessmen
126 M. Jurkynas
(e.g. the cases of Mikhail Khodorkovsky, Pussy Riot, Sergey Magnitsky and Alexei
Navalny), revisionist history broadcasts on the Russia’s First Baltic Channel and
military exercises in the Baltic neighbourhood.
10 According to opinion polls of October 2012, 60 per cent of Lithuanian respondents
see no threats to the state, whereas 18 per cent name Russia and 1.7 per cent identify
Poland as the main sources of threats. ‘Apklausa: realių grėsmių Lietuvai nėra, o jei
bus – mus apgins NATO?’, Delfi Internet Portal, available online at: www.delfi.lt/
news/daily/lithuania/apklausa-realiu-gresmiu-lietuvai-nera-o-jei-bus-mus-apgins-
nato.d?id=60063003 (accessed 10 July 2013).
11 ‘The Lithuanian Constitution Adopted in 1992 Promulgates a Ban on Joining “post-
Soviet Eastern Unions” ’, Lietuvos Respublikos Konstitucija, available online at:
www3.lrs.lt/home/Konstitucija/Konstitucija.htm (accessed 20 July 2013).
12 The Baltic Assembly and the Baltic Council of Ministers served as fora for inter-
parliamentary and intergovernmental cooperation.
13 For instance, Lithuanian mainstream political parties decided for NATO membership in
October 1993. See ‘Lietuvos Respublikos politinių partijų kreipimasis dėl Lietuvos
Respublikos integravimosi į NATO’, Lithuanian Parliament, available online at: www3.
lrs.lt/pls/inter/w5_show?p_r=5042&p_d=62154&p_k=1 (accessed 10 July 2013).
14 The Baltic States benefit from a NATO air policing mission guarding their airspace.
15 ‘Bush Makes a Perilous NATO Pledge’, CATO Institute, available online at: www.
cato.org/publications/commentary/bush-makes-perilous-nato-pledge (accessed 25 July
2013). For an account of the ongoing US security interest in the Baltic States, see
Michel (2011).
16 EU voting rules, as amended by the Lisbon Treaty, require large coalitions of member
states to achieve a qualified majority and this is next to impossible to achieve without
small states’ votes.
17 For example, Lithuania’s GDP amounts approximately 0.14 per cent of total EU GDP,
and the Lithuanian share of total EU population is barely 0.71 per cent, but the
country exercises 2.03 per cent of votes in the Council and provides 1.63 per cent of
European MPs and 3.7 per cent of EU Commissioners, auditors and judges.
18 The European Community and the Baltic States signed agreements on Trade and
Commercial and Economic Co-operation, then included Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia
in the PHARE programme rather TACIS, which focused on ex-USSR countries. Free
Trade Agreements with the EU were concluded in 1994 and Association Agreements
in 1995. Estonia started membership negotiations in 1997, and Lithuania and Latvia
initiated them two years later.
19 Citizens in Lithuania, Latvia and Estonia unequivocally endorsed EU membership for
their respective countries in referenda in 2003.
20 For example, to comply with EU Accession Treaty requirements, in 2009 Lithuania
decommissioned the Ignalina nuclear power facility, which satisfied around 70 per
cent of the country’s electricity needs.
21 Lithuania set the aim of signing an EU–Ukraine Association Agreement at the
November 2013 Eastern Partnership Summit in Vilnius, during its EU Presidency.
Lithuania supports visa liberalization and better mutual trade arrangements as ways to
stimulate progress towards democracy and rule of law in Ukraine, and to reduce Rus-
sia’s influence in the core nation of the Eastern Partnership.
22 See Maigre (2010) on Baltic over-dependence for energy on Russia and Tarus and
Crandall (2012) on Russia’s continuing threat to Estonia.
23 See https://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/connecting-europe-facility (accessed 25
July 2013).
24 ‘Prime Minister: Euro is Matter of Security for Estonia’, 1 January 2011, available
online at: www.vm.ee/?q=node/10524 (accessed 15 July 2013).
25 ‘Saeima Speaker: Euro is a Symbol of Security and Stability’, 18 January 2013, available
online at: www.baltic-course.com/eng/analytics/?doc=68927 (accessed 19 July 2013).
Security concerns of the Baltic States 127
26 ‘A Power Audit of EU 27-Russia Relations’, European Council on Foreign Relations,
7 November 2007, available online at: www.ecfr.eu/content/entry/commentary_pr_
russia_power_audit/ (accessed 19 July 2013).
27 The Baltic and Nordic states hold no mutual grudges from history, which is rather
rare in neighbourly relations. Perhaps, in the medium term, the Baltic States could
gradually be engulfed into the Deutschian (1957) notion of the Nordic security
community.
28 According to Eurostat, in 2012 the ‘richest’ Baltic state, Lithuania, reached 70 per
cent of the EU27’s average GDP, whereas the ‘poorest’ Nordic state, Iceland, had 112
per cent of the EU average. Eurostat, GDP per capita in PPS (Purchasing Power
Standards), available online at: http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/tgm/table.do?tab=tabl
e&init=1&plugin=1&language=en&pcode=tec00114 (accessed 29 August 2013).
29 Margarita Šešelgytė (2012) similarly concludes that Lithuanian security policy prefers
a modern to post-modern understanding of security.
30 ‘The NB8 Wise Men Report’, August 2010, available online at: www.utanrikisra-
duneyti.is/media/Skyrslur/NB8-Wise-Men-Report.pdf (accessed 29 August 2013).
31 At the conference ‘Twenty Years to Lithuanian-Norwegian Diplomatic Relations’,
Vilnius, March 2011.
32 E.g. The Baltic and Nordic countries agreed to host each others’ diplomats in a case
of need, while Latvia and Lithuania are about to follow Estonia in joining the EU’s
Swedish-led Nordic Battle Group in 2015.
33 All three Baltic States recently updated their security agendas: Estonia adopted a new
National Security Concept in 2010, Latvia’s Parliament issued a new National Security
Concept in 2011 and a new State Defence Concept in May 2012, and a new Lithuanian
National Security Strategy was approved in June 2012 (Kaljurand et al. 2012: 36–41).
34 In 2002–2007, the Estonian GDP per capita in PPS grew from 50 to 70 per cent of the
EU average, while the other Baltic States achieved similar growth.
35 ‘Military Expenditure (as a Percentage of GDP)’, The World Bank, available online
at: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/MS.MIL.XPND.GD.ZS?order=wbapi_data_
value_2011+wbapi_data_value+wbapi_data_value-last&sort=asc (accessed 15 July
2013).
36 Gini index, The World Bank, available HTTP: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/
SI.POV.GINI (accessed 15 July 2013).
37 ‘Global OECD Boosted by Decision to Open Membership Talks with Colombia and
Latvia with More to Follow’, The OECD, available online at: www.oecd.org/news-
room/global-oecd-boosted-by-decision-to-open-membership-talks-with-colombia-
and-latvia-with-more-to-follow.htm (accessed 15 July 2013).
38 The cost of heating households rocketed due to high Russian gas prices and lack of
alternatives to gas heating. Public discontent with the whole situation is tangible.
39 About 60 per cent of Estonia’s domestic energy production comes from oil shale. It is
about to be to substantially reduced due to the EU Climate and Energy Package
(Maigre 2010).
40 Lithuania faced a Russian blockade of oil exports via Druzhba pipeline after 2006,
when it chose to sell the oil refinery Mažeikių nafta to a Polish company –PKN Orlen
– instead of a Russian one. Nevertheless, imports of crude oil come through a sea ter-
minal – though with a lower profit margin for the Polish importer.
41 Maigre (2010: 13) claims that ‘direct and indirect Russian presence in the Latvian
energy sector could lead to a so-called “Gazpromisation” of the Latvian political
elite’.
42 Poland joined the project in 2009, but due to delays pulled out two years later.
43 Interview with Associate Professor, Dr. Arūnas Molis, Head of Strategic Analysis and
Research Division at the NATO Energy Security Excellence Centre, 29 June 2013.
44 Demonstrated by NATO’s sponsorship of the Energy Security Excellence Centre in
Vilnius.
128 M. Jurkynas
45 In Estonia, however, cyber-security, and also energy security, governance remains
decentralized among several ministries. Interview with Professor Andreas Kasekamp,
Director of the Estonian Foreign Policy Institute, 7 June 2013.
46 The Council is mandated to monitor cyber-security in the country and provide exper-
tise for the Commission on Coordination of Cybersecurity, established in 2006: but
there are still five or six different institutions dealing with information security includ-
ing the Information Society Development Committee under the Ministry of Transport,
and a Communication and Computer Emergency Response Team established under
the independent Communication Regulation Authority.
47 Since 2012, Latvia has paid more attention to cyber-security issues through the Parlia-
mentary National Security Committee (Baltic News Network, online at: http://bnn-
news.com/national-security-committee-focus-cyber-security-75918, accessed 20 June
2013). However, Latvian cyber-security and energy security governance is dispersed
between the ministries of foreign affairs and economy, though leadership would be
centralized ad hoc in case of emergency. Interview with Andris Sprūds, Director of
the Latvian Institute of International Affairs, 17 June 2013.
48 The Lithuanian President, for instance, in case of emergency or important security
issues, convenes a State Defence Council of high-ranking officials, such as the Prime
Minister, Ministers of Defence and Foreign Affairs, Supreme Commander of Armed
Forces, Head of Security Department and the like.

Bibliography
Bergman, A. (2004) ‘Nordic Integration Assistance: the Case of the Baltic States’, paper
presented at the conference, The Baltic States: New Europe or Old?, University of
Glasgow 22–23 January 2004.
Briguglio, L., Cordina, G., Farrugia, N. and Valla, S. (2006) ‘Conceptualizing and Meas-
uring Economic Resilience’, in Briguglio, L., Cordina, G. and Kisanga, E.J. (eds),
Building the Economic Resilience of Small States, Malta: Islands and Small States
Institute and London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Bukovskis, K. (2012) ‘Latvia’, in Lobjakas, A. and Mölder, M. (eds) EU-Russia Watch
2012, University of Tartu, available online at: http://ceurus.ut.ee/wp-content/
uploads/2011/06/EU-Russia-watch_1–20121.pdf (accessed 20 July 2013).
Deutsch, K. (1957) Political Community and the North Atlantic Area, Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Flockhart, T. (2006) ‘Europeanization: The Myths and the Facts’, Public Policy Research,
13(2): 86–91.
Franklin, Benjamin (1914) Poor Richard’s Almanack 1733,Waterloo, IA: The USC Pub-
lishing Company.
Ingebritsen, C. (2002) ‘Norm Entrepreneurs: Scandinavia’s Role in World Politics’,
Cooperation and Conflict, 37(1): 11–23.
Jurkynas, M.(2007) How Deep is Your Love: Baltic Brotherhood Re-Examined,Vilnius:
Vilniaus universiteto leidykla.
Jurkynas, M. (2012a) ‘Lithuania’, in Ó Beacháin, D., Sheriden, V. and Stan, S. (eds) Happy
Ever After? Life in post-communist Europe after EU membership, London: Routledge.
Jurkynas, M. (2012b) ‘Lithuania’, in Lobjakas, A. and Mölder, M. (eds) EU–Russia
Watch 2012, University of Tartu, Available online at: http://ceurus.ut.ee/wp-content/
uploads/2011/06/EU-Russia-watch_1–20121.pdf (accessed 20 July 2013).
Kaljurand, R. (2013) ‘Security Challenges of a Small State: The Case of Estonia’, in
‘Defence and Security for the Small: Perspectives from the Baltic States’, Centre for
Security concerns of the Baltic States 129
Small State Studies occasional paper: Reykjavik, available online at: http://ams.hi.is/
sites/ams.hi.is/files/defence_and_security_-_layout3.pdf (accessed 15 July 2013).
Kaljurand, R., Neretnieks, K., Ljung, B. and Tupay, J. (2012) ‘Developments in the
Security Environment of the Baltic Sea Region up to 2020’, International Centre for
Defence Studies, available online at: http://icds.ee/fileadmin/failid/Developments%20
in%20the%20Security%20Environment%20of%20the%20Baltic%20Sea%20
Region%20up%20to%202020.pdf (accessed 20 July 2013).
Kirby, D. (1999) ‘Locating the Baltic, Keynote address at the 16th Conference on Baltic
Studies’, Baltic Studies Newsletter 22–23 December 1999, available online at: www.
balticstudies-aabs.lanet.lv/bsn88/bsn88–01.html (accessed 18 July 2013).
Lobjakas, A. (2012) ‘EU–Russian Relations in 2011: A Four Dimensional Space’, in
Lobjakas, A. and Mölder, M. (eds) EU–Russia Watch 2012, University of Tartu, Avail-
able online at: http://ceurus.ut.ee/wp-content/uploads/2011/06/EU-Russia-watch_1–
20121.pdf (accessed 18 July 2013).
Maigre, M. (2010) ‘Energy Security Concerns of the Baltic States’, International Centre
for Defence Studies, available online at: http://icds.ee/fileadmin/failid/Merle_Maigre-
Energy_Security_Concers_of_the_Baltic_States.pdf (accessed 20 July 2013).
Mälksoo, M. (2006) ‘From Existential Politics Towards Normal Politics? The Baltic
States in the Enlarged Europe’, Security Dialogue 37(3): 275–296.
Michel, L. (2011) ‘Baltic Security: Why the United States (Still) Cares’, in Nurick, R.
and Nordenman, M. (eds), Nordic-Baltic Security in the 21st Century, Atlantic Council:
Washington, DC.
Miniotaitė, G. (2003) ‘Convergent Geography and Divergent Identities: A Decade of
Transformation in the Baltic States’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 16/2.
Morozov, V. (2004) ‘Russia in the Baltic Sea Region: Desecuritisation or Deregionalisa-
tion’, Cooperation and Conflict, 39(3): 317–331.
Morozov, V. (2009) ‘Obsessed with Identity: The IR in post-Soviet Russia’, Journal of
International Relations and Development, 12: 200–205.
Neumann, I.B. (1994) ‘A Region-building Approach to Northern Europe’, Review of
International Studies, 20: 53–74.
Ojanen, H. (1999) ‘How to Customize Your Union: Finland and the Northern Dimension
of the EU’, Northern Dimensions, Helsinki: Finnish Institute of International Affairs.
Ozoliņa, Ž. (2012) ‘Latvia’, in Ó Beacháin, D., Sheriden, V. and Stan, S. (eds) Happy
Ever After? Life in Post-communist Europe after EU Membership, London: Routledge.
Šešelgytė, M. (2013) ‘A Midget Warrior: Security Choices of Lithuania’, in ‘Defence and
Security for the Small: Perspectives from the Baltic States’, Centre for Small State
Studies occasional paper, Reykjavik, available online at: http://ams.hi.is/sites/ams.hi.is/
files/defence_and_security_-_layout3.pdf (accessed 15 July 2013).
Tarus, T. and Crandall, M. (2012) ‘Is Russia a threat to Estonian energy security?’, Baltic
Journal of Political Science, December.
Thorhallsson, B. (2006) ‘The Size of States in the European Union: Theoretical and Con-
ceptual Perspectives’, Journal of European Integration, 28(1): 7–31.
The Financial Times (2013) ‘Lithuania’s President Warns of Russia’s Rising Influence in
the East’, 2 July, available online at: www.ft.com/cms/s/0/4eb04500-e32b-11e2-
bd87-00144feabdc0.html#axzz2Y4HMQggO (accessed 25 November 2013).
Veebel, V. and Loik, R. (2012) ‘Estonia’, in Ó Beacháin, D., Sheriden, V. and Stan, S. (eds)
Happy Ever After? Life in Post-communist Europe after EU Membership, London:
Routledge.
8 Security challenges in the
Western Balkans
Building ‘soft’ security after conflict
Višnja Samardžija and Senada Šelo Šabić

Introduction
The region of the Western Balkans (WB) includes seven countries: Albania,
Bosnia and Herzegovina (BiH), Croatia, Macedonia,1 Kosovo, Montenegro and
Serbia – together corresponding to the former Yugoslavia minus Slovenia and
plus Albania.2 Currently crossing the European Union (EU) threshold,3 Croatia
is in a somewhat different position from other WB states in terms of the security
challenges discussed in this chapter. It has carried out a series of deep-reaching
reforms that completed the state-building process, strengthened democracy and
addressed most of the security problems still permeating this region to different
degrees. However, once in the EU Croatia is not able (or willing) simply to leave
regional issues, including security ones, to the remaining Western Balkan States.
The EU expects Croatia to be an anchor of stability in this region, and, also, to
serve partially as a role model for its neighbours: a model of how stabilization
and successful accession to the EU are achieved. However, there are challenges
in the Western Balkans that are not easily solved, and for which stabilization and
EU accession may not provide such conclusive answers as they seem to have
done for Croatia. This chapter will review the situation of all seven states men-
tioned – including Croatia’s interrelationships with the others – and the security
agenda for the region as a whole.
Chapter I of this book proposed using the ‘small state’ concept inter alia as a
‘focusing device’ to assess asymmetric power relations (cf. Thorhallsson and
Wivel 2006: 4, Wivel 2005). All Western Balkan (WB) States are small states by
this relativist definition, being the weaker party in a broader power relationship.
This is true of them all in a global or Europe-wide context, even if within the
region some states are bigger than the others and thus relatively more powerful.

Comparing the Western Balkan States


In terms of the size of population and territory, GDP and military expenditure, the
WB States are relatively small in the European context. The smallest, Montenegro,
with less than 700,000 inhabitants, could be considered a micro-state, while the
largest, Serbia, with a population of slightly more than 7,000,000, is still a small
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 131
state by the criteria used in this book. In total, seven states of the WB region have
some 23 million inhabitants, which is less than 5 per cent of the total current EU
population. Further, the GDP sizes (at real market prices) of these countries suggest
that all of them could also be considered small economies.
As explained, all WB countries except Albania became independent through
the staged dissolution of the former Yugoslavian state during the 1990s, and sub-
sequently,4 and thus started their state-building process within the last two
decades. Kosovo is the youngest state and its process of international recognition
has not been yet completed.5 The countries have reached different levels of
democratic development; some are still facing problems of statehood and fragil-
ity of state institutions, while identity issues, ethnic conflicts, organized crime,
corruption, open border issues and conflict-related threats still generate instab-
ility in the entire region.
Croatia has completed the state-building process, has functioning democratic
institutions, has strengthened the rule of law and made huge transformations in
the area of justice and fundamental rights. But it faces economic problems,
including a prolonged recession that severely impacts upon the progress achieved
in the last decade, and will do so further if the recession and negative growth
rates persist. Montenegro is stable enough to be currently considered the only
regional candidate close to EU entry, but the ongoing problems of fighting cor-
ruption and strengthening the rule of law undermine its state capacities. Each
other state in the region is challenged on at least one fundamental issue that
weakens the very basics of its statehood.6
In the last two decades the whole WB region has faced military conflicts and/
or other types of state destabilization. The capacity of these countries to handle
different types of threats, both from the national and the regional security point
of view, will be assessed in this chapter.
According to the SIPRI military expenditure database (2010),7 the global average
level of expenditure for military purposes as a proportion of GDP is 2.5 per cent,
while among the highest spenders in the EU are the United Kingdom (2.6 per cent)
and France (2.3 per cent). Among WB countries, the highest shares directed to mili-
tary purposes are in Serbia (2.2 per cent), Macedonia (1.4 per cent) and Croatia (1.7
per cent), which suggests that these states do not over-emphasize military threats.
This finding seems to match the general expectations of citizens of the region
regarding the potential risk of military conflicts. According to the Gallup Monitor
(2010), the majority of respondents in Croatia (88 per cent) and in Serbia (62 per
cent) do not anticipate another armed conflict in the region, while positive expecta-
tions of a peaceful future are expressed by 49 per cent of respondents in BiH.8
The countries of the WB region represent quite a heterogeneous group in
terms of progress in democratization and economic development (Table 8.1).
The goal of accession to the EU is the common denominator for the region and
provides the greatest incentive for implementing broad political, economic and
social reforms. Membership in the EU has been seen as a solution for almost all
regional ailments and thus represents the most important leverage and potential
role exercised by an external actor in the region.
Table 8.1 Selected Western Balkan basic indicators

Country Area (km2) Population Real GDP growth rates, GDP at current GDP per capita Military
(sources 1 (1 and 3) 2010 (% change over market prices, 2009 (PPS, EU 27 = 100, expenditure as % of
and 3) previous year) (2) (million euro) (2) 2010) (2) GDP, 2010 (4)

EU 27 average 2.0 11,752 100 –


Albania 28,748 3,002,859 3.5 8,716 28 1.6
Bosnia and Herzegovina 51,197 3,879,296 0.8 12,297 31 1.2
Croatia 56,594 4,480,043 –1.0 45,669 59 1.7
Kosovo 10,887 1,836,529 3.9 – – –
Macedonia 25,713 2,082,370 1.8 6,677 36 1.4
Montenegro 13,812 657,394 2.5 2,981 41 1.9
Serbia 77,474 7,276,604 1.0 28,883 35 2.2

Sources: (1) CIA World Factbook, available online at: www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/ (accessed 25 November 2012); (2) Eurostat, European
Commission, Pocketbook on the enlargement countries, 2012 edition; (3) Eurostat, European Commission. Tables, graphs and maps; (4) SIPRI military expenditure
database, available online at: www.sipri.org/databases/milex/milex (accessed 25 November 2012).
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 133
Demography is important for every state, even more so for a small state. Since
2000, demographic trends in all WB countries show a slowing-down of popula-
tion growth. Albania, Macedonia and Bosnia and Herzegovina retain positive,
but significantly reduced, growth rates, while Croatia, Montenegro and Serbia
recorded negative rates. Kosovo is not included in the statistics (see Table 8.2).9
The size of economies, population and territories, coupled with democratic and
market transitions and a post-conflict environment, creates different kinds of
‘soft’ security challenges that states in the region are confronting individually,
through regional cooperation, and with the assistance of external actors – prim-
arily the EU, NATO, the US and some other recent players in the region, like
Russia and Turkey.

The most important security changes faced by Western


Balkan small states

Hard security vs. soft security threats


Security in the wider sense includes military security plus political, economic,
social and environmental security (Buzan 1991: 19–20). If ‘hard’ security is
understood as military security, ‘soft’ security includes political, social, and eco-
nomic threats to a state (Moustakis 2003: 6). Some authors (e.g. Rincon et al.
2006: 4) extend ‘soft’ challenges to cover extreme poverty, disparity among
societies, infectious diseases, inter-ethnic conflicts, illegal immigration, inter-
national organized crime, corruption and trafficking of human beings. Together
these definitions include most of the threats that weak states face today.
In the process of WB post-conflict stabilization and moves towards Euro-
Atlantic integration, foreign actors in the region have offered some shelter
against both classes of threats. NATO focuses primarily on hard, i.e. military,
issues, while soft security issues are mostly tackled by the European Union in
the framework of the accession process. Since the 1990s, military threats to
Western Balkan countries have been replaced by threats stemming from trans-
border organized crime, corruption, human and drug trafficking, emigration,

Table 8.2 Population growth rate (%) in Western Balkan countries

Country 2002 2003 2004 2009 2010 2011 2012

Croatia 1.12 0.31 –0.02 –0.05 –0.06 –0.08 –0.09


Serbia – – – –0.47 –0.47 –0.47 –0.46
Montenegro – – 3.5 –0.85 –0.78 –0.71 –0.63
Macedonia 0.41 0.4 0.39 0.26 0.26 0.25 0.24
BiH 0.76 0.48 0.45 0.34 0.02 0.01 0.00
Albania 1.06 1.03 0.51 0.55 0.25 0.27 0.28

Source: CIA World Factbook, available online at: www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-


factbook/ (accessed 25 November 2012)
134 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
illegal migration, ethnic intolerance, lack of will to confront the past, environ-
mental problems, emigration of young educated people, and most of all, eco-
nomic hardships.

State weaknesses
A necessary precondition for resisting such threats is that states possess institu-
tional capacity and political legitimacy to implement laws and employ force, if
necessary. The fact that most WB states are weak, unfinished states explains why
soft security threats remain a serious security concern (Kostovicova 2007; Jano
2009; Grdešić 2009).
The Index of State Weakness in the Developing World (Rice and Patrick
2008) measures 141 states by various economic, political, security and social
welfare indicators to produce a list of the weakest states in the world. In global
terms, according to this index, the WB states are far from being the absolute
weakest. Serbia is listed as the weakest of them (positioned at 108), followed by
Albania (ranked 111), BiH (113), Macedonia (114) and Croatia (131). Monte-
negro and Kosovo are not ranked since they became independent at the time the
research was ongoing or just completed, in 2006 and 2008 respectively.
Although WB states score relatively well on this list, a point of concern is the
fact that they are the only European states – except Moldova and Ukraine –
thought weak enough to be included in it.
State weakness has different ‘faces’ in the WB region. For example, the lack
of political consensus on the nature of the state as in BiH (cf High Representa-
tive in BiH 2012), regional constraints as in Macedonia or unfinished territorial
delineation as in Serbia’s case, are specific national concerns that compound the
general weakness of all WB states. The rulings of the International Criminal Tri-
bunal for the Former Yugoslavia (in November 2012), proclaiming Croatian
generals Gotovina and Markač and the former Kosovo Prime Minister, Haradi-
naj, not guilty of war crimes, led to an upsurge of nationalist rhetoric within
Serbia and the shattering of its relations with neighbours. Conversely, when The
Hague Tribunal acquitted Serbian general Perišić in March 2013, criticism of the
tribunal’s modus operandi was heard among Serbia’s neighbours. Nationalist
rhetoric is still a potent instrument to foment mistrust and raise fears in the
region.

Corruption and organized crime


It is no surprise that poorly-governed territories become the ideal place for illegal
businesses. The so-called Western Balkan route is used for drugs, arms and
human trafficking. Dense networks of criminal groups operating across borders
are not easily suppressed even by the coordinated, trained and equipped police
forces of a strong state, much less the police of weak states. Organized criminal
groups benefit from frail states, weak regional infrastructure, uncontrolled
borders and limited policing (Howard and Traughber 2008: 375).10
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 135
The 2013 Europol report states that the Western Balkan route continues to be
used for trafficking drugs, weapons and humans.11 Serious problems in tackling
organized crime, both internal and trans-border, arise from the fact that not only
are WB states’ institutional structures too weak to fight organized crime effect-
ively, but criminal structures can be directly linked to the state apparatus. Stoja-
rová (2007: 111) finds that the existing symbiosis between organized crime and
the security sector undermines efforts at police reform and other initiatives that
would strengthen the rule of law.
The legacy of the conflicts of the 1990s is difficult to exaggerate because it
confronts the processes of institution-building, democratic consolidation, recon-
ciliation and economic revitalization with the need for a comprehensive struc-
tural overhaul of both state and society. This is state-building almost ab initio.
Resistance to changes among those who lose out by a strong rule of law and
increased transparency has been forceful, the most extreme example being the
assassination of a Serbian Prime Minister in 2003.12 The slowness of reforms,
the lack of capacity to effectively counter-corruptive and criminal activities, and
the lack of will to assume governance responsibility are constantly criticized by
the international community (see, for example, European Commission 2012c).
Corruption is perceived as endemic throughout the region (Gallup 2010: 34).
Among 183 countries surveyed, the Transparency International annual corrup-
tion report places WB countries somewhere in the middle. The best performing
are Croatia and Montenegro (ranked at number 66), while Kosovo, at 112, is the
most corrupt in the region.
The 2012 European Commission Progress Reports for the WB countries
underline the need for an effective fight against corruption. While moderate pro-
gress has been noted in Albania and Montenegro, greater efforts are required in
the case of Macedonia and BiH and Serbia saw limited progress. The 2012 EU
Commission’s Feasibility Study for a Stabilization and Association Agreement
for Kosovo also underscores that the country needs to demonstrate a clear com-
mitment to fight organized crime and corruption. Croatia made clear progress in
this sphere during the negotiation process:13 the EC Monitoring Report (2013)
on Croatian preparedness for EU membership concluded that the country had
continued to strengthen its legislative framework to prevent corruption, but this
needed to be effectively implemented.

Economic and social threats


Even without conflict legacies, weak democratic institutions and contested iden-
tities, the slow economic transition to market economy would be a sufficient
source for instability and security threats in this region. Collier et al. (2008) see
two key goals that post-conflict societies should aim for. One is facilitating eco-
nomic recovery, while the other is reducing the risks of renewed conflicts. The
former ultimately plays a crucial role in the latter as well: peace and stability
depend more on economic progress, along with the immediate military presence,
than on political designs.
Table 8.3 Global corruption ranking of Western Balkan States (2005–2011)

Year/no of countries (total) 2005/159 2006/163 2007/180 2008/180 2009/180 2010/178 2011/183

Croatia 70 69 64 62 66 62 66
Serbia 97 90 79 85 83 78 86
Montenegro 97 84 85 69 69 66
BiH 88 93 84 92 99 91 91
Albania 126 111 105 85 95 87 95
Macedonia 103 105 84 72 71 62 69
Kosovo – – – – – 110 112

Source: Transparency International, Corruption by country/territory annual reports, 2011.


Note
The new methodology introduced in 2012 does not enable comparison with the results of the Transparency International’s CPIs of previous years, thus the year 2012
is not included in the table.
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 137
The international financial crisis also struck the WB countries in 2008, threaten-
ing to amplify existing and provoke latent tensions in the region, and to shift the
donor community’s focus towards their own problems (Minić 2009). The region is
characterized by strong inequalities of income distribution and is threatened by
high unemployment, particularly among its youth (Table 8.4).
These countries are facing challenges of fiscal consolidation and structural
reform. De-industrialization and low exports exacerbate already existing problems.
From strong social protection systems in the former Yugoslavia, all its successor
states now have relatively weak social protection systems. According to Bartlett
(2010: 5), the poverty and social insecurity generated in the last two decades has
fed political instability that further undermines the progress of these countries
towards the EU. All these circumstances, accompanied by the lack of a clear EU
membership prospect, could lead to a return of strong populist, nationalist regimes
and bring long-term instability to the region as a result (Sopinska 2009).

Terrorism
The Western Balkan States are not currently targeted by any radical terrorist group
and the threat of radical terrorism remains limited. However, although not provid-
ing the training or the terrain for breeding terrorist groups, the Western Balkans
may play a secondary role as a site for terrorist transit, rest and recuperation
(Woehrel 2005). The US Embassy in Sarajevo called the 2011 shooting at the US
Embassy an incident, not an act of terrorism.14 In 2012, five men were put on trial
on terrorism charges after killing five people at the Smiljkovsko Lake in Mace-
donia, reportedly aiming to create fear, insecurity and inter-ethnic intolerance
among Macedonian citizens (Karajkov 2012). It was found that the perpetrators
were not (yet) connected to any terrorist organization. Infiltration by some radical
Islamic groups was noted in parts of Bosnia and Herzegovina, Sandjak (Serbia),
Macedonia and Kosovo in the late 1990s. Today, the general assessment is that the
threat of Islamic terrorism is primarily cited for political purposes; yet as the fear of
terrorism is rooted in its very unpredictability, it could take just one or two terrorist
acts to jeopardize security here as elsewhere in the world.

Table 8.4 Percentage of unemployed workforce in the Western Balkans, 2005–2011 (%)

2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011

Croatia – 18 11.8 13.7 16.1 17.6 17.7


Serbia – – 18.8 – 16.6 19.2 23.4
Montenegro 27.7 – 14.7 – – – 11.5
Macedonia 37.3 36 34.9 33.5 32.2 31.7 31.4
BiH 44 45.5 29 45.5 40 43.1 43.3
Albania 14.8 14.3 13.8 12.5 12.8 13.5 13.3
Kosovo – – 40 – 45 – 45.3

Source: CIA World Factbook, annual country data, 2005 to 2011.


138 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
Civil security threats
The WB countries are highly exposed and vulnerable to natural hazards, including
floods, earthquakes, forest fires, droughts and heatwaves, as well as man-made dis-
asters linked to infrastructures and industrial pollution. There are also examples of
environmental threats, such as the air pollution from plants and refineries, indus-
trial hazards resulting from old technologies, pollution of coastal waters from
sewage outlets and other threats of a similar kind. Air and water quality, waste
management, recycling and nature protection are among the environmental areas
of concern in the Western Balkans (CSIS – EKEM 2010). The impacts of such dis-
asters are too overwhelming to be handled by a single country, especially when
they have transnational impacts or cross-border implications.

The role of international actors in the Western Balkans:


NATO and the European Union

NATO
NATO focuses on military aspects of security in the Western Balkans. Most coun-
tries in the region want to join NATO. Their shared membership would defuse
conflict threats that the region grappled with in the 1990s, but also strengthen the
rule of law and democratic institutions – prerequisites for enhanced security.
NATO opened its Partnership for Peace programme to WB states and Mace-
donia joined in the mid-1990s, while the others followed by 2000. Croatia and
Albania are full-fledged NATO members as of 2009, while others, apart from
Serbia, are implementing required reforms as a prerequisite for membership.
Montenegro and BiH joined the Membership Action Plan (MAP) in 2009 and
2010 respectively with long reform paths ahead, a task the more difficult given
their moderate public support for NATO membership (59.7 per cent in BiH15 and
37.3 per cent in Montenegro).16 Serbia, although a member of the PfP, is not cur-
rently a potential NATO member since, in 2007, it declared itself a (militarily)
neutral state.17 Public opinion in Kosovo favours NATO membership, but its
membership ambitions are hampered by incomplete recognition.18
The region has also experienced NATO military deployments to counter military
threats. By 2012, the initially 60,000 strong NATO-led international military force
in BiH (deployed in 1995), had been reduced to 600 soldiers, but the NATO-led
Kosovo Force (KFOR) has some 5,500 troops on the ground. The international
military presence has de-militarized local conditions and defused tensions to a point
where military clashes pose no immediate risk, although much work remains to
institute effective civilian control of local armed and other security forces.

The European Union


Since the early 1990s, the European Union has played an important role in the
WB region, aiming to stabilize and democratize the countries and facilitate good,
neighbourly relations. Different tools have been used, from the regional approach
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 139
in the 1990s (EU Council of Ministers 1996) to the current ‘individual merit
approach’ using the accession-related Stabilization and Association Process
(SAP). EU enlargement policy supports the post-war democratic transition,
reforms, regional cooperation and overall Europeanization of the region.
Under the ‘carrot and stick’ conditionality principle, progress towards EU
membership depends on implementing required reforms based on the acquis
communautaire (EU Council of Ministers 1997). Thus the EU’s ‘transformative
power’ plays an important role in institution-building, policy development and
reforms, although not always with the wished-for success. Slow reforms partially
reflect insufficient EU institutional capacity to pursue them, and the general lack
of interest for further enlargement due to the intra-EU crisis; but they certainly
also result from regional weaknesses – including weak institutional capacities,
feeble political will and the perceived uncertainty over accession. Some authors
argue (Stubbs and Solioz 2012: 15) that the narratives of ‘returning to Europe’,
‘convergence’, or ‘widening and deepening’ now seem tarnished and ambiguous
in the face of new sets of power relations and disciplinary practices within the
EU, together with reworked ideas of the core and periphery, ‘old’ and ‘new’
Europe, that reveal the paradoxes of Euro-Atlantic integration.
The EU’s approach towards the WB represents an interaction between its
enlargement policy and the Common Foreign and Security Policy (CFSP), includ-
ing the Common Security and Defence Policy (CSDP) as its operational arm. Ele-
ments of the pre-accession process are mixed with peace and state-building
processes in the post-conflict regional environment. The EU has further used the
WB region for deploying military and civilian CSDP missions, thus upgrading its
crisis management and security role in BiH, Macedonia and Kosovo.19
However, the ever-changing security challenges in the region require a re-
thinking of EU policy towards the region. During its presence, the regional
architecture has changed – two new independent small states appeared since
2006 (Montenegro and Kosovo), and the region gained its first EU member state
in 2013. The overall landscape of the region will be characterized for years to
come by a set of unresolved issues, the most important being the constitutional
and state issues of BiH, Macedonia’s name issue with Greece, and the Belgrade–
Priština dialogue issue. The unresolved – very often bilateral – inter-state dis-
putes still represent one of the region’s biggest challenges and a threat for the
process of enlargement.
The important common task is to deal with the challenges of regional enlarge-
ment following Croatia’s entry to the EU. Croatia is seen as the first success
story of EU enlargement in the WB and its membership proves the credibility of
the Stabilization and Association Process. The most important expected benefit
of Croatia’s accession to the EU is its contribution to regional security. However,
strengthened EU enlargement instruments are needed in the future. A slowing-
down of enlargement processes would bring new frustration, populism and
nationalism in the region and, what is most important, a further slow-down in
reforms. The EU must re-think its strategic approach to the WB region and put
more content into the process of enlargement.
140 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
Regional and national responses to security threats in the
Western Balkans

Regional cooperation
Regional cooperation is understood as a prerequisite for creating stability,
security and long-term peace in Western Balkans, and has been seen as the ‘main
remedy for the regional conflicts’ (Elbassani 2008: 300). Apart from security-
driven reasons, regional cooperation has a strong economic dimension. Today,
the measure of success for a small country is its ability to integrate in the inter-
national system and benefit from access to larger markets at various levels, from
the sub-regional and regional upwards (Bechev 2011: 154).
Regional cooperation is understood as a collective, intergovernmental action
of three or more states that takes place within a geographically-bounded, but
sometimes vaguely defined or politically contestable, setting. The outcomes are
varied and may include trade liberalization, joint regulation, common projects,
institutional arrangements and decision-making procedures, common responses
to threats and issues especially of a political kind and many other joint solutions
(Bechev 2011). Numerous regional organizations and initiatives exist in the WB
region,20 and engaging in them has become a cornerstone of EU accession condi-
tionality for WB states. Initial local reactions to requests for stronger coopera-
tion were not enthusiastic, but it is now accepted as a necessary condition for EU
and NATO membership (Stubbs and Solioz 2012: 23). Over time, the WB coun-
tries have become more active and the ‘ownership’ of regional cooperation has
gradually strengthened.
Cooperation takes place in the fields of justice and home affairs, law enforce-
ment, police cooperation and other security-related areas. The focus is on soft
security issues, such as corruption, trans-border crime, illegal trafficking, migra-
tion management and the promotion of transparency in public administration. A
number of projects or joint activities have resulted, which advance good gover-
nance and help to create intergovernmental frameworks to deal with these chal-
lenges more effectively.
Today, the umbrella organization for WB regional cooperation is the Regional
Cooperation Council (RCC), launched in 2008 as a successor to the South-East
European Stability Pact.21 It operates under the political guidance of the South-
East European Cooperation Process (SEECP). In its sixth year of work, RCC
constitutes a clear-profiled, leading platform for guiding and monitoring cooper-
ation in SEE, and has helped to establish an integrated, regionally-owned coop-
eration mechanism among governmental security sectors. Local ownership of
regional cooperation has improved and must now move to a new level of consol-
idation by taking greater regional responsibility for carrying the process
forward.22
Among many other areas the RCC’s work includes cooperation on security-
related matters, such as justice and home affairs.23 The RCC has initiated the
Regional Police Cooperation Convention for SEE, a cooperation mechanism
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 141
linking the Chiefs of Military Intelligence (SEEMIC), the South-East European
National Security Authorities (SEENSA) and the South-East European Counter-
intelligence Chiefs Forum (SEECIC). The entity known as RACVIAC – Centre
for Security Cooperation (www.racviac.org, accessed 25 November 2013) –
deserves attention as an international, but regionally-owned, academic organiza-
tion that, since 2000, has helped foster dialogue and cooperation on security
matters by transforming thinking on national, regional and international security
cooperation issues.
There are further regional initiatives for security cooperation. The Southeast
Europe Police Chiefs Association (SEPCA, www.sepca-see.eu, accessed 25
November 2013) has, since 2007, promoted the police’s transformation into an
effective and democratic service, while the Police Cooperation Convention for
Southeast Europe (PCC SEE) organizes and monitors the implementation of the
treaty-based procedural mechanism for police regional cooperation.24 The
Regional Anti-corruption Initiative (RAI, www.rai-see.org, accessed 25
November 2013) was established in 2000 as an intergovernmental organization
and regional platform for combining the anti-corruption efforts of governments,
civil society, aid agencies and international organizations. In the area of civil
security, the Disaster Preparedness and Prevention Initiative for South-Eastern
Europe (DPPI SEE), founded in 2000 by the member states of the Stability Pact,
aims to help the countries of the region work together in preventing and respond-
ing to natural and man-made disasters.
Governments in the region have signed a series of bilateral agreements on the
mutual extradition of criminals, who often found refuge in a neighbouring state
by (mis)using the status of dual citizenship.25 These agreements are not applied
to individuals charged with war crimes and cannot be retroactively applied, but
they are another important element of police and judicial cooperation.
These initiatives reflect the progress achieved towards ‘ownership’ of regional
cooperation in the areas of security, particularly in justice and home affairs. It is
important to note that practically all WB countries take part in key initiatives;26
and there has been some visible success. Integrated border management, police
cooperation in combating organized crime and corruption, and civil security
cooperation serve to confront security threats. Regional cooperation on security
fosters dialogue and integrates regional interests into national ones. Much
remains to be done, however, and further efforts are needed to consolidate
regional cooperation.

National responses
Confronted with various security challenges, WB nations have always needed
international, and in particular, European support and mentorship to improve the
conditions for stability and prosperity. One genuinely local effort to improve the
sense of trust and respect has, however, been the policy of reconciliation.27 The
capacity to face the past, and the courage to face victims and apologize to them,
is essential for overcoming mistrust and fear and for laying the basis for honest
142 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
relations based on respect.28 The WB policy of reconciliation has been unan-
imously welcomed and supported by the international community, in particular
by the US, the EU and European capitals.29 However, there is a limit to what
such a policy can solve by itself.
With EU backing, several so-called high-level or structural dialogues have
been initiated in the region to attempt to overcome obstacles perceived as almost
insurmountable. Thus, the EU has launched activities to tackle issues like the
inability of Macedonia to progress towards NATO and EU accession due to the
‘name’ issue (handled by the High-level Accession Dialogue between EU and
the government of Macedonia – HLAD);30 the High-level Dialogue between
Kosovo and Serbia;31 and the Structured Dialogue with Bosnia and Herze-
govina.32 Their main goal is to relieve tensions over the highly-contested topics
they individually deal with, focusing instead on issues where agreements and
consensus can be reached. Dialogue is seen as an instrument to make break-
throughs on issues that have long been blocked, before negotiations on EU
accession for the relevant states can begin.
In contrast to the political sphere, civil society organizations have cooperated
across borders throughout the past two decades, confronting the region’s unre-
solved issues and seeking common solutions. One example is the regional, civil
society-driven initiative RECOM, which is working hard to mobilize support for
an initiative seeking to transform current national narratives that glorify the
national victims of past wars and aiming, instead, to treat all victims of these
wars as a shared memory. The method used for this, namely providing evidence
for each single loss of life in the wars of the 1990s in one document, offers a
blueprint for confronting the past, based on facts.33

Conclusion
Western Balkan states in their recent history of independence have faced
diverse security threats. The violent breakup of the former Yugoslavia led to a
series of succession wars and the creation of new countries that could all be
categorized as small, or even micro-, states. Their security has been jeopard-
ized by armed conflicts, by prolonged economic, political and social transi-
tions, and by slow post-conflict reconciliation. The threat of new military
conflicts is low and is expected to vanish completely once these states com-
plete accession to the EU and NATO. Yet a number of soft security threats
remain, seriously affecting the ‘normality’ associated with peaceful, stable,
democratic and sustainable states.
All WB states are in some way included in the process of accession or mem-
bership of the EU and NATO. As from 2013, Croatia is a member of both.
Albania is a member of NATO, while all other states are either candidates or
potential candidates for membership in both organizations (with the notable
exception of Serbia vis-à-vis NATO membership). The EU accession process is
particularly important for democratic, political, economic and administrative
reforms in the region. Furthermore, the measure of success for a small country
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 143
is, nowadays, its ability to integrate in the international system and benefit from
access to larger markets at various levels, from sub-regional to regional and
further upwards. However, after Croatia’s accession it is hard to envisage
another round of enlargement until 2020 or even later. The slow-down in
enlargement could bring new frustration, populism and nationalism in the region
and, what is most dangerous, another slow-down in local reforms. Essential
reforms are already going slowly, as these states are weakened both by internal
turmoil and by the external and/or regional pressures imposed on them inter alia
by bilateral disputes, and suspension or stalemate in their progress towards EU
membership.
State weakness has been reflected, among other things, in the lack of capa-
city to strengthen the rule of law, to control borders against organized crime
and to fight corruption. The strong society and strong economy that underpin a
viable democratic state have been lacking, leaving the whole process of state-
building – the corner-stone for creating stability and security in the region –
exposed to the often overlapping and sometimes conflicting agendas and
initiatives of different actors. This situation has changed as the EU has
emerged as the most responsible and present actor in the region, although
other actors still play roles.
The smallness of these states, combined with limited public administration
efficiency, clearly affects their capacity to efficiently address economic, social
and security issues. This is why regional cooperation in the area of security, par-
ticularly in the fields of justice and home affairs, is seen as a way forward. The
profile of existing initiatives shows that WB states have jointly responded to a
number of security challenges by regional cooperation, inter alia, in integrated
border management, police cooperation against organized crime and various
other aspects of civil security. Regional cooperation builds mutual trust, although
mutual trust is also a necessary precondition for cooperation. Under such con-
ditions, the WB region (with the exception of Croatia) in the decade to come will
remain an arena for intensive oversight and, in some respects, external adminis-
tration by the EU (and NATO). The transition to a neighbourhood of full-fledged
democracies and viable economies, of societies at peace with themselves and
others, will be long. It may be slow, but the most important point is that it keeps
going.
The heterogeneity of reform processes in the region is unavoidable and there-
fore should be accepted on its own merits. Croatia, as a new EU member state,
can positively impact upon and contribute to the implementation of reforms in
other countries during their accession process, by sharing knowledge, skills and
experience gained during its own EU apprenticeship. EU membership gives
Croatia an opportunity to explore the potential for transforming itself from a
small state to a small power (Jović, 2011: 7) in handling the foreign and security
policy issues facing the Western Balkans. Thus, the slow – and most likely pro-
longed – business of EU accession can be used to implement comprehensive
reforms, while adapting the accession process to each nation’s own capacities
and possibilities.
144 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
Notes
1 In this chapter, the Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia (FYROM or FYR Mace-
donia) is simply called Macedonia.
2 The term South-Eastern Europe (SEE) is sometimes also used to describe this region,
but it is geographically broader and also includes Bulgaria, Romania, Turkey and
Greece; frequently Moldova, and sometimes Slovenia.
3 Croatia entered the EU on 1 July 2013.
4 The Republic of Croatia declared independence in 1991, while Kosovo declared inde-
pendence in 2008. On the other hand, Albania marked 100 years of independence in
2012.
5 The Republic of Kosovo became independent on 17 February 2008. As of 16 March
2013, Kosovo has received 101 diplomatic recognitions: from 99 of the 193 United
Nations (UN) member states, 22 of 27 European Union (EU) member states, 24 of 28
NATO member states, and 32 of 57 Organization of Islamic Cooperation (OIC)
member states. The Government of Serbia does not officially recognize it.
6 Serbia is facing the challenge of the territorial issue and new forms of nationalistic
rhetoric, Kosovo is burdened with the issues of international recognition and identity,
Macedonia with the so-called name issue, Albania with deep internal political rifts
and BiH with the constitutional issue.
7 The SIPRI military database contains data for 171 countries for the period
1988–2011.
8 See, www.balkan-monitor.eu/files/BalkanMonitor-2010_Summary_of_Findings.pdf
(accessed 19 November 2012).
9 The population growth rate is defined as the average annual per cent change in the
population, resulting from a surplus (or deficit) of births over deaths and the balance
of migrants entering and leaving a country.
10 See also Chapter 9, on Moldova and Georgia, in this volume.
11 EUROPOL SOCTA 2013 Report, Chapter 2: Crime Areas, available online at: www.
europol.europa.eu/sites/default/files/publications/socta2013.pdf (accessed 20 November
2012).
12 Prime Minister Zoran Đinđić was assassinated on 12 March 2003, in Belgrade. The
former commander of the Red Berets, an elite Special Operations Unit, founded by
the regime of Slobodan Milošević to carry out special tasks during the wars in the
former Yugoslavia, was accused of organizing the assassination. This tragedy led to
the decision by the Serbian government to dissolve the Red Berets.
13 In 2010, the former Croatian Prime Minister and several ministers in his cabinet were
put on trial on charges of corruption.
14 Mevlid Jašarević, a 23-year-old from Novi Pazar in Serbia, fired at the Embassy; see
(Hopkins and Hadžović 2011).
15 Banja Luka (2011).
16 CEDEM (2012)
17 See www.isac-und.org/download/Neutrality_in_Europe_in_the_XXI_century_and_
the_Case_of_Serbia.pdf (accessed 19 November 2012).
18 The main obstacle has been the position of four NATO members that do not recog-
nize Kosovo’s independence – Spain, Slovakia, Greece and Romania. ‘Kosovo’s Path
towards the NATO Partnership for Peace (PfP) Programme’, Kosovar Center for
Security Studies 2012, p. 9, available online at: http://qkss.org/new/index.php?section
=news&cmd=details&newsid=330&teaserId=11 (accessed 19 November 2012).
19 In BiH, the EU Military Operation, EUFOR Althea, taking over from NATO’s SFOR
to maintain peace and security, was followed by the EU Police Mission EUPM and
the creation of an EU Special Representative, EUSR. In Macedonia the EU Military
Operation EUFOR Concordia, focusing on crisis prevention, was followed by the EU
Police Mission, EUPOL Proxima, later replaced by the EU Police Advisory Team,
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 145
EUPAT. In Kosovo, the EU’s Rule of Law Mission (EULEX Kosovo) is the EU’s
largest CSDP mission and holds responsibility for security and stability following the
UN-mandated Interim Mission, UNMIK.
20 Regional organizations and initiatives in WB countries could be categorized into
several groups according to their legal status and institutional characteristics. Some
function as international intergovernmental organizations or non-governmental organ-
izations (NGOs); others are donor-funded initiatives or projects; and there are many
networks with structures and operations hosted by other, mostly governmental, insti-
tutions (Regional Cooperation Council, 2011).
21 The EU-sponsored Stability Pact for South-Eastern Europe was launched in 1999 as
the international community’s first comprehensive conflict prevention strategy, aimed
at strengthening the efforts of the WB countries to foster peace, democracy, respect
for human rights and economic prosperity.
22 Regional Cooperation Council (2011–2012).
23 The European Commission, which is a member of the RCC, provides financial
support for the Secretariat in Sarajevo and for some of its initiatives.
24 This is adopted by eight countries (Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, The
Former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Moldova, Montenegro, Romania and
Serbia).
25 For a quick grasp of the process, see http://dnevnik.hr/vijesti/hrvatska/hrvatska-i-srbija-
dogovorili-medzusobno-izrucivanje-kriminalaca.html; http://setimes.com/cocoon/setimes/
xhtml/hr/features/setimes/features/2011/05/19/feature-02 (accessed 19 November 2012).
26 In some initiatives Kosovo is still not participating officially.
27 Croatian President, Ivo Josipović, who took office in 2010, made a strong contribution
together with the Serbian President, Boris Tadić, to consolidating relations between
Serbia and Croatia, and improving the sense of reconciliation and understanding in
Bosnia and Herzegovina. The new Serbian government should continue in these
efforts.
28 The policy of reconciliation has been extensively covered in the media, mostly
endorsed but also criticized by nationalist circles on all sides.
29 See, www.state.gov/secretary/rm/2012/10/199931.htm and http://daily.tportal.hr/94848/
Fuele-Tadic-s-visit-to-Vukovar-important-step-towards-reconciliation.html (accessed 19
November 2012).
30 http://europa.eu/rapid/press-release_MEMO-12–187_en.htm?locale=en (accessed 19
November 2012).
31 See, http://setimes.com/cocoon/setimes/xhtml/en_GB/features/setimes/features/2012/09/
27/feature-02 (accessed 25 November 2013).
32 See, http://europa.ba/Default.aspx?id=87&lang=EN (accessed 25 November 2013).
33 See, www.zarekom.org/uploads/documents/2011/04/i_836/f_28/f_1865_en.pdf (accessed
25 November 2013).

Bibliography
Anastasijevic, D. (2006) ‘Organized Crime in the Western Balkans’, available online at:
www.humsec.eu/cms/fileadmin/user_upload/humsec/Working_Paper_Series/Working_
Paper_Anastasijevic.pdf (accessed 19 November 2012).
Bailes, A.J.K. (2008) ‘Does a Small State Need a Strategy?’, University of Iceland, avail-
able online at: http://stofnanir.hi.is/ams/sites/files/ams/Bailes_Final_0.pdf (accessed 19
November 2012).
Balkan Monitor (2010) ‘Insights and Perceptions: Voices of the Balkans – Summary of
Findings’, Gallup, available online at: www.balkan-monitor.eu/files/BalkanMonitor-
2010_Summary_of_Findings.pdf (accessed 19 November 2012).
146 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
Banja Luka (2011) ‘Prime Communications’, available online at: http://prime.ba
(accessed 19 November 2012).
Bartlett, W. (2010) ‘The Social Impact of the Global Economic Crisis in the Western
Balkans With a Focus on the Republic of Macedonia’, European Institute, London:
London School of Economics and Political Science.
Bechev, D. (2011) Constructing South East Europe: The Politics of Balkan Regional
Cooperation, St Antony’s Series, London: Palgrave Macmillan in Association with St
Antony’s College, Oxford.
Börzel, T. (2011) ‘When Europeanization Hits Limited Statehood: The Western Balkans
as a Test Case for the Transformative Power of Europe’, KFG working paper, Berlin:
Freie Universität Berlin.
Buzan, B. (1991) People, States and Fear: the National Security Problem in International
Relations, 2nd edition, Wheatsheaf Books.
Centre for Democracy and Human Rights (CEDEM) (2012) Available online at: http://
cedem.me (accessed 19 November 2012).
Collier, P., Hoeffler, A. and Söderbom, M. (2008) ‘Post-Conflict Risks’, Journal of Peace
Research, 45(4): 461–478.
CSIS, Center for Strategic Studies and EKEM, Hellenic Centre for European Studies
(2010), ‘CSIS-EKEM Policy Report, Assessing Human Security in the Western
Balkans’, December.
Djurdjevic Lukic, S. (ed.) (2010) ‘The Media and Security Sector Reform in the Western
Balkans’, The Geneva Centre for the Democratic Control of Armed Forces, available
online at: www.dcaf.ch/Publications/The-Media-and-Security-Sector-Reform-in-the-
Western-Balkans (accessed 21 November 2012).
Elbasani, A. (2008) ‘EU Enlargement in the Western Balkans: Strategies for Borrowing
and Inventing’, Journal of Balkan and Near Eastern Studies, 10(3): 293–307.
EU Council of Ministers (1996) ‘Conclusions on Former Yugoslavia’, 26 February, EU
Bulletin 1/2–1996.
EU Council of Ministers (1997) ‘Conclusions on the Principle of Conditionality Govern-
ing the Development of the European Union’s Relations with Certain Countries of
South-Eastern Europe, 29 April, EU Bulletin 4–1997.
European Commission (2012a) Eurostat: Pocketbook on the Enlargement Countries,
Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.
European Commission (2012b) ‘Main Findings of the Comprehensive Monitoring Report
on Croatia’s State of Preparedness for EU Membership’, COM (2012) 601 final, Brus-
sels: European Commission.
European Commission (2012c) ‘Enlargement Strategy and Main Challenges 2012–2013’,
COM (2012) 600 final, Brussels: European Commission, available online at: http://
ec.europa.eu/enlargement/countries/strategy- and-progress- report/index_en.htm
(accessed 11 November 2012).
European Commission (2013) ‘Communication from the Commission to the European
Parliament and the Council: Monitoring Report on Croatia’s Accession Preparations’,
COM (2013) 171 final, Brussels: European Commission.
Europol SOCTA (EU Serious and Organised Crime Threat Assessment) (2013) ‘2013
Report’, European Police Office.
Gallup, Balkan Monitor (2010) ‘Insights and Perceptions: Voices of the Balkans’, 2010
Summary Findings available online at: www.balkan-monitor.eu (accessed 10
November 2012).
Grdešić, M. (2009) ‘The Problem of Weak States and Weak Societies in Eastern Europe’
(in Croatian), Anali Hrvatskog politološkog društva.
Security challenges in the Western Balkans 147
High Representative in Bosnia and Herzegovina (2012) ‘Report to the UN Security
Council’, 13 November 2012, available online at: www.ohr.int/ohr-dept/presso/pressr/
default.asp?content_id=47619 (accessed 15 November 2012).
Hopkins, V. and Hadžović, E. (2011) ‘Sarajevo Gunman in Custody, Officials Condemn
Attack’, Balkan Insight, 28 October 2011, available online at: www.balkaninsight.com/
en/article/shooting-at-us-embassy-to-bosnia-and-herzegovina (accessed 15 November
2012).
Horvat, V. (ed.) (2009) ‘Issue Paper on EU Policy toward the Western Balkans –
Regional Perspective, Case studies – Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia, Croatia,
Kosovo’, Prague: Heinrich Boll Stiftung Office, available online at: www.ba.boell.org/
downloads/hbs-brochure-western-balkan.pdf (accessed 21 November 2012).
Howard, R.D. and Traughber, C.M. (2008) ‘The “New Silk Road” of Terrorism and
Organized Crime: The Key to Countering the Terror-Crime Nexus’, in Norwitz, J.H.
(ed.) Armed Groups: Studies in National Security, Counterterrorism and Counterinsur-
gency, Newport, RI: Naval War College, pp. 371–387.
Jano, D. (2009) ‘How Legacies of the Past and Weakness of the State brought Violent
Dissolution and Disorder to the Western Balkan States’, Journal of Peace, Conflict and
Development, 14.
Jović, D. (2011) ‘Croatian Foreign Policy Facing the Challenges of EU Membership’ (in
Croatian), Politička misao, 48(2): 7–36.
Karajkov, R. (2012) ‘Macedonia: Is It Terrorism?’, 11 June 2012, available online at:
www.balcanicaucaso.org/eng/Regions-and-countries/Macedonia/Macedonia-Is-It-
Terrorism-118381 (accessed 15 November 2012).
Kostovicova, D. (2007) ‘State Weakness in the Western Balkans as a Security Threat:
The European Union: Approach and a Global Perspective’, in Serbia 2007 – Liberal
Transformation or Prolonged Transition, Belgrade Centre for Security Policy (BCSP),
pp. 10–15.
Minić, J. (2009) ‘A Decade of Regional Cooperation in SEE – Sharing Guidance, Leader-
ship and Ownership’, in Dialogues, Ownership for Regional Cooperation in the
Western Balkans Countries, Friedrich Ebert Stiftung.
Moustakis, F. (2004) ‘Soft Security Threats in the New Europe: the Case of the Balkan
Region’, European Security, 13(1): 39–56.
Regional Cooperation Council (2011) ‘Western Balkans and Europe 2020 – Supporting
Convergence and Growth: Regional Coordination Conference. Survey of Regional Ini-
tiatives and Task Forces in South East Europe – Summary Findings’, Brussels:
Regional Cooperation Council.
Regional Cooperation Council (2011–2012) ‘Annual Report of the Secretary General of
the RCC on Regional Co-operation in SEE’, Sarajevo: Regional Cooperation Council.
Rice, S.E. and Patrick, S. (2008) ‘Index of State Weakness in the Developing World’,
The Brookings Institution, available online at: www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/
files/reports/2008/2/weak%20states%20index/02_weak_states_index.pdf (accessed 20
November, 2012).
Rincon, A., Ramos, L.E. and Estevez, L. (2006) ‘Soft-security Within the Euro-
Mediterranean Partnership’, Go-EuroMed working paper no. 0611, available online at:
www.go-euromed.org/documents/working_paper/Go-EuroMed_WP_0611_Spain_on_
Security.pdf (accessed 12 November, 2012).
SIPRI Military Expenditure Database (1988–2011) ‘Military Expenditures by Country as
a share (%) of gross domestic product (GDP), 1988–2010’, available online at: www.
sipri.org/databases/milex/ (accessed 12 November 2012).
148 V. Samardžija and S. Šelo Šabić
Sopinska, J. (2009) ‘Western Balkans: Risk of instability’, Europolitics, 30 April, avail-
able online at: www.europolitics.info/dossiers/enlargement/western-balkans-risk-of-
instability-art212350–96.html (accessed 21 November, 2012).
Stojarová, V. (2007) ‘Organized Crime in the Western Balkans’, Human Security in the
Western Balkans (HUMSEC), 1, Graz, Austrai: European Training and Research
Centre for Human Rights and Democracy (ETC), pp. 91–114.
Stubbs, P. and Solioz, C. (eds) (2012) Towards Open Regionalism in South East Europe.
Baden Baden: Nomos Veralsgellgschaft.
Thorhallson, B. and Wivel, A. (2006) ‘Small States in the European Union: What Do We
Know and What Would We Like to Know?’, Cambridge Review of International
Affairs, 19(4): 651–668.
Trauner, F. (2009) ‘EU Internal Security Policies in the Western Balkans: Analysing the
Intersection Between Enlargement and Civilian Crisis Management’, paper presented
to the 11th Biennial International Conference of the European Union Studies Associ-
ation, Los Angeles, USA, available online at: http://aei.pitt.edu/33147/1/trauner._
florian.pdf (accessed 15 November, 2012).
Vrajolli, M. and Kallaba P. (2012) Kosovo’s Path towards the NATO Partnership for
Peace (PfP) Programme, Priština: Kosovar Center for Security Studies.
Wivel, A. (2005) ‘The Security Challenge of Small EU Member states: Interests, Identity
and the Development of the EU as a Security Actor, Journal of Common Market
Studies, 43(2): 393–412.
Woehrel, S. (2005) ‘Islamic Terrorism and the Balkans’, Congressional Research Service
Report for Congress, available online at: www.fas.org/sgp/crs/terror/RL33012.pdf
(accessed 15 November, 2012).
9 Georgia and Moldova
Caught in the outskirts of Europe?
Ruxandra Lupu Dinesen and Anders Wivel

Introduction
The collapse of the Soviet Union in December 1991 led to the creation of fifteen
newly independent states that needed to formulate foreign and security policies
allowing them to meet the challenges of a new international system and a trans-
formed geopolitical environment. The dominance of the Moscow-based Soviet
regime over the rest of the Soviet Union, combined with the Cold War between
the two superpowers, had effectively ‘overlaid’ other conflicts and thereby domi-
nated the security agenda for 45 years (Buzan 1991). Now, with the dissolution
of the Soviet Union, the overlay was lifted and security challenges were diffused
and diversified, with old or new ethnic, religious, ideological, and economic
divisions serving as the basis for conflict. At the global level the political and
military balance of power was transformed, leaving the world ‘off-balance’ with
the United States as the only superpower (Walt 2002).
Not surprisingly, the post-Soviet states encountered serious difficulties as
they entered a period of transition, adjustment and restructuring in all political
sectors, whilst simultaneously witnessing a dramatic drop in economic perform-
ance. Their GDP fell on average between 40 and 50 per cent during the first five
years of independence. Post-Soviet states faced the entire spectrum of the small
state security challenges identified in Chapter 2: namely challenges related to
military hard security, non-state violence, economic security, and accidents and
natural hazards (in particular related to environmental degradation). In addition,
as newly independent states, they typically lacked the official structures for
security policy assessment, decision-making and execution that are identified in
Chapter 2 as key factors for meeting these security challenges. Even 20 years
after independence, many of these states are still in the process of developing
such procedures and are facing the challenge of attracting qualified personnel for
key positions.
Security challenges, as well as the ability to meet them vary, significantly
across the post-Soviet space. Most importantly, and in accordance with the
editors’ definition of a small state in Chapter 1, security challenges vary to the
extent that post-Soviet states are the weaker party in an asymmetric relation-
ship.1 Thus, the Russian Federation typically faces a different set of challenges
150 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
from those of Moldova or Georgia, and a different choice of political, economic
and military instruments when attempting to respond to those challenges. The
absolute and relative size of territory, population and the economy, military
expenditure and political and administrative competence (Waltz 1979; Chapter 1
in this volume), as well as geopolitical location and opportunities for institu-
tional membership and influence (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005a), all affect the
nature and extent of power asymmetries and their effect on small state security.
Taking this point of departure, our analysis explores the security challenges
of two small post-Soviet states, the Republic of Moldova2 and Georgia. Located
in the outskirts of Europe, Moldova and Georgia face some of the security chal-
lenges typically encountered by states outside the highly stable and institutional-
ized European security order, while at the same time aiming explicitly to become
members of that order. The chapter explains and compares the way that each of
them has responded to these challenges, and discusses what policy lessons may
be learned.

Moldova: defensively muddling through to EU membership?


Squeezed between Romania and Ukraine, the Republic of Moldova lies at the
western extremity of the former Soviet Union. Moldova is a member of the
Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS) and borders upon NATO (since
2004) and the EU (since 2007). Devoid of energy resources, and with an eco-
nomic structure highly dependent upon exports to the EU and energy imports
from Russia, Moldova is considered to be the poorest country in Europe, with a
quarter of its citizens falling below its own poverty line.3 In 2012, the IMF
estimated Moldova’s GDP per capita was by far Europe’s lowest, at US$2,037,
compared with the Netherlands at US$46,148.4 This poverty has caused many
Moldovan citizens to leave the country in order to find work abroad – some
estimates mention over a million from a population of c.3.6 million – thereby
triggering a social and economic crisis (Pantiru et al. 2007: 9).
These figures point to the persistent importance of economic security chal-
lenges to the Moldovan state. However, in the Moldovan case, economic security
is closely related to geopolitics, and in particular to the separatist region – the
Transnistrian Moldovan Republic (TMR) – which is by far the biggest challenge
to Moldova’s security.5 Having been merged by Soviet action with the annexed
Romanian province of Bessarabia6 in 1940, this de facto state is today home to
money-laundering, smuggling and, allegedly, weapon trafficking –underpinned
by the presence of the Russian troops stationed in Transnistria (Munteanu 2002:
202). Moldova’s independence, its territorial integrity and its freedom of man-
oeuvre in international affairs, are all dependent on finding a solution to this con-
flict (Emerson and Vahl 2004: 7); but Russia uses its military presence to prevent
a solution that would let Moldova move closer to the EU and NATO (Chifu
2007: 38).
The Transnistrian conflict (and Russia’s involvement in it) are an outgrowth
from the troubled history of the Moldovan state. What today constitutes the
Georgia and Moldova 151
Republic of Moldova has changed hands, in whole or part, several times in the
past between Romania and Russia, making any internal ideological consensus
and nation-building project impossible. Great power intervention resulted in the
reconstruction of the territorial borders of Moldova and the internal composition
of the Moldovan state a number of times over the past centuries. (Yekelchyk
2008: 19). In 1812, when the historic Romanian province of Bessarabia was
annexed by Russia, Moldovans constituted 86 per cent of the population. By the
beginning of the twentieth century, the Moldovan population had been reduced
by almost 40 per cent and only made up 14 per cent of the urban population
(Roper 2008: 80–81). Later, the ethnic and social composition of Moldova was
changed by Soviet social engineering, with the purpose of assimilating the local
ethnic groups (Tudoroiu 2012: 138). Ever since, Moldova has been struggling to
define its identity, caught between Romanianization and Russification (King
2000: 185).
In sum, being a small country located between Romania and Russia has been
decisive for Moldova’s security predicament. Moldova is highly vulnerable to
military attack, having a small and easily accessible territory, and Moldova’s
military capabilities are virtually non-existent. The country is officially neutral,
and a military attack is highly improbable, but the continued presence of Russian
troops and armaments in Transnistria undermines Moldova’s sovereignty. In
addition, the Russian authorities have allowed Moldova, and especially Tran-
snistria, to become transit routes for smuggling drugs and weapons and for
human trafficking from Russia and Central Asia to Europe, thereby undermining
the internal security of the country (Löwenhardt et al. 2001: 615). Economic
security has been affected as well, since most of Moldova’s industry is located in
Transnistria. As already noted, this has left Moldova as the poorest country in
Europe, with much of its economy based on remittances from Moldovan expatri-
ates, and a high dependency on gas deliveries from Russia and the export of
agricultural products to Russia.
The geopolitical context of current Russia–NATO–EU relations is crucial for
understanding Moldova’s security struggles. By expanding eastward, NATO has
touched Russian borders through the Baltic States. The 2008 NATO Summit in
Bucharest did not reach agreement on accepting Macedonia and Albania as
members, nor Ukraine and Georgia as candidate countries. However, keeping an
open door for the alliance’s eastward expansion has retained a prominent place
on NATO’s agenda. Even if the issue is less pressing today than in the first
decade after the end of the Cold War, the 2010 Lisbon Summit reaffirmed the
‘open door’ and this remains official NATO policy today. In line with Article10
of the 1949 Washington Treaty, NATO membership is open to any state demon-
strating its ability to further the principles of that treaty, of contributing to
security in the Euro-Atlantic area, and of meeting a set of political, economic
and military criteria. While stressing what they view as the non-threatening
nature of an enlarged alliance, NATO leaders are equally eager to stress that it is
consensus within the North Atlantic Council that determines the admission of a
new member state, and that no third country will have a say in this decision
152 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
(NATO 2013). This obviously brings the Atlantic Alliance into direct conflict
with Russia’s foreign policy goal of maintaining control over its historical
spheres of influence (Sanchez 2009: 165).
Despite its important geo-strategic location between East and West, the Euro-
Atlantic community generally treated Moldova with neglect in the first years
after the country’s independence. EU and NATO clearly signalled that relations
with the former Communist Central and Eastern countries, who were first in line
for joining the two institutions, had a much higher priority. However, when the
Kosovo crisis in 1999 was followed by a worsening of NATO–Russia relations,
Western politicians began to pay more attention to Moldova. The EU, in par-
ticular, became aware of the proximity of Moldova because of its border with
Romania, an EU candidate country that was to become a member in 2007. Cre-
ating stability at the EU’s border and in the wider European region is one of the
most important goals of the EU; and Moldova has further been acknowledged as
a factor in the context of EU relations with Russia (Sasse 2010: 182).7
Although endowed, at least in this sense, with strategic importance,
Moldova is a small state, whether measured by traditional absolute or relative
power capabilities, or in terms of relational power as suggested in Chapter 1
of this volume. Being situated at the crossroads of two rival security systems,
the Euro-Atlantic, NATO-dominated area and the Russian sphere of interest,
its geopolitical vicinity is less stable than that of most European states (Marcu
2009: 410). Small states are generally far more sensitive to transformations of,
and changes in, international and regional security orders, because their power
deficit usually leaves them without much leverage to influence the transforma-
tion process or its end product (cf. Jervis 1978: 172–173). Moldova, for its
part, has shown limited ability to adjust, politically and economically, to the
new geopolitical challenges arising in the 1990s and for most of the 2000s,
mainly because of the Transnistrian conflict, which leaves it at the mercy of
the Great Powers and undermines its attempts for a more consistent foreign
and security policy.
The EU fears that the Transnistrian conflict and the instability it brings will
affect the security and stability of the EU itself. To Russia, Transnistria has a
more symbolic significance. Russia has traditionally attributed great geo-
strategic importance to the Danube-Black Sea region. After the end of the
World War II, the fourteenth Army of the Soviet Union was stationed in Tran-
snistria in order to be able to intervene in South-East Europe. Russia views
Transnistria as the key to the Balkans, and by leaving the area, it would lose its
influence on the whole region (Gabanyi 2008: 5). Further, and as noted above,
by holding Transnistria in this limbo situation, it prevents political and constitu-
tional normalization in Moldova and thereby makes Moldovan eligibility for
EU or NATO entry highly problematic (Tudoroiu 2012: 149). Consequently,
Moldova’s foreign and security policy during most of the 1990s was a balan-
cing act. Moldova wanted Russia’s support, and acknowledged its historical ties
to Russia as well as its dependence on Russia for energy and trade. At the same
time, Moldovan leaders used the West to counterbalance the threat of Russian
Georgia and Moldova 153
dominance of Moldovan politics and security (Villarroel 2005: 63–66). As
emphazised by local experts, Transnistria is the main issue that makes Moldova
important in the geopolitical considerations of both the EU and Russia (author’s
interviews with local experts).
Small states typically face the choice between a defensive and a proactive
foreign policy position: between the safeguarding of autonomy (often by taking
a neutral or non-aligned position vis-à-vis the Great Powers), or active engage-
ment in international society in order to seek protection and influence (Mour-
itzen 1997: 101–106). The Moldovan case illustrates that in practice, small states
tend to balance between offensive and defensive policy positions. They often
choose a defensive position when faced by a military threat, and a more offen-
sive position in international institutions where common rules help create a level
playing field, making traditional power capabilities (i.e. military power) less
important (Neumann and Gstöhl 2006: 20).
In terms of hard security, Chisinau has chosen a defensive position by declar-
ing the country permanently neutral, trying to avoid falling back under the
Russian sphere of influence.
As a newly established country, Moldova’s stability in the 1990s was
extremely fragile. At the time, the political elite saw permanent neutrality as the
only sensible solution for the country’s combination of geopolitical location with
an almost total lack of military forces and military experience. Neutrality was a
cheap and convenient way of defending the sovereignty and independence of the
country (Cebotari 2010: 86) without provoking any of the Great Powers –though
Russia did try to convince Moldova to become member of several security struc-
tures led by itself. In addition, neutrality is incompatible with foreign military
bases, which provided an argument for requesting the withdrawal of Russian
forces and defence equipment and technology sited in Transnistria (The Consti-
tution of the Republic of Moldova, Article 11).
Neutrality has been successful in the sense of defending the status quo at
low cost, but Russia remains active in the Transnistrian conflict and has sig-
nalled that it is unwilling to withdraw its troops. As a consequence, Moldova
has shifted towards an offensive ‘soft’ security strategy by declaring Euro-
pean integration as the goal of its foreign and security policy, as officially
stated in the National Security Strategy of Moldova, a document finalized in
2011 (National Security Strategy of Moldova 2011, own translation). The
strategy underlines the importance of the UN, OSCE and NATO for
Moldovan security and signals the nation’s commitment to participate in
missions under the EU’s Common Security and Defence Policy (CSDP). Moldova’s
national security:

may not be conceived separately from the European security. The process of
European integration and acquiring of EU membership will positively influ-
ence and consolidate the security of the Republic of Moldova and will bring
stability and prosperity to the country.
(National Security Strategy of Moldova 2011: 25)
154 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
Moldova’s pro-European position dates back to the early 1990s, but has been
emphasized only since the late 2000s. Soon after its independence, Moldova
declared that its future belonged to Europe and its successive governments have
stressed their wish to join the Union. Moldovans are the most pro-EU citizens
among the neighbourhood countries (CIVIS 2011: 122). This attitude was espe-
cially cemented after an election crisis in 2009, when the Alliance for European
Integration (AEI) came to power. Since then, the Moldovan government has
shown a far-reaching willingness to comply with all EU norms and requirements
concerning democratization, and has often initiated reforms in strategic areas
even before receiving a request from the EU to do so (Niemann and de Wekker
2010: 26–27; authors’ interview with Moldovan official).
The strategy has seemingly paid off, as the EU has acknowledged the pro-
gress of Moldovan reforms. However, the changing geopolitical landscape of
Europe has played a role as well. After Romania’s accession to the EU, the latter
recognized Moldova’s strategic role in efforts to create stability at the Union’s
borders. Illegal migration, trafficking and the presence of a frozen conflict,
together with the positive attitude towards European integration from the
Moldovan side, provided strong reasons for intensifying cooperation with this
small country. In addition, the failure of Ukraine’s democratization after the
‘Orange Revolution’ has created a demand for other success stories in EU neigh-
bourhood policy. In recent years, Moldova’s political reforms and soft security
strategy have placed the country in a favourable position to meet this demand
(Boostra 2011: 1–5); so much so, that Moldova is coming to be viewed as a
litmus test of EU influence in the region.
The relationship between the EU and Moldova changed substantially after the
launch of the European Neighbourhood Policy (ENP) in 2004, following the big
enlargement of the EU with ten new member states. An Action Plan was signed
in 2005, and the EU increased its presence in Moldova by opening a full Euro-
pean Commission Delegation and by appointing an EU Special Representative
for Moldova. The EU has increased its financial support to Moldova from €40
million in 2007 to €122 million in 2012 (Delegation of the European Union to
Moldova 2013). Also, an EU Border Mission was deployed at the Moldovan–
Ukrainian border to prevent illegal traffic. After the change in government in
2009, negotiations over an advanced Association Agreement (AA) were opened
and included talks on a Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Agreement
(DCFTA). Even more important, the EU has offered visa liberalization, which
will eventually lead to a visa-free regime, thereby easing the Moldovan feeling
of isolation after the accession of Central European countries to the EU (Boostra
2011: 2). At the moment of writing, July 2013, the negotiations on the Free
Trade Agreement have been completed and both the AA and the DCFTA are
expected to be initialled at the Vilnius Eastern Partnership Summit in November
2013 (Council of the European Union 2013). Romania has had an important role
in this development, as the most outspoken supporter of Moldova’s European
path and one of the driving forces in the European integration process (author’s
interviews with Romanian diplomats and politicians).
Georgia and Moldova 155
Approaching the EU has not ameliorated relations with Russia, which sees its
interests lying in the status quo. It has only shown willingness to accept a peace
agreement for the Transnistrian conflict under conditions that are extremely
favourable for its own geopolitical interests, i.e. that it can keep its ‘peacekeep-
ing’ troops and ammunition in Transnistria, and that the political outcome should
be ‘federalization’ (Socor 2012: 5). The importance of Transnistria was emphas-
ised by Russia in March 2012 by the appointment of a special Presidential envoy
for Transnistria, Dmitry Rogozin, thereby (among other things) signalling disap-
proval of Moldova’s continuing rapprochement with the EU (Socor 2012: 3).8

Georgia: normalizing the anti-small state?


Located in the Caucasus, south of Russia and in close proximity to the Middle
East, Georgia’s geostrategic location is notable for several reasons. According to
the Georgian government, Georgia should primarily be seen as a bridge between
East and West, or rather, as the bridge from West to East: a role that casts
Georgia as a distinctly European country having expert knowledge of how to
manage relations with the Caucasus, the Middle East and beyond. On this view
Georgia belongs with the rest of Europe inside NATO and the EU and is more
logically compared to the Baltic States than to Armenia and Azerbaijan.
To Russia, by contrast, Georgia is an important part of its own sphere of
interest. As illustrated by the 2008 Russo-Georgian war over the two Georgian
breakaway republics, Abkhazia and South Ossetia, Georgia may even represent
a test-case for Russia in how far it can go to control this sphere of interest
without facing serious repercussions from international society. Georgia further
challenges Russia’s interests politically, by its explicit ideological admiration for
the United States, liberal democracy and market economy (although not always
practised to the degree that it is preached); and economically, by providing an
energy corridor to Europe without the involvement of Russia. To the United
States, Georgia serves as a spearhead: politically, as a showcase for the possib-
ility of liberal democracy and market economy outside Europe and North
America, and militarily, by its location between Russia and the Middle East and
willingness to contribute actively to military missions in Iraq and Afghanistan.
However, Georgia is also a potential source of instability and provocation in
US–Russian relations. To the EU, Georgia is a small state in the close vicinity of
Europe, with internal security issues that may create instability beyond its own
borders, and, therefore, it is exactly the kind of state that the European Security
Strategy was intended to deal with. But Georgia also forces upon European
decision-makers a discussion about how far to the East the Union may be
expanded, and how to balance between Europe’s ideals about international
society and its interests in cordial relations with Russia.
The security and survival – even the construction – of Georgia have been
closely tied to relations with Russia throughout Georgia’s history.9 The eastern
Georgian kingdom of Kartli-Kakheti was annexed by Russia in 1801, and the
western Georgian kingdom of Imereti was annexed by Russia in 1810. More
156 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
territories were gradually annexed to Georgia during the nineteenth century,
including Abkhazia in 1864. Georgia declared its independence from Russia in
May 1918, following the Russian Revolution of 1917 but in February 1921,
Russia installed a Communist government loyal to Moscow (Nichol 2008).
Georgia, Armenia and Azerbaijan were incorporated into the Transcaucasian
Federated Soviet Socialist Republic (TcFSSR) in 1922, and Tbilisi was the
capital of Georgia (as well as the entire TcFSSR) from 1922 until the re-
emergence of Georgia, Armenia and Azerbaijan as separate Soviet republics in
1936.
The collapse of the Soviet Union resulted in the collapse of a Georgian state
that included Abkhazia and South Ossetia, two breakaway republics with de
facto independence from Georgia since 1990. This was the result of an action-
reaction process involving Georgia, Russia and the two breakaway republics,
which simultaneously strengthened nationalist discourse on all sides, both before
and after Georgia’s declaration of independence in April 1991. The Russian
army continued to be the most powerful military force in Georgia in the first few
years after independence, supplying weapons – legally and illegally – to Abkhaz
and South Ossetian separatists as well as to the Georgian army, controlling the
border with Turkey and maintaining the headquarters of the Russian Transcau-
casian Military District (ZAVKO) in Tbilisi (Gordadze 2009: pp. 33–34). Geor-
gia’s position as a Russian quasi-protectorate gradually changed from the
mid-1990s with increased cooperation with the United States. No longer on the
verge of collapse, Georgia began to strive towards de facto independence from
Russia and a break with 200 years of Russian military dominance. The United
States increasingly contributed to Georgia’s economic and military recovery and
supported the Baku-Tbilisi-Çeyhan pipeline project, which would reduce
Russian power over the region’s energy resources. In 1999, Georgia resiled from
its treaty of collective security with Russia and announced its intention to free
itself of all ‘foreign military presence’, i.e. the Russian military bases in Georgia
(Gordadze 2009: 44). In 2002, Georgia and the United States agreed on the
Georgian Train and Equipment Programme. The US training of Georgian forces
and support for the Georgian military were initially meant to reduce tensions
between Russia and Georgia; they aimed to strengthen anti-terrorist cooperation
between the United States and Russia in the aftermath of 9/11 by equipping and
training Georgian forces to control the Pankisi Gorge, where Chechen separatists
were hiding. Over time, however, US–Georgian cooperation was strengthened
by Georgian participation in the Iraq War (eventually growing to 2000 troops,
the third largest contribution to the Coalition of the Willing) and by US assist-
ance in transforming Georgian defence to make it NATO-compatible, thereby
directly challenging Russian influence in the Caucasus (Hamilton 2010:
205–206).
The diminishing level of Russian influence over Georgian society was accen-
tuated by the Rose Revolution in November 2003, which brought Mikhail Saa-
kashvili to presidential power. Although the Saakashvili government made an
initial attempt at rapprochement with Russia during its first six months in office,
Georgia and Moldova 157
major bones of contention remained: economic and political dependence on
Moscow, Russian military bases and the status of Abkhazia and South Ossetia
(Tsygankov and Tarver-Wahlquist 2009: 310). In particular, disagreement over
Abkhazia and South Ossetia led to provocations from both sides, and relations
between Georgia and Russia quickly deteriorated. In the following years, the
Saakashvili Administration made no secret of its intention to reincorporate Abk-
hazia and South Ossetia. Georgian military bases were placed in Senaki near
Abkhazia and in Gori near South Ossetia, and Georgia openly worked to
destabilize the South Ossetian and Abkhazian leaderships (Cheterian 2009:
158–159).10
The cornerstone of Georgian security policy became its close political and
military relationship with the US (Mouritzen and Wivel 2012: 97–112; Nichol
2008, 2013). Through the above-mentioned Train and Equipment Programme,
created in 2002 to ‘assist in the implementation of western standards in the Geor-
gian armed forces’ (Jones 2005: 29), which included a particular focus on train-
ing in counter-insurgency tactics (Lynch 2006: 52), the US played a vital role in
reforming Georgia’s defence capabilities. Georgian defence was significantly
upgraded between 2004 and 2008, with the procurement of battle tanks, drones,
artillery and anti-air systems. US assistance, including new equipment such as
helicopters and financial support as well as training, aimed specifically to bring
Georgian military capabilities up to par with NATO standards. In addition, the
US supported closer relations between NATO and Georgia, including an ill-fated
attempt to push for Georgian (and Ukrainian) NATO Membership Action Plans
at the Bucharest Summit in the spring of 2008. The US had more success with
its support for Georgia’s Individual Partnership Action Plan, which was endorsed
by the North Atlantic Council in 2004. Also, NATO assigned a Special Repre-
sentative to South Caucasus and Central Asia as well as a NATO Liaison Officer
to each of the two regions. This was followed up by a transit agreement allowing
NATO to transport troops and equipment through Georgian air, sea and land
space (Lynch 2006: 53). In addition, through the Sustainment and Stability
Operations Programme, the US trained two Georgian peacekeeping battalions
for service in Iraq (Jones 2005: 29; Staun 2009: 13). This close bilateral military
cooperation was further demonstrated in the latter half of July 2008, shortly
before the war with Russia, when 1,000 American troops participated in a joint
military exercise with Georgian troops labelled, ‘Immediate Response’ (Staun
2009: 10).
In August 2008, Georgian–Russian relations deteriorated further, when war
erupted between the two countries over South Ossetia and Abkhazia after a
series of provocations from both sides. The result of the war was an unequivocal
Georgian defeat, leaving Russian troops less than an hour’s drive from the Geor-
gian capital. The US had offered political support to Georgia before, during and
after the war. However, at the same time, Washington signalled its intention to
avoid any direct confrontation with Russia, and in 2009 Russia and the US re-
established cordial relations, leading to an official ‘resetting’ of their relations.
More generally, with the end of the George W. Bush Presidency and the demise
158 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
of neo-conservative influence on US foreign policy priorities, the ‘market value’
of being a spearhead of US democratization efforts outside the Euro-Atlantic
area has fallen sharply. Accordingly, Georgia has aimed to diversify its foreign
policy, relying less exclusively on US support and aiming for closer relations
with the EU and its neighbouring countries of Turkey and Azerbaijan. Georgia
remains nonetheless a supportive and close ally of Washington, and NATO entry
remains a primary objective of Georgian foreign and security policy. But the
route to membership is made difficult by the unsettled status of the two break-
away republics and the continuation of a strained relationship with Russia,
factors that continue to call Georgian security and stability in question. In addi-
tion, NATO stresses the importance of observing the rule of law and the devel-
opment of democratic institutions and administrative procedures if Georgia is to
accede (see, for example, Civil Georgia 2013a). Georgia currently seems to be
making little progress on these issues, or perhaps, even slipping backward in
performance, which may be the result of increased scrutiny as much as of polit-
ical developments in Georgia itself. Prior to the 2008 war, the US’ strong
backing for the Saakashvili government sometimes seemed to sideline the pro-
motion of Georgian democratic development in general (cf. Cooley and Mitchell
2009).
In the aftermath of the 2008 war, the United States helped Georgia to conduct
a comprehensive assessment of the latter’s armed forces. Subsequently, the US
has played a vital role in reforming Georgian defence institutions and training
programmes, with a view to improving force structure, procurement and training
and to securing future interoperability with US and NATO armed forces (Nichol
2013: 42–45). However, this renewed assistance effort no longer includes the
transfer of weapons, raising concerns among the Georgian leadership that they
have been left defenceless in the wake of a renewed Russian threat (Civil
Georgia 2010a).
In January 2012, Presidents Saakashvili and Obama agreed to enhance
defence cooperation on training and surveillance, potentially opening the door
for Georgian purchase of surveillance systems and small arms ammunitions
(Nichol 2013: 45). In October 2012, Georgia increased the number its troops
contributing to the International Security Assistance Force (ISAF ) in Afghan-
istan to 1,570, thereby making it the largest non-NATO contributor to ISAF
(Australia comes second with 1,550 troops). In contrast to most ISAF contrib-
utors (and NATO members), Georgia is willing to continue to deploy troops in
Afghanistan beyond 2014 in order to assist Afghan National Security Forces
(Nichol 2013: 6).
The EU has played a less prominent role than NATO in Georgian security,
and no member state has taken on a role of ‘sponsor’ akin to the one played by
the United States in NATO. The EU, under the French 2008 Presidency, did take
on the role of a mediator, effectively brokering a peace agreement between
Russia and Georgia, but – reflecting the outcome of the war – in effect provided
no guarantees on when and how Russian troops would leave the Georgian ter-
ritory. Still, the EU did manage to step in as a stabilizer at a time of trouble and
Georgia and Moldova 159
achieved a ‘surprising success’ by illustrating its ability to play a political role in
its geopolitical neighbourhood (Mouritzen and Wivel 2012: 139–156). More-
over, closer Georgian ties with the EU would underpin political stability and
democratic consolidation and provide Georgia with a geopolitical ‘anchor’,
which would be useful in avoiding further military conflict (Waal 2011: 41–42).
Accordingly, the Georgian leadership views closer relations with the EU, and
potentially EU membership, as complementary to its bid for NATO membership
and as providing further safeguards against Russian influence. It is expected that
an Association Agreement with the EU will be completed by the end of 2013.
Attempts at regional security cooperation in South Caucasus that could serve
as alternatives to either the Western alliance or closer cooperation with Russia
have been virtually non-existent. GUAM (the grouping of Georgia, Ukraine,
Azerbaijan, Moldova) has been viewed – in particular by Russia – as a US
backed alternative to the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), but the
organization has had little impact on either the military or economic security of
the member states. A stronger, though largely informal, alliance is taking shape
between Georgia, Turkey and Azerbaijan. Foreign Ministers of the three coun-
tries met in Trabzon, Turkey, in 2012 and in Batumi, Georgia in 2013, where
they signed a ‘sectoral cooperation action plan’. Georgian Foriegn Minister,
Maia Panjikidze stressed that ‘Georgia’s close and friendly relations with Turkey
and Azerbaijan are based on a strategic partnership’, whereas Turkish Foriegn
Minister, Ahmel Davutoglu, confirmed that Turkey was supporting the ‘Euro-
Atlantic aspirations of Georgia and Azerbaijan’ (Civil Georgia 2013b). The
agreement thus seemed to solidify the division of the region into ‘two diverging
alliances’: Turkey, Georgia and Azerbaijan cooperate with the support of the
United States, while Armenia cooperates with Russia and Iran (Gahrton 2010:
10). Energy and transport figure prominently in both informal alliances. Turkey,
a GUAM observer with Latvia, is the biggest trading partner of Georgia – a Free
Trade Agreement between the two countries entered into force on November 1,
2008 – and the two countries cooperate on energy, transport and tourism. Minor
border disputes have not prevented Azerbaijan and Georgia from cooperating on
transport and energy, and both countries aim to join NATO.
In sum, whereas Georgia in the 2008 war confuted all normal expectations of
small state security policy by engaging in direct military conflict with a neigh-
bouring great power, the active diplomatic engagement of Georgia latterly with
NATO and (to a lesser degree) the EU, Turkey and Azerbaijan – aimed at creat-
ing the necessary institutional infrastructure for both security cooperation and
trade – points to a ‘normalization’ of Georgia’s external affairs.

Comparing Moldova and Georgia: geopolitics and the limits


of small state strategy
The security strategies of both Moldova and Georgia illustrate how small states
‘are stuck with the power configuration and its institutional expression, no matter
what their specific relation to it is’ (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005b: 4). Both states
160 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
suffer from a close geopolitical proximity to Russia, and neither of the two states
can do much to change this. To Russia, both states are important for symbolic as
well as practical political reasons. Russia views Transnistria as a key to the
Balkans and, by keeping it in a limbo situation, it prevents accession of Moldova
to the EU or NATO. Russia views Georgia as a US spearhead in the Caucasus
and as an agent of Western values and unwanted political change; at the same
time, Georgia is seen as a direct challenge to Russian energy interests. Both
states occupy a geostrategic location between East and West yet both countries
have been relatively neglected by the EU and NATO, despite heavy US support
in Georgia’s case. Russian troops are located in Transnistria as well as Abkhazia
and South Ossetia. Finally, the current security challenges of both countries are
heavily affected by their history.
At the same time, Georgia and Moldova differ in terms of geopolitical loca-
tion. While both countries are located between Russia and the West, the close
proximity of Moldova to both EU and NATO member states leaves it in a differ-
ent position vis-à-vis these institutions from Georgia, located in the Caucasus
and by the Black Sea. Georgian security and survival is more peripheral to the
European great powers, because instability in the Caucasus is unlikely to have a
direct effect on European stability. Therefore, a realistic EU membership per-
spective is more likely to be given to Moldova than to Georgia. Moreover, offer-
ing Georgia a path to EU membership would most likely provoke Russia as well
as Turkey.
Georgia and Moldova have also pursued contrasting small state strategies
regarding their hard security. Moldova has chosen a defensive strategy, prim-
arily seeking to ‘hide’ from Russia, and trying to avoid provoking the great
power next door by declaring itself a neutral country. Georgia has staked high
political claims in the form of the re-integration of South Ossetia and Abkhazia,
and it has refused to give in to Russian interests. In terms of soft security, the
two countries have chosen an active strategy towards the EU; both have emphas-
ized their desire to join the EU and have made significant progress towards this
goal during the last three years.
While Georgia’s economy is in better shape than Moldova’s, and the same
can be said about its efforts to combat corruption, Moldova’s democracy –
according to Freedom House11 – has improved extensively since the change into
a pro-EU government in 2009. In terms of civil society, independent media and
national democratic governance,12 Moldova has improved its scores since 2007,
while Georgia’s scores worsen or stagnate. In Moldova’s case, this could reflect
both the government’s more determined strategy to gain an EU membership per-
spective, albeit in a distant future, and the EU’s more sustained support both
financially and politically. Consequently, Moldova’s bargaining power vis-à-vis
the EU is stronger today than Georgia’s.
Last but not least, the conflicts that the two countries are confronted with are
different in nature and importance for Russia and the EU. While the conflicts in
Abkhazia and South Ossetia are closely related to questions of sovereignty and
national autonomy on both sides of the conflict line, the Transnistria conflict
Georgia and Moldova 161
originates in the political and economic interests of the Transnistrian political
elites. After the war in Georgia in 2008, Russia was quick to recognize Abkhazia
and South Ossetia as independent states, but has not done the same regarding
Transnistria. In fact, all stakeholders in the Transnistrian conflict agree that a
solution should be found, whereby Transnistria remains a part of Moldova; and
Russia has signalled its willingness to come to an agreement on this issue by
signing the Meseberg memorandum.13 In contrast, Russia has refused to recipro-
cate President Saakashvili’s pledge in 2010 that, ‘Georgia will never use force to
roll back the Russian occupation and to restore its control over the occupied
areas’ (Civil Georgia 2010b).
For both countries, however, their security challenges since the end of the
Cold War illustrate the strategic limitations of many small states. Despite the
widened action space of small states in general since the end of the Cold War,
there are important variations within and between regions. Recent literature on
the security of small European states has pointed to the opportunities for influ-
ence if these states devise the right strategies (e.g. Arter 2000; Jakobsen 2009;
Wivel 2005). Yet, as illustrated by the recent political history of Moldova and
Georgia, these opportunities are often conditioned upon geopolitical and histor-
ical peculiarities that are not easily generalized outside the Euro-Atlantic area or
even the EU. Geopolitical location (within the Russian sphere of interest) and
historical legacy (most notably the inheritance of weak and corrupt political and
administrative institutions) have constrained these two countries’ ability to
respond to their individual challenges, and have impeded their integration into
the EU and NATO.

Conclusion
The security challenges of Moldova and Georgia are likely to continue in the
years to come. In the short- and mid-term perspective, the probability that
Moldova will remain a source of instability in the region is rather high. Even
if a formal solution is found to the conflict in Transnistria, that region’s re-
integration into Moldova proper is likely to be costly and tense, with potential
repercussions for Moldova as well as its neighbours (Cebotari and Xenofontov
2011: 32–33). In general, Moldova has little choice but to follow the advice of
the EU on political and societal reform as closer relations with the EU, and
eventually EU membership, remain the nation’s best bet for security and
stability in the future. For Georgia the challenges are even greater. Located in
the Caucasus, and viewed by Georgians themselves, as well as by Russia and
the United States, as a symbol of the spread of Western values into the heart
of the Russian sphere of interest – as well as a concrete challenge to Russian
energy interests – there is little reason to believe that Russia will allow
Georgia to enter the Euro-Atlantic institutional structures of the EU and
NATO. Even worse for the Georgians, the 2008 war illustrated that neither the
US nor the EU are willing to put their relations with Russia at risk for the sake
of Georgian security.
162 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
At the same time, both countries face two fundamental dilemmas. First, like
other small states with little short-term prospect of membership of Euro-Atlantic
institutions, Moldova and Georgia face a dilemma between subjugation and
obsolescence (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005c: 34). If they stand firm on preserving
national autonomy, they risk being viewed as obsolescent by the leading member
states of the EU and NATO. The implications were brutally clear for Georgia in
the 2008 war, when military confrontation with Russia ran counter to the inter-
ests of the United States and the European powers. Conversely, however, eager-
ness to please in order to obtain institutional membership may lead to
subjugation, risking the sacrifice of core national interests. For both Moldova
and Georgia, one vital but difficult task in the years to come will be to define the
‘red lines’ that they are not willing to cross in order to obtain membership of EU
and NATO, and to signal these red lines to the leading members of the institu-
tions without forfeiting the prospect of membership.
A second, and potentially more severe, dilemma is related to the political
identity of the state in general: Which values serve as the legitimate base for
policy making? The EU and NATO are populated with post-modern states that
accept multi-level decision-making and overlapping political authorities and
identities as a basis for policy making, resulting in collective support for a glo-
balized economy and political and military interventions. In contrast, Moldova
and Georgia share with Russia and other post-Soviet states a more traditionalist
‘modern’ view of policy making, based on centralized administrative, police and
military institutions and the persistence of national authority in economic and
security affairs.14 If these states really want sustainable solutions for their
national economic and security interests, they may, in the future, need to accept
a post-modern way of doing politics, with all the risks that this entails for states
not only smaller but also less consolidated than those who set the agenda in the
EU and NATO.

Notes
1 The editors’ definition of small states identifies a small state as ‘the weaker part in an
asymmetric relationship, unable to change the nature or functioning of the relation-
ship on its own’ (see Chapter 1 of this volume).
2 Called Moldova in the rest of the chapter.
3 World Bank estimate, see www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2013/04/10/moldova-
economic-update (accessed 10 April 2013).
4 IMF World Economic Outlook Database for 2012, available online at: www.quandl.
com/economics/gdp-per-capita-all-countries (accessed 15 November 2012).
5 There are different spellings of Transnistria, such as Transdniestria or Trans-Dniestr.
Nevertheless, Transnistria is the most commonly used name internationally, and is the
one followed here.
6 Bessarabia is the name of one of the historical provinces of Romania and corresponds
to the territory of the current Republic of Moldova, without the province of
Transnistria.
7 See also the European Internal Security Strategy, available online at: http://europa.eu/
legislation_summaries/justice_freedom_security/fight_against_organised_crime/
r00004_en.htm (accessed 15 April 2013).
Georgia and Moldova 163
8 Neither the Commonwealth of Independent States (CIS), nor GUAM (created in 1997
and short for the grouping of Georgia, Ukraine, Azerbaijan and Moldova) has had any
significant influence on Moldova’s foreign policy. The members of CIS have had
interests that were too divergent and Russia has lost interest in the CIS, partly because
of its diminishing importance for Russia’s economy. At the same time, GUAM has
been very weak, with Russia doing everything it can to prevent its members from sub-
stantive security cooperation (Papava 2008: 50) – see also p. 159.
9 For a more comprehensive account of Georgian security history up to the 2008 war,
on which this brief summary is based, see Mouritzen and Wivel (2012: 9–16).
10 As one analyst noted of the first few years after the Rose Revolution, ‘Tbilisi’s over-
arching strategy seems quite coherent in retrospect. Tbilisi’s understanding was that
the status quo prevailing since the early 1990s needed to be altered, should the con-
flicts ever approach solutions’ (Nilsson 2009: 94).
11 The democracy score for Moldova was 5 in 2008 and 4.89 in 2012; for Georgia, the score
was 4.79 in 2008 and 4.82 in 2012. The ratings are based on a scale of 1 to 7, with 1 rep-
resenting the highest level of democratic progress and 7 the lowest. See, www.freedom-
house.org/sites/default/files/2012%20%20NIT%20Tables.pdf (accessed accessed 23
August 2012); www.freedomhouse.org/report/nations-transit/2008/Moldova (accessed
accessed 23 August 2012); and www.freedomhouse.org/report/nations-transit/2008/
Georgia (accessed 23 August 2012). The Democracy Score (DS) is an average of ratings
for Electoral Process (EP); Civil Society (CS); Independent Media (IM); National Demo-
cratic Governance (NGOV); Local Democratic Governance (LGOV); Judicial Frame-
work and Independence (JFI); and Corruption (CO).
12 Moldova’s ratings in 2007 compared with 2012 were as follows: civil society (CV)
3.75 vs. 3.5; independent media (IM) 5.25 vs 5.0; national democratic governance
(NDG) 5.75 vs. 5.50. Georgia’s ratings in 2007 compared with 2012: CS 3.50 vs.
3.75; IM 4.0 vs. 4.25; NDG 5.50 vs. 5.75. See: www.freedomhouse.org/report/nations-
transit/2007/Moldova (accessed 23 August 2012); www.freedomhouse.org/report/
nations-transit/2007/Georgia (accessed 23 August 2012).
13 Memorandum signed at a meeting between Chancellor Angela Merkel and President
Dmitri Medvedev on 4 and 5 June 2010 in Meseberg, Germany. It proposed a joint
approach by the EU and Russia to resolve the conflict, including the setting up of a
joint Political and Security Committee (EU-R-PSC) at minister level. Transnistria
thereby became a test-case for future EU cooperation with Russia.
14 See Sørensen (2001) for the general distinction.

Bibliography
Arter, D. (2000) ‘Small State Influence within the EU: The Case of Finland’s Northern
Dimension Initiative’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 38(5): 677–697.
Boostra, J. (2011) ‘Moldova: An EU Success History?’, Policy Brief, 92, FRIDE.
Buzan, Barry (1991) People, States and Fear: An Agenda For International Security
Studies in the Post-Cold War Era. 2nd edition, Hertfordshire: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Buzan, B., Kelstrup, M., Lemaitre, P., Tromer, E. and Wæver, O. (1990) The European
Security Order Recast: Scenarios for the Post-Cold War Europe, London: Pinter.
Cebotari, S. (2010) ‘The Republic of Moldova between Neutrality and NATO Member-
ship Status’, Postmodern Openings, 1(3): 83–91.
Cebotari, S. and Xenofontov, I. (2011) ‘The Republic of Moldova in the Context of the
European Security System’, Postmodern Openings, 2(6): 23–35.
Cheterian, V.(2009) ‘The August 2008 War in Georgia: From Ethnic Conflict to Border
Wars’, Central Asian Survey, 28(2): 155–170.
164 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
Chifu, I. (2007) ‘Moldova between East and West’, in Quo Vadis Moldova?, European
Integration Study Centre (Lithuania) and Institute for Development and Social Initi-
atives ‘Viitorul’ (Moldova), Lviv: Multi-M., pp. 35–40.
Cooley, A. and Mitchell, L. (2009) ‘No Way to Treat Our Friends: Recasting Recent
U.S.–Georgian Relations’, Washington Quarterly, 32(1): 27–41.
Civil Georgia (2010a) ‘Saakashvili Wants U.S. to Help with Defensive Arms’, September
12, available online at: www.civil.ge/eng/article.php?id=22662 (accessed 19 July
2013).
Civil Georgia (2010b) ‘Georgia Makes “Unilateral Pledge” of Non-Use of Force’,
November 23, available online at: www.civil.ge/eng/article.php?id=22880 (accessed
19 July 2013).
Civil Georgia (2013a) ‘Rasmussen on Georgia’s NATO Integration’, 27 June 2013, avail-
able online at: www.civil.ge/eng/article.php?id=26217 (accessed 19 July 2013).
Civil Georgia (2013b) ‘Azerbaijani, Georgian, Turkish FMs Pledge Closer Ties’, 28
March, available online at: www.civil.ge/eng/article.php?id=25903 (accessed 19 July
2013).
CIVIS (The Centre of Sociological, Politological and Psychological Analysis and Investiga-
tions) (2011) Public Opinion Barometer of the Republic of Moldova 2011, available
online at: http://civis.md/Archive/Brosura_BOP_05.2011_prima%20parte.pdf (accessed
19 July 2013).
Constitution of the Republic of Moldova (no date) Available online at: www.presedinte.
md/const.php?lang=eng (accessed 12 December 2012).
Council of the European Union (2013) ‘EU – Republic of Moldova Cooperation Council
Fifteenth Meeting’, Luxembourg 25 June 2013, 11472/13 (Presse 290), available online
at: www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_data/docs/pressdata/en/er/137612.pdf (accessed
9 July 2013).
Delegation of the European Union to Moldova (2013) ‘EU-Moldova Relations: basic
facts’, available online at: http://eeas.europa.eu/delegations/moldova/eu_moldova/
index_en.htm, accessed 9 July 2013.
Emerson, M. and Vahl, M. (2004) ‘Moldova and the Transnistrian Conflict’, in Coppie-
ters, B., Europeanization and Conflict Resolution: Case Studies from the European
Periphery, Ghent: Academia Press, pp. 1–29.
Gabanyi, A.U. (2008) ‘The Republic of Moldova and NATO – an Ambiguous Relation-
ship’, in Security Policy Library 3, Oslo: Den Norske Atlanterhavskomité.
Gahrton, P. (2010) Georgia: Pawn in the New Great Game, London: Pluto Press.
Gordadze, T. (2009) ‘Georgian-Russian Relations in the 1990s’, in Cornell, S.E. and
Starr, F.S. (eds), The Guns of August 2008: Russia’s War in Georgia, New York: M.E.
Sharpe, pp. 28–48.
Hamilton, R. (2010) ‘The Bear came through the Tunnel: An Analysis of Georgian Plan-
ning and Operations in the Russo-Georgian War and Implications for U.S. Policy’, in
Rich, P.B. (ed.), Crisis in the Caucasus: Russia, Georgia and the West, Abingdon:
Routledge, pp. 202–234.
Jervis, R. (1978) ‘Cooperation under the Security Dilemma’, World Politics 30: 167–214.
Jakobsen, P.V. (2009) ‘Small States, Big Influence: The Overlooked Nordic Influence on
the Civilian ESDP’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 47(1): 81–102.
Jones, J.L. (2005) ‘Statement of General James L. Jones, USMC Commander, United
States European Command before the Senate Armed Service Committee in March 1,
2005’, available online at: http://armed-services.senate.gov/statemnt/2005/March/
Jones%2003–01–05.pdf (accessed 9 December 2012).
Georgia and Moldova 165
King, C. (2000) The Moldovans. Romania, Russia, and the Politics of Culture, Stanford
University: Hoover Institution Press.
Löwenhardt, J., Hill, R. and Light, M. (2001) ‘A Wider Europe: The View from Minsk
and Chisinau’, International Affairs, 77(3): 605–620.
Lynch, D. (2006) Why Georgia Matters, Chaillot paper 86, Paris: Institute for Security
Studies.
Marcu, S. (2009) ‘The Geopolitics of the Eastern Border of the European Union: The
Case of Romania–Moldova–Ukraine’, Geopolitics, 14(3): 409–432.
Mouritzen, H. (1997) External Danger and Democracy: Old Nordic Lessons and New
European Challenges, Aldershot, UK: Dartmouth Publishing Company.
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (eds) (2005a), The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration,
London: Routledge.
Mouritzen, H, and Wivel, A. (2005b) ‘Introduction’, in Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (eds)
The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration, London: Routledge.
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (2005c) ‘Constellation Theory’, in Mouritzen, H. and Wivel,
A. (eds) The Geopolitics of Euro-Atlantic Integration, London: Routledge.
Mouritzen, H. and Wivel, A. (2012) Explaining Foreign Policy: International Diplomacy
and the Russo-Georgian War, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Munteanu, I. (2002) ‘Social Multipolarity and Political Violence’, in Kolstø, P. (ed.)
National Integration and violent Conflict in Post-Soviet Societies. The Cases of Estonia
and Moldova, Lanham, Oxford: Rowman & Littlefield, pp. 197–227.
North Atlantic Treaty Organization (2013) ‘NATO Enlargement’, available online at:
www.nato.int/cps/en/natolive/topics_49212.htm (accessed 7 June 2013).
Neumann, I.B. and Gstöhl, S. (2006) ‘Introduction: Lilliputians in Gulliver’s World?’, in
Ingebritsen, C., Neumann, I.B. and Gstöhl, S. (eds) Small States in International Rela-
tions, Seattle: University of Washington Press, pp. 3–36.
Nichol, J. (2008) ‘Russia–Georgia Conflict in South Ossetia: Context and Implications
for U.S. Interests’, 24 October, Washington, DC: Congressional Research Service.
Nichol, J. (2013) ‘Armenia, Azerbaijan, and Georgia: Political Developments and
Implications for U.S. Interests’, report for Congress, Washington, DC: Congressional
Research Service, 24 January.
Niemann, A. and de Wekker. T. (2010) ‘Normative Power Europe? EU Relations with
Moldova’, European Integration online papers (EIoP), 14(14), available online at: http://
eiop.or.at/eiop/index.php/eiop/article/view/2010_014a/189 (accessed 3 April 2011).
Nilsson, N. (2009) ‘Georgia’s Rose Revolution: The Break with the Past’, in Cornell, S.E.
and Starr, F.S. (eds) The Guns of August 2008: Russia’s War in Georgia, Armonk,
New York: M. E. Sharpe, pp. 85–103.
Pantiru, M., Black. R. and Sabates Wheeler, R. (2007) ‘Migration and Poverty Reduction
in Moldova’, working paper C10, Development Research Centre on Migration, Glo-
balisation and Poverty, Falmer: University of Sussex.
Papava, V. (2008) ‘On the Role of the “Caucasian Tandem” in GUAM’, Central Asia and
the Caucasus, 3–4(51–52): 47–55.
Pintea, I., Helly, D. and Pananainte, P. (2011) Prospects for Moldova’s Cooperation within
the Common Security and Defence Policy, Soros Foundation Moldova, Chisinau.
Roper, S. (2008) ‘Post-Soviet Moldova’s National Identity and Foreign Policy’, in
Schmidtke, O. and Yekelchyk, S. (eds) Europe’s Last Frontier? Belarus, Moldova, and
Ukraine between Russia and the European Union, New York: Palgrave Macmillan,
pp. 79–97.
166 R. Lupu Dinesen and A. Wivel
Sanchez, A. (2009) ‘The “Frozen” Southeast: How the Moldova–Transnistria Question
has Become a European Geo-Security Issue’, Journal of Slavic Military Studies, 22(2):
153–176.
Sasse, G. (2010) ‘The ENP and the EU’s Eastern Neighbours: Ukraine and Moldova as
Test Cases’, in Whitman R. and Wolff, S. (eds) The European Neighbourhood Policy
in Perspective, Basingstoke and New York: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 181–205.
Socor, V. (2012) ‘Russia Multiplies Conditions for Conflict-Resolution in Moldova’,
Eurasia Daily Monitor, 9(145).
Sørensen, G. (2001) Changes in Statehood, Houndmills: Palgrave.
Staun, J. (2009) ‘Den georgiske beslutningsproces’, in Mouritzen, H., Møller, K.J. and
Staun, J. (eds) ‘Krigen i Kaukasus 2008: Baggrund, dynamik og international per-
spektiver’, DIIS working paper: 7–17.
Tsygankov, A.P. and Tarver-Wahlquist, M. (2009) ‘Duelling Honors: Realism, Construc-
tivism and the Russia-Georgia Divide’, Foreign Policy Analysis, 5(4): 307–326.
Tudoroiu, T. (2012) ‘The European Union, Russia, and the Future of the Transnistrian
Conflict’, East European Politics and Societies, 26(1): 135–161.
Vahl, M. and Emerson, M. (2004) ‘Moldova and the Transnistrian Conflict’, in Coppie-
ters, B. (ed.) Europeanization and Conflict Resolution. Case studies from the European
Periphery. Ghent: Academia Press, pp. 1–29.
Villarroel, E. (2005) Moldova: The Quest for Balance, Jagiellonian University in Krakow:
Centre for European Studies.
Waal, T. de (2011) Georgia’s Choices: Charting a Future in Uncertain Times, Washing-
ton, DC: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.
Walt, S. M. (2002) ‘Keeping the World “Off-Balance”: Self-Restraint and U.S. Foreign
Policy’, in Ikenberry, G.J. (ed.) America Unrivalled, Ithaca and London: Cornelle Uni-
versity Press, pp. 121–154.
Waltz, K.N. (1979) Theory of International Politics New York: McGraw-Hill.
Wivel, A. (2005) ‘The Security Challenge of Small EU Member States: Interests, Identity
and the Development of the EU as a Security Actor’, Journal of Common Market
Studies, 43(2): 393–412.
Yekelchyk, S. (2008) ‘Out of Russia’s Long Shadow: The Making of Modern Ukraine,
Belarus, and Moldova’, in Schmidtke, O. and Yekelchyk, S., Europe’s Last Frontier?
Belarus, Moldova, and Ukraine between Russia and the European Union, New York:
Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 10–28.
10 The security of the European
micro-states
Archie W. Simpson

It is apparent that the token of success of the European micro-states has so far
been their ability to neutralise the limitations stemming from their distinctive
geographic, social and economic attributes, and to turn these potentially negative
characteristics to their advantage in the international playing field.
(Dózsa 2008: 95)

Introduction
The study of the European micro-states is unfamiliar to many scholars and stu-
dents of international relations because the former are very small, have very little
power, offer no significant threat to others and are often viewed as being some-
what anachronistic. The micro-states are usually seen as being insignificant
members of the international community because of their diminutive size and
are often overlooked as objects of serious study. However, upon a closer look
they are quite fascinating and offer new insights into international politics. To
illustrate this takes a few interesting facts: San Marino is the oldest Republic in
the world with a history stretching back to 301 AD; the tiny Pyrenean state of
Andorra has two heads of state, namely the President of France and the Bishop
of Urgell; Monaco has the world’s highest population density due to its urban
setting; and the smallest state in the world is the Vatican City State, which coin-
cidently, is also host to the world’s biggest institution, the Roman Catholic
Church, with between 1.3 and two billion followers. There is much to be gleaned
by exploring the European micro-states and this chapter will highlight some of
the security issues associated with these very small polities.
Using a simple population threshold of one million people allows 44 sover-
eign micro-states1 to be identified in the international community and ten of
these are in Europe. They are Andorra, Cyprus, Iceland, Liechtenstein, Luxem-
bourg, Malta, Monaco, Montenegro, San Marino and the Vatican City State
(sometimes also referred to as the Holy See). Each has a distinct security
dilemma, unique history and engagement with international politics. As dis-
cussed in Chapter 1, using absolute criteria in defining states by their size is
highly problematic and can be contested; there is no consensus concerning what
constitutes a ‘small state’ or indeed a ‘micro-state’. The European micro-states
have very little power in the international system, have very narrow policy
168 A.W. Simpson
options, fewer interests, have little say in international politics and are con-
sequently vulnerable to outside pressures. Additionally, the micro-states are
always the weaker party in any asymmetric relationship with other states – with
the possible exception of the Vatican, depending on the issue at hand. Nairn
(1997) suggests that the small ‘scale’ of the micro-states undermines their capa-
city to act in international politics.
The European micro-states are a disparate collection of states, as some are
islands, some are landlocked, some are former colonies, some have existed for
centuries, many are democracies, while some are not true democracies. For all,
however, their smallness in size permeates into all aspects of politics, both
domestically and in terms of foreign policy and economic policy. The smallness
of the micro-states limits them in terms of capabilities, restricts policy options,
reduces diplomatic representation, increases their vulnerabilities especially eco-
nomically, and places particular pressures on their national security.
This chapter will first address definitional issues, including some problems
and criteria used in defining micro-states. It will then give brief descriptions of
the European micro-states, in order to establish who they are. The main common
characteristics and key features of micro-states will be identified, including the
varying levels of democracy. The chapter will then run through some relevant
issues relating to micro-state security, including military issues, other security
topics and economic strategies.

Definitions
As stressed in Chapter 1, and as Maass writes, ‘no consensus-definition of the
small state has yet emerged, despite an abundance of characterizations, ration-
ales and proposed definitions’ (2009: 65). Aside from the many quantitative,
qualitative and subjective features proposed by various authors, defining small
states or micro-states inherently involves a relative dynamic: State A is small
when compared to State B, as discussed in Chapter 1. This means that ‘ulti-
mately a judgmental element must creep into the exercise of categorising states
by size’ (Archer and Nugent, 2002: 5). Moreover, the question of definition is
sometimes complicated by the language used. A number of terms including
‘small states’, ‘small nations’, ‘weak states’, ‘small powers’, ‘minor powers’ and
‘small countries’ are commonly found in literature and may be used interchange-
ably by scholars and decision-makers. Yet, these terms may have different con-
notations and clarity is important, not least when distinguishing small states from
micro-states. Correctly expressed, micro-states are a sub-field of small state
studies; they are, in simple terms, very small states.
Whilst there is no agreed consensus as to what constitutes a ‘small state’,
there is a greater amount of agreement among scholars regarding the definition
of ‘micro-states’. The Scandinavian political scientist, Dag Anckar (1998,
2002, and 2004) argues that the usual criterion for defining micro-states is a
population of less than one million people. Others who have used this yard-
stick include Harden (1985), Sutton and Payne (1993), Warrington (1994),
The security of the European micro-states 169
Christopher (2002) and Simpson (2008). There are, however, other competing
definitions including that of Ali Naseer Mohamed (2002), who suggests that
1.5 million people is the threshold; Plischke (1977), who suggests that micro-
states have populations of under 100,000 or between 100,000 and 300,000;
and Armstrong and Read (1995; 2003; also Armstrong et al., 1998), who
define micro-states as having populations of three million or less. Plischke
(1977) suggested that membership of the United Nations (UN) was also
important in the definition of micro-states. When he wrote this, a number of
European micro-states, specifically Andorra, San Marino and Monaco, were
excluded from his list as they were not UN member states; but since the end
of the Cold War all three have joined the UN. Wivel and Oest argue that
micro-states are, ‘permanently stuck as the weak party in asymmetric relation-
ships internationally and therefore forced to adopt strategies that cope with the
permanency of their weakness’ (Wivel and Oest 2010: 434).
For the purpose of this chapter, three criteria will be used to define micro-
states. The first is that they are sovereign: namely, they fulfil the criteria of legal
statehood as established by the 1933 Montevideo Convention on the Rights and
Duties of States. Article 1 of the Convention sets down four criteria:

The state as a person of international law should possess the following qual-
ifications: a) a permanent population; b) a defined territory; c) government;
and d) capacity to enter into relations with the other states.
(1933 Montevideo Convention of the Rights and Duties of States, Article 1)

There are a myriad of non-sovereign polities (or non-self-governing territories as


the United Nations describes them) around the globe and in Europe, including
Gibraltar, disputed territories such as Northern Cyprus or Transnistria, Mount
Athos in Greece, and dependencies such as the Isle of Man or the Channel
Islands. These territories are small but are not recognized widely as being sover-
eign states.
The second criterion follows from statehood: being a member of the United
Nations. With South Sudan joining the UN in 2011, there are now 193 member
states (United Nations 2012a). Membership of the UN codifies and reinforces
the status of statehood and is also important in terms of being recognized by the
international community. The Vatican City is the smallest sovereign state in the
world, both in terms of population and territorial size, and it has ‘observer
status’2 at the UN. Whilst this is not full membership per se, it does – for all
practical purposes – denote membership, and allows the Vatican City to be
included as a European micro-state throughout this chapter.
The third criterion relates to population. A micro-state is here defined as
having a population of one million people or less, following the practice of
Anckar (1998, 2002 and 2004), Warrington (1994) and Christopher (2002),
among others. As noted, this relatively simple and arbitrary threshold produces
44 micro-states around the world in 2013, including the likes of the Bahamas,
Cape Verde, Fiji, the Maldives and Swaziland,3 and ten micro-states in Europe.
170 A.W. Simpson
Who are the micro-states of Europe?
The ten European micro-states currently include two islands in the Mediter-
ranean (Cyprus and Malta); two mountainous states (Andorra and Liechtenstein);
one island state in the North Atlantic (Iceland); a founding member of the Euro-
pean Union (Luxembourg); one theocracy (Vatican City); one state in the
Balkans (Montenegro); the world’s oldest republic (San Marino); and one glam-
orous Principality (Monaco) famed for its casinos. Eccardt writes, ‘few people
know much about microstates, though millions visit them each year’ (Eccardt,
2005: 1). Each micro-state has its own singular feature(s) that help attract
tourism and distinguish them beside their larger neighbours.
Andorra lies in the Pyrenean Mountains between France and Spain and is a
well-known destination for skiers, though it also has a small tobacco-growing
industry. This tiny state has also become a tax haven in order to attract rich resi-
dents and tourists; it has been estimated that ten million people visit each year,
partly for the duty-free goods available (BBC 2012). Nairn calls Andorra ‘a glo-
rified duty-free emporium at the bottom of a ski-slope’ (Nairn 1997: 137). This
democratic co-Principality has a parliament of 28 members, who are elected
every four years. Given its small population of around 85,000 and geographic
location, Andorra has chosen to establish economic ties to the European Union
(EU), including use of the euro currency, though it is not a member state. During
both the Spanish civil war and World War II, Andorra declared neutrality as a
means of guaranteeing its own security. However, both France and Spain also
have treaty obligations (Bartmann, 2002: 369–370) to support Andorran sover-
eignty and security.
Cyprus is an island state and former British colony in the Eastern Mediterra-
nean, with a population almost reaching one million. In 1974, fearing a coup
orchestrated in Athens, Turkey invaded and the island has been divided ever
since. Northern Cyprus declared independence in 1983, but this was only recog-
nized by Turkey. Since the invasion, UN peacekeepers have patrolled the dis-
puted border and kept the peace. In 2004, Cyprus joined the EU and it was
thought that this could provide a platform for unification; but following referen-
dums in Cyprus and in the North, this has yet to happen. The Cyprus economy is
largely based on agriculture, tourism, some industry (quarrying) and some
service industries, including online gambling.
Iceland is known as the land of fire and ice and was the second micro-state to
join the UN in 1946. It lies in the North Atlantic and is on the boundary between
the North American and Eurasian tectonic plates, which means earthquakes are
common occurrences and the landscape is full of volcanoes. The Icelandic Par-
liament, or Alþingi (All-thing), has 63 members and dates back to AD 930,
making it one of the oldest parliaments in Europe. In the late 1940s, Iceland
joined the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO) and adopted an Atlanti-
cist outlook. Iceland is famed for its fishing, which accounted for much of its
economic development and growth, though in the past two decades it has diver-
sified into aluminium production, tourism, banking and green energy. With the
The security of the European micro-states 171
financial collapse of 2008, Iceland was essentially made bankrupt due to the
over-stretching of its banking sector. Since 2008, Iceland has seen the rise of
new political parties, proposals for a new constitution have been drawn up and it
has applied for EU membership.
The landlocked Principality of Liechtenstein is located in the mountain
slopes of the Rhine Valley, between Switzerland and Austria. Its small size of
160 km2 or 61.8 miles2, and small population of around 35,000 people, encour-
aged it to become a tax haven in the post-war years, though there is some
farming and some industry (dental products). The micro-state is officially
neutral and uses Swiss francs as currency. Liechtenstein joined the UN in
1990. In recent times its banking sector has been criticized by the OECD for a
lack of transparency; there are around 10–15 banks located in the Principality
and many wealthy people from around the world have accounts based there.
There are estimates that around 5,000 British citizens hold accounts worth bil-
lions of pounds in Liechtenstein bank accounts (www.guardian.co.uk/busi-
ness/2009/aug/11/tax-havens-liechtenstein, accessed 25 November 2013).
High levels of bank secrecy, coupled with low tax levels, have led to allega-
tions of money-laundering by terrorists, criminals and those avoiding taxation,
which are embarrassing for the Principality, especially as many of the banks
are owned by the Royal family.
The Grand Duchy of Luxembourg is located in the heart of Western Europe
and borders upon Belgium, France and Germany. With iron ore deposits found
in the 1840s, Luxembourg quickly became a major steel producer throughout the
Industrial Revolution, which created great wealth and prosperity. By 1913 the
Grand Duchy was the sixth largest producer of pig iron and the world’s fourth
largest steel exporter (Strikwerda 1993: 1114–1115). Luxembourg is a founding
member of many international organizations, including the UN, EU, NATO,
WTO, IMF and World Bank. Some key institutions of the EU are located in
Luxembourg, including the European Court of Justice, the Court of Auditors and
the EU’s Official Publications office (Hey 2003: 78). Like other micro-states in
Europe, Luxembourg has a thriving banking sector and low-tax economy that
attracts investments from around Europe. With its location, industrial history,
banking industry and its hosting of EU institutions, Luxembourg is an exception-
ally wealthy micro-state.
The island of Malta, like Cyprus, was a British colony and gained its inde-
pendence in 1964. Malta has a long history going back to ancient times and has
been occupied by the Phoenicians, Greeks, Romans, the Knights of St John and
the British. Turnout in Maltese elections is usually very high and there is a
strong two-party system in operation, involving the Labour Party and the Nation-
alist Party. Malta relies largely on tourism but also has a shipbuilding industry,
and its location in the Eastern Mediterranean made it ideal as a trading nation.
Malta joined the EU in 2004 and the Eurozone in 2008. Since joining the EU,
there has been an influx of immigration, largely from North Africa, which has
created some local problems. During the NATO intervention in Libya in
2011–2012, many Libyans sought refuge in Malta.
172 A.W. Simpson
The Principality of Monaco is located on the French Riviera and is often por-
trayed as a playground for the rich and wealthy. Monaco is famed for its casinos,
its annual Formula One race, banking secrecy, and for the ruling Grimaldi
family. Monaco relies a great deal on the French for the collection of certain
taxes (VAT or indirect sales tax), defence (Monaco has no army), provision of
civil servants and judges and utilities such as water and rail networks. However,
it has its own small National Council of 24 members, which can be dismissed by
the Prince of Monaco; is a UN member; and uses the euro currency. It has a con-
stitutional monarchy and the current Prince is Albert II. In the early 2000s, the
French Parliament was highly critical of Monaco for its banking practices (see
p. 179) and a long-standing bilateral treaty was consequently re-written. Under
the provisions of the old treaty, Monaco would become French if there were no
male heir; but under the new terms, the Monaco Royal family can now adopt a
successor to maintain its sovereign independence. Of the 30,000 residents, only
about 6,000 are Monacan citizens; the rest are wealthy residents.
Montenegro was part of the Former Republic of Yugoslavia (FRY), but is
now Europe’s newest micro-state. It joined Yugoslavia under the Treaty of Ver-
sailles in 1919 and became independent in 2006 by way of a referendum. Monte-
negro lies on the Adriatic, has borders with Bosnia and Herzegovina, Serbia and
Kosovo, and has long-term aspirations to join the EU and NATO. Around one-
third of the population are ethnic Serbs out of a population of around 632,000
and there are some underlying political tensions relating to national identity and
the violent fragmentation of FRY in the 1990s. Montenegro has a unicameral
parliament of 81 members, is a member of the UN and has a multi-party system.
It is trying to encourage tourism and investment by presenting itself as ‘the pearl
of the Mediterranean’ (www.visit-montenegro.com/, accessed 25 November
2013), but a key export is aluminium.
San Marino is located in the northeast of Italy, was established in AD 301 and
has a singular political system. San Marino does not have a written constitution
and formally became democratic in 1906 (Sundhaussen 2003: 214), when elec-
tions were first held. At arringo meetings held twice a year, the two Captains
Regent are appointed. These are the Heads of State/Head of Government and
hold power alongside the Grand and General Council, a 60-member parliament.
Kohr writes, ‘they choose two consuls every six months with the result that prac-
tically every citizen functions at some time during his life as his country’s chief
of state’ (2001: 113). Bartmann writes, ‘San Marino is responsible for its own
security. A steadfast commitment to a policy of neutrality was maintained
throughout the Second World War’ (2002: 369). Today the micro-state has no
formal military capabilities, but as it is totally surrounded by Italy, it might be
argued that both Italy and, by extension, NATO help to defend it.
The Vatican City State was formally established in 1929 by the Lateran
Treaty with Italy, though clearly its history dates back many centuries. Eccardt
writes, ‘[the] Vatican city may be the most unusual country in the world’
(Eccardt 2005: 299). The Vatican occupies an area of 0.442 km or 44 hectares
(roughly 100 acres) and has a population of less than a thousand citizens.
The security of the European micro-states 173
However, there are about 4,000 people who live in Rome and work in the
Vatican, which exempts them from Italian income tax. The Pope is Head of State
and Head of Government and is leader of about 1.3 to two billion Roman Cath-
olics globally, thus wielding enormous [soft] power and respect in world affairs.
The Pope is elected for life4 by a conclave, which is essentially all the Cardinals
of the Catholic Church under the age of 80; this is the only form of democracy in
the Vatican. As the Vatican (or Holy See) is host to the Roman Catholic religion,
it adopts a neutral position in international politics with which full UN member-
ship is seen as incompatible;5 thus its UN status is that of an ‘observer’ (United
Nations 2012c). While not an EU member state, the Vatican uses the euro as its
official currency.

Characteristics of micro-states
The micro-states of Europe are very small, both in terms of territory and in terms
of population. They thus have few natural resources (except in a few cases),
smaller working populations, smaller domestic markets, small governments and
small bureaucracies. Smallness permeates into all aspects of public life and pol-
itics. For example, unicameral parliaments are the norm for the European micro-
states, with Andorra having 28 parliamentary representatives and Montenegro
having 81 (see table 10.1). Governments are often also small, with Liechtenstein
having a government of five members (plus the Prince) and Iceland ten members
(plus the President).
The political and economic elites of the micro-states know each other well, as
there are so few of them. In the Principalities of Liechtenstein and Monaco, this
is particularly true. The Royal family in Liechtenstein owns many of the banks

Table 10.1 Size of micro-state parliaments in Europe

Parliament (members) Type of government

Andorra 28 Co-Principality/democratic
Cyprus 56 Republic/democratic
Iceland 63 Republic/democratic
Liechtenstein 25 Principality/semi-democratic
Luxembourg 60 Grand Duchy/democratic
Malta 65 Republic/democratic
Monaco 24 Principality/democratic
Montenegro 81 Republic/democratic
San Marino 60 Republic/democratic
Vatican City – Theocracy/non-democratic

Sources: Various, including BBC, CIA World Factbook, and national websites (all accessed in
2012).
Notes
Andorra has two heads of state; Liechtenstein underwent constitutional changes in 2002 giving the
Prince wider powers to dismiss parliament and government; in Montenegro an MP shall be elected
for every 6,000 voters; and the only voting in the Vatican is via a conclave to elect a new Pope.
174 A.W. Simpson
that provide the Principality’s main source of wealth and prosperity; and the
Prince of Monaco owns much of Monaco. A small, ruling elite usually means
improved communications, fewer political barriers and less bureaucratic wran-
gling. However, it may also lead towards incestuous and dysfunctional politics,
as perhaps illustrated by the banking collapse in Iceland in 2008, in which
bankers and politicians were too closely aligned. For Dag Anckar (2003), the
smallness of the micro-states also contributes to a tendency towards democracy.
However, it could also be said that many of the micro-states in Europe have
anachronistic political institutions, such as San Marino with its selection of its
two Captains Regent every six months; the dominance of the Prince in Liechten-
stein politics; and the unique position – and indeed election – of the Pope in the
Vatican City.
The smallness of micro-states usually means greater homogeneity in terms of
national identity and ethnicity. While citizenship in the Vatican is uniquely
based on profession rather than national identity and some micro-states such as
Andorra and Monaco have more non-citizens than citizens in residence, national
identity in the micro-states is important both in terms of societal security and in
affirming democracy. The only problematic micro-state in this regard is Cyprus.
Since the 1970s, the island has been divided, with Turkish Cypriots in the north-
ern third of the island and Greek Cypriots in the rest. The Cyprus problem is a
long-standing issue in European politics, and has not been solved by the Repub-
lic of Cyprus’ EU membership, for which the UN has sought various solutions
over decades, including the Annan Plan (UN 2004). As Sepos writes, this plan:

. . . foresaw the evolution of the Cyprus Republic into the United Republic of
Cyprus, with a different name, flag, and national anthem. Borrowing heavily
from the Swiss and Belgian federal models, it proposed the construction of
a common state with a single sovereignty, consisting of Greek-Cypriot and
Turkish-Cypriot component states, with their own legislative and executive
powers.
(Sepos 2008: 30)

While there has been a greater political dialogue between Cyprus and northern
Cyprus since the start of the millennium, the prospect of unifying the island
remains problematic.
The European micro-states have very little power globally or even within
Europe, with the Vatican City providing a certain exception to the rule. They do
occasionally become the subject of international debate and concern,6 as in
Cyprus’ case, but for the most part the micro-states remain largely insignificant
actors. Sometimes, they make material contributions to international develop-
ments such as Luxembourg’s role in shaping the EU from its foundation
onwards. As another example, in the late 1960s, the Maltese UN Ambassador,
Arvid Pardo, played a crucial role in introducing concepts and policies desig-
nating the seas and seabed as part of the ‘common heritage of mankind’, which
were incorporated into international law by 1982. Thus while limited in terms
The security of the European micro-states 175
of power and influence, as sovereign actors the micro-states have some ability
to affect international relations, often through membership of international
organizations.
Many of the European micro-states are wealthy, but they also rely on neigh-
bouring states for various forms of economic sustenance, such as imports of
foods and fuels and utilities like water and electricity. Thorhallsson (2011; see
also Alesina and Spolaore 2005) argues that small states need political and eco-
nomic ‘shelter’ from larger states and/or institutions in order to survive in the
globalized world, and this may be particularly true for micro-states.
Since the financial crash of 2008, some micro-states have suffered serious
economic worries highlighting their vulnerability when combined with risky
policy choices – most notably, Cyprus and Iceland. Some others, such as
Andorra, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg and Monaco, have become tax havens or
offshore financial centres to encourage both investments and wealthy residents.
These micro-states have many banks and financial services that attract billions of
dollars worth of investments (on which more below). The Vatican has enormous
wealth, much of it coming from donations by people across the world, but also
from property and banking. As the Vatican does not publish economic data,
there is much speculation about its wealth. One British newspaper, the Daily
Telegraph, reports that the Vatican has property investments worth up to €700
billion (Daily Telegraph 2011) and in addition, it has priceless artefacts and
works of art.
Luxembourg as a capital city of the EU in the heart of Western Europe, has
gained a high level of economic stability and wealth. As seen in Table 10.2, it is
noticeable that only Iceland maintains its own national currency, and debates
there since 2008 on EU membership have largely focused on whether to join the

Table 10.2 Selected economic data of the European micro-states

Unit of GDP per capita (ppp) Exports estimates, US$/£


currency US$/£ 2011 estimates (year)

Andorra Euro $37,200 $70 million (2011)


Cyprus Euro $26,290 $7.716 billion (2012)
Iceland Krona $38,700 $5.1 billion (2012)
Liechtenstein Swiss Francs $89,000 (2012 data) £3.325 billion (2010)
Luxembourg Euro $81,900 $15.5 billion (2012)
Malta Euro $26,000 $3.67 billion (2012)
Monaco Euro $63,000 (2009 data) $711 million (2010)
Montenegro Euro $11,700 $640 million (2011)
San Marino Euro £36,200 (2009 data) $2.576 billion (2010)
Vatican City Euro – –

Source: CIA World Factbook (www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/wfbExt/region_


eur.html, accessed 15 October 2012).
Notes
GDP Per capita (ppp) indicates total GDP on a purchasing power parity basis, divided by population
as oft 1 July for the given year.
176 A.W. Simpson
euro or not. During the twentieth century, Iceland benefited from fish, clean
energy and (at least before 2008) very low levels of unemployment. The micro-
states also rely heavily upon tourism to generate income. Each with its own
unique landscape, traditions and history, they are able to sell themselves as
idyllic locations for vacations. Andorra has skiing and attracts around ten million
visitors each year, many taking advantage of duty-free products, and many on
day trips from neighbouring Spain. Monaco presents itself as a glamorous locale
with casinos; Cyprus and Malta compete for tourists seeking Mediterranean sun-
shine; Iceland has epic scenery, many outdoor pursuits and volcanoes; and if you
have $70,000 you can hire Liechtenstein for a night (Sinmaz 2011). Thus the
different micro-states have adopted different economic strategies for survival,
while striving – within the constraints of smallness – to diversify the economic
base as much as possible. The evolution of the internet and online enterprises
has helped, with online casinos and banks being based in many of the micro-
states including Malta, Iceland, Liechtenstein and Luxembourg.7

Military issues and solutions


The smallness of the micro-states makes them inherently weak and vulnerable,
especially in military terms. Indeed many of the micro-states in Europe do not
have military capabilities and have special arrangements to safeguard their
security. Barry Bartmann suggests that Andorra, Iceland, Liechtenstein, Monaco
and San Marino are, ‘constabulary microstates with police and coastguard units
but no formal military establishment’ (Bartmann 2002: 369). The Vatican City
has the ‘Swiss Guard’, but has adopted a policy of neutrality and, given its loca-
tion, essentially relies on Italian defence forces. Bailes and Gylfason write,
‘Iceland has never created its own armed forces and is likely never to create
them’ (Bailes and Gylfason 2009: 149). Iceland and Luxembourg are, however,
members of NATO, which guarantees their military security, while Liechten-
stein is a neutral state surrounded by two other neutral states, namely Switzer-
land and Austria. Andorra and Monaco have security guarantees from their
larger neighbouring states; France is responsible for the defence of Monaco;
while both France and Spain are responsible for the defence of Andorra.8 These
are historic arrangements that evolved because of the size, location and vulner-
ability of the micro-states. The irrelevance of any (military) threat from such
states towards their neighbours helps explain their lack of armed forces, as it
disposes of most reasons for their larger neighbour(s) to threaten them either.
Since the end of World War II and the creation of the UN, the consolidation of
international law and the ideals of collective security also offer some guarantees
for micro-states.
Some micro-states in Europe do have armed forces: the Republic of Cyprus
had a military budget of around US$550 million in 2010, with an army consist-
ing of 10,000 national guard and a further 50,000 reservists, plus a maritime
wing of 300 personnel (European Defence Information 2012). The Cyprus
problem is a sufficient explanation of why the Republic has armed forces;
The security of the European micro-states 177
further, UN peacekeepers remain deployed there and there are two British
military bases on the island. Malta has modest armed forces numbering around
2,000, including maritime personnel (Armed Forces of Malta 2012); and Monte-
negro is applying to join NATO via the Membership Action Plan (MAP)
process.9 The Balkan micro-state has less than 10,000 military personnel and
abolished conscription in 2006.

Security issues and solutions


While offering no real threat in themselves, micro-states may possess strategic
value by virtue of location. During the Cold War, Iceland was of great strategic
importance for NATO due to its position in the North Atlantic GIUK (Green-
land, Iceland, United Kingdom) gap, where Soviet naval activities were closely
monitored. Since the end of the Cold War, this has become less important. Lux-
embourg’s central location meant that the Germans invaded in 191410 and in
1940, on the way to attack France and the other Low Countries. After 1945,
Luxembourg entered NATO partly to avoid its geographical position leading to
further conquest, and as part of the general dynamics of post-war security archi-
tecture (see Table 10.3). Both Cyprus and Malta, as Mediterranean islands, were
important to the British Empire and, as noted, the UK still has bases in the
former. The examples of Andorra, Liechtenstein11 and perhaps San Marino, with
their less than strategic locations, prove the rule as they have not been involved
in any serious wars since the nineteenth century.
Just as for ‘small’ states, membership of international organizations like the
UN, NATO and the EU can play a crucial part in multi-functional security solu-
tions for the European micro-states. Supremely exposed as they are to external

Table 10.3 Membership of international organizations (with date of first membership)

UN EU NATO OSCE CoE (Council of Europe)

Andorra 1993 – – Yes 1994


Cyprus 1960 2005 – Yes 1961
Iceland 1946 – 1949 Yes 1950
Liechtenstein 1990 – – Yes 1978
Luxembourg 1945 1956 1949 Yes 1949
Malta 1964 2005 – Yes 1965
Monaco 1993 – – Yes 2004
Montenegro 2006 – – Yes 2007
San Marino 1992 – – Yes 1988
Vatican City observer – – Yes –

Sources: www.un.org; www.nato.int; http://europa.eu/about-eu/countries/index_en.htm; www.osce.


org/who/83; http://hub.coe.int/web/coe-portal (data correct as of November 2012).
Notes
Andorra, Monaco, San Marino and the Vatican City are part of the Eurozone; Iceland applied for EU
membership in 2009 and is part of the Schengen Agreement and the European Economic Area
(EEA). Montenegro is currently an applicant state for EU membership.
178 A.W. Simpson
pressures, changes in global economic trends, environmental challenges and cul-
tural influences as well as domestic disruption, these very small entities may be
interpreted as using organizations for ‘shelter’ (Thorhallsson 2011) and/or for
bandwaggoning (see Reiter in Ingebritsen et al. 2006: 239–240). Membership of
international organizations offers them new channels of diplomacy, greater
security guarantees under international law and closer relations with other states
in Europe or beyond; while, in the case of NATO membership, Article 5 places
them under the protection of the US nuclear umbrella. Since the end of the Cold
War in the late 1980s, the security architecture of Europe has evolved towards
an even denser network of multilateral organizations in Europe, whether eco-
nomic, political or military, which reinforce the idea of collective security and
active security cooperation.
While the European micro-states are not necessarily members of all European
regional and sub-regional organizations, all of them belong to at least one organ-
ization providing a certain level of security or, at least, a forum to raise their
security concerns. Besides the institutions in Table 10.3, other groupings such as
the Nordic Council, Benelux, the British Commonwealth, EFTA and the Council
of Baltic Sea States include various numbers of these states.
The non-military security issues facing micro-states are shared with most
other states: for instance climate change, societal issues due to patterns of migra-
tion and demographic changes, trends in global markets, international crime and
the threat of pandemics. Consequently, good governance becomes an essential
element in developing resilience, fostering economic stability, encouraging
national identity and developing good relations with other, larger neighbours.
This does not always occur, as illustrated by the economic crisis in Iceland or
the division of Cyprus since the early 1970s. For most micro-states in Europe,
the important security issue lies in developing resilience in governance and in
economic development.

Economic strategies
The inherent economic vulnerabilities of the micro-states in Europe have encour-
aged various economic strategies. There are some benefits in smallness for the
micro-states, including the ability to be flexible in building a market share in
niche areas like banking, communications or tourism. Yet there is always some
dependence on neighbouring states for key economic inputs, especially for the
island micro-states, while all micro-states are limited in natural resources. As
already seen, EU membership has been particularly important for some of them
as a way to encourage investment, gain access to larger markets and benefit from
policies such as the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) and regional funds. As
a founding member of the European Community in 1956 and member of the
European Coal and Steel Community since 1951–1952, Luxembourg has gained
great economic benefit, building on steel and its central location to achieve the
EU’s highest GDP per capita. The two other micro-state members of the EU,
Cyprus and Malta, both joined for largely economic reasons. The free movement
The security of the European micro-states 179
of people, goods, capital and services within the EU allows them to attract new
investments, encourage further tourism and gain assistance on issues like water
quality and management. The EU has reportedly invested €151.5 million in the
Maltese road system since 2004 (Camilleri 2011), a significant amount for a
small island. For Cyprus, EU funds are important but membership might also
ease the long-term prospect of unity with the North.
Andorra, Monaco, San Marino and the Vatican12 all use the euro despite not
being EU members. This is partly for historical reasons: before the euro both
San Marino and the Vatican used the Italian lira, while Monaco used the French
franc, and Andorra used both the French currency and the Spanish peseta.
However, it is also a practical device since having a separate currency is quite an
expensive aspect of economics. By participating in a currency union with other
– and stronger, larger – economies, the micro-states can free-ride and gain eco-
nomic protection as well as benefits. Liechtenstein uses the Swiss franc for
similar reasons.
As already seen, several micro-states have adopted the more controversial
economic strategy of becoming ‘offshore’ financial centres – also known as tax
havens. For Drezner (2001) the micro-states have ‘sold’ their sovereignty by
making this choice, and states like Andorra, Liechtenstein and Monaco have
been heavily criticized for it by the OECD. Certain EU member states, like
Malta and Luxembourg, have also adopted tax haven status in order to attract
investment. Palan writes,

In one form or another, practically every country in the world offers some
sort of haven from taxation and regulation for residents . . . what distin-
guishes tax havens . . . is that they explicitly aim to take advantage of a com-
petitive position by offering reduced regulation or capital tax.
(Palan and Abbot 1999: 169)

In essence, these micro-states adopt low levels of taxation, low levels of finan-
cial regulation and high levels of secrecy over financial matters. On the one
hand, this can be viewed as a clear and successful economic strategy to attract
inward investment. It could also be argued that the size of the micro-states
deprives them of options like mass manufacturing or agricultural production,
while tax haven status needs no special resources. However, tax havens – espe-
cially if weakly regulated – can help tax evaders, criminals and (possibly) terror-
ists, in hiding their finances. Large multinational corporations often open
accounts in states like Luxembourg or Monaco in order to offset profits and thus
pay less taxation in the states, where their profits are made. In an era of instant-
aneous capital transfers through the use of computers and the internet, moving
money to offshore financial centres becomes increasingly easier and more effi-
cient, but also more subject to abuse.13
Palan (2002: 155) identifies a number of European micro-states and other
small territories as offshore financial centres: Andorra, Cyprus, Liechtenstein,
Luxembourg, Malta and Monaco; and Gibraltar, Guernsey, Sark, Isle of Man,
180 A.W. Simpson
Jersey and Madeira. The low-tax regime in many micro-states attracts wealthy
residents – many people who live in Monaco and Andorra are multimillionaires
– which brings other, knock-on economic advantages. States like Andorra,
Monaco, Liechtenstein and Luxembourg, that have followed such strategies,
have been able to attract billions of dollars, pounds and euros into their eco-
nomies in consequence. Palan (2002) reports that, according to some estimates,
‘more than half of the world’s stock of money passes through these tax havens14
. . . it is estimated that about 20 per cent of total private wealth . . . are invested
offshore’ (Palan 2002: 156).

Conclusion
The inherent smallness of the European micro-states makes them vulnerable to
outside pressures. However, they have developed a series of strategies to ensure
that they are economically viable and have the minimal capabilities of statehood.
For some micro-states, this means becoming offshore financial centres; for others it
means participation in European integration; but all rely on an open economy to
trade with the world and encourage inward investments. The development of inter-
national law throughout the twentieth century and international organizations such
as the United Nations, European Union and NATO, coupled with friendly relations
with neighbours, have guaranteed the survival of these Lilliputian states. Smallness
also contributes to micro-state security by making them less threatening to others,
by limiting the resources that others might want to take from them and by making
them strategically insignificant. By being good neighbours to larger states, micro-
states usually manage to avoid conflict – though with notable exceptions such as
the Cod Wars between Iceland and Britain, as well as Cyprus’ fate. Domestic
factors such as democracy, national identity, good governance and economic via-
bility are also essential elements in the security of the European micro-states. In the
end, economics is probably the central security issue for these entities as it under-
pins their viability as states, contributes to government capabilities and ensures
domestic economic security for their people.

Notes
1 A dictionary definition of ‘micro’ means ‘extremely small’, ‘minute in scope or cap-
ability’ and it also means importantly, ‘a millionth’ (http://dictionary.reference.com/
browse/micro?s=t, accessed 25 November 2013).
2 Palestine was granted ‘non-member Observer status’ at the United Nations in
November 2012 through a vote of the General Assembly (United Nations 2012b).
3 The microstates are, in alphabetical order, Andorra, Antigua and Barbuda, Bahamas,
Bahrain, Barbados, Belize, Brunei, Cape Verde, Comoros, Cook Islands, Cyprus, Dji-
bouti, Dominica, East Timor, Equatorial Guinea, Fiji, Grenada, Guyana, Iceland, Kirib-
ati, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, Maldives, Malta, Marshall Islands, Micronesia,
Monaco, Montenegro, Nauru, Qatar, St Kitts and St Nevis, St Lucia, St Vincent, Samoa,
San Marino, Sao Tome and Principe, Seychelles, Solomon Islands, Surinam, Swaziland,
Tonga, Tuvalu, Vanuatu and Vatican City State. The Cook Islands are represented in
the UN by New Zealand and the Vatican City has ‘observer status’ at the UN.
The security of the European micro-states 181
4 In February 2013, Pope Benedict XVI announced his intention to resign: an action
unprecedented in modern history since Pope Gregory XII resigned in 1415.
5 This has been contested on occasions due to the outlook and attitude of the Vatican on
issues such as contraception, women’s rights, religious freedom, and various health
issues such as HIV/AIDS.
6 See (Quester 1983) for more on this.
7 On post-modern economic options for small spaces, see Chapter 14 in this volume.
8 Andorra was neutral during both World Wars and throughout the Spanish civil war of
the 1930s.
9 In 1999, NATO launched the MAP scheme to assist countries wishing to join the Alli-
ance in their preparations by providing advice, assistance and practical support on all
membership requirements.
10 In 1914, Luxembourg was occupied by the Germans in violation of its neutral
position.
11 Throughout both World Wars, Liechtenstein adopted a neutral position. However, it was
bombed by Allied forces during World War II, partly because of its geographic position
next to Austria and partly because the Allies did not fully accept its neutrality. After the
war, around 500 Soviet troops defected to Liechtenstein from Austria and were granted
asylum. Many, around 300, returned to the Soviet Union later.
12 The Vatican’s use of the euro makes this the first time since the dissolution of the
Holy Roman Empire in 1806 (Bobbit 2002: 559) that coins with an image of the Pope
have been in circulation in continental Europe.
13 In 2000, French parliamentarians published reports into various tax havens in
Europe, including Monaco, alleging that the authorities in Monaco were complicit
in aiding criminals, terrorists and tax evaders. While France collects VAT for the
Principality, amounting to around £170 million per annum, the MPs claimed that
Monegasque banking secrecy helped to hide ‘hot money’ (Assemblée Nationale
2000).
14 This includes other global tax havens outside Europe.

Bibliography
Alesina, A. and Spolaore, E. (2005) The Size of Nations, Cambridge Massachusetts and
London: MIT Press.
Anckar, D. (1998) ‘Bicameral Microstates: A Commonwealth Category’, The Round
Table, 347: 367–378.
Anckar, D. (2002) ‘Why are Small Island States Democracies?’, The Round Table, 365:
375–390.
Anckar, D. (2003) ‘Direct Democracy in Microstates and Small Island States’, World
Development, 32(2): 379–390.
Anckar, D. (2004). Politik i lilleputtar: mikrostater i komparativ belysning. Åbo, Finland:
Åbo akademis förlag.
Archer, C. and Nugent, N. (2002) ‘Introduction: Small States and the European Union’,
Current Politics and Economics of Europe, 11(1): 1–10.
Armed Forces of Malta (2012) The Armed Forces of Malta, available online at: www.
afm.gov.mt/home?l=1 (accessed 2 November 2012).
Armstrong, H. and Read, R. (1995) ‘Western European Micro-States and EU Auto-
nomous Regions: The Advantages of Size and Sovereignty’, World Development,
23(7): 1229–1245.
Armstrong, H. and Read, R. (2003) ‘Microstates and Subnational Regions: Mutual Indus-
trial Policy Lessons’, International Regional Science Review, 26(1): 117–141.
182 A.W. Simpson
Armstrong, H., De Kervenoael, R.J., Li, X. and Read, R. (1998) ‘A Comparison of the
Economic Performance of Different Microstates, and Between Microstates and Larger
Countries’, World Development, 26(4): 639–656.
Assemblée Nationale, (2000) ‘La Principauté de Monaco’, Paris: Assemblée Nationale,
(French parliamentary report).
Bailes, A.J.K. and Gylfason, Th. F. (2009) ‘ “Societal Security” and Iceland’, Stjórnmál
og stjórnsýsla, 1/4, available online at: www.irpa.is/article/view/980/pdf_110.
Bartmann, B. (2002) ‘Meeting the Needs of Microstate Security’, The Round Table, 365:
361–374.
BBC (2012) ‘Andorra Country Profile’, available online at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/
world/europe/country_profiles/992562.stm (accessed 25 July 2012).
Bobbitt, P. (2002) The Shield of Achilles, London: Allen Lane.
Briguglio, L., Cordina, G. and Kisanga, E.J. (eds) (2006) Building the Economic Resil-
ience of Small States, Malta and London: Islands and Small States Institute (Malta) and
Commonwealth Secretariat.
Camilleri, I. (2011) ‘EU Investing €151.5 Million in Maltese Roads’, The Times of Malta,
9 July, available online at: www.timesofmalta.com/articles/view/20110907/local/EU-
investing-151–5-million-in-Maltese-roads.383619 (accessed 14 November 2012).
Christopher, A.J. (2002) ‘Decolonisation without Independence’, GeoJournal, 56: 213–224.
Daily Telegraph (2011) ‘Wealth of Churches vs Wealth of People’, Daily Telegraph,
available online at: www.telegraph.co.uk/news/religion/8790126/Wealth-of-churches-
vs-the-wealth-of-people.html (accessed 9 October 2012).
Davies, N. (1997) Europe: A History, London: Pimlico.
Dózsa, D. (2008) ‘EU Relations with European Micro-States. Happily Ever After?’,
European Law Journal, 14(1): 93–104.
Drezner, D.W. (2001) ‘Sovereignty for Sale’, Foreign Policy, 125: 76–77.
Eccardt, T. (2005) Secrets of the Seven Smallest States of Europe, New York: Hippocrene
Books Inc.
European Defence Information (2012) ‘Cyprus’, available online at: www.armedforces.
co.uk/Europeandefence/edcountries/countrycyprus.htm (accessed 20 November 2012).
Harden, S. (ed.) (1985) Small is Dangerous: Micro States in a Macro World, London:
Pinter/David Davies Memorial Institute of International Studies.
Hey, J.A.K. (2003) Small States in World Politics, Boulder, CO and London: Lynne
Rienner Publishers.
Ingebritsen, C., Neumann, I., Gstöl, G. and Beyer, J. (eds) (2006) Small States in Inter-
national Relations, Seattle and Reykjavik: University of Washington Press/University
of Iceland Press.
Kohr, L. (2001) The Breakdown of Nations, Totnes and London: Green books/New Euro-
pean Publications.
Maass, M. (2009) ‘The Elusive Definition of the Small State’, International Politics, 46
(1): 65–83.
Misra, A. (2004) ‘Theorising “Small” and “Micro” State Behaviour using the Maldives,
Bhutan and Nepal’, Contemporary South Asia, 13(2): 133–148.
Mohamed, A.N. (2002) ‘The Diplomacy of Micro-states’, discussion paper in Diplomacy,
78, The Hague: Netherlands Institute of International Relations, available online at:
www.clingendael.nl/publications/2002/20020100_cli _paper_dip_issue78.pdf (accessed
30 September 2012).
Montenegro (2012) ‘Visit Montenegro’, www.visit-montenegro.com/ (accessed 10
August 2012).
The security of the European micro-states 183
Montevideo Convention (1933) Available online at: www.cfr.org/sovereignty/
montevideo-convention-rights-duties-states/p15897 (accessed 14 November 2012).
Nairn, T. (1997) Faces of Nationalism: Janus Revisited, London: Verso.
Palan, R. (2002) ‘Tax Havens and the Commercialization of State Sovereignty’, Inter-
national Organization, 56(1): 151–176.
Palan, R. and Abbott, J. with Deans, P. (1999) State Strategies in the Global Political
Economy, London and New York: Pinter.
Plischke, E. (1977) Microstates in World Affairs: Policy Problems and Options, Wash-
ington, DC: American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research.
Quester, G. (1983) ‘Trouble in the Islands: Defending the Micro-States’, International
Security, 8(2): 160–175.
Sepos, A. (2008) The Europeanization of Cyprus: Polity, Policies and Politics, Basing-
stoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Simpson, A.W. (2008) ‘Nations and States’, in Salmon, T. and Imber, M. (eds) Issues in
International Relations, London and New York: Routledge.
Sinmaz, E. (2011) ‘Liechtenstein for Hire at $70,000 a Night’, Guardian, 15 April, avail-
able online at: www.guardian.co.uk/world/2011/apr/15/liechtenstein-hire-rental-scheme
(accessed 7 October 2012).
Strikwerda, C. (1993) ‘The Troubled Origins of European Economic Integration: Inter-
national Iron and Steel and Labor Migration in the Era of World War I’, The American
Historical Review, 98(4): 1106–1129.
Sundhaussen, U. (2003) ‘Peasants and the Process of Building Democracy Politics:
Lessons from San Marino’, Australian Journal of Politics and History, 49(2): 211–221.
Sutton, P. and Payne, A. (1993) ‘Lilliput under Threat: The Security Problems of Small
Island and Enclave Developing States’, Political Studies, 41(4): 579–593.
Thorhallsson, B. (2011) ‘Domestic Buffer versus External Shelter: Viability of Small
States in the New Globalised Economy’, European Political Science, 10: 324–336.
Treanor, J. (2009) ‘Britain and Liechtenstein Strike Deal on Tax Avoidance’, Guardian,
11 August 2009, available online at: www.theguardian.com/business/2009/aug/11/tax-
havens-liechtenstein (accessed 12 August 2012).
United Nations (2004) The Comprehensive Settlement Of The Cyprus Problem, available
online at: http://unannanplan.agrino.org/Annan_Plan_MARCH_30_2004.pdf (accessed
10 October 2012).
United Nations (2012a) ‘Growth in the United Nations membership, 1945-present’, avail-
able online at: www.un.org/en/members/growth.shtml (accessed 17 June 2012).
United Nations (2012b) ‘General Assembly grants Palestine non-member observer State
status at UN’, available online at: www.un.org/apps/news/story.asp?NewsID=43640&
Cr=palestin&Cr1= (accessed 20 December 2012).
United Nations (2012c) ‘Permanent Observers’, available online at: www.un.org/en/
members/nonmembers.shtml (accessed 3 August 2012).
Warrington, E. (1994) ‘Lilliput Revisited’, The Asian Journal of Public Administration,
16(1): 3–13.
Wivel, A. and Oest, K.J.N. (2010) ‘Security, Profit, or Shadow of the Past? Explaining
the Security Strategies of Microstates’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs,
23(3): 429–453.
This page intentionally left blank
Part III
Comparative insights
This page intentionally left blank
11 Botswana as a small
developmental state
Ian Taylor

Introduction: the developmental conundrum


At independence in 1966, the population of Botswana was just over half a
million people, living in a country the size of France. The country had only four
miles of paved roads, nine secondary schools, and the capital had to be relocated
from Mafeking (remaining in South Africa) to Gaborone to place it inside the
actual borders of the new nation. Botswana was then among the 25 poorest and
least-developed countries in the world. Surrounded by hostile, minority-ruled
states, the small state was hardly a candidate for anything other than failure; yet
its relative success has confounded predictions. This chapter seeks to
understand why.
For Africa, the various international financial institutions have argued that
African states, particularly small African states, lack the capacity to pursue pol-
icies similar to the developmental states of East Asia, whilst being far too sus-
ceptible to vested interests in the political realm. Supporters of this view, known
as the ‘impossibility thesis’, claimed that African states that remained in the
business of guiding development threatened to bring disaster, and must be reined
in by Structural Adjustment Progrmmes (SAPs). Whilst recognizing the prob-
lematic nature of many African state formations, the consequent pressure for
across-the-board liberalization and state rollback has been similarly dubious. It
is extremely important today to challenge the thesis that state involvement
inexorably leads to economic decline and that a developmental orientation in
Africa is impossible – even for small countries such as Botswana.

Botswana as a developmental state


Botswana is famed for its diamond resources and it is true that the revenues from
diamond extraction have powered the country’s growth. However, an abundance
of mineral wealth on its own explains nothing in looking at Botswana’s success:
as the case of Sierra Leone demonstrates, natural resources may in fact sabotage
nation-building and development. As Leith (2000: 4) writes, ‘the growth of the
Botswana economy is not simply a story of a mineral enclave with an ever
growing government, attached to a stagnating traditional economy’.
188 I. Taylor
There is, of course, a major problem in defining a developmental state simply
from its economic performance. Not all countries with good growth rates are
developmental states. As Mkandawire (1998: 2) remarks:

the definition of the ‘developmental state’ runs the risk of being tautological
since evidence that the state is developmental is often drawn deductively
from the performance of the economy. This produces a definition of a state
as developmental if the economy is developing, and equates economic
success to state strength while measuring the latter by the presumed out-
comes of its policies.

Referring to Africa specifically, Mkandawire adds:

In Africa, we have many examples of states whose performance up until the


mid-1970s would have qualified them as ‘developmental states’ in the sense
conveyed by current definitions, but which now seem anti-developmental
because the hard times brought the economic expansion of their countries to
a halt. Recognition of episodes and possibilities of failure leads us to a defi-
nition of a developmental state as one whose ideological underpinnings are
developmental and one that seriously attempts to deploy its administrative
and political resources to the task of economic development.
(Ibid.)

Following this, in Botswana there has been a definite commitment by the state to
pursue development. This goes back to the first Presidency of Sir Seretse Khama,
who was conscious of developing a relative backwater of the British Empire. A
conscious and disciplined leadership has seen as one of its main duties as the
need to develop professional institutions with competent bureaucrats. Indeed, the
very process of post-independence nation-building took on a character that was
inspired by the fundamental task of development at all levels of society and gov-
ernment. This developmental ethos was accepted and advanced both by the polit-
ical and bureaucratic elites and by the institutions that they built up.
This experience echoes Ha-Joon Chang’s argument that a developmental state
should act as an entrepreneurial agent whilst engaging in institution- and
capacity-building (Chang 1999). Certainly, the robustness and level of capacity
of state institutions in other developmental states have been crucial. In 1981,
Botswana’s then Minister of Finance and Development Planning, Peter Mmusi,
spoke of the need for a:

purposeful government which acquires the expertise to deal with companies on


its own terms . . . the important word is purposeful—and I believe our govern-
ment has been able to put together strong negotiating teams, has backed them
up with well-worked-out negotiating mandates, and has then overseen the
implementation of our major mining agreements with detailed care as well.
(quoted in Harvey and Lewis 1990: 119)
Botswana as a small developmental state 189
Attempting to account for how and why a disciplined and competent state
apparatus emerged post-independence is what we shall turn to next.

Explaining the ‘miracle’


Explanations and accounts of Botswana’s development trajectory are diverse.
One school of thought may be called the ‘African Miracle’ school, which is
mainly positive and largely economistic in its approach and misses the inher-
ently political nature of Botswana’s post-independence experience. Though this
‘school’ covers a variety of views, it does in the main approach Botswana’s post-
independence from a largely uncritical stance, asking whether Botswana is
indeed ‘A Model for Success?’ (the subtitle of Picard’s 1987 book, The Politics
of Development in Botswana). Those working more from a political economy
perspective have been more critical. Such analysts do, of course, acknowledge
the country’s rapid economic growth and efficient state machinery, as well as the
long-running liberal democracy. However, they are more critical of the profound
contradictions that have developed alongside Botswana’s developmental trajec-
tory. Such a position questions a situation where there is ‘Poverty in the Midst of
Plenty’, blaming it on deliberate policy choices made as part of the develop-
mental state project (Gulbrandsen 1996).
Touching on factors in Botswana’s relative success, Samatar asserts that ‘a
key force that distinguishes successful from failed states is the social chemistry
of the dominant class and the discipline of its leadership’ (1999: 6). Samatar is
critical of the social polarization and disparities of income within the country.
However, Samatar also argues that Botswana’s wealth grants the elite a certain
space that can be used in order to resolve the more iniquitous inequalities,
through determined policy choices and implementation.
According to Samatar, Botswana’s success as a developmental state is rooted
in a professional bureaucracy that has conducted and implemented policy
making efficiently. This has been made possible by an essential alliance amongst
elites. Patrick Molutsi has identified five factions of the ruling elite in Botswana:
elected representatives; traditional rulers; the higher echelons of the bureaucracy;
the business elite; and leading cattle-ranchers. Many of these actors can be
located in two or more of these categories (Molutsi 1989a: 105). This elite alli-
ance has privileged policies that have sought to attract private FDI, whether for
mineral or manufacturing ventures – mostly the former. Receipts from this have
been diverted into national development projects (Hill and Mokgethi 1989).
Another leg of these policies is to promote, support and protect local businesses,
primarily in the urban areas: the Financial Assistance Policy (see pp. 195–6) is a
classic example. Such interventions have been possible because a strong state
apparatus was built post-1966, that did not deteriorate into private patronage net-
works as elsewhere in Africa. Rent-seeking activities have thus been minimal
(Theobald and Williams 1999; cf. Good 1994).1
Crucially at independence the first President, Seretse Khama, enjoyed a legiti-
macy – drawn from his position as (former) chief of the dominant Tswana tribe
190 I. Taylor
– that was unrivalled. This, coupled with the legacy of neglect left by the British,
meant that there was no real opposition to Khama’s agenda:

Unlike in most other African countries, Britain left no army, no strong bur-
eaucracy, and a weakling middle class. This situation created a critical tech-
nical and political vacuum at independence. The Tswana educated elite [of
whom Khama was one] was so small that it ended up collaborating with the
colonial state, the chiefs and European settlers to form the new ruling class
at independence.
(Molutsi 1989a: 104)

This vacuum was a double-edged sword, for whilst it meant a state with emas-
culated capacity at independence, it also gave Khama and his circle the space to
strip chiefs of their political power. Any threat to the new state’s legitimacy
originating from a chief was nipped in the bud. The Chieftainship Act of 1965
meant that power was granted to the President to recognize, or not recognize, a
traditional ruler, making all chiefs subordinate to the central government. In
addition, a House of Chiefs was established, but with no legislative powers
(Somolekae and Lekorwe 1998). At one blow, this dissolved potential opposi-
tion to building up a strong state apparatus, and concerted opposition to the new
government in general; it alsos removed a potential site of alternative power.
Instead, traditional rulers, dependent on the state for official recognition, served
as facilitators for the implementation of policy, particularly in rural areas. In this
sense, their role within Botswana was re-invented and chiefs became agents of
the government at the grass-roots level.
Furthermore, the post-colonial elite has dominated the National Assembly in
such a way that state resources were not diverted to maintain patronage net-
works, but, rather, were available to be deployed for development. A relative
working autonomy has allowed the political and bureaucratic elite to formulate
policies that have benefited national development even whilst benefiting tradi-
tional elites (e.g. policies on cattle production). Acemoglu (Acemoglu et al.
2001: 44) write:

[T]he members of the BDP [Botswana Democratic Party] and the political
elite that emerged after 1966 had important interests in the cattle industry,
the main productive sector of the economy. This meant that it was in the
interests of the elite to build infrastructure and generally develop institutions
. . . which promoted not only national development, but also their own eco-
nomic interests. This development path was considerably aided by the fact
that the constitution and policies adopted by the BDP meant that there were
no vested interests in the status quo that could block good policies.

One of the key explanations for Botswana’s development trajectory has been the
commitment to development and the willingness to articulate a national vision
for development by the elite or ‘a national perspective that will carry the national
Botswana as a small developmental state 191
psyche to a level of providence, with a sense of future, so as to define its ambi-
tion or desired level of progress’ (Robi 1994: 487). The centrepiece of the state’s
development efforts since the inception of the first National Development Plan
(NDP) from 1968 to 1973, has been to raise the standards of living of the popu-
lation of Botswana. In line with this, development plans have been guided by the
planning objectives of sustainable development, rapid economic growth, eco-
nomic independence and social justice (Republic of Botswana 1997a). The
NDPs have the added advantage of granting policy implementers a great degree
of space between themselves and the politicians. Thus a technical document,
drafted by experts and then approved by elected representatives, serves as the
blueprint for government policy. ‘Once the new plan is approved, politicians’
proposals not in the plan are turned aside on the grounds that only emergency
measures can be adopted until the next plan is formulated’ (Molutsi 1989b: 112).
Botswana thus echoes the developmental state of Johnson, where ‘the politicians
reign and the state bureaucrats rule’ (Johnson 1981: 12).
In addition, and in a conscious imitation of another developmental state’s
Vision 2020 (namely Malaysia), a Presidential Task Group produced a document
entitled ‘A Framework for a Long Term Vision for Botswana’. The ‘Vision
2016’ is supposed to be a national manifesto to guide future National Develop-
ment Plans (NDPs) as well as broad government policy, and it is a statement of
long-term goals together with proposals for a set of strategies to meet them
(Republic of Botswana 1996 and 1997b) According to Mkandawire:

it is this ideology-structure nexus that distinguishes developmental states


from other forms of states. In terms of ideology, such a state is essentially
one whose ideological underpinning is ‘developmentalist’ in that it con-
ceives its ‘mission’ as that of ensuring economic development.
(Mkandawire 1998: 2)

Vision 2016 and the various NDPs, are an indication of the developmentalist nature
of Botswanan governance. Through them, ‘by planning within the context of a
market economy, government policy has tended to influence the direction of gov-
ernment expenditure during the planning period while providing an environment in
which private sector activity can thrive’ (Edge 1998: 334). Yet, the state elite’s
commitment to development alone does not explain Botswana’s experience. As
Maundeni puts it, ‘developmental commitment needed to be matched with institu-
tional capacity. Creating a truly developmental state requires that the whole state
machinery must be subjected to the leadership of an economic agency of the state’
(Maundeni 2001: 18). This economic agency was, as mentioned, the Ministry of
Finance and Development Planning, staffed by an able civil service.
As one consequence, economic advice has been sought from technocrats, par-
ticularly when preparing NDPs and budgets. Indeed, the link between finance
and national development is made explicit by the existence in Botswana of a
single Ministry of Finance and Development Planning (MFDP) located in the
Vice-President’s office. It is pertinent to add that, prior to becoming President
192 I. Taylor
after Seretse Khama’s death, Quett Masire was Minister of Finance and Devel-
opment Planning and had been Vice-President for 14 years. Similarly, prior to
assuming the Presidency in 1998, current President, Festus Mogae, had been
Masire’s Vice-President for five years as well as being Minister of Finance and
Development Planning. Peter Mmusi, who resigned as Vice-President in 1993
under a cloud, had also held the MFDP post. Such a ministry, with its close links
to the executive, has secured a balance between development planning and
budgeting, as well as strengthening the capacity to implement national goals and
demonstrating a commitment to economic development.
This commitment first emerged after a struggle within the Ministry of Finance
in the immediate post-independence period. Essentially, two factions fought over
the new country’s future economic policy. On the one hand, the Permanent Sec-
retary, Alfred Beeby, insisted on the need to ‘balance the books’ and ‘refused to
entertain any ideas about economic development until moneys in hand’ (Morton
and Ramsay 1994: 63). Opposed to this highly conservative stance were a group
of young economists such as Pierre Landell-Mills and Quill Hermans, who
favoured ‘aggressive planning for economic growth, identification of potential
projects, and then finally lobbying internationally for potential sources of aid or
loans to finance the projects. Moreover, they even promoted the idea of borrow-
ing money to finance development’ (ibid). The latter fraction, fortuitously, had
the ear of Quett Masire, then Vice-President. Beeby had Landell-Mills were
thrown out of the civil service for ‘insubordination’, which for a period of six
weeks (November–December 1966), caused a rift between Masire and President
Khama. The matter was finally resolved after a commission of enquiry that even-
tually saw the creation of the Ministry of Development Planning with Hermans
as Permanent Secretary and Landell-Mills as Senior Government Economist.
It would not be too much of an exaggeration to say that the foundations for
the Botswana developmental state were laid during the ‘Landell-Mills affair’, in
the sense that, thereafter, the key Ministry of Development Planning was
developmentally-driven, whilst the objectives of the bureaucrats were politically-
driven and supported by both Seretse Khama and Quett Masire. Meredith Woo-
Cumings has argued that nationalism and a national vision lies at the heart of a
developmental state (1999b: 8) and ‘in many respects development has been
Botswana’s ideology’ (Lewis 1993). As Sir Seretse Khama argued:

When we attained independence in 1966 we had no economic base from


which to proceed with the development of our country. Our chances of sur-
vival as a viable country were almost nil but we were not discouraged nor
could we ever willingly return to the old days of colonial neglect. Having
accepted the challenges of independence we had no other alternative but to
get down to work to make our independence a meaningful one.
(Khama 1980: 323)

In specifically understanding Botswana as a developmental state, Samatar argues


that the Botswanan elite has successfully utilized the receipts from the country’s
Botswana as a small developmental state 193
diamonds to expand the state as a facilitator (or ‘entrepreneurial agent’). This
sea change in philosophy from Beeby’s fiscal conservatism to Landell-Mills et
al.’s more development-oriented policies has been crucial, with the state not
shying away from an active involvement in promoting the market. Pilot institu-
tions have been built to stimulate growth in the private sector, the Botswana
Development Corporation being a prime example. Botswana Development Cor-
poration Limited (BDC) was established in 1970 as Botswana’s main agency for
commercial and industrial development and all of its ordinary shares are owned
by the government of Botswana. The BDC’s primary objective is to assist in the
establishment and development of commercially viable businesses in Botswana.
Its roles include the provision of financial assistance to investors with commer-
cially viable projects, the building of partnerships with investors capable of cre-
ating and growing commercially viable businesses and the support of projects
that generate sustainable employment for Botswana. An important aim of the
BDC is to encourage citizen participation in business ventures (see Botswana
Development 1985; Botswana Development Corporation 1995; and Botswana
Development Corporation 2000).
Similarly, the Botswana Export Development and Investment Authority
(BEDIA), set up by the government in November 1997, is designed to promote
investment into Botswana, with special emphasis on export-oriented manufac-
ture; to identify market outlets for products manufactured in Botswana, and to
construct factory buildings. Reflecting the close links between the public and
private sector, the board of directors of BEDIA is made up of private-sector rep-
resentatives alongside representatives from the Ministry of Commerce and
Industry and the Ministry of Finance and Development Planning.
Regarding the role of the bureaucracy in Botswana’s developmental state: this
effective and competent service has been able to implement policy directives
without miring itself and the country in over-expenditure and other pitfalls associ-
ated with many other such apparatuses, particularly in Africa. Expatriates were
retained (as opposed to much of the rest of Africa) in order to help train up a local
but competent and educated civil service – symbolically, for a number of years, the
head of the civil service was a white Kenyan. Because of the lack of education
afforded to local Batswana under the colonial period, this gradualism was neces-
sary. The local cadre of bureaucrats thus underwent a period of tutelage and learn-
ing that has enabled them to gradually – and smoothly – take over the running of
the country. Now, the Botswanan civil service has a ‘proven capacity to take pre-
emptive policy action and generally pursue policies in the long-term interest of the
country’ (Charlton 1991: 265). Combined with well-trained and well-educated
Botswanans who have a low tolerance threshold of corruption, this means that the
bureaucracy in Botswana is a tool rather than an obstacle for development. Further-
more, linking Botswana’s bureaucracy with the developmental state literature on
the autonomy of the bureaucracy, du Toit (1995: 121) correctly asserts that:

[T]he autonomous bureaucracy, in coalition with the ruling Botswana


Democratic Party has succeeded through its technocratic priorities of growth
194 I. Taylor
and stability (at the expense of participation and equity), in establishing a
solvent enough state which is able to deliver public goods (roads, schools,
watering facilities, clinics etc) on a non-tribal, non-regional basis, so as to
ensure that the minimum requirements of jointness of supply and non-
excludability are met. Ensuring that the state is seen as neutral, not as an
ethnic body . . . contributes to its legitimacy and that of the regime.

According to Maundeni (no date: 10), ‘Botswana has maintained a strong and
relatively autonomous and effective bureaucracy by insulating the planning bur-
eaucrats from societal pressure, employing expatriates and by targeting the train-
ing of locals’. ‘In practice the civil service, not the political leadership, has
dominated policymaking’ (Somolekae 1993: 116). The autonomy of this bureau-
cracy was, of course, socially anchored within the wider milieu of webs and net-
works that linked the cattle-ranchers, politicians and bureaucrats together. This
sort of ‘embedded autonomy’ (Evans 1995) characteristic of developmental
states, created a dynamic interaction between the various (cross-cutting) groups
that stimulated policies favourable not only to the elites themselves, but also to
development. Clearly, developmental states must be involved in a network of
ties, which secure them to groups or classes that can become allies in the pursuit
of societal goals. What has occurred in Botswana is a typical developmental
state situation where the bureaucracy and the ruling party mesh. Evidence to
confirm this is ‘the commonness of the recruitment of senior civil servants
directly not just into the ruling party politics but into senior government posts’
(Charlton 1991: 283). The classic example was previous President, Festus
Mogae, who was variously been Planning Officer, Director of Economic Affairs,
Alternate Governor for Botswana at the IMF, Governor of the Bank of Bot-
swana, Permanent Secretary to the President, Secretary to the Cabinet, Minister
of Finance and Development Planning and finally Vice-President in 1992 before
taking over the presidential reins in 1998.
Some claims have been made that the state has overly favoured an elite frac-
tion of cattle farmers (e.g. Picard 1980 and Parson 1981). This presupposes,
however, a high degree of influence over policy by some interest groups. In
reality, as Holm has pointed out when talking specifically of rural development
and the supposed influence of some ‘bovine elite’, ‘the critical debate on a policy
takes place within the government, not in parliament or in public discussion . . . it
is dominant ministries which shape policy outcomes’ (Holm 1985: 175). Molutsi
(1989b: 126) has gone further to assert that:

Without denying that important government policies benefit the rich and influ-
ential sections of society . . . the state is not sui generis an instrument of local
shopkeepers and cattle owners. Instead it is capable because of its relative auto-
nomy from the major classes in society of concurrently advancing accumula-
tion programmes in favour of the propertied classes on the one hand and
welfare programmes for the poor masses on the other. The latter especially is
important if the state is to establish itself as legitimate for the entire population.
Botswana as a small developmental state 195
It can be argued that the embedded autonomy of the bureaucracy and diverse
ministries have thus served Botswana well, cushioning policy from special-
interest lobbying, though perhaps at a cost of the democratic accountability of
the bureaucracy. The limitations placed on organized labour, in particular, in the
name of nation-building, have been highlighted by some observers (Mogalakwe
1997). Having said that, as in other developmental states, social engineering is
integral to the project. This has been facilitated in Botswana – meaning that there
has been minimal opposition to the dominant elites’ programmes – by civil
society being poorly developed and disorganized, and democratic input being
weak in any case (Molutsi and Holm 1990). In particular, the fragmented opposi-
tion has meant that the BDP has enjoyed hegemonic – if not wholly unchal-
lenged – status since independence.
Freed from such diverse pressures emanating from below, the bureaucracy
has served a crucial role and it is true that ‘the government [has] invested heavily
in infrastructure, health and education and attempted to foster industrial develop-
ment. The key to all this was the creation of a meritocratic bureaucracy and
extensive state capacity’ (Acemoglu et al. 2001: 29). Consequently, ‘public
sector development administration is at once broader and more focussed than
traditional public administration because the state itself serves both as the engine
of growth within the economy and as the primary source of social development
nationally’ (Edge 1998: 336–337).
Following on from this, parastatals have been created in a country that lacks
sufficient local capital – the most notable examples being Botswana Power Cor-
poration, the National Development Bank, Botswana Railways and the Botswana
Development Corporation. In order to finance these, the government has created
a mechanism whereby funds are transferred out of the Consolidated Fund into
three special funds, namely the Domestic Development Fund, which is the
state’s own contribution to capital projects as opposed to donor aid; the Revenue
Stabilization Fund, which absorbs short-term revenue increases and is used to
provide short-term funding to parastatals and local government; and the Public
Debt Service Fund, which provides long-term funding to parastatals. This mech-
anism controls excess spending by central government. Hudson (1991: 57) has
written that ‘the government has had mixed success with these loans, from a
credit worthiness point of view. From a development point of view however,
they have been a great success’.
The state has been keen to diversify the economy away from its traditional
export base and towards manufacturing, particularly as minerals are a finite
resource and ‘the economy’s prospects of continuing rapid growth must lie
mainly with the further development of manufactured exports’ (Harvey 1991:
337). Indeed, the government has noted with alarm the vulnerability of Botswana
to an over-reliance on diamonds in face of the issue of ‘conflict diamonds’
(Daily News (Gaborone) July 6, 2001). To this end, Gaborone has followed a
conscious policy of promoting the industrial sector as a means of diversifying
Botswana’s economy. The Financial Assistance Programme (FAP) has been a
part of this policy. Established in 1982 and revised in 1989 and 1995, FAP was
196 I. Taylor
created to assist businesses that produce or process goods for import substitution
or for export. Large-scale mining and the cattle industry are excluded from FAP
support. Eligible activities for assistance include manufacturing, small- and
medium-scale mining, agriculture other than cattle, selected ‘linking’ service
industries and tourism. Linking service industries are defined as those that
provide a marketing or collection function for the productive activities, includ-
ing associated repair and maintenance facilities. Brewing or distilling operations
do not qualify for assistance.
New projects and expanding productive businesses can apply for assistance,
but only those which raise the national income and have a reasonable chance of
becoming financially viable will receive support. Businesses qualifying for
assistance are classified into three categories:

• Small-scale projects – having fixed capital investment of less than P75,000.


FAP assistance in this category is restricted to citizens. Assistance is in the
form of grants, with amounts determined by location, woman ownership and
number of jobs created;
• Medium-scale projects – having fixed capital investment of between
P75,000 and P2 million;
• Large-scale projects – having fixed capital investment in excess of P2
million.

Small- and medium-scale industrial projects that qualify are administered by the
Department of Industrial Affairs in the Ministry of Commerce and Industry. The
Ministry of Finance and Development Planning administers the large-scale pro-
jects. However, such mechanisms have largely failed to diversify the economy:
despite the best efforts of the state, Botswana has been unable to emulate such
Asian developmental states as South Korea or Taiwan in building up a large-
scale, competitive manufacturing base. This has been a failing of the country’s
development experience.

Concluding remarks
Botswana is not some sort of utopia in the Kalahari. The country faces serious
problems related to equity within society. It can hardly be said that everyone
has benefited meaningfully from raised incomes or higher standards of living,
despite the extensive provision of health and education facilities as well as
access to potable water and a decent transport infrastructure. As Picard has
pointed out, ‘the primary beneficiaries of government policy in the areas of
economic and rural development have been the organizational elites, bureau-
cratic, professional and political, who dominate the system’ (Picard
1987: 264).
Although Botswana is a ‘cattle country’, this obscures the fact that almost
half of all Botswanans own no cattle at all, with less than 10 per cent of the
population owning about 50 per cent of the country’s cattle. These cattle barons
Botswana as a small developmental state 197
have benefited from government policy on beef, although the receipts from meat
exports also go into state coffers. Samatar and Oldfield (1995: 661) consider that
the Botswana Meat Commission, which manages the country’s beef industry,
‘has nurtured the collective interest of the dominant strata while providing serv-
ices for the many small producers’. Four out of five rural households survive on
the income of a family member in town or abroad. ‘That still leaves a significant
number of rural households, usually female-headed, with no source of income
known to statisticians’ (Parsons 2000).
The creation of a more equitable society and the fairer distribution of
resources is now Botswana’s greatest developmental challenge, which will
define the success or otherwise of the post-independence project. A less elitist,
and more egalitarian, dimension to Botswana as a developmental state is
urgently required. Although some of the inequality in the country is due to spe-
cific policy choices, it is also true – as Tsie (1998: 15) points out – that:

some of the contradictions of Botswana’s development policy are rooted in


the capitalist system that the country has followed. . . . Here one has in mind
the tendency of capitalist economies to generate severe income inequalities
in the early stages of their development.

Now that Botswana has established the fundamentals of a working bureaucracy


and an excellent infrastructure with a large amount of foreign reserves, a more
proactive stance on inequality should be put in place (see Botswana Institute for
Development Policy Analysis 1996).
The commitment to development by both the political and bureaucratic elites
is thus central, but not enough. Plenty of African states have been developmental
on paper, but very few indeed have been successful. What seems to have sepa-
rated Botswana from other African states is the strategy of putting into place
institutions that have helped sustain growth. This has been part of a broader
national developmental vision that has sought to coordinate investment plans.
With the state acting as an entrepreneurial agent, there has been, to varying
degrees, coordination between the private and the public sectors – the parastatals
being a prime example. According to Edge:

In Botswana, the developmental state is based on a foundation of capitalism


in which the government, through a wide variety of incentives, actively pro-
motes private investments by national and multinational corporations, while
creating profit-based public enterprises and investing directly in private
firms.
(Edge 1998: 334)

All this has been facilitated by an efficient and well-trained bureaucracy, which
has resisted the descent into corruption that has been the hallmark of much of the
civil service in other parts of the continent. Indeed, skills development, not only
in the bureaucracy but also in the wider private sphere, has been an important
198 I. Taylor
aspect of Botswana’s success – the National Productivity Centre, which came
about after fact-finding missions to Malaysia and Singapore, being a prime
example.
Despite the criticism of inequality within the country, it is still true that ‘state
intervention can play a vital role in creating the conditions for sustained trade
growth and in ensuring that trade expansion translates into poverty reduction –
as the examples of both Botswana and Mauritius in Africa have demonstrated’
(Carroll and Carroll 1997). The Botswanan developmental state has achieved
respectable accomplishments; it may even be argued that Botswana’s strategy
has shown that ‘a disciplined activist African state that governs the market is
essential for industrial development and recovery’ (Owusu and Samatar 1997:
270). In this sense, the lessons that states may pick up from the Asian experi-
ence, namely the construction of ‘local counterparts to the proximate institu-
tional prerequisites of East Asian success – bureaucracies with a capable
economic core and government-business relations based on scepticism combined
with communication and support in return for performance delivered’, might
also be applied to Botswana’s case (Evans 1998: 83). The assessment seems
correct that:

Botswana [has] defied the thrust of prevailing development orthodoxy,


which claims that African states cannot enhance industrial development
through interventionist strategy. Botswana’s state-governed industrial
strategy supports recent research on the ‘East Asian miracle’, which under-
scores the fundamental importance of state intervention in industrial
transformation.
(Owusu and Samatar 1997: 289)

Equally, the ‘primacy of politics’ in the complex process of development has


been fundamental and decisive (Leftwich 2000), inferring that it is not how much
state intervention should take place, but rather what kind.
Obviously, the very different historical and cultural contexts from which
various development experiences have evolved make direct comparisons and the
borrowing of models problematic (Clapham 1996). Developmental states cannot,
as Leftwich (2000: 169) points out, ‘be had to order’. Nonetheless, there is such
a thing as a broad developmental state model that helps account for the relative
success not only of Taiwan or Singapore, but also of Botswana. Moreover, the
possibility of more developmental states on the continent should not be written
off (Stein 2000). As Peter Evans has written:

in the best of all possible worlds, African and Latin American countries
would follow the lessons generated by the East Asian experiences in the
same way that East Asian policy-makers followed western models of capit-
alism: with such originality and inventiveness as to outperform the original.
Hopefully the art of leapfrogging is not yet dead.
(Evans 1998: 83)
Botswana as a small developmental state 199
Note
1 It should be pointed out that the examples that Good cites, and which are held up as
somehow indicative of the levels of corruption in Botswana, are drawn from a lengthy
period of time, while similar crimes, unfortunately, are uncovered on a weekly basis in
South Africa and elsewhere.

Bibliography
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson, J. (2001) ‘How Botswana Did It: Comparative
Development in Sub-Saharan Africa’, unpublished paper.
Botswana Development Corporation (1985) Botswana Development Corporation: The
First Fifteen Years, Gaborone: BDC.
Botswana Development Corporation (1995) Twenty-Fifth Anniversary, Gaborone: BDC.
Botswana Development Corporation (2000) ‘Annual Report 2001: Maintaining the
Momentum’, Gaborone: BDC.
Botswana Institute for Development Policy Analysis (1996) Study of Poverty and Poverty
Alleviation in Botswana, Gaborone: BIDPA/Ministry of Finance and Development
Planning.
Botswana: Review of Commerce and Industry (2000) Gaborone: B and T Industries.
Carroll, B.W. and Carroll, T. (1997) ‘State and Ethnicity in Botswana and Mauritius: A
Democratic Route to Development?’, Journal of Developing Areas, 33(4): 464–486.
Chang, H.-J. (1999) ‘The Economic Theory of the Developmental State’, in Woo-
Cumings, M. (ed.) The Developmental State, New York: Cornell University.
Charlton, R. (1991) ‘Bureaucrats and Politicians in Botswana’s Policy-making Process:
A Reinterpretation’, Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, 29(3):
265–282.
Clapham, C. (1996) ‘The Developmental State: Governance, Comparison and Culture in
the “Third World” ’, in Imbeau, L. and McKinlay, R. (eds) Comparing Government
Activity, Basingstoke: Macmillan.
Colclough, C. and McCarthy, S. (1980) The Political Economy of Botswana: A Study of
Growth and Distribution, Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Du Toit, P. (1995) State Building and Democracy in Southern Africa: A Comparative
Study of Botswana, South Africa and Zimbabwe, Pretoria: HSRC.
Edge, W. and Lekorwe, M. (eds) (1998) Botswana: Politics and Society, Pretoria: Van
Schaik.
Evans, P. (1995) Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation, Princeton:
Princeton University Press.
Evans, P. (1998) ‘Transferable Lessons? Re-examining the Institutional Prerequisites of
East Asian Policies’, Journal of Development Studies, 34(6): 66–86.
Good, K. (1994) ‘Corruption and Mismanagement in Botswana: A Best-Case Example’,
Journal of Modern African Studies, 32(3): 499–521.
Gulbrandsen, O. (1996) Poverty in the Midst of Plenty, Bergen: Norse Publications.
Harvey, C. (1991) ‘Botswana: Is the Economic Miracle Over?’, Journal of African Eco-
nomics, 1(3): 335–368.
Harvey, C. and Lewis, S. (1990) Policy Choice and Development Performance in Bot-
swana, New York: St Martin’s Press.
Hudson, D. (1991) ‘Booms and Busts in Botswana’, Botswana Notes and Records, 23:
47–67.
200 I. Taylor
Hill, C. and Mokgethi, D.N. (1989) ‘Botswana: Macroeconomic Management of Com-
modity Booms, 1975–86’, in World Bank Successful Development in Africa, Washing-
ton, DC: World Bank.
Holm, J. (1985) ‘The State, Social Class and Rural Development in Botswana’, in Picard,
L. (ed.) The Evolution of Modern Botswana, Lincoln: University of Nebraska Press.
Holm, J. and Molutsi, P. (eds) (1989) Democracy in Botswana, Gaborone: Macmillan.
Hope, K.R. (1996) ‘Growth, Unemployment and Poverty in Botswana’, Journal of Con-
temporary Studies, 14(1): 53–67.
International Monetary Fund (2000) World Economic Outlook 2000, New York: IMF.
Jefferis, K. (1998) ‘Botswana and Diamond-Dependent Development’, in Edge, W. and
Lekorwe, M. (eds) Botswana: Politics and Society, Pretoria: Van Schaik.
Jefferis, K. and Kelly, T.F. (1999) ‘Botswana: Poverty Amid Plenty’, Oxford Develop-
ment Studies, 27(2): 211–231.
Johnson, C. (1981) ‘Introduction: The Taiwan Model’, in Hsiung, J.S (ed.) Contemporary
Republic of China: The Taiwan Experience, 1950–1980, New York: Praeger.
Kaplinksy, R. (1991) ‘Industrialisation in Botswana: How Getting the Prices Right
Helped the Wrong People’, in Colclough, C. and Manor, J. (eds) States or Markets?
Neo-liberalism and the Development Policy Debate, Oxford: Clarendon.
Khama, S. (1980) ‘Addressing the Nation on the Occasion of the Tenth Anniversary of
Independence—30 September 1976’, in Carter, G. and Morgan, P. (eds) From the
Frontline: Speeches of Sir Seretse Khama, London: Rex Collings.
Leith, C. (2000) ‘Why Botswana Prospered’, unpublished paper.
Leftwich, A. (2000). States of Development: On the Primacy of Politics in Development,
Cambridge: Polity Press.
Lewis, S. (1993) ‘Policymaking and Economic Performance: Botswana in Comparative
Perspective’, in Stedman, S.J. (ed.) Botswana: The Political Economy of Democratic
Development, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Maundeni, Z. (no date) ‘The Public Policy Process in Africa: The Case of Botswana’,
paper prepared for ‘Botswana Leadership Development Programme’, coordinated by
the Department of Adult Education of the University of Botswana and Corde.
Maundeni, Z. (2001) ‘State Culture and the Botswana Developmental State’, paper pre-
sented to the Department of Political and Administrative Studies, University of Bot-
swana, January 25.
Mkandawire, T. (1998) ‘Thinking About Developmental States in Africa’, paper pre-
sented at the UNU-AERC workshop on ‘Institutions and Development in Africa’, UNU
Headquarters, Tokyo: Japan, October 14–15.
Mogalakwe, M. (1997) The State and Organised Labour in Botswana: ‘Liberal Demo-
cracy’ in Emergent Capitaism, Aldershot: Ashgate.
Molutsi, P. (1989a) ‘The Ruling Class and Democracy in Botswana’, in Holm, J. and P.
Molutsi (eds) Democracy in Botswana, Gaborone: Macmillan.
Molutsi, P. (1989b) ‘Whose Interests Do Botswana’s Politicians Represent?’, in Holm, J.
and Molutsi, P. (eds) Democracy in Botswana, Gaborone: Macmillan.
Molutsi, P. and Holm, J. (1990) ‘Developing Democracy When Civil Society is Weak:
The Case of Botswana’, African Affairs, 89(356): 323–341.
Morton, B. and Ramsay, J. (1994) The Making of a President: Sir Ketumile Masire’s
Early Years, Gaborone: Pula Press.
Owusu, F. and Samatar, A. (1997) ‘Industrial Strategy and the African State: The Bot-
swana Experience’, Canadian Journal of African Studies, 31(2): 268–299.
Parson, J. (1981) ‘Cattle, Class and the State in Rural Botswana’, Journal of Southern
African Studies, 7(2): 236–265.
Botswana as a small developmental state 201
Parsons, N. (2000) Botswana History Pages, ‘Economy’, October, available online at:
http://ubh.tripod.com/bw/bhp13.htm# (accessed 25 November 2013).
Picard, L. (1980) ‘Bureaucrats, Cattle and Public Policy: Land Tenure Change in Bot-
swana’, Comparative Political Studies, 13(3): 313–356.
Picard, L. (1987) The Politics of Development in Botswana: A Model for Success?,
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Republic of Botswana (1996) Presidential Task Group – A Framework for a Long Term
Vision for Botswana, Gaborone: Government Printers.
Republic of Botswana (1997a) National Development Plan 8 1997/8–2002/03, Gaborone:
Government Printers.
Republic of Botswana (1997b) Presidential Task Group – Vision 2016: Towards Pros-
perity For All, Gaborone: Government Printers.
Robi, M. (1994) ‘Economic Policy for the 21st Century’, in Brothers, S., Hermans, J. and
Nteta (eds) Botswana In the 21st Century, Gaborone: BotswanaSociety.
Samatar, A. (1999) An African Miracle: State and Class Leadership and Colonial Legacy
in Botswana’s Development, Portsmouth: Heinemann Press.
Samatar, A. and Oldfield. S. (1995) ‘Class and Effective State Institutions: The Botswana
Meat Commission’, Journal of Modern African Studies, 33(4): 651–668.
Somolekae, G. (1993) ‘Botswana and Democracy in Botswana: What Type of a Relation-
ship?’, in Stedman, S.J. (ed.) Botswana: The Political Economy of Democratic Devel-
opment, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Somolekae, G. and Lekorwe, M. (1998) ‘The Chieftaincy System and Politics in Bot-
swana, 1966–95’, in Edge, W. and Lekorwe, M. (eds) Botswana: Politics and Society,
Pretoria: Van Schaik.
Stedman, S.J. (ed.) (1993) Botswana: The Political Economy of Democratic Develop-
ment, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Stein, H. (2000) ‘The Development of the Developmental State in Africa: A Theoretical
Inquiry’, occasional paper, Copenhagen: Centre of African studies, University of
Copenhagen, December.
Theobald, R. and Williams, R. (1999) ‘Combating Corruption in Botswana: Regional
Role Model or Deviant Case?’, Journal of Commonwealth and Comparative Politics,
37(3): 117–134.
Tsie, B. (1998) ‘The State and Development Policy in Botswana’, in Hope, K.R. and
Somolekae, G. (eds) Public Administration and Policy in Botswana, Kenwyn: Juta.
Woo-Cumings, M. (ed.) (1999a) The Developmental State, New York: Cornell Univer-
sity.
Woo-Cumings, M. (1999b) ‘Introduction: Chalmers Johnson and the Politics of National-
ism and Development’, in Woo-Cumings M. (ed.) The Developmental State, New
York: Cornell University.
World Bank (1999) Botswana: A Case Study of Economic Policy Prudence and Growth,
Washington, DC: World Bank.
12 Small state security in Asia
Political and temporal constructions of
vulnerability
Alan Chong

Introduction and historical background


Any investigation of Asian small states’ security and foreign policies runs up
against the challenge of distinguishing objective ‘smallness’ from subjective
frames of analysis. This does not mean that social science cannot be applied to
Asian small states; but research on these states needs to start through the optic of
a historical empathy. Statehood was an import from the West, via colonialism,
and hence sovereignty as a recognizable institution begins only with the advent
of a post-colonial Asia. Small states, as a category of actorness, enter the dis-
course of empirical trends only when the post-colonial leaderships deploy the
propaganda claim that their new states have been vulnerable since inception.
Historically, pre-modern Asia has never produced its own narrative of small-
ness. The dominant political traditions of the time approached boundaries and
collective power in terms of mandala, negara, and pan-regional civilization. The
mandala was an inspiration from Buddhism, whose ideological footprint covered
much of present-day South Asia, Southeast Asia and even parts of present-day
southern China. The mandalic system of political order resembled a concertina-
like pattern of overlapping political realms presided over by a god king termed a
devaraja, whose legitimacy was purportedly derived from Providence. (Wolters
2004: 28–37) Following Buddhist principles, the devaraja acquired his seat
through divine revelation of his high personal merit and achievements that were
attributable to God. Though possessing an army, the key ramparts of his author-
ity lay in the architectural majesty of his temples, his court pageantry, martial
displays and the ability to marshal manpower for agriculture and building these
monuments to Providence. A single devaraja could also outrank any number of
other rivals if he could prove himself worthy of their tributes and protect them
and their peoples from physical and other-worldly harm. The devaraja ruled in
expansionary mode and claimed tributes from as many proximate and distant
realms as possible, using political agents to gather intelligence on the state of
loyalties on the peripheries of his mandala. In the resulting contest for alle-
giances, the idea of smallness was notably absent; in its place was the notion of
greater or lesser allegiance. Furthermore, the logic of the mandala dictated a
fusion between domestic and ‘external’ political concerns, a feature that con-
tinues to bedevil the modern small state.
Small state security in Asia 203
The negara represented a variation upon the mandalic system, widely prac-
tised across Southeast Asia, in which the proto-state – as anthropologist Clifford
Geertz characterized nineteenth-century Bali – manifested itself as what he
termed a ‘theatre state’. The performance in and around the Court of the local
potentate was the polity in itself. In Geertz’s own description,

. . . it was a theatre state in which the kings and princes were the impresarios,
the priests the directors, and the peasants the supporting cast, stage crew,
and audience. The stupendous cremations, tooth filings, temple dedications,
pilgrimages, and blood sacrifices, mobilizing hundreds and even thousands
of people and great quantities of wealth, were not means to political ends:
they were the ends themselves, they were what the state was for.
(Geertz 1980: 13)

Geertz goes on to assert that to be seen as an effectual political entity, the theatre
state had to represent itself as an ‘exemplary centre’ – not unlike the cosmology
of the mandalic system. It had to manifest in the eyes of its subjects the majesty
of heavenly order on earth. In this dispensation, the question of smallness did
not even arise. The criterion for effective proto-sovereignty across borders was
the degree of awe that the royal court could muster.
Much of the pan-regional Confucian culture typifying what is today called the
Northeast Asian sub-region, namely the two Koreas, Mongolia, Japan and China,
can be described as broadly similar to both the negara and mandala of South
and Southeast Asia. Confucian culture incorporated references to a mandate
from Heaven in court ceremonies, rituals and the imperial roles of the incumbent
monarch and his officials. Moreover, the Court had to behave in an exemplary
manner in rendering justice and instrumental delivery for the needs of the
common people (Gernet 1982: Chapters 3–4). The tributary system that con-
nected the Chinese Court and the vassal kingdoms of Korea and Mongolia is
well known as an expression of the majesty of the Emperor (or Empress) exer-
cising the mandate from above. Despite the rebellious political postures of the
vast majority of Japanese kingdoms, or Shogunates, the latter also imitated the
essence of Confucian politics in their governance of domestic and foreign
relations.
Looking at these patterns, it is clear why any inquiry into Asian small state
security must ask the constructivist question: How do modern twentieth-century
post-colonial leaders conceptualize what managing a modern small state means?
To find the answer, however, the colonial impact on Asian states must be briefly
surveyed as another complicating layer in the socialization of security percep-
tions. The advent of the European colonization of Asia, from roughly the late
1400s through till the mid-1960s, left an indelible impact in terms of population
groups’ identities, their mobilities, their positioning within an economic hier-
archy and finally their borders (Hunter 1966: Chapters 4–5; Mason 2005:
Chapter 11). European colonialism inscribed new practices upon the traditional
ways of Asian states and societies. Colonialism is by definition extractive and
204 A. Chong
intrusive in both economic and demographic senses. The Portuguese, Spaniards,
Dutch, British, French and Americans were in Asia to seek out raw materials for
fuelling the industrial revolution in Europe and North America. They imposed
imperialist systems of social and political organization upon the natives to sys-
tematize economic extraction, and also to re-settle their own surplus and unem-
ployed populations from the metropole. Cultural groupings that had oriented
themselves under the mandalic, negara and pan-regional Asian belief systems
suffered a rude shock when they had to adhere to notions of sovereignty and
fixed boundaries, as well as coping with Western demands for extra-territorial
rights and privileges. Some of the traditional Asian elites ruled with the support
and calculated tolerance of the new colonial masters, while others were summar-
ily removed from power altogether in the name of restoring peace and subservi-
ence to colonial economics. In territories such as Cambodia, Borneo, Burma, the
Dutch East Indies, Malaya, Philippines, Singapore and Vietnam, the colonial
masters encouraged immigration by sizable numbers of Chinese and ‘Indians’
(chiefly Tamils and Malayalees from South Asia) in order to expedite economic
development, since these races were seen as more inclined towards diligence,
sacrifice and rentier functions under forceful leadership than the indigenous eth-
nicities of Southeast Asia (Hunter 1966: 60–72). Where their leaderships were
pliable, the indigenous ethnicities were set against the imported races by being
employed in less sensitive colonial government posts to police public order and
traffic flows. In these ways, the colonial impact redrew and fixed the modern
borders of Asia, while heightening inter-racial discord under the cold logic of
economic exploitation.
The modern Asian small state’s perspective comes into being when the
‘agency’ of the post-colonial sovereign state attempts to reconcile its fixed terri-
torial nature with the ‘structure’ of nationalisms that straddle borders, the global
economic system and issues of international order as determined by the actions
of Great Powers. As the Malayan Representative to the United Nations com-
mented, barely four months after Malaya gained independence from the United
Kingdom, under Cold War conditions ‘communist terrorism in Malaya had
aroused interest in America about Malaya and had resulted in publicity without
our own effort’ (Ismail 2009: 6).
Malaya was approximately one-third the territorial size of the neighbouring
newly-independent archipelagic state of Indonesia, whose foreign policy was
oriented towards Maoist China and the USSR, and Malaya’s population was
approximately 8 per cent of Indonesia’s at that time. The Malayan government
found common cause with the departing British colonial power in suppressing a
Communist insurgency, while the nationalist politicians in Jakarta entertained
the notion of solidarity among all anti-colonial forces, including left-wing parties
and trade unions. Furthermore, Maoist China retained a special channel of socio-
cultural influence amongst the ethnic Chinese citizens of Malaya, who consti-
tuted approximately one-third of the total population.
The Cold War had indeed foisted upon much of Asia a new combination of
demographic and geographical disparities with ideological insecurity. In the
Small state security in Asia 205
checkerboard interpretations of Moscow, Beijing and Washington, small states
were either ‘beachheads’ for wider regional domination and revolution, or ‘weak
but strategically important allies’, to be propped up. One can go on to trace the
mirrored logics between the Americans ‘rescuing’ South Korea between 1950
and 1953 and the Chinese and Soviets ‘arming the fraternal’ Socialist Republic
of Vietnam between 1950 and 1975, extending these subsequently to any number
of proxies throughout Asia. The ‘domino theory’ espoused by the Eisenhower
Administration in the mid-1950s crystallized a highly rigid Cold War narrative
of vulnerability for the non-Communist small states of South Vietnam, Laos,
Cambodia, Burma, Malaya and Singapore. Taiwan, too, could fit into such a
logic if the case were made in relation to the shipping lifelines transiting Tai-
wanese waters en route to South Korea and Japan. In South Asia, Pakistan and
even supposedly non-aligned India and Sri Lanka were seen as bulwarks against
Soviet and Chinese encroachments westward and southward.
This coincidence of Cold War political constructions of vulnerability with the
formal independence of these Asian small states resonates with the editors’ pro-
posal in Chapter 1 of this volume, to adhere to a qualitative and relational defini-
tion of the small state, and with their view that such definitions must start with
the small state’s power weaknesses. The small state is theoretically powerless to
protect itself from determined attacks from abroad; it is powerless to assert its
autonomy under most circumstances, and is therefore capable of only a highly
circumscribed range of reactions; it is powerless to affect the ‘games’ being
played on the international stage; and it is ultimately powerless in its position as
a miniscule player on that stage.1 This fits perfectly with the present chapter’s
preference for a constructivist approach to the study of Asian small states.2 Asian
small states define their weaknesses in security in relation to an imported polit-
ical form, namely the nation-state, and to their leaders’ perceptions – in this per-
spective – of dangers lurking in the wider international order either for their
recently demarcated borders or the constitution of their domestic societies.
Nonetheless, a caveat should be made here that powerlessness is not a finite and
irredeemable condition. The creative employment of soft power by some Asian
small states defies ‘conventional’ readings of their powerlessness. (Chong and
Maass 2010)
The remainder of this chapter seeks to articulate a set of general features of
Asian small state security by examining the security experiences of two small
states: Sri Lanka and Singapore. Placed respectively in South and Southeast
Asia, each of these has experienced significant internal dissension affecting its
foreign relations and external security. Such a pattern is both historical in the
Asian region, and consistent with the findings of many Commonwealth
Secretariat-inspired reports on the international plight of small states (Charles et
al. 1997). Each state has also confronted the question of power projection by its
larger neighbours, some of whose behaviour verged on the predatory and directly
threatened the small states’ autonomy. Against the larger evolving backdrop of
an Asia transiting from colonialism to post-colonial independent statehood, both
states today exemplify the new Asia coming to terms with a regional
206 A. Chong
international society (Chong 2011) that expects relatively constant adherence to
new norms of sociality and management of conflicts without resort to overt
military action. These are, in turn, the minimum prerequisites for a society hos-
pitable to Asian small states.
Each case study is organized in three thematic sections: internal sources of
insecurity and coping strategies, namely state and nation-building issues; exter-
nal sources of insecurity and coping strategies; and the present and future chal-
lenges to intermestic security. The shorthand term ‘intermestic’ (i.e. a
combination of international and domestic) reflects the fact – also highlighted in
this chapter’s conclusions – that the management of small states’ problems
requires constant calibration between domestic and external pressures. The polit-
ical spaces attached to their respective sovereignties admit very little margin for
error if statehood and nationhood are not to be called into question.

Sri Lanka: security as intermestic from Cold War to


post-Cold War

Internal security as a state and nation-building issue: colonized race


and reverse justice
As an island state of nearly 65,000 km2 lying off the southern tip of the Republic
of India (3.3 million km2), the Democratic Socialist Republic of Sri Lanka is
dwarfed by its giant neighbour. Yet its name, ‘Sri Lanka’, derived from the san-
skrit language indigenous to much of South Asia and other Buddhist cultures,
translates as ‘venerable island’. Lanka, its ancient, shortened name, was closely
associated with dynasties that were founded on the island by royal migrants from
what is today the Indian mainland. Buddhism arrived in this way when the son
of the Mauryan king, Ashoka, came from the mainland to spread the message of
Gautama Buddha to the reigning Lankan monarch, Devanampiya Tissa. Tissa
was so impressed by Buddha’s teachings that he embraced the new faith and
compelled his subjects, the Sinhala population, to do likewise. The Sinhalese
were already religiously inclined in their own fashion, having derived their col-
lective identity from the symbols Sinha (lion) and Hela (pristine or pure).
Already skilled craftsmen and monument builders, they applied their energies to
celebrate their new religion by perfecting statues of Buddha and adorning
temples and palaces with Buddhist motifs. This picture of the ancient Lanka
retains clear echoes of the aforementioned mandalic and negara influences, but
more importantly, it signified the centrality of the Buddhist religion to the cul-
tural identity of the majority of the indigenous population.
The advent of British colonialism, by the 1700s, introduced a sizable Tamil
population in the northern part of the island through officially-encouraged migra-
tion from southern India. It is worth noting that Tamils had settled in Sri Lanka,
and practised Hinduism, long before the British arrival. What changed was the
British logic of actively encouraging Indian, or ‘Estate’, Tamils to settle in Sri
Lanka to operate the coffee and tea plantations that the British saw fit to
Small state security in Asia 207
introduce to the island. They settled in the hill country in and around Kandy in
the centre of the island and in the northern Jaffna peninsula. Collectively, the
Tamils consistently formed the second largest ethnic population on the island.
But the majority Sinhalese, comprising 70 per cent of the island’s population,
has never regarded the Tamils – especially the Indian Tamils – as a natural part
of any Sri Lankan nation (Malik et al. 2009: 314–315).
Upon achieving independence from the British in 1948, the Sinhalese-
dominated government interpreted decolonization to mean reversing the privi-
leges accorded by the British to the Indian Tamils. The Sri Lankan Tamils were
also quickly disenfranchised by Sinhalese government policies that sought to
establish a post-colonial narrative treating them as marginal subjects, who had
enjoyed colonial favour while the British rulers discriminated against Buddhist
customs and the Sinhala language. As one scholar observed, ‘the fundamental
sources of the [long running] ethnic conflict in Sri Lanka can be traced to a spe-
cific historical context of the evolution of a multi-ethnic society under a mono-
ethnic state’ (Sahadevan 2012: 48). Yet another scholar took the view that state- and
nation-building was artificially rendered coterminous by strategically ‘othering’
rival ethnicities within the same territorial space (Krishna 2010: 220). Although
Indian Tamils elected six representatives to the first parliament in 1947, they lost
their seats quickly thereafter, since the Sinhalese-dominated government refused
citizenship to all Indian Tamils. Despite further fits and starts in Indian Tamils’
political representation, between 1952 and 1977 there were no Indian Tamils in
parliament at all (Malik et al. 2009: 325).
At the same time, all Tamils in Sri Lanka were widely perceived as profiting
from the preferences accorded them by the British, including their facility with
the English language, and hence their better performance in business, the profes-
sions and in academia vis-à-vis the Sinhalese. The post-colonial government,
exercising sovereignty from its seat in Colombo, sought to deport most Tamils
to either India or Pakistan, triggering much friction with those similarly inde-
pendent states. It was a portentous sign that, in 1964, Sri Lankan Prime Minister
Sirimavo Bandaranaike and Indian Prime Minister Lal Bahadur Shastri negoti-
ated arrangements to grant Sri Lankan citizenship to nearly 300,000 of the
975,000 Indian Tamils while deporting 525,000 of the remainder to India. The
remaining 150,000 were to be vetted and subject to further negotiation as to
whether they were fully stateless persons. This issue has yet to be resolved
(Malik et al. 2009: 315).
Meanwhile, successive governments headed by Sinhalese Presidents enacted
discriminatory policies against the Tamils in the name of a Sinhalese anti-
colonial nationalism. Chief among these were the declaration of Sinhala as the
only official language of the new nation (in 1956); a declaration that it was the
solemn duty of the state to protect and advance Buddhism (in 1972); various
strategies of economic development that favoured the Sinhalese acquiring
cultivable land at the expense of ethnic minorities; and finally, affirmative action
policies ‘designed to redress the incongruence between ethnic proportions and
public goods, especially in access to higher education and professional courses’
208 A. Chong
(Krishna 2010: 222). The last policy basically meant giving privileged access to
Sinhalese to facilitate their occupational mobility over other ethnicities. It was
no surprise that the Tamils in Sri Lanka resorted to violence by 1977, culminat-
ing in a full-blown insurgency by 1983, when Sinhalese extremists staged anti-
Tamil riots across the country. The lead Tamil insurgent grouping emerged as
the Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam (LTTE) as a result. Despite mediation by
India and its peacekeeping presence in northern Sri Lanka between 1987 and
1990, the UN’s good offices, and even Norwegian mediation, the Sri Lankan
government resolved to crush the LTTE insurgency through military means.
They succeeded in 2009, by destroying the final LTTE stronghold in the Jaffna
peninsula, and killing its leader in the process.
The efforts made for state and national consolidation by the newly inde-
pendent Sri Lankan government after 1948 were thus clearly equated with an
internal security issue. The ‘security’ of the politically awakened and historically
sentimental Sinhalese majority was translated by its leaders into a struggle to
establish a largely mono-ethnic nation-state. The socio-political injuries of colo-
nialism were to be avenged by the newly enfranchised, hitherto marginalized,
ethnic majority, repeating a cyclical political pattern of hegemony. Internal
security under the succession of Sinhalese leaders meant literally ensuring one
nation’s subjugation of another within the same state. Such is one half of the
canvas of Sri Lanka’s elite perception of small state security.

External sources of insecurity and coping strategies


There is an almost universal consensus among scholars that Sri Lankan foreign
policy routinely reflects domestic or ‘intermestic’ concerns. The above-
mentioned Sinhalese-Tamil conflict is the prime driver, followed by economic
development. However, India also enters the Sri Lankan intermestic sphere via
the Tamil disapora across the narrow Palk Strait separating the two countries.
As one scholar put it, ‘these are states whose peoples are organically con-
nected but politically divided by lines that are only arbitrarily designated
internal or international at particular historical moments’ (Rajagopalan 2005:
107). The Sri Lankan government’s mixture of dread and constructive engage-
ment vis-à-vis India was most clearly actualized in the ill-fated Indian peace-
keeping operation in the Jaffna Peninsula between 1987 and 1990. India’s
unrelenting anxiety about neighbouring insurgencies and irredentist move-
ments spilling over into its own fragile inter-ethnic relations has in fact pro-
voked Indian intrusions into the domestic spheres of all of its immediate
neighbours in South Asia. The most obvious case is the Indian concern with
Islamist terrorism – reinvigorated since 9/11 – in Pakistan, Afghanistan and
Bangladesh; but New Delhi has also exercised its military muscle all around
its peripheries, from Kashmir to Sri Lanka’s Jaffna Peninsula and to the Mal-
dives, where Indian forces intervened to restore a sitting President in
November 1988. Most recently, New Delhi has despatched a sizable fleet to
participate in the Gulf of Aden multinational anti-piracy patrol.
Small state security in Asia 209
It was this fear of India actively policing its extended security frontier that
drove Sri Lankan Prime Ministers during the better part of the Cold War to
propose initiatives such as the Indian Ocean Zone of Peace (Kodikara 1980).
Colombo sought to dissuade both Cold War superpowers from any active rivalry
in the Indian Ocean, which could only draw in India to Sri Lanka’s detriment.
The Zone of Peace concept overlapped conveniently with Colombo’s enthusias-
tic participation in the Non-Aligned Movement, where India was also an active
member (Kodikara 1980: 883–887). Opposing superpower-led polarization that
would distract newly-decolonized and Third World states from their focus on
national development, the Zone simultaneously served as a clarion call to avoid
basing foreign policies on notions of political and military competition. In 1974,
Prime Minister Sirimavo Bandaranaike’s words were equally directed at New
Delhi, Washington and Moscow:

My proposal was that the Indian Ocean should be made a Zone of Peace. It
should be free of the presence of Big Powers in a state of rivalry and com-
petition; that military installations established by these Powers should be
dismantled and removed; and that it should be secured for lawful commer-
cial and other peaceful uses and pursuits.
(quoted in Kodikara 1980: 880)

In fact, the Peace Zone concept has never progressed beyond examination by an
ad hoc committee at the UN. Its value in its Cold War context was probably
more rhetorical and moral in nature. In concrete terms, it legitimized Colombo’s
intermestic attempts to tie India’s hands in the eyes of regional and global public
opinion, while also politically justifying Colombo’s welcome for the Americans’
countervailing presence on the British-owned Indian Ocean island of Diego
Garcia (Manor and Segal 1985). As President Jayawardene said in the late
1970s, ‘I don’t know if we want the Americans to get out of the Indian Ocean. If
there is a change in India and there is some threat to Ceylon [i.e. Sri Lanka] we
might need Diego Garcia’ (quoted in Manor and Segal 1985: 1179). More
recently, with the rise of Chinese power across East Asia, Sri Lanka has wel-
comed Chinese economic investments and arms sales as a pointed counterbal-
ance to India. Sri Lanka has declared its appreciation for Chinese military
supplies in its fight against the LTTE insurgents (DeSilva-Ranasinghe 2011). In
contrast, the Western states have threatened Colombo with sanctions over the
brutalities committed by its military forces in its war against the LTTE.
Courting rival Great Powers has remained an essential tool of Colombo’s
foreign policy in the face of geopolitical threats created by a larger neighbour and
by other Great Powers themselves. This still holds good some four decades later,
even though Sri Lanka continues to be a member of the South Asian Association
for Regional Cooperation (SAARC). More spectacularly, in 2009, China approved
Sri Lanka’s application for dialogue partner status in the Shanghai Cooperation
Organization, a grouping of Central Asian states that includes China and Russia
but includes India only as an observer (DeSilva-Ranasinghe 2011: 62).
210 A. Chong
Present and future challenges to intermestic security
Since independence, Sri Lankan security policies have been dominated by the
internal ethnic strife roiling its politics. Despite foreign allegations of brutality
and human rights violations during the LTTE’s final defeat in 2009, the logic of
exclusionist nationalism at home remains politically appealing for the current
President, Mahinda Rajapaksa, and his party, the United People’s Freedom Alli-
ance. He is perceived by most Sinhalese as the ‘hero’ who ended the LTTE’s
reign of terror, and his government can tout their success in resettling 250,000
refugees and rebuilding essential infrastructure in the war zone, seeding a steady
economic recovery (Goodhand 2012: 132–133). No amount of foreign pressure
is likely to dislodge the current Sinhalese-dominated regime from power, and the
leadership seem to find an international pariah status for the Sri Lankan state tol-
erable so long as economic growth and general inter-state peace in South Asia
are not seriously disturbed. Indeed, Rajapaksa has urged Sri Lankan diplomats to
wage a more aggressive propaganda effort worldwide to counter LTTE sympa-
thizers’ ‘misinformation campaign’ (TamilNet 2013; ZEENEWS.com 2012).
Meanwhile, relations with the great powers continue in a status quo with the
Indian power balanced by Chinese influence, even as relations with the West are
strained over the human rights imbroglio stemming from the war against the LTTE.
In this respect, Colombo exhibits classic small state behaviour vis-à-vis the great
powers, namely hedging its bets and courting rivals. But the bigger source of insec-
urity stems ironically from the blind domestic pursuit of Sinhalese nationalism.
The military victory over the Tamil insurgency may prove illusory over the long
term if Tamils are compelled to seek redress in ever more violent ways through the
familiar intermestic dimension. One avenue of indirect pressure from the Tamil
diaspora has arisen through US pressures for Sri Lankan government account-
ability before the UN Human Rights Council. In 2013, this campaign was actively
abetted by the NGO Human Rights Watch and by an independent journalist whose
docudrama, ‘No Fire Zone: the Killing Fields of Sri Lanka’ was screened before
the UN Human Rights Council (Cumming-Bruce 2013).

Singapore: security as intermestic from Cold War to


post-Cold War
Like Sri Lanka vis-à-vis India, Singapore is an island state at the southern tip of
a larger neighbour – Malaysia – separated by two narrow bodies of water, the
Straits of Johor and the Straits of Malacca. Although Malaysia occasionally
regards itself as small in relation to the rest of Asia and the developing world,
Singapore can only boast a territorial land area of 715 km2 in comparison to
Malaysia’s 330,000 km2. Lying immediately southward across the equally
narrow Straits of Singapore is the Republic of Indonesia’s expanse of 1.9
million km2 in land area and 1.8 million square kilometres of maritime sover-
eignty. The latter statistic is relevant to Singapore’s security calculations, since
Indonesia has officially defined itself under international law as an archipelagic
Small state security in Asia 211
state and has officially claimed large swathes of surrounding sea areas either as
part of its formal jurisdiction or as its exclusive economic zone. Since Singa-
pore’s economy thrives largely upon trade, financial flows and hosting trans-
portation links across Southeast Asia, East Asia, Oceania and the Middle East,
access to maritime and air spaces is a multi-dimensional security concern.
Aside from the evident need for straightforward territorial defence, the socio-
political integrity of the island’s politics must also serve to ensure that the gov-
ernance of the state does not invite any undesirable foreign intervention that
might precipitate a complete collapse of the Republic’s legally recognized sover-
eignty. This internal security dimension was born of the circumstances surround-
ing the Republic’s struggle for Federation with the newly independent state of
Malaya in September 1963, and its subsequent ejection from that very Federa-
tion of Malaysia, which precipitated independence in August 1965.
Singapore did not exist as a continuous and distinct entity in ancient times. If
not for the British East India Company’s acquisition of the island for entrepôt
trade in 1819, it could have just as easily faded into obscurity as one of the many
islets straddling the narrow straits linking the Indian Ocean and the South China
Sea. The British colonial administration contributed significantly to Singapore’s
political evolution as a society and polity distinct from the rest of the colonized
Malay world. London instructed its representatives to preserve a political culture
conducive to trade by granting crown colony status to the island, investing it
with its own full-time Governor. Singapore embraced functionally streamed
immigration from India, China and even the Middle East, so that the governor
and his officials presided over ‘communities’ of Chinese, Indians, Arabs and
Malays, represented by a few approved leaders drawn from backgrounds in com-
merce, the local civil service or village administration. The colonial bureaucracy
pigeonholed the races according to economic aptitude (Swettenham 1948:
123–172, 231–233). The Chinese were good for all occupations, but especially
for manual labour in the godowns, factories and plantations, and for operating
their own trading companies. The ‘Indians’, mostly Tamils, Malayalees, Gujara-
tis, and Sinhalese, were either brought in as convict labour or encouraged to
emigrate to Singapore by the British to alleviate poverty in India; they were seen
as best deployed for public works projects and plantations, with a minority estab-
lishing efficient money-lending services for themselves and the general public.
Finally, the Malays were treated as fit for serving as policemen, security guards,
waiters, drivers and fishermen. The Arabs were meanwhile tolerated by the colo-
nial masters as important players in strengthening the merchant base that estab-
lished Singapore’s reputation as a free port for intra-Asian trade.
This motley profile was to influence Singapore’s subsequent nationalist pol-
itics. While nationalist awakenings in Malaysia and Indonesia were obsessed
with restoring an indigenous racial majority’s political dominance – i.e. the
Malays, Javanese and so forth – and revolted against blatant abuses of colonial
power that exploited cheap native labour and natural resources for maximum
profits, Singaporean nationalism was expressed in gentler tones against both the
British and the temporary Japanese rulers during World War II. Before the end
212 A. Chong
of the War, the different racial communities tended to regard Singapore as a tem-
porary home, with perhaps the exception of the Malays. They were tuned in to
the respective nationalist currents in India, China and the Middle East, on the
assumption that they would ultimately return to their ancestral homelands. The
British had succeeded for more than a century in inculcating a culture of prag-
matic loyalty devoid of emotional rootedness. There were negligible attempts at
democratic consultation with the colonial subjects, except where the Governor
chose to listen to the appointed Asian members of the Legislative Council.
Moreover, the British clamped down on most manifestations of virulent anti-
British movements.
It required the Japanese Occupation to stir a deeper anti-colonial awakening.
One immediate impact was the visible emasculation of the British rulers’ pres-
tige in the eyes of their erstwhile colonial subjects, due to their surrender and
subsequent humiliation by Japan (Christie 1998: Chapter 4). While the Japanese
reproduced their emphatic anti-Chinese policies drawn from occupied China,
they largely continued with Britain’s ‘divide and rule’ attitude towards race rela-
tions in Singapore. They went further, however, in deliberately stoking antago-
nism amongst the races, supporting Malay nationalism, and arming Indian
nationalists for a possible insurrection in British India in tandem with a Japanese
invasion. The Chinese were subject to discrimination, torture and summary
executions. After the Japanese were defeated by Allied arms elsewhere in the
Pacific, the returning British only awakened further soul-searching amongst their
subjects by mismanaging the return to civilian rule, tolerating widespread cor-
ruption and misplaced reconstruction priorities, and – what was worse – institut-
ing a citizenship plan that sharply distinguished between permanent subjects,
whose domicile was defined by their birth or by their length of stay in Singapore
(Chew 1991: 361–362; Christie 1998: 188–201). Such policies catalysed the
widespread feeling amongst the ‘Singaporean’ population of all races that the
British could not be counted on to safeguard their interests. Unprecedented
large-scale anti-British protests across the Straits of Johor, in Malaya, could not
fail to suggest to the people of Singapore that they might struggle in tandem to
throw off colonial rule, albeit with a different trajectory.
In Singapore, the British did not resort to the truncheon to squelch nationalist
dissent. Indeed, once the agitation by the nationalists in Malaya reached the
point of no return, London’s need to hold on to Singapore diminished tremen-
dously. Singaporean nationalists themselves had to start reflecting: Could Singa-
pore be assimilated into the Malayan population on grounds of intertwined
histories and economic viability? Most Singaporean nationalist parties adopted
the platform of multiracialism, offering all races an equal stake in the future of
the post-colonial nation-state (Chew 1991: 362–363). The leading parties of the
1950s and the 1960s, the Labour Front and the People’s Action Party (PAP),
both envisaged an ultimate federation within a Malayan political milieu
entrenched along racial lines and ethnic affirmative action. The British favoured
Singapore’s federation with Malaya, since it would solve their security and eco-
nomic conundrums once they granted independence to Singapore.
Small state security in Asia 213
As it turned out, the politics of Singapore’s brief membership in the newly-
named Federation of Malaysia accentuated the differences in governing their
respective post-colonial societies. For a start, Singapore’s demographic profile
included a 75 per cent Chinese majority, while Malaysia’s exhibited a 60 per
cent bumiputra Malay majority. While Singapore’s PAP envisaged a future
founded upon evolutionary multiracialism and meritocracy, the reigning coali-
tion of ethnically-based parties in Kuala Lumpur espoused a deeper commitment
to restore the rights of the indigenous people of the land – the ethnic Malays who
spoke Bahasa Melayu and practised Islam as their sole religion. These differ-
ences could not be reconciled, especially after large-scale racial riots broke out
in 1964 between Chinese and Malays, and both ruling parties decided that the
Federation could not survive with Singapore and Malaysia as equal partners.
This history helps to delineate a Singaporean internal security problematique.
At the moment of retrieving independence by virtue of being asked to leave the
Federation in 1965, the independent Singapore was bereft of a natural and reli-
able economic hinterland; there was no reliable historical precedent for manag-
ing its independence under modern capitalism; moreover, Singaporean society
was distinctively constituted in multiracial terms, but also through its practice of
multi-ethnic representation within a single political party. Added to this were the
lessons learned against allowing ethnic preferences to solely determine political
priorities, or letting foreign models of governance (from Malaysia or elsewhere)
be imitated by local political protagonists. Subjectively, all such factors fed into
a multi-dimensional ‘survivalist paranoia’ that justified authoritarian measures to
bridle the liberal democracy and socialism that had served initially as foreign
inspirations to nationalist parties in Singapore. As the first PAP Prime Minister,
Lee Kuan Yew, embarrassingly put it, island nations seemed like political jokes
when he started out in politics in the 1950s (Wilairat 1975: 30). The nascent Sin-
gaporean national security culture was designed to pre-empt this dire scenario.
Singapore’s internal security was tellingly likened by the country’s eloquent
first Foreign Minister, S. Rajaratnam (Rajaratnam 1987: 533–539), to a small
ship navigating tumultuous seas. The official inference was that the passengers
ought not to quarrel and fight amongst themselves, much less argue and mutiny
against the captain and his crew. In return for obedience and support, the captain
would select the most talented and capable members for his crew from among
the passengers. With this internal harmony in place, the entire ship of state
would sail safely across time and through any adversity. The ‘tight ship’ analogy
also meant insulating the entire vessel against ‘undesirable’ ideological influ-
ences that could disrupt harmonious crew–passenger relations.
The two pillars of a Singaporean internal security culture accordingly became:
first, domestic political corporatism as a defence mechanism in the face of post-
colonial intermestic adversity; and second, making the Singaporean polity more
just and efficient than all its neighbourly rivals in Southeast Asia (Chong 2013:
69–71). Political corporatism, under the continuous dominant party rule of the
PAP since self-government in 1959, is manifested in terms of the wide range of
civic and socio-economic organizations such as the People’s Association; the
214 A. Chong
National Trades Union Congress, a high-level trade union confederation; the
Citizens Consultative Committees; the Inter-Racial Confidence Circles; the Sin-
gapore Employers’ Federation; the various foreign Chambers of Commerce; and
the network of Government-Linked Companies delivering essential services
such as power utilities, public transportation and telecommunications. Formal
and openly competitive opposition party politics is frowned upon. This orderly
picture has, however, been jolted by a series of electoral reverses suffered by the
PAP from 2011 onwards. It seems the ‘passengers’ have been feeling pressured
by the entry of foreigners aboard the ship, intensifying economic competition for
jobs, schools and housing places, and consequent alienation and disenchantment
with the leaders’ management (Chong 2012).
The second pillar of Singaporean internal security, the need to be ideologi-
cally distinct from its neighbours, seems to have better weathered the course of
time and change. It is defended through the discourse of a Singaporean demo-
cracy with Asian and other locally synthesized characteristics. These character-
istics entail grafting a constitutionally-defended, multiracial principle into the
electoral system; a Presidency with circumscribed powers to act as a check upon
the elected parliament and cabinet; the principle of meritocracy; unstinting vigil-
ance against persons and movements intending to violate Singapore’s cherished
multiracial peace; and the co-opting of a large range of civil society organiza-
tions (listed above) into a state-led national purpose. The mixture is deliberately
designed to construct a Singapore better than its larger neighbours in terms of
social justice and economic redistribution. In the long term, both pillars of
internal security are intended to showcase a viable Singapore existentially
defying its critics.

External sources of insecurity and coping strategies


Singapore’s external threats are intricately derived from its internal political
fears as well as its integration into a capitalist global economy. They fall into
three concentric circles: the first featuring Malaysia and Indonesia. The second
circle features the rest of Southeast Asia, wider Asia and the Great Powers;
while the third features the so-called ‘non-traditional security issues’ that encom-
pass economic security, environmental security and other human security topics.
In relation to Malaysia and Indonesia, there is a straightforward Singaporean
concern that the more incendiary currents of nationalistic politics, as played by
elites in Kuala Lumpur and Jakarta, will translate into political and military
adventures at Singaporean expense. There are plenty of ‘political baggage’
issues left over from the past as possible triggers, including territorial disputes
over the islands of Pedra Branca and its nearby islets, the maritime boundaries
extending into the Straits of Malacca, and parts of the Straits of Johor affected
by reclamation works on some of the Singapore-owned islands in the vicinity.
Other issues only recently, or partially, resolved have included disputes arising
from economic/commercial interdependence in the fields of water supply and
rail development. The Pedra Branca dispute went to the International Court of
Small state security in Asia 215
Justice in 2008 under mutual consent and the judgement consequently awarded
the main island to Singapore, leaving minor islets still subject to adjudication.
On the territorial defence front, Singapore remains wary of Malaysia’s unde-
clared political ambitions vis-à-vis the ‘island that separated from the mainland’,
and which now shows up the deficiencies in Malaysia’s political economy
simply by being a richer, yet smaller, multiracial neighbour. To insure against a
Malaysian invasion, the Singapore Armed Forces maintains a technologically
advanced and rigorously trained force of up to 300,000 personnel, inclusive of
reserves in the army, navy and air force. While this force is probably sufficient
to deter, and if necessary defeat, a Malaysian military still modernizing after
decades of specializing in domestic counter-insurgency against communist guer-
rillas, deterrence is probably a purely psychological gambit vis-à-vis the much
larger neighbour to the south, Indonesia (Huxley 2000).
With Indonesia, the ‘baggage’ underpinning Singaporean fears stems from
Jakarta’s attempt to confront both Singapore and Malaya through a low-intensity
war during the brief period in which the latter were federated into Malaysia.
Although Sukarno’s policy of ‘confrontation’ with both territories ended with
his removal in a coup that paved the way for a more pro-western President
Suharto, Singaporeans fear that Jakarta might again treat the island state as a
convenient political football should Indonesia fall back into extreme domestic
dissension. Such a moment in fact recurred in 1968, when Singapore executed
two Indonesian saboteurs it caught for perpetrating a bombing against a promi-
nent city building during Konfrontasi. Only Suharto’s goodwill stanched calls
from within his own government to invade Singapore in retaliation. Another
crisis moment was reached between 1999 and 2000, in the aftermath of the
Asian Financial Crisis, when two Presidents in succession – Habibie and Abdur-
rahman Wahid – threatened to teach the Singaporeans a lesson by joining hands
with Malaysia in severing water supplies to the island. If such discourse does
reveal latent strategic intentions, the Singapore Armed Forces will need to signal
to Jakarta that if ever the proverbial miniscule ‘poison shrimp’ is ingested – and
even if an invasion could destroy the smaller state’s practical sovereignty – it
will inflict an awful lot of damage on the predator.
In the second circle, Singaporean security perceptions were heavily framed
by the Cold War machinations of China, the USSR and the US, along with
manoeuvres at the UN, where the weaker and smaller states were always trying
to ‘tie up the Gullivers’ using diplomatic means. The Republic was born in the
midst of the Cold War, and directly experienced the dangers of infiltration and
sabotage by Communist agents throughout the 1950s and 1960s as well as Indo-
nesian saboteurs during Konfrontasi. Even after the Sino-Soviet split, Beijing’s
propaganda vilified the non-Communist nationalist elites across Southeast Asia
and pledged support for wars of revolution. Singapore became a target of the
Communist strategy of funding ‘open front activities’, such as trade unions, pro-
fessional and cultural organizations, and of mounting ‘black operations’ through
local newspapers. The USSR was geographically further away, but its support
for North Vietnam (and subsequently the reunified Socialist Republic of
216 A. Chong
Vietnam), and attempt to seed revolution southwards from Cambodia and Laos,
psychologically rattled the Republic’s planners. The increasingly muscular
Soviet military presence at Cam Ranh Bay and Danang, in Vietnam, reinforced
fears of intimidation and political blackmail by Moscow. Even the Americans
were initially suspected of, and caught, using the CIA in an attempt to bribe both
Singaporean intelligence officials and the PAP to do their bidding (Lee 2000:
500–501). Moreover, Premier Lee observed that the Americans tended to treat
their weak Asian allies in a heavy-handed manner whenever they had expended
their political utility (Lee 2000: 502–503). Yet among the Great Powers, Lee
tended to see the Americans in the most consistently positive light during the
Cold War. He defended Washington’s armed engagement in Vietnam as a neces-
sary holding operation that allowed Southeast Asian small states to muster psy-
chological and economic strengths to defeat the blandishments of Communist
propaganda through solid economic growth and wealth distribution. Moreover,
Washington’s Most-Favoured-Nation trading status was a boon for Singapore’s
economy.
After the Cold War, American friendship was retained even as Singapore
welcomed the return of a more normalized Chinese power and the reduced
Russian Federation into more constructive diplomatic roles within the Asia-
Pacific region. PAP leaders argued that a multiple, omni-directional and passive
balance between militarily powerful big and medium-sized powers would best
preserve an Asian peace (Leifer 2000: Chapter 4). In the new fluid conditions
where the Americans had to watch the Chinese as peer competitors, and the
Chinese similarly with Japan and India, the Singaporeans expected that these
‘multiple suns and planets’ would exert sufficiently cross-cutting security gravi-
tational pulls to cancel one another out, while simultaneously deterring any
potential Vietnams or Indonesias from diplomatic and military adventures at
Singapore’s expense. Fostering multilateral defence relations through joint exer-
cises of information exchange, personnel visits and tri-service exercises could
help sustain this fluid balancing, while Free Trade Agreements would bind the
big and medium powers into a win-win network of interdependence (Huxley
2000: 196–228).
Finally, the newly independent Singapore quickly learned the value of joining
international and regional organizations as strategic multipliers to offset the hard
military power of potential rivals and predators (Jayakumar 2011). Singaporean
diplomats co-founded the Forum of Small States (FOSS) as an informal caucus
at the UN to bring a measure of solidarity to small state positions that cut across
regions and national interests. FOSS also provided the UN Secretariat with a
pool of neutral states able to supply impartial chairmen and other intermediaries
for assorted UN missions. Singapore has, for instance, supplied chairs for the
UNCLOS negotiations in the early 1980s, the 1992 UNCED Conference in Rio
de Janeiro and the 1996 World Trade Organization Ministerial Conference in
Singapore. The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) is seen by
Singaporean policy makers as a ‘loose neighbourhood association’ that can help-
fully commit all its neighbours to the non-use of force in settling bilateral
Small state security in Asia 217
disputes. The informal diplomatic face-saving device known as the ‘ASEAN
Way’, that allows ASEAN members to opt out of ASEAN consensual declara-
tions, suits Singaporean interests since it defuses bilateral confrontations on
innumerable occasions. Frequent invocations of the ASEAN Spirit often allow
member states to gracefully climb down from looming diplomatic and military
fisticuffs (Chong 2011).
The third circle of external threats comprises ‘non-traditional security’ (NTS)
issues, such as economic security, environmental security and other forms of
human security such as the safety of foreign workers in Singapore, the safety of
Singaporean workers overseas, monitoring and stopping transnational criminal
activity operating through Singapore and the treatment of persons liable for
extradition to other countries. It might seem that Singapore’s chances of having
its voice heard are tied to its open economy – integrated closely with the major
Asian, European and North American states – but its concerns would register far
less if it did not also belong to ASEAN, APEC, WTO, IMF and the UN. These
multilateral institutions serve as agenda amplifiers and information junctions,
facilitating like-minded collaboration on issues of common interest (Dent 2002).
They also reduce Singapore’s transaction costs, should it need to muster a moral
majority to move a collaborative economic arrangement forward. The possibility
of treating trade and financial negotiations as a non-zero-sum exercise serves
Singapore’s interest in maintaining access to financial and commodities markets.
On the environmental front, Singapore’s informal coalition-building with the
FOSS and other like-minded states will helpfully draw attention to global
warming. Singapore’s technological research and development base in bioengi-
neering and civil engineering can offer widely applicable expertise in water
desalination, eco-friendly urban planning, urban food management and tropical
forest protection. Having solved its ‘small state’ environmental issues within a
densely populated, land-hungry setting, the Republic can deploy technical soft
power by offering the world small-scale, ‘value-added’ solutions for typical
urban challenges (Chong 2013: 75–76). Perhaps more tenuous and risky is Sin-
gapore’s attempt to manage, and sustain, an influx of foreign expatriates within
the confines of a small island state, drawing upon the globalized economy for
constant labour adjustments in step with the ebb and flow of housing projects
and other infrastructure upgrades on the island. Foreigners working in Singapore
have raised a host of issues for the city’s police and manpower agencies through
crimes they commit against both locals and other foreigners, as well as labour
exploitation issues in the transport, construction and domestic help sectors
(Chong 2012). These and other non-traditional security issues can only be solved
through entrenched international networking by Singapore’s security planners.

Present and future challenges to intermestic security


In many ways, Singapore’s profile both conforms to, and defies, a strict defini-
tion of a small state. On the one hand, its modern history began as an act of
British colonialism, when it became a port serving an entire portion of Her
218 A. Chong
Majesty’s Asian empire. The impact of Japanese occupation and nationalist
upheaval awakened the island’s population to questions of their destiny, trigger-
ing the search for nationhood and statehood. Only when this new nation-state-to-
be started to measure its size and dependence against its equally new
post-colonial neighbours did it become self-defined as a small state. On the other
hand, its internal and external sources of threats have compelled Singaporean
policy makers to appraise the solutions to those problems in fairly bold ways
that push the envelope in terms of advanced balancing behaviour and vigorous
participation in multilateralism. This extraordinary profile, combining histori-
cally constructed challenges with tremendous efforts to overcome them, places
the centre of gravity of Singapore’s security within the human dimension.
First, the Republic’s response to the historical legacies of population and the
prevailing insecurities of an ‘accidental nation’, comes close to an officially
encouraged culture of strategic paranoia. Security for Singaporeans means
relentlessly striving to overcome the menace of resource shortages, the envy of
potentially revanchist neighbours, and a complex interdependence with the
world’s major economies. PAP-run governments have, since 1984, promulgated
a ‘Total Defence’ concept to deal with the mostly intermestic nature of the
island’s security threats, with five dimensions: social, political, economic, psy-
chological and military. Social defence means maintaining the unity of the
people in the face of a common adversity; political defence involves a whole-
government approach to threats to the entire nation-state; economic defence has
been explained above; psychological defence refers to the need for the citizen to
be convinced of the nobility of defending the country and sacrificing one’s life
for it if needed; and military defence refers to the Singapore Armed Forces’
mission as already outlined. Total Defence reads well on paper, but it is likely to
be effective only when the citizens internalize it along with a large dose of stra-
tegic paranoia inculcated through the formal educational system. Strategic para-
noia simply means that security cannot be taken for granted; it is a bicycle that
needs to be ridden constantly so that the rider will not fall off. Eternal vigilance
is the price for security.
Second, the Republic’s concept of deterrence involves not just military ele-
ments but also ‘civilian deterrence’ by official and diplomatic action. Singa-
pore’s vigorous pursuit of bilateral and multilateral diplomacy seeks both to
generate a reputation for reliable partnership with like-minded states, and to
position the Republic as a constructive member of the international community.
The hope is that larger players whose actions could damage Singapore (directly
or incidentally) will think twice before going ahead with their plans, and instead
consider inclusive win-win approaches. Often, as a former Foreign Minister
points out, this dual thrust of deterrence and diplomacy is best achieved through
driving diplomacy from the backseat:

Sometimes, initiatives by Singapore are not well received by some officials,


especially from our larger neighbours, who see themselves as the ‘natural’
leaders of the region or in ASEAN. We have to manage these sensitivities
Small state security in Asia 219
carefully while ensuring that we achieve our substantial objectives. One way
is for our larger neighbours or even a third neutral country to reap the public
accolades.
(Jayakumar 2011: 26)

Many ASEAN declarations and the achievements of the Asia-Europe Meetings


(ASEM) have been generated in this way.

In conclusion: Asian small states as political and temporal


constructions
Insofar as Asian small states can offer a lesson for the generic study of small
state security, it should be centred upon the idea of their artificial construction.
The examples of Sri Lanka and Singapore are best understood against the back-
drop of Asia’s structural patterns of political evolution. As we have seen, one
cannot identify more than ‘proto-states’ in Asia’s ancient past. Small states were
inconceivable as natural and logical entities, even if polities could be classified
in terms of greatness and smallness of stature. It is fixed territoriality, imported
through the colonial experience, that introduces the modern notion of the Asian
small state. It compels the state to police its borders and filter interdependence
through those border controls. The consequent sense of danger from external or
internal ‘Others’ triggers huge insecurity, to be tackled by the small state’s polit-
ical and bureaucratic apparatuses.
What typical security considerations may one then impute to the Asian small
state? First, the political construction of the Asian small state means that it is
experimenting with a new form – its fixed borders, which divide the domestic
and external spheres. Within the domestic, smallness – as seen in both our case-
studies – invites paranoia about unfamiliar peoples encountering one another in
tight spaces under the polarizing question of recognizing citizenship. Citizenship
accords rights as well as duties: hence all applicants are scrutinized both by bur-
eaucrats and fellow-citizens for potential internal threats. This was the case of
the Sinhalese vs. the Tamils in Sri Lanka, and in the existential multiracial
experiment that is Singapore. One might even include the cases of the Philip-
pines and Bangladesh in this category (Iftekharuzzaman 1998; Morada and
Collier 1998). The securitization of ‘belonging’ is heightened in a confined ter-
ritory, where quarrels are louder and more emotional, and also linked with issues
of economic redistribution. Economic security is also fundamentally about who
can stay and who must leave the domestic space.
Second, the temporal construction of the Asian small state derives from the
political. The issue of ‘who goes and who stays’ within the domestic realm can
also be referred to history: but history itself can be reinterpreted to reverse the
categories of admission vs. ejection. As our case-studies show, moreover, tem-
poral understandings of small state security can also be derived from hegemonic
interpretations imposed from neighbouring states and Great Powers. If these
actors seek to turn the small state into a direct appendage of their security
220 A. Chong
perimeter, the classic small state dilemma articulated by Annette Fox and David
Vital comes into play (Vital 1967: Fox 1959). The weak fear the strong and
submit, but mostly in response to the dominant international and regional orders
of their time. In the cases studied in this chapter, the Cold War placed a new and
alien straitjacket upon small state security concerns. One can think of the cases
of Laos, Nepal and Taiwan, and, at a stretch, South Korea and North Korea
(Hickey 2000; Hey 2003; Kang 1998). Even for small states that were not so
clearly converted into proxies, big-power rivalries and designs of strategic ambi-
tion generated significant external security discomfort and distortion of domestic
priorities. Thus, one might say that in the light of this study, the international
security of the Asian small state is a product of accidental construction. Asia’s
ancient history and its present confirm that diagnosis through contrast.

Notes
1 See Chapter 1 in this volume.
2 A good survey of the ‘constructivist approach’ to state security analysis can be found
in (Zehfuss 2002: 10–23).

Bibliography
Ayoob, M. (1985) ‘The Primacy of the Political: South Asian Regional Cooperation
(SARC) in Comparative Perspective’, Asian Survey, 25(4): 443–457.
Charles, Dame E. (1997) A Future for Small States: Overcoming Vulnerability. Report by
a Commonwealth Advisory Group, London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Chew, E.C.T. (1991) ‘The Singapore National Identity: Its Historical Evolution and
Emergence’, in Chew, E.C.T. and Lee, E. (eds) A History of Singapore, Singapore:
Oxford University Press, pp. 357–368.
Chong, A. (2011) ‘A Society of the Weak, the Medium and the Great: Southeast Asia’s
Lessons in Building Soft Community among States’, in Astrov, A. (ed.) The Great
Power (mis)Management: The Russian–Georgian War and its Implications for Global
Political Order, Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing.
Chong, A. (2012) ‘Disciplining Globalization for Local Purposes? The Peculiarity of
Contending Singaporean Economic Nationalisms’, in D’Costa, A.P. (ed.) Globaliza-
tion and Economic Nationalism in Asia, Oxford: Oxford University Press,
pp. 177–201.
Chong, A. (2013) ‘Singapore and the Soft Power Experience’, in Cooper, A.F. and Shaw,
.T.M. (eds) The Diplomacies of Small States: Between Vulnerability and Resilience,
Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 65–80.
Chong, A. and Maass, M. (2010) ‘Introduction: The Foreign Policy Power of Small
States’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 23(3): 381–382.
Christie, C.J. (1998) Southeast Asia in the Twentieth Century: A Reader, London: I. B.
Tauris Publishers.
Cumming-Bruce, N. (2013) ‘Sri Lanka Urged to Complete Review of Alleged Atrocities’,
International Herald Tribune, 20 March, p. 3.
Dent, C.M. (2002) ‘Reconciling Multiple Economic Multilateralisms: The Case of Singa-
pore’, Contemporary Southeast Asia, 24(1): 146–165.
Small state security in Asia 221
DeSilva-Ranasinghe, S. (2011) ‘Another Bead in the “String of Pearls”? Interpreting Sri
Lanka’s Foreign Policy Realignment’, China Security, 19: 57–67.
Fox, A.B. (1959) The Power of Small States: Diplomacy in World War II, Chicago: Uni-
versity of Chicago Press.
Geertz, C. (1980) Negara: The Theatre State in Nineteenth Century Bali, Princeton, New
Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Gernet, J. (1982) A History of Chinese Civilization (2nd edition), New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Goodhand, J. (2012) ‘Sri Lanka in 2011: Consolidation and Militarization of the Post-
War Regime’, Asian Survey, 52(1): 130–137.
Hey, J.A.K. (ed.) (2003) Small States in World Politics: Explaining Foreign Policy Beha-
viour, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Hunter, G. (1966) Southeast Asia – Race, Culture and Nation, London: Oxford Univer-
sity Press for Institute of Race Relations.
Huxley, T. (2000) Defending the Lion City: The Armed Forces of Singapore, St Leon-
ard’s: Allen and Unwin.
Iftekharuzzaman (1998) ‘Bangladesh: A Weak State and Power’ in Alagappa, M. (ed.)
Asian Security Practice: Material and Ideational Influences, Stanford: Stanford Uni-
versity Press, pp. 315–337.
Ismail, A.R. (2009) Malaya’s First Year at the United Nations – As Reflected in Dr
Ismail’s Reports Home to Tunku Abdul Rahman, ed. I. Tawfik and K.B. Ooi, Singa-
pore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Jayakumar, S. (2011) Diplomacy – A Singapore Experience, Singapore: Straits Times Press.
Kang, D. (1998) ‘North Korea: Deterrence Through Danger’, in Alagappa, M. (ed.) Asian
Security Practice: Material and Ideational Influences, Stanford: Stanford University
Press, pp. 234–263.
Kodikara, K.U. (1980) ‘Continuity and Change in Sri Lanka’s Foreign Policy:
1974–1979’, Asian Survey, 20(9): 879–890.
Krishna, S. (2010) ‘Sri Lanka: Challenges in State Consolidation and Minority Integra-
tion’, in Paul, T.V. (ed.) South Asia’s Weak States: Understanding the Regional Insec-
urity Predicament, Stanford, California: Stanford Security Studies, Stanford University
Press, pp. 220–240.
Lee, Kuan Yew (2000) From Third World to First. The Singapore Story: 1965–2000,
Singapore: Times Editions.
Leifer, M. (2000) Singapore’s Foreign Policy: Coping with Vulnerability, London:
Routledge.
Malik, Y.K., Kennedy, C.H., Oberst, R.C., Kapur, A., Lawoti, M. and Rahman, S. (2009)
Government and Politics in South Asia. Vol. Six, Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.
Manor, J. and Segal, G. (1985) ‘Causes of Conflict: Sri Lanka and Indian Ocean
Strategy’, Asian Survey, 25(12): 1165–1185.
Mason, C. (2005) A Short History of Asia (2nd edition), Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.
Morada, N.M., and Collier, C. (1998) ‘The Philippines: State versus Society’ in Ala-
gappa, M. (ed.) Asian Security Practice: Material and Ideational Influences, Stanford:
Stanford University Press, pp. 549–578.
Nye Jr, J.S. (2004) Soft Power: The Means to Success in World Politics, New York, New
York: Public Affairs.
Rajagopalan, S. (2005) ‘South Asia’s Small States in World Politics’, in Hagerty, D.T.
(ed.) South Asia in World Politics, Lanham, Maryland: Rowman and Littlefield,
pp. 89–112.
222 A. Chong
Rajaratnam, S. (1987) ‘Interview No. 3 (14 December 1985)’, in Chan, H.C. and ul Haq,
O. (eds) The Prophetic and the Political: Selected Speeches and Writings of S. Rajarat-
nam, Singapore: Graham Brash and St Martin’s Press, pp. 517–540.
Sahadevan, P (2012) ‘Ethnic Peacemaking in Sri Lanka: The Politics of an Autonomy
Solution’, in Ganguly, R. (ed.) Autonomy and Ethnic Conflcit in South and South-East
Asia, Abingdon: Routledge, pp. 46–87.
Swettenham, F. (1948) British Malaya: an Account of the Origins and Progress of British
Influence in Malaya (3rd edition), London: George Allen and Unwin.
TamilNet (2013) ‘Canadian minister fails to address genocide, annihilation of Tamil ter-
ritory’, 3 February, available online at: www.tamilnet.com/cat.html?catid=79&view=s
ummary&year=2013&month=&date= (accessed 5 February, 2013).
Vital, D. (1967) The Inequality of States: A Study of the Small Power in International
Relations, Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Wilairat, K. (1975) Singapore’s Foreign Policy: The First Decade, Field Report Series
no. 10, Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Wolters, O.W. (2004) History, Culture, and Region in Southeast Asian Perspectives (2nd
edition), Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
ZEENEWS.com (2012) ‘Foreign Policy Challenges Remain for Sri Lanka’, 8 July, avail-
able online at: zeenews.india.com/news/south-asia/foreign-policy-challenges-remain-
for-sri-lanka_786148.html (accessed 28 November, 2012).
Zehfuss, M. (2002) Constructivism in International Relations: The Politics of Reality,
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
13 What Caribbean post-2015?
Developmental and/or fragile? Old
versus new security?
Timothy M. Shaw

. . . the circulation of commodities is one of the unifying aspects of Caribbean


history. . . . Globalization has not just happened to the Caribbean, the Caribbean
has participated in the making of globalization . . . four things . . . circulate:
people, capital, drugs and information.
(Bronfman 2007: 5–6)

Perceptions of Caribbean security are shifting with the world-wide emergence of


a ‘new security agenda’. . . . This blurred the boundaries between crime, migra-
tion, and war and the distinctions between criminal, migrant and enemy.
(Bowling 2010: 3)

Introduction
Severe security challenges are not new to the small states of the Caribbean.1
The Caribbean was the centre of piracy in the seventeenth century; in the
twenty-first, it is at the core of the global, especially Western hemisphere,
drugs trade and related criminal activities – what has been called the drugs/
gangs/guns/masculinities nexus (Bagley 2012; Naim 2006; Naylor 2005) – as
well as serving as a sensitive bellwether for environmental (UNEP 2008) and
economic (Pantin 2005) security. Transnational organized crime (TOC) is
nothing new in the region (Farer 1999; Madsen 2009), but it has become tech-
nologically more sophisticated: from sailboats to cell-phones, cutlasses to
AK47s. In former times, the response was colonialism and the Royal Navy.
Today the reaction is expressed through efforts for human security and devel-
opment (Bowling 2010: 279–309), focusing especially on environmental
security but also ‘citizen security’ (UNDP 2012a, b and c) and ‘private
security’ (Friman and Andreas 1999) – the last refuge for the middle class in
fragile states? This chapter uses both comparative/generic, and, specifically,
Caribbean, cases and insights (Harriott 2003; Townsend 2009; UNDP 2012b)
to illuminate old and new security challenges (Clarkson et al. 2013; Friman
2009; Glenny 2009)
224 T.M. Shaw
What is security in the Caribbean?
There are many definitions of the Caribbean(s): from the more ‘micro’ to the
more ‘macro’, the latter including diasporas in North America and Europe. To
identify and understand the security challenges of the region, this chapter seeks
to go beyond the ‘new regionalism’ of non-state (corporate and civil society)
formulations, towards recognition of the important informal and even illegal
dimensions (Fanta et al. 2013). The Caribbean can be understood as more than a
set of either formal or informal economies/societies/polities, however compat-
ible or otherwise these may be; it can also be addressed in terms of transnational
diasporas and/or as a nexus of drugs/gangs/guns/masculinities (Harriott 2003;
Townsend 2009). Hence the focus here on five sets of overlapping ‘trans-
national’ relationships that pose challenges to national and regional, human and
citizen securities (Bowling 2010): transnational families, civil societies, supply
chains including offshore finance/money-laundering (Palan et al. 2010; Vlcek
2008), crime networks and governance nexuses (Bronfman 2007).
To carry out this conceptual approach, several analytical traditions will need
to be employed; not just the notion of small island states as developed in inter-
national relations, international political economy and international development
studies, but also insights from anthropology, criminology, development, history,
security, sociology, transnational phenomena and especially ‘new regionalisms’
(Shaw et al. 2011). Together these will inform the prospects of several altern-
ative, analytical and applied, future scenarios for the Caribbean in the post-
Millennium Development Goals (MDG) world after 2015 (Singh and Izarali
2013). Will the region’s dominant character be more developmental (Kyung-Sup
et al. 2012), and/or fragile (Brock et al. 2012)? The Caribbean example suggests
that the heuristic, ‘varieties’ perspective could be extended from capitalisms to
versions of security. Islands are unavoidably outward-looking, and include
myriad diasporas, so their trans- and non-national relations are vulnerable to
both old and new security challenges (Bowling 2010: 31–36). This is true
regardless of whether the challenges arise from old or new imperial powers,
from the Europeans and US, or from the BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India and China)
and other emerging economies/powers like MIST (Mexico, Indonesia, South
Korea and Turkey) (O’Neill 2011).
In order to understand Caribbean small state security, this chapter juxtaposes
a set of ‘transnational’ relations (Brown 2011; Hale and Held 2011) – families,
civil societies, supply chains, crime networks and governance nexuses – with
notions of new as well as old security These seem to fit or resonate in the case of
today’s Caribbean(s). Both the transnational and the regional spheres include
economic, ecological, social and state relations, both formal and informal.
Together they can advance analyses of both the transnational and the regional
dimension (Laursen 2010), and they suggest a range of possible futures for
Caribbean actors before the end of the second decade of the present century
(Bishop 2013; Bishop and Payne 2010; Payne and Sutton 2007), as indicated in
the concluding paragraphs. But they also include old and new security
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 225
dimensions, both national and human. At the start of the present decade, the
Caribbean – reinforced by Central America – advanced a novel notion of ‘citizen
security’ in response to the ubiquitous guns/gangs/drugs/masculinities nexus
(UNODC 2012), as discussed below. As Ben Bowling (2010: 4) indicates:

. . . ‘new’ security threats are by no means restricted to the Caribbean. All


over the world, security sector leaders have become concerned with TOC,
drug trafficking, international terrorism, people smuggling, human traffick-
ing, money laundering and cybercrime. However, the history, geography,
and political economy of the Caribbean make it uniquely vulnerable to par-
ticular forms of transnational criminality.

Given the contemporary variety of regional security issues and responses at the
start of the second decade of the twenty-first century (Griffiths 2004; Harriott
2003; UNDP 2012a), the adoption of a ‘new’ transnational and regionally
defined perspective on today’s Caribbean would seem to be appropriate (Mace et
al. 2011). Orthodox frameworks cannot capture the diversity and dynamism of
contemporary regional security dilemmas, which operate not just at micro-,
meso- or macro-levels, or in inter- and non-state contexts, but also increasingly
include informal and illegal transactions at all levels and in all sectors (Soder-
baum and Shaw 2003). Enquiring into the interconnections among these three or
four distinct yet interrelated ‘regions’ also challenges traditional disciplinary
approaches (Singh and Izarali 2013).
Furthermore, inter-regional relations are also of growing salience, even when
duplicative or competitive rather than compatible or cooperative, as a reflection
of the proliferation of organized regions at all levels. This is especially so of
relationships built around the European Union (EU) with its 27–28 members,
such as the Asia-Europe Meetings (ASEM), Economic Partnership Agreements
(EPAs) (Laursen 2010), Mediterranean policies (Zank 2009), and sectoral
systems of pipeline projects and the like (Aalto 2008), as analysed by the aca-
demic networks NETRIS2 (Fanta et al. 2013) and GR:EEN,3 which share the
United Nations University’s Comparative Regional Integration Studies pro-
gramme4 as their hub. The distinctive, divergent character of different regions
has intensified as the current ‘global’ financial crisis has impacted them differ-
ently. Asia has been less affected than either the EU, the North American Free
Trade Area (NAFTA) or the North Atlantic; hence the focus in the UN Develop-
ment Programme’s (UNDP) 2013 Human Development Report (UNDP 2013)
on ‘The Rise of the South’.
Finally, the Caribbean region – like all other groups of Small Island Develop-
ing States (SIDS) – faces profound transnational environmental as well as eco-
nomic challenges, as regularly outlined at the annual Conferences of the Parties
to the UN Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCC) and other inter-
national debates on the follow-up to the Kyoto Protocol. The reporting of rel-
evant hazards by the UN Environmental Programme (UNEP 2008) and other
authorities is definitive; hence the advocacy of regional environmental networks
226 T.M. Shaw
like the Caribbean Natural Resources Institute (CANARI)5 and the establishment
of the Caribbean Community Climate Change Centre (CCCC) in Belize.6 In turn,
this is tending to shift the balance of prominence between the Association of
Caribbean States (ACS)7 and the Caribbean Community CARICOM,8 since the
former – despite being more ‘meso-’ in scale, including the isthmus as well as
the islands – has always been more concerned with the environment than the
latter.

Security and society in the Caribbean


What constitutes the Caribbean? . . . Among scholars, ‘the Caribbean’ is a
socio-historical category . . . it embraces the islands and parts of the adjoin-
ing mainland . . . and may be extended to include the Caribbean Diaspora
overseas. As one scholar observes, there are many Caribbeans. . . . In short,
the definition of the Caribbean might be based on language and identity,
geography, history and culture, geopolitics, geoeconomics, or organization.
(Girvan 2005: 304)

Societal developments and security challenges are closely intertwined in the


Caribbean. Keeping in mind the discussion in Chapter 2 on societal and human
security, this section explores the close relation between society and security in
the region.9 The ‘Caribbean’ can be more narrowly and broadly defined, ranging
from a set of all/some of the heterogeneous islands, to versions that include both
islands and mainland Central America – el gran caribe – and that stretch to the
extra-regional diasporas. In the formal terms of intergovernmental institutions,
this means progressing from smaller groups like the Organization of Eastern
Caribbean States (OECS), through CARICOM and the Caribbean Cooperation
and Development Committee (CDCC) to the ACS, which we have noted as
being more focused than others on the ‘green’ agenda. In terms of non-state
actor definitions, it means academic/civil society networks ranging from the
Caribbean Development Policy Centre (CPDC to the wider Coordinadora
Regional de Investigaciones Económicas y Sociales (CRIES) and Caribbean
Studies Association (CSA); and for the private sector, corporate structures
ranging from Unilever to Nestlé, from the Republic Bank to RBC or Scotiabank,
from Caribbean Airlines to Copa, or from B-Mobile and Flow to Digicel. In this
context, admittedly, spillover from the recent crisis in the form of the demise of
the Colonial Life Insurance Company (CLICO) and Stanford corporate empires
has had a continuing negative impact (ECLAC 2009). And cutting across such
geospatial and economic networks are linguistic communities: anglophone, fran-
cophone, Dutch-speaking and Spanish-speaking, along with several Creoles.
While a few analysts have recognized such diversity in the formal political
economy of the Caribbean, extending to the diasporic, few have extended their
analysis to the informal and illegal spheres. Just two chapters out of the 37 in the
encyclopaedic reader on The Caribbean Economy, edited by the late Dennis
Pantin (2005), treat levels of interaction/integration (Chapter 14 by Norman
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 227
Girvan) or diasporas/remittances (Chapter 29 by Wendell Samuel). The present
chapter seeks to go beyond such orthodoxies in view of the generic spillover
from the informal and illegal, which has important inter-regional implications,
not least for security.
The new regionalism(s) perspective (Shaw et al. 2011) has itself generated a
debate about the informal and illegal dimensions, which earlier and more formal
analyses at the end of the last century – from the UNU-World Institute for
Development Economics Research (WIDER) through to UNU-CRIS (Hettne
and Inotai 1994; Hettne et al. 1999; Soderbaum and Shaw 2003) – tended to
exclude even from what was then called ‘new’ regionalism (singular). Here,
however, I take the informal and illegal to be inseparable from the formal and
legal in terms of definitions and implications of Caribbean relations in the second
decade of the twenty-first century (Shaw 2010b).
Symbolic of the contrast between the formal and informal, the legal and
illegal, is the irony of the region’s de facto ‘free trade’ in drugs and guns (Bagley
and Walker 1994; Farer 1999; Friman 2009; Fiorentini and Peltzman 1997; Grif-
fiths 2004; Madsen 2009), contrasting with the myriad de jure restrictions on
trade in legitimate goods. The Caribbean continues to be a major route for drugs
even if Central America and now West Africa are also growing as entrepots:
there are variable ‘balloon effects’ depending on preferred drug and market
(Bagley 2012; Seelke 2011). Yet the Caribbean Single Market and Economy
Strategy (CSME) has been largely stillborn, while despite all efforts of the uni-
formed services, organized crime flourishes. Similarly, informal sector traders –
ubiquitous ‘higglers’ – circumvent myriad obstacles even when regular supply
chains cannot. And private security companies – both local and global, legal and
otherwise – are increasingly substituting for ineffective official police, thus
further redefining the state in the contemporary Caribbean: from colonial/inde-
pendent/dependent to transnational, and now on to narco-islands (Bishop and
Payne 2010).
The borderline between legal and illegal, formal and informal is of great
importance in the Caribbean given the fine line between, say, offshore banking
and money-laundering (Vlcek 2008), the jewelry trade and property develop-
ment. Hence the evolution of international efforts at regulation: from the Organ-
ization for Economic Cooperation and Development’s (OECD) Harmful Tax
Competition Initiative, to the same organization’s Financial Action Task Force
(FATF ),10 and its Caribbean office established in Trinidad and Tobago in the
early1990s,11 to Tax Information Exchange Agreements (TIEAs). The first
Obama Administration and the global financial crisis led, further, to the estab-
lishment of a Global Forum on Transparency and Exchange of Information for
Tax Purposes to monitor/peer review related progress. A variety of island juris-
dictions are involved in such transactions, ranging from Jersey and Mauritius to
Barbados, Bermuda, the Cayman Islands and Trinidad and Tobago (Palan et al.
2010). Hence the imperative to standardize and monitor forms of compliance at
the end of the first decade of the twenty-first century, intensified by the continu-
ing ‘global’ – or at least EU – economic crisis.
228 T.M. Shaw
Some of the diversity of the Caribbean can be captured in various sets of con-
temporary regional indicators, from GDP per capita and the Human Develop-
ment Index (HDI) to competitiveness and homicide rates. Here, I concentrate on
the seven Most Developed Countries (MDC) identified by the Caribbean Devel-
opment and Cooperation Committee (CDCC) of the Economic Committee for
Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC):12 Bahamas, Barbados, Belize,
Guyana, Jamaica, Suriname and Trinidad and Tobago. This sub-branch of
ECLAC includes nine ‘associated states’ from amongst the EU’s Overseas
Countries and Territories (OCTs), drawn from the British, Dutch and US islands,
several of which play important communications and financial roles, both legal
and otherwise.
Per capita purchasing power parity (PPP) incomes in the Caribbean stretch
from US$31,900 for the Bahamas to US$1,300 for Haiti (see Table 13.1). The
region likewise is mid-ranked in the World Economic Forum’s Global Com-
petitiveness Index (covering 133 countries):13 Puerto Rico at number 42, and
Barbados at number 44, lead, with Suriname (number 102) and Guyana
(number 104) trailing; in mid-field, Trinidad and Tobago is number 86,
Jamaica is number 91 and the Dominican Republic is number 95. The region
scores quite well in terms of the UNDP Human Development Index (UNDP
2009), being concentrated in the High and Medium HD categories. Only Bar-
bados is categorized as Very High, at number 37 out of 182; otherwise, the

Table 13.1 Caribbean incomes per capita, 2012

In constant US$ (PPP): CARICOM average US$6,439

Bahamas 31,900
Barbados 25,800
Trinidad and Tobago 20,400
Antigua and Barbuda 18,300
St Kitts and St Nevis 16,500
Dominica 14,400
Grenada 13,900
St Lucia 13,300
Suriname 12,600
St Vincent and the Grenadines 12,000
Dominican Republic* 9,800
Jamaica 9,300
Belize 8,900
Montserrat 8,500**
Guyana 8,100
Haiti 1,300
Average 14,062.5

Source: CIA World Factbook (2012).


Notes
* Not member of CARICOM (see www.caricom.org/jsp/community/member_states.jsp?
menu=community)
** 2006 estimate.
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 229
range is from Antigua and Barbuda at number 47, to Haiti at number 149, with
Cuba at number 51, Trinidad and Tobago at number 64, Suriname at number
97, Jamaica at number 100 and Guyana at number 114. UNDP’s ranking
(2012c) of Caribbean regional HDI at the turn of the decade presented a
similar range, from Very High/High (Barbados, Bahamas and Trinidad and
Tobago over 0.760) to Medium Human Development (Belize, Suriname and
Guyana), and Low for Haiti (0.545).
Compared to other regions, the Caribbean is under-represented in the eighth
annual ranking (2012) of the Failed States Index published by the journal
Foreign Policy: just Haiti at number seven appears in the top ten, with no other
Caribbean states in the list of 60 (cf. Baranyi 2011; Brock et al. 2012: 130–134).
In terms of homicide rates (UNODC 2012), however, the region presents
impressive statistics, with Jamaica’s 59.5 per 100,000 in 2008 being just
below the world’s highest rate from Honduras at 60.9, while Trinidad and
Tobago at 39.7 beats Columbia at 38.8; St Kitts at 35.32 just trails South Afri-
ca’s 36.5. Other high rates are reported for Anguilla at 27.6, Dominican
Republic at 21.5 and Puerto Rico at 20.4, with the lowest levels coming from
the Bahamas at 13.7 and Barbados at 8.7. The US rate is 5.2 per 100,000 of
the population.
The impact of armed violence on achieving and sustaining the Millennium
Development Goals was the subject of a symposium at the University of the
West Indies’ Institute of International Relations in late June 2010. At the turn
of the decade, UNDP undertook a project with leading Caribbean analysts,
such as Anthony Harriott (2003), to prepare a regional questionnaire on
‘citizen security’ (UNDP 2012c), designed to highlight, analyse and capture
the negative consequences of such violence on human development/security.
It advanced ‘citizen security’ as an authentic, resonant Caribbean concept
(UNDP 2012a).
Symptomatic of Caribbean issues implicating North America was a major
police raid in Toronto in May 2010 by a thousand police officers, leading to
the arrest of some 80 alleged members of the Jamaican ‘Shower Posse’ gang
or network. Shortly after, in mid-2010, came a protracted and bloody shoot-
out around Kingston’s Tivoli Gardens in the attempt to capture and extradite
‘Coke’ Dudus – who had been energetically protected by Prime Minister
Goulding – to the US: a case that was symptomatic of the corrosive effects of
drug lords on states’ autonomy (Friman and Andreas 1999; Girvan 2005).

Transnational trends and Caribbean small state security


Having shown that transnational economic, environmental and regulatory pro-
cesses among others are of central importance for small state security in the
Caribbean, this section zooms in on the importance of the transnational aspect of
families, civil society, supply chains and crime networks for security, and dis-
cusses the response to these developments in the form of transnational
governance.
230 T.M. Shaw
Transnational families
The creation of Caribbean transnational networks rests on the foundation of
a transnational family, in which migrants and their families have multiple
home bases with ongoing commitments and loyalties that straddle territorial
boundaries.
(Wiltshire 2006: 175)

Contemporary, like historical, migration has been very uneven throughout the
Caribbean, with recent outflows being most significant from Guyana and Jamaica
to North America and from Suriname to the Netherlands (some 200–250,000
Surinamese now in the Dutch diaspora vs. 450,000 at home). There are estim-
ated to be as many Guyanese in the US, especially in New York City, and
Canada, particularly Scarborough Ontario, as at home: +/–700,000 each. Their
presence, along with technological changes, has led to a dramatic rise in inter-
national communications, such as phone conversations, especially using mobiles
and phone-cards, and airline flights, with remittances growing from US$20
million in 2000 to US$200 million mid-decade. Guyana’s reliance on remit-
tances is highest in the Latin America-Caribbean region; it is even higher than
Haiti’s (IDB 2009: 10) and provides a quarter of GDP. Similarly for Jamaica,
which has some million Jamaicans abroad and less than three million at home,
with remittances totalling US$2 billion in the mid-2000s – some 20 per cent of
GDP (World Bank 2008). Western Union and Moneygram have become
ubiquitous in diasporic communities in the north and capital cities in the south,
even if remittance flows, particularly from the US and southern Eurozone
members like Spain, have been under pressure since the 2008 financial crisis.
Remittances to Latin America and the Caribbean (LAC) grew throughout
almost all of the first decade of the twenty-first century, but peaked in
2006–2008, declining in 2009 back to 2005 levels (ECLAC 2009) as a reflection
of the knock-on effects of the global financial crisis, particularly in the trans-
Atlantic centres of the US and the UK. However, when inflation is factored in,
remittances in local currencies may have actually increased in 2009, and flows
are expected to stabilize at the start of the second decade (IDB 2009: 3). The
overlap between remittances, money-laundering and income from drugs, is prob-
lematic; Mexico may receive as much as US$20–40 billion each year from the
drugs trade with the US.
Transnational Caribbean families can be considered as central to the evolu-
tion of transnational civil society focused on the region (Reis 2004; Scher 2009;
Thomas-Hope 2009).

Transnational civil society


The Caribbean is a unique and complex concatenation of virtually every
ethnic group in the world . . . sociopolitical traits have been amalgamated
and Eurocentric dominance has been mitigated. The region has truly been a
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 231
crucible of various cultures. This blending, not only of institutions but also
of ethnicity, has produced the uniquely Caribbean Creoles.
(Hillman 2009: 11–12)

The digital revolution has transformed both political economy and social culture,
let alone informal and illegal flows, around the Caribbean, notably through a trio
of ‘transformative processes: the introduction of cellular telephones, the adop-
tion of the internet, and the proliferation of offshore gambling sites’ (Bronfman
2007: 12).14
The region has always been defined by its music and sports, as well as cuis-
ines, symbolised by Carnival and other festivals. If its legendary cricket prowess
has been in decline, some of its athletes have excelled at the recent summer
Olympics. Such skills are reinforced by diasporic connections, such as cricket
teams in the UK county competition, or now, India’s Premier League
Diasporas can make demands regarding development, democracy and security
back home, potentially with an impact on the North’s foreign policies. This
aspect of ‘double’ public diplomacy (i.e. both inside and about the Caribbean)
was symbolized by the last months in office of Michaëlle Jean as Governor-
General in Canada, when she was also a celebrity diplomat for her native Haiti
after its 2010 earthquake; in turn, this generated her post-retirement appointment
as a UNESCO Ambassador. Of note also, is the proliferation of Home Town
Associations, most active when natural disasters hit home, as in diasporic
responses to the earthquake in Haiti.
Just as transnational Caribbean civil society has well-established historical
roots, so too the region’s supply chains go back centuries and include the flow of
forced as well as free people.

Transnational supply chains


. . . the circulation of commodities is one of the unifying aspects of Carib-
bean history. All islands are shaped by things that circulate, and more so in
the recent past, when aspects of globalization have made it easier for things
to circulate at greater quantities and greater speed.
(Bronfman 2007: 5)

Supply chains around the region have evolved from barrels to containers and air-
freight/couriers using cell-phones and tracking devices. Each brand’s hubs are
distinctive, while personal postboxes are bought in Miami to be used as offshore
addresses; methods range from banana boats and Cable and Wireless to Flow
and B-mobile internet connections, commercial courier services and more.
The thin red line(s) of imperial connections based on traditional industrial tech-
nologies have been superseded, post-independence, by post-industrial, digital tech-
nologies leading to real and virtual hubs and spokes. Regional and global hubs rise
and fall around older and newer supply chains (Gibbon et al. 2010), impacted by
technological and infrastructural as well as security developments. Examples are
232 T.M. Shaw
the expansion of the Panama Canal and container ports, or Copa (as well as Carib-
bean Airlines): reflecting emerging economies vs. emerging powers, including
emerging cities. The whole process has been accelerated by the recent global crisis,
which has redefined vulnerability and resilience, especially for small island devel-
oping states (SIDS) (Cooper and Shaw 2013), thereby also reinforcing the impera-
tive of transnational governance as discussed below.
As Bronfman (2007) and others indicate, with modernity, the region has
‘advanced’ from spices to drugs, cutlasses to guns, pirates to gangs, gunpowder to
AK47s, depending on supply and demand, regulations and enforcement. Novel
forms of supply chains exploit the ‘dark’ side of globalization, including intellec-
tual property violations via pirated CDs and apps (Naim 2006). In response, extra-
territorial EU and US rules tend to impact both goods and services (Gibbon et al.
2010), compounded by diasporic demands/expectations in the North.

Transnational crime networks


Illicit flows of all kinds have been part of the Caribbean’s history. Goods
have circulated to the region, from the region, and through the region.
(Bronfman 2007: 8)

Jamaica occupies a unique place in the history of illicit flows because both
marijuana and cocaine move in and out of the island.
(Bronfman 2007: 12)

In the late 1990s and early 2000s, the security challenges described above
resulted in a rethinking of what security is and how policy makers may respond
effectively to the challenges at hand (Bagley 2012; Bagley and Walker 1994;
Fiorentini and Peltzman 1997; Friman and Andreas 1999; Friman 2009; Madsen
2009). Symbolizing the burgeoning Southern ‘agency’ over drugs – as with other
contemporary issues such as global warming and resource extraction – the Latin
American Commission on Drugs and Democracy,15 chaired by a trio of eminent
ex-Presidents, has begun to redefine the discourse away from criminalization and
towards health, society, economy and so forth (Bagley 2012; Seelke 2011). In
turn, it spawned two further Commissions – Global and West African – all
seeking to contain the violence of the global inter-regional trade through decrim-
inalization: ‘towards a paradigm shift’ to end the unwinnable ‘war on drugs’.
In response to escalating violence, policy discussions have generated inter-
governmental institutions like the CARICOM Implementation Agency for Crime
and Security (CARICOM-IMPACS)16 and professional networks like the Asso-
ciation of Caribbean Commissioners of Police (ACCP)17 and the Caribbean
Association of Judicial Officers (CAJO)18 (Bowling 2010: 321–323). Mean-
while, as confidence in state security declined, the private security sector has
expanded and diversified, both at the national (e.g. Guardsman in Jamaica and
northern Caribbean)19 and the global level (e.g. G4S, see www.g4s.com,
accessed 30 June 2013): but by whom/how is it to be regulated? The Montreux
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 233
Document (2011), which proposes a code of conduct for private security com-
panies, offers one such framework, and many locally active companies have
signed up to it.
In 2012, UNODC estimated that the global drugs sector was worth over
US$300 billion or approximately 1 per cent of global GDP annually (UNODC
2012). The value of drugs increases the further they are away from production,
where their value is low; it multiplies 200 times between production and con-
sumption, especially when moving from South to North. Hence the spread of
narco-states or shadow states into the Caribbean, with their distinctive state–
economy balances (Harriott 2003; Glenny 2009; Griffiths 2004; Naim 2006;
Townsend 2009), including Guyana, Haiti, Jamaica and Puerto Rico. Legal
remittances (IBRD 2006; IDB 2009) and illegal money-laundering (Naylor
2006), have attracted G8 and OECD attention, leading to the aforementioned
Caribbean branch of FATF (UNODC 2010; Vlcek 2008). In the US, the drugs
sector is worth some US$200 billion annually including crime, health, policing
and productivity costs; in the EU the sector costs c. €35 billion annually. Hence
the imperative for ‘transnational governance’ responses to the challenges posed
by both formal/legal and informal/illegal transnational relations (Brown 2011;
Shaw 2010a).
Interestingly, based on late-2010 national surveys, the UNDP (2012a) has
itself begun to advocate the notion of ‘citizen security’ to advance freedom from
fear in the region, based on a regional survey at the start of the decade (UNDP
2012b). This goes beyond generic notions of collective human security/
development to reflect both the nature of personal/familial insecurity in the
contemporary Caribbean, and popular opinion about fear of crime, victimization
and limited confidence in the police and justice system (UNDP 2012b). The
concept constitutes a welcome Southern reaction to ‘global’ insecurities, as it
presents an authentic Caribbean voice. Human security focuses on collective
good; citizen security on individual/family/community, etc. as reflected in the
Caribbean Regional HDI already mentioned, which broadly repeats the annual
global analyses/rankings (UNDP 2012c). As Bowling (2010: 283) asserts: ‘The
greatest threat to security in the Caribbean is not the consumption of drugs, but
the armed violence and corruption that are endemic to illicit markets’.

Transnational governance
While private authority beyond the state has become a popular theme of
academic writing, the role of stakeholders in the Southern hemisphere as
objects and subjects of private transnational governance has rarely been
addressed in the literature.
(Dingwerth 2008: 607)

‘Transnational studies’ (Khagram and Levitt 2007) have further emphasized the
development of ‘transnational governance’ (Hale and Held 2011) as a generic
set of responses to novel and emerging ‘global’ issues (Shaw 2010a). Given the
234 T.M. Shaw
characteristic inclusion of non-state actors, the process may also be described as
‘private transnational governance’ (Dingwerth 2008), ‘non-state transnational
transfers’ (Brown 2011) or ‘non-state market-driven’ governance (Bernstein and
Cashore 2008), depending on discipline, case, period, etc. It is usually ‘hybrid’,
typically involving a range of heterogeneous actors, non-state as well as state,
acting in partnerships as in the classic International Campaign to Ban Landmines
that led to the ‘Ottawa Process’.20 The rich variety of such alliances, campaigns,
certification schemes, codes, commissions, councils, initiatives, networks, part-
nerships and processes, etc. is captured in tables in Dingwerth (2008: 628–630)
and Bernstein and Cashore (2008: 281–283).
Such transnational or ‘global’ governance can be treated as an extension or
contemporary form of established international law and international organiza-
tion, which have been primarily, even exclusively, intergovernmental. The new
approaches have evolved from the Ottawa and Kimberley Processes, through
Forestry and Fisheries Certification schemes, to the discrete initiatives now
brought together in the International Social and Environmental Accreditation
and Labelling Alliance.21
New forms of governance for the several Caribbeans may lead to alternative
futures by 2015 or the end of the current decade (Bishop and Payne 2010; Payne
and Sutton 2007): moving from orthodox small state alliances to address myriad
Caribbean/global concerns, including climate change (Shaw 2010a). Public or
network diplomacy by SIDS can maximize leverage internationally by using non-
state partners, such as private sector and civil society, media and culture (Cooper
and Shaw 2009; Shaw 2010a). Caribbean diasporas can impact a range of both
home- and host-country policies. New governance networks can develop, some-
times in rather unlikely sectors (cf. Iheduru 2011 on African examples). Further,
because of its numerous countries and hence votes, the Caribbean is active in inter-
regional processes such as CARIFORUM’s Economic Partnership dialogue with the
EU, besides links with MERCOSUR22 and the Organization of American States
within the hemisphere (Mace et al. 2010), and with the African Union and the Asso-
ciation of Southeast Asian Nations beyond it (De Lombaerde and Schulz 2009).
Based on this discussion, it is possible to identify two important trends. The
first concerns a redefinition of security in the region. Threats to national and
human security from ‘old’ and ‘new’ factors, such as climate change and gang
culture (Bronfman 2007: 63–85; Griffiths 2004; Naim 2006; Townsend 2009)
have promoted: (1) the novel notion of ‘citizen security’ (UNDP 2012), and (2)
‘transnational security’, as terrorism and crime cannot be defeated in one country
alone (Bowling 2010). This also means engaging new types of actors and inter-
ests, especially in soft law arenas like fisheries and forest certification (Bernstein
and Cashore 2008; Dingwerth 2008), while recognizing that illicit global sectors
are amongst the world’s freest and may involve major, under-recognized ‘multi-
national corporations’. Accordingly, Friman and Andreas argue that the ‘illicit
global economy’ needs to be recognized for its ‘transnational nature . . . and its
global scope’ and advocate ‘the inclusion of the illicit global economy in the
central debates within the international relations literature’ (Friman and Andreas
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 235
1999: 5, 17). As Bowling (2010: 315) concludes, transnational responses are
imperative in response to transitional crime:

Transnational security cooperation must be harnessed more closely to the needs


of local neighbourhoods if it is to become part of the solution to community
insecurity. . . . We should admit that the ‘war on drugs’ has been ineffective in
its own terms and counterproductive in the pursuit of human security.

More generally, an infinite range of issues and relations at all levels, involving
myriad, heterogeneous actors/coalitions/networks (Shaw et al. 2011), is trans-
forming the meaning of Caribbean regionalisms and security.
The second trend involves new small state vulnerabilities. Small polities, a
growing proportion of the world’s states, are increasingly affected by climate
change and illicit economies inter alia. How far should they be considered vul-
nerable rather than resilient in the changing global economic and environmental
context (Bishop and Payne 2010; Cooper and Shaw 2013)? These vulnerabilities
are closely related to the trends just mentioned in transnational relations, both
formal and informal, legal and otherwise (Khagram and Levitt 2007).

What/whose security post-2015?


If the Caribbean was an invention of the 20th century, it seems certain to be
reinterpreted and perhaps transcended in the 21st. The Caribbean of tomor-
row will not be an exclusively Anglophone or Hispanic conception; and it
will not be tied exclusively to geographic space or definition. If it survives
at all, it will be a community of shared economic, social and political inter-
ests and strategies that encompasses different languages and cultures and the
Caribbean Diaspora.
(Girvan 2005: 315)

Just as we may identify several Caribbeans (Mohammed 2009), so we may


abstract several futures beyond 2015 and the demise of the MDGs (Bishop and
Payne 2010; Payne and Sutton 2007), including scenarios along the vulnerable
and resilient divide (Cooper and Shaw 2013). But this dialectic becomes more
problematic or complicated when more informal and illegal transnational rela-
tions are incorporated, with diasporas and remittances becoming increasingly
salient. Hence the need to address the old/new security distinction: What balance
by 2015?
Clearly, only a minority of Caribbean political economies are likely to
achieve ‘developmental’ status, with hopefully a similarly small minority slip-
ping into the ranks of the fragile or failed, like Haiti (Baranyi 2011; Donais and
Korr 2013; Muggah 2005). The majority will have their prospects largely deter-
mined by a mix of regional and global fortunes, increasingly impacted by
climate change; hence the persistence of fragile or failed states. Developmental
and democratic deficits will persist, moderated by ubiquitous connectivity
236 T.M. Shaw
facilitating continuous transnational communication. And by 2020, if not before,
Caribbean relations with the BRICS will come to balance if not exceed those
with the North Atlantic rim (Mace et al. 2010).
The kaleidoscope of different Caribbeans, both contemporary and historical,
advances and reinforces notions of varieties of capitalisms and civil societies as
well as the plurality of regionalisms. It should continue to inform debates about
the compatibility or competitiveness of such formal and informal, macro- and
micro-regionalisms: all features that will help determine the Caribbean’s destiny
as the MDG era ends in 2015.

Notes
1 On the concept of small states and its relevance for understanding small state security,
see Chapter 1 in this volume.
2 See www.netris-acp.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
3 See www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/csgr/green/(accessed 30 November 2013).
4 UNU-CRIS, see www.cris.unu.edu (accessed 30 November 2013).
5 www.canari.org/ (accessed 30 November 2013).
6 www.caribbeanclimate.bz (accessed 30 November 2013).
7 www.acs-aec.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
8 www.caricom.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
9 In accordance with Chapter 2, this chapter understands societal security problems as
damaging society both physically and in its established peaceful routines, while
human security is understood as related to both ‘freedom from fear’ and ‘freedom
from want’. See Chapter 4 in this volume on societal security for a more comprehen-
sive discussion of the concept.
10 See, www.fatf-gafi.org/ (accessed 30 November 2013).
11 See, www. fatf-gafi.org/ (accessed 30 November 2013).
12 See www.eclac.org/portofspain (accessed 30 November 2013).
13 See, www.weforum.org/issues/global-competitiveness.
14 On the latter, see Andrew Cooper (2011) on the rise and fall of gambling based in
Antigua, under bilateral US pressure, which the WTO was unable to contain.
15 See, www.cbdd.org.br/blog/tag/comissao-latino-americana-sobre-drogas-e-democracia/
(accessed 30 November 2013).
16 See, www.caricomimpacs.org/impacs/index.php?option=com_content&format=feed&
type=rss (accessed 30 November 2013).
17 See, www.accpolice.org/accp/default.asp?V_SITE_ID=6 (accessed 30 November
2013).
18 See, www.thecajo.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
19 See, www.guardsmangroup.com (accessed 30 November 2013).
20 See, www.icbl.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
21 See, www.isealalliance.org (accessed 30 November 2013).
22 See, www.mercosur.int (accessed 30 November 2013).

Bibliography
Aalto, P. (ed.) (2008) The EU-Russian Energy Dialogue: Europe’s Future Energy
Security, Aldershot: Ashgate.
Bagley, B.B. (2012) Drug Trafficking and Organized Crime in the Americas: Major
Trends in the 21st Century, Washington DC: Woodrow Wilson Center.
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 237
Bagley, B. and Walker, W.O. (eds) (1994) Drug Trafficking in the Americas, Miami, FL:
University of Miami N-S Center.
Baranyi, S. (2011) ‘Introduction: Peacebuilding and Reconstruction in Haiti’, Journal of
Peacebuilding and Development, 6(3): 3–16.
Bernstein, S. and Cashore, B. (2008) ‘The Two-Level Logic of Non-State Market Driven
Global Governance’, in Rittberger, V. and Nettesheim, M. (eds), Authority in the
Global Political Economy, London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 276–313.
Bishop, M.L (2013) The Political Economy of Eastern Caribbean Development, London:
Palgrave Macmillan, forthcoming.
Bishop, M.L and Payne, A. (2010) Caribbean Regional Governance and the Sovereignty/
Statehood Problem. Waterloo: CIGI, Caribbean paper no. 8.
Bowling, B. (2010) Policing the Caribbean: Transnational Security Cooperation in Prac-
tice Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Brock, L., Holm, H.-H., Sorensen, G. and Stohl, M. (2012) Fragile States, Cambridge:
Polity Press.
Bronfman, A. (2007) On the Move: The Caribbean since 1989, Halifax, NS: Fernwood.
Brown, S.S. (ed.) (2011) Transnational Transfers and Global Development, London: Pal-
grave Macmillan.
Clarkson, A., Paheco-Pardo, R. and Talani, L.S. (eds) (2013) Dirty Cities: Globalization
and the Urban Underground, London: Palgrave Macmillan, forthcoming.
Cooper, A.F (2011) Internet Gambling Offshore: Caribbean Struggles over Casino Capit-
alism, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Cooper, A.F. and Shaw, T.M. (eds.) (2013) The Diplomacies of Small States: Between
Vulnerability and Resilience (2nd expanded edition), London: Palgrave Macmillan.
De Lombaerde, P. and Schulz, M. (eds) (2009) The EU and World Regionalism: The
Makability of Regions in the 21st Century, Farnham: Ashgate Publishing.
Dingwerth, K. (2008) ‘Private Transnational Governance and the Developing World: A
Comparative Perspective’, International Studies Quarterly, 52(3): 607–634.
Donais, T. and Knorr, A.C. (2013) ‘Peacebuilding from Below vs the Liberal Peace: The
Case of Haiti’, Canadian Journal of Development Studies, 34(1): 54–69.
Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean (ECLAC) (2009) Economic
Survey of the Caribbean 2008–2009, Port of Spain, October.
Fanta, E., Shaw, T.M. and Tang, V.T. (eds) (2013) Comparative Regionalisms for Devel-
opment in the 21st Century: insights from the Global South, Farnham: Ashgate Pub-
lishing.
Farer, T. (ed.) (1999) Transnational Crime in the Americas, New York: Routledge for
Inter-American Dialogue.
Fiorentini, G. and Peltzman, S. (eds) (1997) The Economics of Organized Crime, New
York: Cambridge University Press for CEPR.
Friman, H.R. (ed.) (2009) Crime and the Global Political Economy, Boulder, CO: Lynne
Rienner Publishers.
Friman, H.R. and Andreas, P. (eds) (1999) The Illicit Global Economy and State Power,
Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.
Gibbon, P., Ponte, S. and Lazaro, E. (eds) (2010) Global Agro-Food Trade and Stand-
ards: Challenges for Africa, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Graduate Institute Of International And Development Studies (GIIDS) (2009) Small Arms
Survey 2009: Shadows of War. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for GIIDS.
Girvan, N. (2005) ‘Reinterpreting the Caribbean’, in Pantin, D. (ed.) The Caribbean
Economy: A Reader, Kingston: Ian Randle, pp. 304–318.
238 T.M. Shaw
Glenny, M. (2009) McMafia: A Journey through the Global Criminal Underworld,
Toronto: Anansi.
Griffiths, I. (ed.) (2004) Caribbean Security in the Age of Terror: Challenge and Change,
Kingston: Ian Randle.
Hale, T. and Held, D. (eds) (2011) Handbook of Transnational Governance Cambridge:
Polity Press.
Harriott, A. (ed.) (2003) Understanding Crime in Jamaica, Mona: UWI Press.
Hettne, B. and Inotai, A. (1994) The New Regionalism: Implications for Global Develop-
ment and International Security, Helsinki: UNU-WIDER, February.
Hettne, B., Inotai, A. and Sunkel, O. (eds) (1999) Globalism and the New Regionalism,
London: Macmillan.
Hillman, R.S (2009) ‘Introduction’, in Hillman, R.S. and D’Agostino, T.J. (eds) Under-
standing the Contemporary Caribbean (2nd edition), Boulder, CO: Lynne Reinner
Publishing, pp. 1–18.
Iheduru, O.C (2011) ‘ECOWAS’, in Shaw, T.M., Grant, J.A. and Cornelissen, C. (eds)
(2011) Ashgate Research Companion to Regionalisms, Farnham: Ashgate Publishing.
Inter-American Development Bank (IDB (2009) ‘Remittances in Times of Financial
Instability: Impact of the Financial Crisis on Remittances to Latin America and the
Caribbean’, available online at: www.iadb.org/en/publications/publication-detail,7101.
html?id=68048 (accessed 30 June 2013).
International Bank of Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) (2006) Global Economic
Prospects: Economic Implications of Remittances and Migration, Washington, DC:
IBRD.
Khagram, S. and Levitt, P. (eds) (2007) The Transnational Studies Reader, New York:
Routledge.
Kshetri, N. (2013) Cybercrime and Cybersecurity in the Global South, London: Palgrave
Macmillan.
Kyung-Sup, C., Fine, B. and Weiss, L. (eds) (2012) Developmental Politics in Transition:
The Neoliberal Era and Beyond, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Latin American Initiative on Drugs and Democracy (2009) ‘Drugs and Democracy:
Toward a Paradigm Shift’, statement by the Latin American Commission on Drugs and
Democracy, Washington, DC: LAIDD.
Laursen, F. (ed.) (2010) Comparative Regional Integration: Europe and Beyond,
Farnham: Ashgate Publishing.
Mace, G., Cooper, A.F. and Shaw, T.M. (eds) (2010) Inter-American Cooperation at a
Crossroads, London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Madsen, F. (2009) Transnational Organized Crime, Abingdon: Routledge.
Mohammed, P. (2009) Imaging the Caribbean: Culture and Visual Translation, Oxford:
Macmillan Education.
Montreux Document on private military and security companies, signed 17 September
2008, available online at: www.eda.admin.ch/psc (accessed 15 December 2012).
Muggah, R. (2005) ‘Securing Haiti’s Transition: Reviewing Human Insecurity and the
Prospects for Disarmament, Demobilization and Reintegration’, Geneva: Small Arms
Survey, occasional paper no. 14.
Naim, M. (2006) Illicit: How Smugglers, Traffickers and Copycats are Hijacking the
Global Economy, New York: Anchor.
Naylor, R.T. (2005) Wages of Crime: Black Markets, Illegal Finance and the Underworld
Economy, Ithaca, NY: Cornell UP.
O’Neill, J. (2011) The Growth Map: Economic Opportunity in the BRICs and Beyond,
New York: Portfolio/Penguin.
Caribbean post-2015: old versus new security 239
Palan, R., Murphy, R. and Chavagneux, C. (eds) (2010) Tax Havens: How Globalization
Really Works, Ithaca, NY: Cornell UP.
Pantin, D. (ed.) (2005) The Caribbean Economy: A Reader, Kingston: Ian Randle.
Payne, A. and Sutton, P. (2007) ‘Repositioning the Caribbean within Globalization’,
Waterloo: CIGI, Caribbean paper no. 1.
Reis, M. (2004) ‘Theorizing Diaspora: Perspectives on “Classical” and “Contemporary”
Diaspora’, International Migration, 42(2): 41–60.
Scher, P.W. (ed.) (2009) Perspectives on the Caribbean: A Reader in Culture, Migration
and Representation, Malden: Wiley-Blackwell.
Seelke, C.R. (2011) Latin American and Caribbean: Illicit Drug Trafficking and US
Counterdrug Programs, Washington, DC: Congress Research Service, May.
Shaw, T.M. (2010a) ‘Commonwealth and Global Development: Contributions to Private
Transnational Governance’, Commonwealth and Comparative Politics, 48(1): 91–111.
Shaw, T.M. (2010b) ‘New Regionalisms Post-EPAs: What Prospects for Sustainable
Development in Africa and the Caribbean?’, in Laursen, F. (ed.) Comparative Regional
Integration: Europe and beyond, Farnham: Ashgate Publishing, pp. 193–211.
Shaw, T.M. (2012) ‘Energy and CSR in TandT in the Second Decade of the 21st
Century’, in Sagebien, J. and Lindsay, N. (eds) Governance Ecosystems: CSR in the
Latin American Mining Sector, London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 245–259.
Shaw, T.M. (2013) ‘How Many Caribbeans in 2020: Vulnerable? Resilient? Informal
and/or Illegal?’, in Singh, P. and Izarali, M.R. (eds) The Contemporary Caribbean:
Issues and Challenges, New Delhi: Shipra, pp. 1–15.
Shaw, T.M., Grant, J.A. and Cornelissen, S. (eds) (2011) Ashgate Research Companion
to Regionalisms, Farnham: Ashgate Publishing.
Singh, P. and Izarali, M.R. (eds) (2013) The Contemporary Caribbean: Issues and Chal-
lenges, New Delhi: Shipra.
Soderbaum, F. and Shaw, T.M. (2003) Theories of New Regionalism: A Palgrave reader,
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Thomas-Hope, E. (ed.) (2009) Freedom and Constraint in Caribbean Migration and
Diaspora, Kingston: Ian Randle.
Townsend, D. (2009) ‘No Other Life: Gangs, Guns and Governance in Trinidad and
Tobago’, Geneva: Small Arms Survey, working paper no. 8.
UNDP (2009) Human Development Report 2009: Overcoming Barriers: Human Mobility
and Development, New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
UNDP (2012a) ‘Caribbean Human Development Report 2012: Human Development and
the Shift to better Citizen Security’, Port of Spain.
UNDP (2012b) ‘Caribbean Human Development Report 2012: UNDP Caribbean Security
Survey 2010: Summary of the Findings’, Port of Spain.
UNDP (2012c) ‘Caribbean Human Development Report 2012: Estimating a CARICOM
Human Development Index’, Port of Spain.
UNDP (2013) Human Development Report 2013: The Rise of the South: Human Pro-
gress in a Diverse World, New York.
UNEP (2008) ‘Climate Change in the Caribbean: The Challenge of Adaptation’, Panama,
October.
UNODC (2010) ‘Annual Report 2010: Promoting Health, Security and Justice’, Vienna.
UNODC (2012) ‘World Drug Report 2012’, Vienna.
Vlcek, W. (2008) Offshore Finance and Small States: Sovereignty, Size and Money,
London: Palgrave Macmillan.
240 T.M. Shaw
Wiltshire, R. (2006) ‘Implications of Transnational Migration for Nationalism: The
Caribbean Example’, Annals of the NY Academy of Sciences Volume 645: Towards a
Transnational Perspective on Migration: 175–187.
World Bank (2008) Migration and Remittances Factbook 2008, Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Zank, W. (ed.) (2009) Clash or Cooperation of Civilizations? Overlapping Integration
and Identities, Farnham: Ashgate Publishing.
14 The security concerns of designed
spaces
Size matters
Godfrey Baldacchino

Introduction
Recent years have seen a crescendo of complaints by the OECD, the EU, gov-
ernments of large countries and ‘tax justice’ organizations vilifying the practice
of offshore finance:

Through complex networks of financial centres and secrecy jurisdictions –


serviced by an infrastructure of accountants, lawyers and bankers – coun-
tries are deprived of a sufficient tax base to support good governance, and
illicit activities that feed corruption and violent conflict are encouraged.
(Mackenzie 2012: 1)

As a result, the offshore financial system should be ‘. . . recognised as a threat to


human security’ (ibid.). In the wake of a systematic process of crackdown, shaming
and condemnation, many small states and territories have had to take measures that
improved the transparency and reduced the anonymity of their offshore finance
regimes. And yet, the world of offshore finance is not going away any time soon.
Just because the small guy is at the wrong end of the stick does not mean that the
big guy gets to have his way. Just being controversial does not mean that offshore
finance centres, and the states that host them, will go out of business.
This brief yet timely cameo helps to capture the argument of this chapter: the
absolute size of a state can have a significant influence on the extent to which
power asymmetry translates into powerlessness for the smaller player. This
volume departs from an understanding of small states – Lilliputian, as they have
also been called (Keohane 1969; Neumann and Gstöhl 2006) – as the weaker
actors in asymmetric power relationships (see the discussion in Chapter 1 of this
volume). They are often considered as reactive players in the international
system (e.g. Handel 1981); and face an ‘inevitable deficit of power’, whether in
trying to coerce, or resist being coerced by others (Mouritzen 1997: 101–106).
And this may well be so, in some cases, some of the time. But there are clear
departures from this behavioural syndrome. Just as in a David and Goliath
contest, David can win, against all odds, and live another day. And, as Keohane
(1969: 310) reminds us, Lilliputians can overwhelm a Gulliver.
242 G. Baldacchino
What is a small state? The importance of statehood
Small states have been defined as ‘the weaker actors in asymmetric power rela-
tionships’ (Mouritzen and Wivel 2005; Rickli 2008); but such a definition may
put too much emphasis on power and size and too little on the status of state-
hood. After all, most states today – including the world’s smallest sovereign
entities – are no longer preoccupied by concerns for their existence and survival
qua states, even in the face of the expansionist ambitions of stronger regional
powers. State extantism (see Schaffer 1975: 25) means that today the political
survival of even ‘failed states’ (e.g. Connell 2006) is not endangered, since these
do not risk their incorporation into the territory of an expansionist neighbour.
Throughout the twentieth century, and into the twenty-first, only the ‘states’ of
Somaliland, South Yemen and Zanzibar have disappeared as they were swal-
lowed by neighbouring, expansionist states. Rather than being gripped by the
fear of domination or invasion – a key concern for the likes of Machiavelli
(1515) – states today are more concerned with and disposed to utilize that key
capacity of sovereignty: the right and ability to make laws, in order to ‘optimize
the health and wealth of the state and its people’ (Braun 2000: 12).
Such a politically rational reading of the exercise of territorial power is com-
parable to the Foucaultian concept of ‘governmentality’: the smart deployment
of actual and potentially available capacities to secure desirable fiscal, human,
material, legal or geopolitical resources (Foucault 1991: 93; Kuehls 1996: 67;
Baldacchino 2012). This is a performative act of government-as-agency: deploy-
ing somewhat systematic modes and technologies of power that go beyond the
spontaneous exercise of power over others, and whose purpose is ‘the regulation
of conduct by the more or less rational application of the appropriate technical
means’ (Hindess 1996: 106). Such a state capacity extends naturally and legiti-
mately to its own territories, its own citizens and its own resources; but it often
includes extra-territorial scope, defined as the ability to impact on the conduct of
others beyond one’s juridical reach. Foucault describes these behaviour patterns
and relationships of power as ‘strategic games between liberties’ (Foucault 1988:
19; also Adler-Nissen and Gad 2013). The purposes for which such con-
temporary ‘imaginative geographies’ (Said 1979) may be deployed can also be
roughly generalized, falling into certain patterned initiatives: these include maxi-
mizing tax revenue, growing tourism, securing military rents, attracting inter-
national students or foreign skilled workers, facilitating emigration (and ensuing
remittances) or luring foreign aid and investment.

As the stakes get higher, governance becomes more creative


The stakes get increasingly higher with decreasing size of territory and popula-
tion. With the very smallest of jurisdictions, extra-territorial reach is syn-
onymous with economic survival. Thus, even a sub-national jurisdiction like
Pitcairn – arguably the world’s smallest – can survive, mainly by its successful
claims and overtures (what Foucault would define as ‘bio-politics’) vis-à-vis
The security concerns of designed spaces 243
British taxpayers, American stamp collectors and Filipino sailors. ‘The only cash
economy of Pitcairn is the sale of stamps and the sale of handicrafts to passing
ships’ (Ridgell 1995: 149). Meanwhile, for the small archipelagic states of the
Maldives, Marshall Islands, Kiribati and Tuvalu, climate change and concomi-
tant sea level rise may bring about the complete submerging of their land ter-
ritory, making the wholesale migration and translocation of their populations to
other countries a distinct policy option.
These possibilities thrust the international relations of small jurisdictions into an
arena of creative governance. The setting is a function of the large number of small
sovereign states that exist today – the UN-supported Forum of Small States has
105 states as members (Government of Singapore 2012) – and of the expanding
number and significance of both sub-national and supra-national entities. The stage
is set for conventional (state–state) bilateral and multilateral deals; but also for new
forms of agreements and the para/proto-diplomacies that imbricate sub-state and
non-state territories and that have evolved from the metropolitan–peripheral and
colonial relationships of the twentieth century (e.g. Kelman et al. 2006).1 Small-
ness, often accompanied by islandness, low/no populations and relative isolation,
facilitates the room for such ‘creative political economy’ (Baldacchino and Milne
2008) or ‘norm entrepreneurship’ (Ingebritsen 2002).
This chapter critically reviews the opportunity for crafting and managing such
‘design initiatives’ by such ‘states of exception’ (Agamben 2005). Many of these
initiatives – high security prisons, ‘tax havens’, refugee camps, geo-strategic mil-
itary bases, remote weapons test and dump sites, special autonomous regions, duty-
free zones, heritage and conservation parks, spaces without right of abode, and
various ‘mix and match’ combinations of the above – can be argued to pose
‘security threats’. Excising, zoning, detaching, niching, outbordering, dislocating,
insulating, unbundling, quarantining or offshoring, are some of the performative
action verbs that can be used to describe a clutch of different design initiatives that
share many basic characteristics, and which involve the endowment of specific
legal spaces with particular and closely circumscribed privileges and powers, often
ratified by domestic law (Baldacchino 2010: 4). By means of such techniques,
states exploit distance, precariousness and ambiguous status (Mountz 2011).
And yet, it may be easier to undertake such measures on part of one’s territory,
rather than on a sovereign state’s territory in toto. Any activity deemed to be ‘off-
shore’ may need to be seen in relation to other, more conventional activities that
are taking place ‘onshore’, and in the same country; and such policy measures may
be accompanied by deliberate jurisdictional reform that renders such spaces as
administratively self-governing enclaves, easier to fence off and ring-fence, simul-
taneously defining and restricting the zone of exclusion in which specific practices
can operate. Indeed, it is in a clever combination of offshore and onshore that states
seek to ‘have the cake and eat it too’ (Palan 1998), exploiting both conformity (e.g.
with international law) and truancy in their public policy pursuits.
Thus, and for example, Australia has declared large sections of its offshore
waters, islands and reefs as ‘non-Australia’ for the purposes of asylum seekers
and has transformed Christmas Island into an irregular migrant detention
244 G. Baldacchino
centre; the remote and islanded nature of the space enhances the experience of
detention. Hong Kong is not a country, being part of the People’s Republic of
China; but, as a special administrative region, it enjoys executive, legislative
and independent judicial power; is a ‘top Pacific Basin offshore financial
centre’ (Roberts 1994: 102); and has its own flag, stamps, currency and inter-
net domain name (.hk). Labuan is an offshore finance centre in Indonesia. The
United States pioneered a free trade zone on Staten Island, NY in 1937; and
Okinawa remains the home to most of the US forces stationed in Japan. Prob-
ably the best known example of such offshore spaces is Guantánamo Bay, in
Cuba, which has effectively been crafted and variously described as a ‘jurid-
ical limbo’, ‘black hole’, ‘zone of indetermination’ and a ‘carefully con-
structed legal absence’; it is a threshold where the border between inside and
outside is deliberately ambiguous and uncertain (Bigo 2007: 17–18; Fletcher
2004; Reid-Henry 2007: 630). In all these examples, the idiosyncratic space is
defined in relation to the rest of a country where other, different regulatory
regimes prevail.
However, compare these developments occurring in sub-national jurisdictions
with those involving small states in toto. Nauru has resumed its offer of deten-
tion services for Australian asylum seekers. Cyprus and Malta are destinations
for irregular migrants transiting from North Africa and the Middle East into the
European Union. Mauritius has been a successful, whole-country, free trade
zone since 1992. Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, Singapore and the Bahamas are
amongst the world’s premier ‘offshore’ finance centres. Bahrain is the site of a
significant US Navy base, with some 6,000 personnel, offering port facilities to
the US Fifth Fleet. In all these cases, as in various others, it is not practical – and
often impossible – to ring-fence such operations other than in a manner that is
fully and wholly contiguous with the national territory.
To what extent does the distinctiveness of small states make them espe-
cially attractive, and often default candidates of choice, for such a thrust of
political design? And to what extent does this same specificity render these as
spaces that generate security concerns within both domestic and international
political economy? We understand these challenges to fall largely within three
distinct yet interrelated parameters: (1) the inordinate social and economic
impact of major external logistic and infrastructure investments in small
states; (2) the relative non-feasibility of transfer, or spillover of negativities, to
other parts of the same country; and (3) the potential capture of the state, and
the co-optation of local elites, in support of specific ventures in creative gov-
ernance. These matters will now be elaborated upon and reviewed in turn,
using suitable examples.

Inordinate impacts
Small states have higher economic elasticities: they tend to grow faster and have
higher productivity growth than larger countries, but their economic depressions
also tend to be deeper and more pronounced (Baldacchino 1998):
The security concerns of designed spaces 245
The opening of a garment factory employing 200 people is no big deal to
most territories, but it could significantly reduce unemployment in a smaller
jurisdiction. Of course, the converse applies as well: the closure of a fish-
processing plant employing 200 people could be seen as a national disaster.
(Baldacchino 2011: 238)

Small states also generally secure better terms in foreign aid: one of the most
well-established generalizations in the foreign assistance field is the so-called
‘small country effect’, according to which aid per head increases, and the terms
of aid improve, as the size of the country declines (Streeten 1993: 200). ‘A few
million dollars go a long way on a speck of land’ (The Economist 1991).
Given these reasons, one should not be surprised to note that what are, in
absolute terms, modest investments become disproportionately significant in
small economies. Nauru, a country with some 12,000 citizens, has gone from
being one of the world’s richest countries to one of the world’s poorest on a
per capita basis. When the detention facility was opened for the Australian
Government, it ‘pumped so much money into Nauru’s economy that it soon
came to account for a fifth of the nation’s revenue’ (Squires 2008). Small eco-
nomies are typically more volatile, with more erratic episodes of boom and
bust, than larger neighbours (e.g. Carse 1998, comparing the Isle of Man to
the United Kingdom).
Consider next the inordinate impact of a high-profile US base, with some
5,000–6,000 personnel located in a small country where over half the resident
population consists of foreigners. Tensions have occasionally been running
high with regard to the stationing of the US military base (and home to the US
Fifth Fleet) in Bahrain, the smallest state in the strategic Persian Gulf. First
the Emirate, then the (short-lived) National Assembly, had given notice to the
US to withdraw its military presence from Bahrain during the 1973 Egypt–
Israeli conflict, and again in summer 1974 (Winckler 2007: 67–74). More
recently, high levels of unemployment and the continuous presence of the US
base ‘have given radical Sunni and Shi’a Islamist groups a reason for discon-
tent and led to rapid growth in their popularity’ (Karolak 2010: 10–11). The
minority Sunni Al Khalifa monarchy in Bahrain may have succeeded in tem-
porarily crushing mass protests by the majority Shi’ites and driving them out
of the capital Manama. However, ‘the frustration and anger in Bahrain con-
tinues to bubble to the surface in protests’ more than a year after a Saudi-
backed crackdown (Dorsey 2012).
Modest social events can also become excessively noteworthy in small island
politics; various episodes highlight the more ‘combustible’ socio-political atmo-
sphere prevalent in small states (e.g. Richards 1982; Baker 1992), where meas-
ures that do not meet public support cannot be located out of sight, and out of
mind. Take Cyprus and Malta: they have been receiving boatloads of irregular
migrants arriving from Africa and the Middle East. The impact of even modest
(but socially very visible) arrivals can be disproportionately significant, as policy
makers and the media often argue:
246 G. Baldacchino
As Maltese policy makers often emphasize, in particular vis-à-vis other EU
members states, relative to population size, an inflow of 2,000 immigrants
into Malta equates to more than 400,000 arriving in Germany, or to around
300,000 entering France, the UK, or Italy.
(Lutterbeck 2009: 121)

But the arrival of often dark-skinned, often non-Christian, irregular immigrants


has also triggered an appeal to, and a nostalgia for, a mythical representation of
nationhood in both island states: one premised on the national character as
solidly white-skinned, racially pure, European and Christian (Catholic in Malta;
Greek Orthodox in Cyprus), and including a converse suspicion and fear of the
‘Other’. Hence a xenoscape presents itself, riddled with negative affect and a
dislike of the stranger, and translated into a surge of populist, anti-immigrant
political discourse (e.g. Teerling and King 2012; Lutterbeck 2009).

Non-feasibility of transfer
Moreover, both these countries (and Malta more so than Cyprus) have limited
land areas and relatively very high population densities: once the irregular immi-
grants are landed, there is no hinterland, no ‘Christmas Island scenario’ to which
they can be despatched. Furthermore, and according to the Dublin II Agreement
of the European Union (EU), meant to prevent ‘asylum shopping’, an irregular
migrant’s application for asylum has to be handled by the EU member state
where that migrant was first landed: thus, once disembarked in the EU, irregular
migrants are expected to stay in their country of landing. No wonder both Cyprus
and Malta disagree with these provisions which have created a disproportionate
burden on EU border states, and especially on the two small Mediterranean
island countries (see Sansone 2011).
In the Pacific, a low-lying atoll archipelago state like Tuvalu struggles with
the implications of climate change and sea level rise. Whereas residents of other
islands facing inundation, erosion, increasing storm intensity and encroaching
salinity have been able to relocate elsewhere within their own country (as did the
Carteret Islanders in Papua New Guinea – Monbiot 2009), the Tuvaluans do not
have that luxury: their whole country is prone to sea level rise – nine atolls, with
a total land area of 26 km2 (see also the discussion of environmental security in
Chapter 5 of this volume). Unsurprisingly, Tuvaluans are voting with their feet:
there are already many more settled elsewhere in such countries as New Zealand
and Australia than remain on the territory of their own small state. Opportunities
for migration, under a variety of classes, to these destination countries are act-
ively sought.
In the eastern Caribbean, small island states like Dominica, Grenada, St Lucia
and St Vincent have had to radically shift their economies, highly dependent for
decades on the export of bananas under preferential arrangements (involving a
duty free quota per country) to the United Kingdom and the European Union,
following a ruling by the World Trade Organization that had been instigated by
The security concerns of designed spaces 247
the USA and more competitive banana growers in Central America, and which
declared such arrangements discriminatory. Total banana exports still accounted
for 30 to 60 per cent of all merchandise exports from these island states in the
1980s. Such a heavy reliance on one major export crop subjects such small econ-
omies to trade dependence and vulnerability to various forms of external shocks,
which include price fluctuations, crop diseases and natural disasters (see Wil-
liams and Darius 1998). Such island states have been obliged to shift to alterna-
tive economic activities (cocoa, nutmeg, tourism, marijuana) in a relatively short
period of time, with their small economies struggling to make up for the loss of
earnings from the banana industry (Grynberg 2006).
But it is not easy for a small economy to avoid an inordinate dependence on
one export item. The best economic scenario to aspire to is one that sees the
economy shuttling from one form of vulnerability to another (see also the dis-
cussions of economic security in Chapters 2 and 3 of this volume); rarely are
there any robust, credibly alternative, resilient sectors that can boldly take up the
slack. Consider as an example the economic yo-yoing of the Caribbean island
state of St Lucia, set up as a plantation economy following European discovery.
Sugar drove the plantation economy for many decades but was eclipsed by coal
(1880s–1930s), which was in turn overtaken by bananas during the 1960s;
tourism then surpassed the banana ‘green gold’ in revenue in 1993 (see Ellis
2005).

Capture of the (small) state?


With a state mechanism that is small in absolute terms, and a see-through
decision-making process, it is fairly easy to personalize public policy making in
small states. In spite of its small size, however, the state in a small state is
omnipotent and ubiquitous. It plays a disproportionate role in a small country: as
the employer of last resort; and as a highly transparent, person-driven apparatus
that dispenses ‘cargo’ and other benefits, especially to the politically sympathetic
(Baldacchino 2011: 238; Clarke and Payne 1987). Hence, the stakes are raised
for attempts to influence, or control, such an important actor.
Such accusations are often raised at offshore finance centres, most of which
are small, often island, states and territories. It is claimed that various small
states and territories today may have not just deployed, but actually traded in,
their sovereignty, or part thereof, in exchange for economic largesse, by exploit-
ing a nuanced juridical space facilitated and condoned by smallness, islandness
and peripherality. ‘Financial capital has been able successfully to penetrate these
small, vulnerable political economies, often capturing their states in order to
promote favourable legislation’, claim Hampton and Christensen (2002: 1668).
Palan (2002: 172) argues that such small states have gone so far as to prostitute
their sovereign rights. Palan et al. (2010: 187) also argue that the political
independence of small states could be ‘more apparent than real, for their
developmental and social goals are subject to the whim of foreign capital’. A
British government Commission of Enquiry concluded that there was ‘a high
248 G. Baldacchino
probability of systemic corruption’ by elected members of the Turks and Caicos
Islands, leading to a suspension of the constitution (Hampton and Christensen
2010: 10). Autonomous jurisdictions, like the Channel Island Bailiwick of
Jersey, have been accused of having been taken over by international finance
capital, which then aligns the small state to serve its (tax evasive) purposes:
‘having established predominance, the financial services sector used its political
power to secure additional fiscal and regulatory advantages’ (Christensen and
Hampton 1999: 186). Of course, many citizens and scholars from small states
beg to differ (e.g. Gallienne 2007).
Small states are vulnerable to various kinds of organized crime. ‘Here, the
asymmetries between the intelligence and policing resources of the [small] state
and the resourcefulness of the criminals who prey upon it can be immense’
(Bartmann 2007: 301). In the Solomon Islands, corruption is rife in fishing and
forestry, and most of it involves Chinese, Japanese, Koreans and Malaysians,
who ‘often operated corruptly [and] developed close relations with politicians’
(Crocombe 2007: 180). Or take the case of the Bahamas, where a pall of corrup-
tion (financed by drugs trans-shipment and narcotics trade) shrouded the Pin-
dling government and ran deep into society, neutralizing law enforcement
officers and the police force (Bartmann 2007: 303; Bullington 1991: 75). The
Bahamas archipelago, with its myriad islands, inlets and cays that are so difficult
to monitor, is also prone to an illicit ‘refugee trade’, involving refugees from
Haiti (Bartmann 2007: 304–305).

Differently dangerous
In the case of a sub-national jurisdiction like the Turks and Caicos, where White-
hall maintains final executive authority, a serious situation can be, and has been,
tackled by an extra-territorial decision, unpalatable though that may be. But such
measures are by definition unavailable in the case of sovereign states. Inter-
national law, as enshrined in the 1933 Montevideo Convention and the various
principles governing the workings of the United Nations, precludes interference
by states in the internal workings of other sovereign states, irrespective of their
size. Indeed, one of the arguments brought forward in the period after the end of
World War II, against the independence of ‘micro-states’, was that they could
not be trusted to act as responsible states; then, the fear was that a Malta, an
Iceland or a Vanuatu could destabilize finely balanced ‘Cold War’ politics (see
Baldacchino 2009; and Premdas and Howard 1985). In no uncertain terms, The
Economist (1970) called Malta and Iceland ‘damned dots’ for daring to rattle
superpower balance in the early 1970s.
Now, the dangers are different. Neighbouring, larger powers seek to uphold the
security of small states (and indirectly their own) by supporting security pro-
grammes, training police and drug squad personnel, providing intelligence, soft-
ware and hardware (such as surveillance technology, coastguard vessels,
search-and-rescue helicopters). But there are real limits to the effectiveness of such
measures. Ultimately, a serious crisis (social, political, economic, environmental,
The security concerns of designed spaces 249
or a toxic combination of these) will loom in any given small state; this is not a
question of if, but when. Such a situation – as with the 2010 earthquake in Haiti, or
the 2006 coup in Fiji, and, eventually, global warming refugees from Tuvalu? – is
likely to trigger, as a bare minimum, a wave of out-migration, with the most mobile
citizens of the affected small state heading towards richer, more stable, neighbour-
ing countries. It is such access to residence, labour markets and eventual citizen-
ship that remains at the top of the list of aspirations of many small state citizens.
This explains why many sub-national jurisdictions – including some that could
become independent if they wanted to – prefer not to become independent, and
instead consolidate their integration within larger, richer states: the November 2012
decision by Puerto Ricans for their territory to become the fifty-first state of the US
is moot (see The Guardian UK 2012).
Another development that once again puts small states at the forefront of
innovative governance is the growth of the electronic-gaming industry (Bald-
acchino 2010: 78). Attractive locations from which to operate online casinos and
poker rooms now include Alderney, Curaçao, Gibraltar, the Isle of Man and
Matsu islands (Taiwan), but also the sovereign states of Antigua and Barbuda
and Malta (On-Line Casino Locator 2008). Companies that are granted a licence
to operate are typically not permitted to take bets from the citizens of their
respective island base (e.g. On-Line Casino City 2008). Small jurisdictions are
thus attractive to gaming companies, since only a fraction of their potential client
base is legally excluded. (For the small jurisdictions themselves, any high social
impact on gamblers from other countries is, presumably, not their concern.)
Meanwhile, and in spite of various attempts at a crackdown, the operations of
finance capital show no signs of abating, and one should seriously question
whether the continued existence of offshore finance centres owes much to their
valued services within the global political economy. Indeed, the design of legis-
lation by onshore states is just as complicit in the positive and negative effects of
the offshore economy as are the small sovereign economies that host offshore
finance centres (Vlcek 2009). Who, then, is posing the security threat?

Conclusion
‘The openness of small states . . . is . . . structural, and may not be ameliorated by
policy or strategy of any kind’ (Worrell 2012: 6). ‘Governmentality’ can be
problematic when a state finds itself structurally prone to exogenous shocks and
‘invasions’ that can impact on the very fabric of the state. Until a few decades
ago, domestic and international observers would have been concerned with the
likelihood of a Falklands (invaded by Argentina in 1982 and then recovered by
Britain following a military operation); or a Grenada (victim of a violent coup
and then a US-led military intervention in 1983); or a Kuwait (invaded by Iraq in
1990). Today, the temptations versus the practical and moral risks of what have
been termed as the ‘pseudo-development strategies’ of small states pose a more
bewildering dilemma calling for non-traditional policy responses (Baldacchino
1993). The status of small states as sites of imaginative geographies, and the
250 G. Baldacchino
description of their citizens and policy makers as norm entrepreneurs, could be
fruitful lessons in how necessity can prove to be the mother of invention. Indeed,
as Streeten (1993) has cleverly observed, most small states enjoying long-term
prosperity (including Barbados, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg, Malta and Singa-
pore) have few exploitable local and natural resources. In a world gripped by a
wave of neo-liberalism, and in spite of their often assumed role as followers and
powerless pawns in international relations, small states qua states have consider-
able wriggle room for policy manoeuvre, in spite of the visible chagrin of their
larger, notionally more powerful neighbours.
Let us end with another cameo. This time, the focus is on the United Nations
and its Security Council, where attempts to its reform have clashed with the veto
powers of its ‘permanent five’ (P5) members: China, France, Russia, the United
Kingdom and the United States. But in March 2006, a group of five different
countries – Costa Rica, Jordan, Liechtenstein, Singapore and Switzerland –
tabled a resolution to the UN General Assembly, calling for reform to the
working methods of the Security Council: limiting the use of the veto, and
enhancing transparency and accountability (United Nations 2006; see also
MacQueen 2010; Trachsler 2010). These called themselves the ‘S5’: the small
five. Interestingly, this initiative has received a surprising level of support from
some influential countries, including Argentina, Canada and Japan. Of course,
the P5 vetoed it; but here we are still talking about the proposal, and its merits.
‘Soft power’ or ‘weak power’ is especially potent when wielded by those least
expected to (Nye 2004; Lindell and Persson 1986); here, size does matter.

Note
1 See also Chapter 13 in this volume.

Bibliography
Adler-Nissen, R. and Gad, U.P. (eds) (2013) European Integration and Postcolonial
Sovereignty Games: EU’s Overseas Countries and Territories, London: Routledge.
Agamben, G. (2005) State of Exception, translated by K. Attell, Chicago, IL: University
of Chicago Press.
Baker, R.A. (1992) Public Administration in Small and Island States, West Hartford, CT:
Kumarian Press.
Baldacchino, G. (1993) ‘Bursting the Bubble: The Pseudo-development Strategies of
Microstates’, Development and Change, 24(1): 29–51.
Baldacchino, G. (1998) ‘Far Better to Serve in Heaven than to Reign in Hell: Malta’s
Logic of Relating to the European Union’, in Baldacchino, G. and Greenwood, R. (eds)
Competing Strategies of Economic Development from Small Islands, Charlottetown,
PE: Institute of Island Studies, University of Prince Edward Island, pp. 213–238.
Baldacchino, G. (2009) ‘Thucydides or Kissinger? A Critical Review of Smaller State
Diplomacy’, in Shaw, T.M. and Cooper, A.F. (eds) The Diplomacies of Small States:
Between Vulnerability and Resilience in the Global Political Economy, Basingstoke,
Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 21–40.
The security concerns of designed spaces 251
Baldacchino, G. (2010) Island Enclaves: Offshoring Strategies, Creative Governance and
Subnational Island Jurisdictions, Montreal QC: McGill-Queen’s University Press.
Baldacchino, G. (2011) ‘Surfers of the Ocean Waves: Change Management, Intersectoral
Migration and the Economic Development of Small Island States’, Asia Pacific View-
point, 52(3): 236–246.
Baldacchino, G. (2012) ‘Governmentality is all the Rage: The Strategy Games of Small
Jurisdictions’, The Round Table: Commonwealth Journal of International Affairs,
101(3): 235–251.
Baldacchino, G. and Milne, D. (2008) The Case for Non-sovereignty: Lessons from Sub-
national Island Jurisdictions, London: Routledge.
Bartmann, B. (2007) ‘Island War and Security’, in Baldacchino, G. (ed.) A World of
Islands: An Island Studies Reader, Charlottetown PE and Luqa, Malta: Institute of
Island Studies, University of Prince Edward Island and Agenda Academic,
pp. 295–322.
Bigo, D. (2007) ‘Detention of Foreigners, States of Exception, and the Social Practices of
Control of the Panopticon’, in Rajaram, P.K. and Grundy Warr, C. (eds) Borderscapes:
Hidden Geographies and Politics at Territory’s Edge, Minneapolis MN: University of
Minnesota Press, pp. 3–34.
Braun, B. (2000) ‘Producing Vertical Territory: Geology and Governmentality in late
Victorian Canada’, Ecumene/Cultural Geographies, 7(1): 7–46.
Bullington, B. (1991) ‘A Smugglers’ Paradise: Cocaine Trafficking through the
Bahamas’, Crime, Law and Social Change, 16(1): 59–83.
Carse, S. (1998) ‘Sustaining Small Island Development: Isle of Man’, in Baldacchino, G.
and Greenwood. R. (eds) Competing Strategies of Economic Development from Small
Islands, Charlottetown, PE: Institute of Island Studies, University of Prince Edward
Island, pp. 268–291.
Christensen, J. and Hampton, M.P. (1999). ‘A Legislature for Hire: The Capture of the
State in Jersey’s Offshore Finance Centre’, in Hampton, M.P. and Abbott, J.P. (eds)
Offshore Finance Centres and Tax Havens: The Rise of Global Capital, Basingstoke:
Macmillan, pp. 166–191.
Clarke, C. and Payne, T. (eds) (1987) Politics, Security and Development in Small States,
London: Allen & Unwin.
Connell, J. (2006) ‘Nauru: The first failed Pacific State?’, The Round Table: The Com-
monwealth Journal of International Affairs, 95(383): 47–63.
Crocombe, R. (2007) Asia in the Pacific Islands: Replacing the West, Suva, Fiji Islands:
ISP Publications, University of the South Pacific.
Dorsey, J.M. (2012) ‘Jordan, Bahrain and Saudi: Pressures for Reform’, MidEastPosts.
com, 29 October, available online at: http://mideastposts.com/2012/10/jordan-bahrain-
and-saudi-pressures-for-reform/ (accessed 17 May 2013).
Ellis, G. (2005) ‘St Lucia’s Declining Banana Trade’, BBC News, 2 August, available
online at: http://news.bbc.co.uk/1/hi/world/americas/4737473.stm (accessed 17 May
2013).
Fletcher, G.P. (2004) ‘Black Hole in Guantánamo Bay’, Journal of International Crimi-
nal Justice, 2(1): 121–132.
Foucault, M. (1988) ‘The Ethic of Care for the Self as a Practice of Freedom’, in J. Ber-
nauer and D. Rasmussen (eds) The Final Foucault, Boston, MA: MIT Press.
Foucault, M. (1991) ‘Governmentality’, in Burchell, G., Gordon, C. and Miller, P. (eds)
The Foucault Effect: Studies in Governmentality, Chicago IL: University of Chicago
Press, pp. 87–104.
252 G. Baldacchino
Gallienne, T. (2007) Guernsey in the 21st Century: A View from the First Decade, Guern-
sey: Gallant Publishing.
Government of Singapore (2012) ‘Small States’, Ministry of Foreign Affairs, available
online at: www.mfa.gov.sg/content/mfa/international_issues/small_states.html (accessed
17 May 2013).
Grynberg, R. (2006) WTO at the Margins: Small States and the Multilateral Trading
System, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Guardian (UK) (2012) ‘Puerto Ricans Favour Statehood, Poll Shows’, 8 November,
available online at: www.guardian.co.uk/world/2012/nov/08/puerto-ricans-favour-
statehood (accessed 17 May 2013).
Hampton, M.P. and Christensen, J. (2002) ‘Offshore Pariahs? Small Island Economies,
Tax Havens, and the Re-configuration of Global Finance’, World Development 30(9):
1657–1673.
Hampton, M.P. and Christensen, J. (2010) ‘Small Island Economies: Exploring Altern-
ative Development Strategies to Hosting Offshore Finance’, Kent Business School
working paper no. 227, available online at: www.taxjustice.net/cms/upload/pdf/
Hampton__Christensen_what_next_for_OFCs_WP227_July_2010.pdf (accessed 17
May 2013).
Handel, M. (1981) Weak States in the International System, London: Frank Cass.
Hindess, B. (1996) Discourses of Power: From Hobbes to Foucault, Oxford: Blackwell.
Ingebritsen, C. (2002) ‘Norm Entrepreneurs: Scandinavia’s Role in World Politics’,
Cooperation and Conflict, 37(1): 11–23.
Karolak, M. (2010) ‘Religion in a Political Context: The Case of the Kingdom of
Bahrain’, Asia Journal of Global Studies, 4(1): 4–20, available online at: http://ajgs.
org/index.php/AJGS/article/view/77/115 (accessed 17 May 2013).
Kelman, I., Davies, M., Mitchell, T., Orr, I. and Conrich, B. (2006) ‘Island Disaster Para-
diplomacy in the Commonwealth’, The Round Table: The Commonwealth Journal of
International Affairs, 95(386): 561–574.
Keohane, R.O. (1969) ‘Lilliputians’ Dilemmas: Small States in International Politics’,
International Organization, 23(2): 291–310.
Kuelhs, T. (1996) Beyond Sovereign Territory, Minneapolis MN: University of Minne-
sota Press.
Lindell, U. and Persson, S. (1986) ‘The Paradox of Weak State Power: A Research and
Literature Overview’, Conflict and Cooperation, 21(2): 79–97.
Lutterbeck, D. (2009) ‘Small Frontier Island: Malta and the Challenge of Irregular Immi-
gration’, Mediterranean Quarterly, 20(1): 119–144.
Machiavelli, N. (1908 [1515]) The Prince, translated by Marriott, W.K., available online
at: www.constitution.org/mac/prince00.htm (accessed 17 May 2013).
McKenzie, D. (2012) ‘Human Security and the Offshore Financial System: Underdevel-
opment, Corruption and Arms’, available online at: http://visar.csustan.edu/aaba/Mac-
kenzie2012.pdf (accessed 17 May 2013).
MacQueen, B. (2010) ‘Muslim States and Reform of the United Nations Security
Council’, Journal of Middle Eastern and Islamic Studies (in Asia), 4(3): 47–64.
Monbiot, G. (2009) ‘Climate Change Displacement has Begun; But Hardly Anyone has
Noticed’, Guardian (UK), 8 May, available online at: www.guardian.co.uk/environ-
ment/georgemonbiot/2009/may/07/monbiot-climate-change-evacuation (accessed 17
May 2013).
Mountz, A. (2011). ‘The Enforcement Archipelago: Detention, Haunting, and Asylum on
Islands’, Political Geography, 30(3): 118–128.
The security concerns of designed spaces 253
Mouritzen, H. (1997) External Danger and Democracy: Old Nordic Lessons and new
European Challenge, Aldershot: Dartmouth Publishing.
Mouritzen, H., and Wivel, A. (2005) The Geopolitics Of Euro-Atlantic Integration,
London: Routledge.
Neumann, I.B., and Gstöhl, S. (2006) ‘Lilliputians in Gulliver’s World’, in Ingebritsen,
C., Neumann, I.B., Gstöhl, S. and Beyer, J. (eds) Small States in International Rela-
tions, Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press/Reykjavik: University of Iceland
Press, pp. 3–36.
Nye, J.S. Jr (2004) Soft Power: The Means to Success in World Politics, New York:
Public Affairs.
On-Line Casino City (2008) ‘Malta’, available online at: http://online.casinocity.com/
jurisdictions/malta/ (accessed 17 May 2013).
On-Line Casino Locator (2008) ‘Where are internet casinos located?’, available online at:
www.online-casinos.com/beginnersguide/faq6.asp (accessed 17 May 2013).
Palan, R. (1998) ‘Trying to Have Your Cake and Eating It: How and why the State
System has Created Offshore’, International Studies Quarterly, 42(4): 625–644.
Palan, R. (2002) ‘Tax Havens and the Commercialisation of State Sovereignty’, Inter-
national Organisation, 56(1): 151–176.
Palan, R., Murphy, R. and Chavagneux, C. (2010) Tax Havens: How Globalization Really
Works, Ithaca NY: Cornell University Press.
Premdas, R.R. and Howard, M.C. (1985) ‘Vanuatu’s Foreign Policy: Contradictions and
Constraints’, Australian Outlook, 39(3): 177–186.
Reid-Henry, S. (2007) ‘Exceptional Sovereignty? Guantánamo Bay and the Re-colonial
Present’, Antipode, 39(4): 627–648.
Richards, J. (1982) ‘Politics in Small, Independent Communities: Conflict or Consen-
sus?’, Journal of Commonwealth & Comparative Politics, 20(2): 155–171.
Rickli, J.-M. (2008) ‘European Small States’ Military Policies after the Cold War: From
Territorial to Niche Strategies’, Cambridge Review of International Affairs, 21(3):
307–325.
Ridgell, R. (1995) Pacific Nations and Territories: The islands of Micronesia, Melanesia,
and Polynesia, Honolulu, HI: Pacific Region Educational Laboratory.
Roberts, S. (1994) ‘Fictitious Capital, Fictitious Spaces: The Geography of Offshore Fin-
ancial Flows’, in Corbridge, S., Martin, R. and Thrift, N. (eds) Money, Power and
Space, Oxford: Blackwell, pp. 91–115.
Said, E. (1979) Orientalism, New York: Vintage.
Sansone, K. (2011) ‘Asylum Ruling “strengthens” Malta’s Stand for Change’, The Sunday
Times of Malta, 23 January, available online at: www.timesofmalta.com/articles/
view/20110123/local/asylum-ruling-strengthens-malta-s-stand-for-change.346623
(accessed 17 May 2013).
Schaffer, B. (1975). ‘The Politics of Dependence’, in Selwyn, P. (ed.) Development
Policy in Small Countries, London: Croom Helm, pp. 24–53.
Squires, N. (2008) ‘Nauru Scrambles as Australia Closes Island’s Detention Center’,
Christian Science Monitor, 26 March, available online at: www.csmonitor.com/World/
Asia-Pacific/2008/0326/p04s02-woap.html (accessed 17 May 2013).
Streeten, P.P. (1993) ‘Special Problems of Small Countries’, World Development, 21(2):
197–202.
Teerling, J. and King, R. (2012) ‘Of Hubs and Hinterlands: Cyprus as an Insular Space of
Overlapping Diasporas’, Island Studies Journal, 7(1): 19–48.
The Economist (1971) ‘Damned Dots’, London: The Economist Newspapers, 31 July, p. 16.
254 G. Baldacchino
The Economist (1991) ‘The Pacific Idea’, London: The Economist Intelligence Unit, 16
March.
Trachsler, D. (2010) ‘UN Security Council Reform: A Gordian Knot?’, CSS Analysis in
Security Policy, no. 72, Zurich: ETH Zurich, Center for Security Studies, available
online at: http://e-collection.library.ethz.ch/eserv/eth:1585/eth-1585–01.pdf (accessed
17 May 2013).
United Nations (2006) ‘General Assembly Resumes Debate on Security Council Reform,
with Several Divergent Proposals Still under Consideration’, General Assembly
GA/10484, New York: United Nations, available online at: www.un.org/News/Press/
docs/2006/ga10484.doc.htm (accessed 17 May 2013).
Vlcek, W. (2009) ‘Behind an Offshore Mask: Sovereignty Games in the Global Political
Economy’, Third World Quarterly, 30(8): 1465–1481.
Williams, O.H. and Darius, R. (1998) Bananas, the WTO and Adjustment Initiatives in
the Eastern Caribbean Central Bank Area, Mimeo, 16pp, Castries, St Lucia: Eastern
Caribbean Central Bank, available online at: www.eccb-centralbank.org/PDF/Rpann98.
pdf (accessed 17 May 2013).
Winckler, D.F. (2007) Amirs, Admirals and Desert Sailors: Bahrain, the U.S. Navy, and
the Arabian Gulf, Annapolis, MD: US Naval Institute Press.
Worrell, D. (2012) ‘Policies for Stabilization and Growth in Small Very Open Eco-
nomies’, occasional paper no. 85, Washington, DC: Group of Thirty, available online
at: www.group30.org/images/PDF/ReportPDFs/OP85.pdf (accessed 17 May 2013).
Index

Page numbers in italics denote tables, those in bold denote figures.

9/11 see September 11 terrorist attacks autonomy 6–7, 32, 109, 116, 153, 193–4,
205, 229
Abkhazia 33, 155–6 Azerbaijan 156
Āboltiņa, Solvita 118
Afghanistan, Iraq and see Iraq and Bahamas 244, 248
Afghanistan Bahrain 244–5
African Union 30 Bailes, A.J.K. 176
Albania: corruption progress 135; Baku-Tbilisi-Çeyhan pipeline project 156
demographic trend 133; growth rate Baldacchino, G. 60–1
133; NATO membership 138; state Bali 203
weakness ranking 134 Balkans: Icelandic response 104; Western,
Alderney 249 see also Western Balkans
Alliance of Small Island States (AOSIS) Baltic states: adoption of the euro 118;
89 cyber-security 114, 121–3; and the EU
Anckar, D. 168–9, 174 38, 113–14, 117–19, 121; invasions 117;
Andorra 167, 170, 173, 176–7, 179–80 NATO and EU membership 113, 117;
Andreas, P. 234 OECD membership 122; political
Ansip, Andrus 118 identity 119; rebirth of independence
Antigua 249 116; Russian interest 123; security
Armenia 156 environment see Baltic states security
Armstrong, H. 61, 169 environment; security governance
ASEAN (Association of Southeast Asian 123–4; Soviet annexation 116; see also
Nations) 216–18, 234 Estonia
Asian financial crisis 215 Baltic states security environment:
Asian small states: colonialist perspective institutionalized collaboration 116;
203–4; constructivist perspective 203; issues 113; new security challenges
historical perspective 202–6; minimum 120–4; Nordic–Baltic relations 119–20;
prerequisites for a society hospitable to overview 113–15; regional affiliation
206; as political and temporal choices 119–20; size, identity and
constructions 219–20; sources of relationships 115–16; Western
temporal construction 219; see also engagement vs autonomy/neutrality
Singapore; Sri Lanka 116–19
Asian tsunami: Danish response 103; bandwaggoning 26, 35, 96, 99, 178
Finnish response 98–9; Swedish Bangladesh 85
response 75, 100 Barbuda 249
asylum shopping 246 Barnett, J. 81–2, 85
Austria, Congress of Vienna recognition 3 Bartlett, W. 137
256 Index
Bartmann, B. 172 overview 224–6; transnational trends
Beeby, Alfred 176, 192–3 see Caribbean transnational trends;
Bernstein, S. 234 vulnerability to transnational criminality
Bertram, G. 60–1 225
Bessarabia 150 Caribbean transnational trends: civil
Betsill, M.M. 82–3 society 230; crime networks 232–3;
Betzold, C. 89 families 230; governance 233–5; supply
Bishop, M.L. 61 chains 231–2
Bosnia-Herzegovina (BiH): corruption Cashore, B. 234
progress 135; demographic trend 133; casino capitalism 62
EU crisis management and security role Chang, H.-J. 188
139; EU Structured Dialogue 142; lack Chernobyl disaster 81
of political consensus 134; NATO China 9, 85, 203–4, 209, 211–12, 215, 224
membership progress 138; public Christensen, J. 247
expectations of peaceful future 131; Christopher, A.J. 169
radical Islamic infiltration 137; state citizen security 223–5, 229, 233–4
weakness ranking 134 civil forces, need for military cooperation
Botswana: development trajectory see with 36
Botswana’s development trajectory; climate change: economic opportunities
factions of the ruling elite 189; first created by 86–7; and economic security
President 189; mineral wealth 187; 84; impact on small archipelagic states
population at independence 187 243, 246; mitigation and adaptation
Botswana’s development trajectory 85–6; Nordic states’ perspective 106;
189–90; and bureaucratic autonomy small island developing states’
193–5; centrepiece and blueprint 191; vulnerability to 86; and small state
and citizen participation 193; and civil vulnerability 34; threats to international
service training 193; and security 85
developmentalist ideology 191; the Cold War: Asian perspective 204–5,
economic diversification attempts 209, 215–16; Georgian/Moldovan
195–6; elite alliance’s role 189–90; perspectives 149; Icelandic perspective
Financial Assistance Programme (FAP) 177; Nordic perspective 96–7, 107–8
195; growth stimulating institutions 193; Collier, P. 135
and the Landell-Mills affair 192; colonialism 202–3, 205, 208, 223
parastatals 195; and the retention of commodity volatility, and vulnerability 56
expatriates 193 Common Agricultural Policy 178
Bowling, B. 233, 235 comprehensive security 28, 99
Briguglio, L. 50 conflict diamonds 195
Bronfman, A. 232 Confucian culture 203
Buddhism 202, 206–7 Congress of Vienna 3
Burma 205 conscription, Nordic states 98, 100, 103, 108
Bush, George W. 29, 117 construction bubbles 59
Buzan, B. 66, 68–9, 74 Copenhagen School 28
Cordina, G. 56
Cambodia 205, 216 corruption: Bahamian perspective 248;
the Caribbean: banana industry 246–7; Baltic perspective 120; Botswanan
drug trade 223–5, 227, 229, 232–3; perspective 193, 197, 199n1; Caribbean
failed states rankings 229; greatest threat perspective 233; closeness and 72; and
to security 233; historical perspective economic security 61; and offshore
223; homicide rates 229; human finance 241; Singaporean perspective
development rankings 228–9; incomes 212; societal security and 73; Solomon
per capita 228; inter-regional relations Islands perspective 248; Turks and
and 225; post-2015 security outlook Caicos Islands 248; Western Balkan
235–6; redefinition of security in 234; perspective 131, 133, 134–5, 140–1;
security and society 226–9; security Western Balkan rankings 136
Index 257
cosmopolitan small states, internal East Timor 36
stratification 33 Eccardt, T. 170
Costa Rica 37 economic security: Baltic perspective 118,
Côte d’Ivoire 36 121; climate change mitigation and 84;
Council of the Baltic Sea States 105 dimensions of 46; resilience and 57;
creative governance: drivers of 243; security strategies 58–61; vulnerability
inordinate impacts 244–6; non- and 47–57
feasibility of transfer 246–7 electronic-gaming industry 249
crime see organized crime embedded autonomy 194–5
crises, financial see Asian financial crisis; energy security: Baltic perspective 108,
global financial crisis 113–14, 117–18, 122; Georgian
crisis management, international see perspective 159; Moldovan perspective
international crisis management 152
crisis response unit, Iceland’s (ICRU) environmental security: Barnett’s
104–5 proposed definition 82; calls for a
Croatia: corruption performance 135; redefinition of national security 81;
democratic development 131; Caribbean perspective 225; climate
demographic trend 133; entry to the EU change 83–5 (see also climate change);
139; EU expectations 130; military concept analysis 81–4; dimensions of
expenditure 131; NATO membership discourse 81; disease 85;
138; state weakness ranking 134 environmental conflict discourse 82–3;
cronyism 61 free rider approach 87; hazard types
Cuba 35, 244 27; hotspots 85; international security
Curaçao 249 threats 85; need for cooperation 84;
cyber-security: Baltic perspective 114, norm entrepreneurship 88–90; options
121–3; Nordic perspective 100, 105, for small state influence 87–90; vs
106; small state perspective 33 other security dimensions 87;
Cyprus 170, 174, 176–9, 244–6 relevance for small states 84–7; sea
level rise 85; Singaporean perspective
de-securitization 29 217; types of threats 84; Western
Denmark: Baltic assistance provision 103; Balkan perspective 138; see also
‘base and ban’ policy 107; climate climate change
change effects observation 87; defence Estonia: financial reserves accumulation
restructuring 106; GHG reductions 90; 121; nuclear power ambitions 122;
NATO membership 96; norm political identity 119; quest for NATO
entrepreneurship 88; post-Cold War and EU membership 103; Russian
change in power calculations 107; speaking minorities 123
security dilemma 108; security European micro-states 167;
environments 102–4 characteristics 173–6; criteria 169;
Detraz, N. 82–3 current listing 170–3; definitional
Deudney, D. 81 issues 168–9; economic data 175;
developmental state, definitional issues economic strategies 178–80;
188 international power 167, 174;
Diego Garcia 209 membership of international
Đinđić, Zoran, assassination of 144n12 organizations 177; military issues and
Dingwerth, K. 234 solutions 176–7; national identity and
Dominica 246 ethnicity 174; offshore financial
domino theory 205 centres 179; parliament sizes 173;
Drezner, D.W. 179 political and economic elites 173;
drugs: Caribbean perspective 223–5, 227, reliance on neighbouring states 175;
229, 232–3; global value 233; Moldovan role of membership of international
perspective 151; value of US sector 233; organizations 177–8; security issues
Western Balkan perspective 133–5 and solutions 177–8; UN membership
du Toit, P. 193 169–70
258 Index
European Union (EU): acidification defence responsibilities 176; military
strategy 89; aid deployment mechanisms expenditure 131; responsibility for
71; Andorra’s ties 170; Baltic defence of Monaco 176
perspective 113–14, 117–19, 121; Friman, H.R. 234
Caribbean perspective 228, 234, 246;
consular assistance efforts 75; costs of gaming industry 249
drugs sector 233; Cyprus joins 170; Gazprom 119
energy security concerns 117–18; and Geertz, C. 203
European micro-states’ security 179; geography, and vulnerability 56, 85
Georgian perspective 155, 158–60; geopolitical environment, impact of post-
‘homeland’ security support 38; impact war transformation 4
of perceived moral liberalism 119; Georgia: alliances with Turkey and
influence of small states in 88; Azerbaijan 159; breakaway republics
intervention competence 29–30; and 33, 155; declaration of independence
irregular migration 244, 246; location of 156; defence upgrade 157; and the EU
key institutions 171; Malta joins 171; 155; geopolitical/strategic comparison
military expenditure 131; Moldovan with Moldova 159–61; geostrategic
perspective 150, 152–5, 160; Nordic location 155; relations between NATO
perspective 98–101, 103, 106–8; and 157; and the United States 155–8,
regional counting procedures 59; 159; war with Russia 157; Baku-Tbilisi-
security actor development 4; sheltering Çeyhan pipeline project 156; EU and
value and sources 38–9; sovereignty NATO’s roles 158; ISAF contribution
modifications 39; Western Balkan 158; Rose Revolution 156; Russia and
perspective 130–1, 133, 135, 137, 155
138–9, 142 Gibraltar 179, 249
Europeanization 4, 113–14, 117, 120, 139 global financial crisis: Baltic perspective
Evans, P. 198 121; Icelandic perspective 105, 107;
export composition, and vulnerability 55–6 micro-states’ vulnerability 175; and
export earnings, volatility in 60 remittance flows 230; and small island
Exxon Valdes oil spill 81 developing states 232; and small state
vulnerability 26–7, 54, 58; Western
failed states 189, 242 Balkan perspective 137
Faroe Islands 96, 108 global warming: impact on small island
Ferrugia, N. 56 states 34, 249; Singaporean perspective
Fiji 249 217; see also climate change
financial crises see Asian financial crisis; globalization: Caribbean perspective 223,
global financial crisis 231; and novel forms of supply 232; and
Finland: bandwaggoning policy 99; regional identity 119; threats inherent in
defence posture 98; and the EU 38; and 62
global security challenges 98–9; norm Gore, Al 83
entrepreneurship 88; and the Petersberg governance: creativity in 242, 244 (see
Tasks 98; security environment 98–9; also creative governance); good 57–9,
societal security expertise 71 61, 140, 178, 241
foreign aid, small country effect 245 governmentality 242
foreign trade dependence, and greenhouse gas emissions 85–7, 89–90
vulnerability 60 Greenland 87, 96, 108
Former Yugoslavian Republic of Grenada 35, 246
Macedonia see Macedonia growth, good governance and 61
fortress mentality 40 Grybauskaitė, Dalia 114
Foucault, M. 242 Gstöhl, S. 84
Fox, A.B. 3, 220 GUAM organization 36
France: Andorran treaty obligations 170; Guantánamo Bay 244
Congress of Vienna recognition 3; Cote Guernsey 179
d’Ivoire intervention 36; micro-state Gulf War 4
Index 259
Guyana 228–9, 230, 233 international agreements, and resilience 60
Gylfason, F. 176 international crisis management, Nordic
states’ involvement 98, 100, 103–4
Habibie, B.J. 215 international organizations, European
Haiti 34, 101, 228–9, 231, 233, 248–9 micro-state membership 177
Hampton, M.P. 247 international security, defining small states
hard security 35–7, 103, 115, 117, 123, in 5–9
133, 149, 153, 160 international security threats,
Harden, S. 168 environmental security 85 (see also
Helveg Petersen, Niels 103 climate change; environmental security)
Hinduism 206 international society, development of 6
homeland security 67 intervention by large states, examples of
Hong Kong 244 35–6
Hudson, D. 195 Inuit communities, environmental threats
human capital 48, 52, 61 to 85
human rights: Baltic perspective 117, Iran 159
119–20; Russian perspective 123; Sri Iraq and Afghanistan 4, 37, 121, 155;
Lankan perspective 210 Baltic perspective 121; Georgian
human security: Caribbean perspective perspective 155–8; Nordic perspective
223, 233; doctrine analysis 28, 67; 101, 103, 106; and small state security 4
environmental security and 81–3; Iraq war 156
UNDP roots 82; Western attitudes 68 Ireland 38, 58–9
human trafficking 98, 105, 133–4, 151 Isle of Man 179, 249
humanitarian intervention 28 isolation: states which have chosen self-
hydropower 86 sufficiency and 46; and vulnerability 57

Iceland: airspace issues 108; Jamaica 228–9, 230, 233


bandwaggoning 96; banking collapse Japan 203
174; characteristics 176; climate change Jean, Michaëlle 231
and 86; Cold War strategic importance Jersey 180, 248
177; crisis response unit (ICRU) 104–5; Johnson, C. 191
currency 175; GHG emissions 86;
Kyoto exemptions 86; military security Kashmir 208
176; national currency 175; NATO Katzenstein, P.J. 59
membership 96, 176; norm Keohane, R.O. 241
entrepreneurship 88; perceptions of Khama, Seretse 188–9, 192
causes of security/insecurity 106; Kimberley Process 234
security environment 104–5, 170–1; size Kiribati 243
of government 173; societal security Kohr, L. 172
expertise 71; UN membership 170 Kola Peninsula 96
Ilves, Toomas Hendrik 114 Korea 203
immigration: securitization theory on 68; Kosovo: corruption performance 135; EU
and social exclusion 105; and societal security role 139, 142; international
security 72 recognition 131; NATO membership
import demand, consequences of high ambitions 138; radical Islamic
levels 48 infiltration 137
India 85, 205, 207–12, 216, 224 Kronsell, A. 89
Indian Ocean tsunami see Asian tsunami Kyoto Protocol 86, 89, 225
Indian Ocean Zone of Peace 209
Indonesia 106, 204, 210–11, 214–15, 244 Landell-Mills, Pierre 192–3
Ingebritsen, C. 37, 88 Laos 205, 216
insecurity: defining 47; risk vs 47 large state intervention, examples of 35–6
institutions, sheltering 38–9 Lebanon 75
internal security issues 28 Lee Kuan Yew 213, 216
260 Index
Leftwich, A. 198 geopolitical/strategic comparison with
Lévy, B.-H. 114 Georgia 159–61; historical perspective
Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam (LTTE) 151; identity issues 151; location 150;
208–10 neutrality 153; relationship with EU
Libya 106 154–5; and Russia 151–3, 155; strategic
Liechtenstein 171, 173, 176–7, 179, 244 importance 152; and the Transnistrian
Lisbon Treaty 71 conflict 150, 152–3, 155
Lobjakas, A. 116 Molutsi, P. 189
Luxembourg 171, 175–9, 244 Monaco 167, 172, 174, 176, 179–80
Mongolia 203
Maass, M. 168 Montenegro: corruption performance 135;
Maastricht Treaty 109n3 criminality allegations 33; demographic
Macedonia: corruption progress 135; trend 133; historical perspective 172;
demographic trend 133; military NATO membership application 177;
expenditure 131; state weakness ranking parliamentary representatives 173;
134 population 130; state capacity 131
Machiavelli, Niccolò 242 Montevideo Convention 248
Madeira 180 multi-dimensional version of security 28
Malaya 204–5, 211
Malaysia 211, 214–15 Nairn, T. 168, 170
Maldives 208, 243 nation-state: monopoly of violence 28;
Mali 103 realist and Westphalian approaches 28
Malta 171, 176–9, 244–6, 249 national security, calls for a redefinition of
marginalization 32 81
market concentration, and vulnerability 55 NATO: aid deployment mechanisms 71;
Marshall Islands 243 Baltic perspective 113, 117, 121;
Masire, Quett 192 European micro-states perspective 171,
material power capabilities 6 176–7; Finnish perspective 99; Georgian
Mathew, J.T. 81 perspective 155, 157–9; Icelandic
Matsu Islands 249 perspective 104, 170, 177; intervention
Maundeni, Z. 191, 194 competence 29–30; membership criteria
Mauritius 244 151; Moldovan perspective 150, 153;
Mexico 224, 230 Nordic perspective 96, 98, 101–3,
micro-states: arguments against 107–8; Partnership for Peace 99, 117,
independence 248; definition 8, 169; 138; relations between Georgia and 157;
global total 169; and taxation 180; Swedish perspective 99; and
Western Balkan 130; see also European Transnistria 160; Western Balkan
micro-states perspective 133, 138
migration: Caribbean perspective 230; natural disasters 27–8, 38, 67, 69, 80, 105,
climate change and 243, 246 231, 247
military expenditure: global levels 131; as Nauru 244–5
proxy for power resource measurement nepotism 61, 72
6, 8; Western Balkan perspective 130 Netherlands 119, 150, 230
military security 7, 82, 102, 133, 176 Neumann, I.B 84
Miniotaitė, G. 119 neutrality 32, 116, 153, 170, 172, 176, 194
Mkandawire, T. 188, 191 New Zealand 37
Mmusi, Peter 188, 192 non-state transnational phenomena,
modern security, Buzan’s sub-divisions 67 regional cooperation 38
Mogae, Festus 192, 194 non-state violence 28, 101, 149
Mohamed, A.N. 169 non-zero-sum peaceful cooperation 37
Moldova 117; biggest challenge to security Nordic states: Baltic collaboration 117;
150; election crisis 154; ethnic and cyber-security 100, 105, 106; energy
social composition 151; GDP per capita security 118; impact on global norms
150; geopolitical context 150–1; and ambitions 37; post-Cold War
Index 261
relationship 95; some comparisons 95; Palan, R. 179, 247
see also individual states Palestine, UN status 180n2
Nordic states’ security environments: Panama 35
Arctic Council membership 106; pandemics 28, 34, 62, 69, 99, 105, 178
background 96–7; challenges and Pantin, D. 226
responses 105–6; and the Cold War Papua New Guinea 85
96–7; Denmark 102–4; differences 106; parastatals 195
disarmament initiatives 107; evaluation Pardo, Arvid 174
107–9; Finland 98–9; Haga cooperation Partnership for Peace (NATO) 99, 117,
106; Iceland 104–5; institutionalized 138
cooperation 105, 108; national Payne, A. 168
challenges and responses 97–105; peace missions 30, 39
NATO membership 96; Norway 101–2; peacekeeping: Moldovan perspective 155;
post-Cold War policy options 97; Nordic perspective 97–8, 101, 103,
Sweden 99–101; unanswered dilemmas 107–8; Sri Lankan perspective 208
108 Pedra Branca 214
Nordstream gas pipeline 118 Picard, L. 189
norm entrepreneurship: AOSIS 89; Baltic piracy 38
perspective 118; factors for effective Pitcairn 242
89–90; Nordic perspective 37, 88, 90; Plischke, E. 169
requirements 87; small island The Politics of Development in Botswana
developing states 89; smallness and 243 (Picard) 189
North Vietnam 215 population size: as criterion for micro-
Northern Europe, climate change and new statehood 169; immigration and 246; of
opportunities 86 micro-states 8; as proxy of economic
Northern-hemisphere small states, focus of characteristics 8; as small state indicator
mainstream literature 27 6, 47; Western Balkan perspective 130
Norway: carbon neutral ambitions 87; Portugal 59
NATO membership 96; norm poverty 48, 121, 137, 150, 198, 211
entrepreneurship 88; security power: measuring 6; Waltz on 6–7
environment 101–2 power possession definition of small states
6–8
Oest, K.J.N. 169 price volatility, solutions for 60
offshore activities: Asian perspective 244; Prussia, Congress of Vienna recognition 3
Australian perspective 243; Caribbean
perspective 224, 231; European Micro quality of life, safeguarding 30
state perspective 175, 179–80; examples
of 243–4; global political value 249; Rajapaksa, Mahinda 210
Guantánamo Bay 244; offshore finance Rajaratnam, S. 213
as threat to human security 241; Rasmussen, A.F. 103
vilification 241, 247; world’s premier Read, R. 61, 169
offshore finance centres 244 reconciliation, Western Balkan policy 142
Oldfield, S. 197 refugee issues: Bahamian perspective 248;
online casinos 176, 249 environmental 248–9; Nordic
Organization for Security and Cooperation perspective 107; Sri Lankan perspective
in Europe (OSCE) 29 210
organized crime: Caribbean perspective Regional Cooperation Council (RCC) 140
232–3; Nordic perspective 98, 105; relative size 26, 46–9, 54, 84, 150
small states’ vulnerability to 248; remittances: Caribbean perspective 230;
Western Balkan perspective 131, 133, ‘imaginative geographies’ and 242;
134–5, 141 Moldovan perspective 151; problematic
Ottawa Process 234 overlap with money-laundering and
drugs income 230
Pakistan 205 renewable energy 84, 86, 118, 122
262 Index
repatriation, tourism and 74 small state security 4; and US/Russian
Republic of Moldova see Moldova anti-terrorist cooperation 156
resilience: concept analysis 57; economic Serbia: corruption progress 135;
resilience index 57, 58; economic demographic trend 133; military
security and 57; elements 57; expenditure 131; population 130; state
international agreements and 60; social weakness ranking 134
cohesion and 59; volatility solutions and Seychelles 42n13
60 sheltering institutions 38–9
resource curse 60 Sierra Leone 36, 187
responsibility to protect, UN definition Simpson, A.W. 169
42n6 Singapore: British perspective 212; Cold
risk: insecurity and 47–8; smallness and War perspective 215–16; colonial past
32; under-development and 49 211; demographic profile 213;
Romania 9, 152, 154 environmental issues 217; external
Rose Revolution, Georgia 156 sources of insecurity and coping
Rothstein, R. 7 strategies 214–17; founding of Forum of
Russia: Baltic interest group sponsorship Small States 216; intermestic security
123; Baltic states’ preoccupation 113; challenges 217–19; and international/
Congress of Vienna recognition 3; regional organizations 216; Japanese
determinants of European countries’ occupation 212; land area 210;
modern-day relations with 116; Finnish Malaysian perspective 213; military
perspective 99; and Georgia 155; strength 215; nationalist politics 211;
Moldova and 151–3, 155; roots of non-traditional security issues 217;
national identity 116; view of the Baltic Pedra Branca dispute 214; pillars of
states 116; view of Transnistria 152 internal security 213–14; ‘political
Russkiy Mir Foundation 123 baggage’ issues 214–15; relations with
Russo-Georgian War 100, 155 America 216; relations with Indonesia
215; sources of external threat 214; state
Saakashvili, Mikhail 156 and nation building issues 210, 214;
Samatar, A. 189, 192, 197 ‘tight ship’ analogy 213; total defence
San Marino 37, 172, 174, 177, 179 concept 218
Sark 179 size: the question of 47; vulnerability’s
satellite status 26 relationship to 52
Schengen Treaty 38, 118 small economies, levels of vulnerability 34
sea level 34, 83, 85–6, 243, 246 small island developing states (SIDS):
securitization theory, analysis 28–9, 68 definition 58; the global financial crisis
security: increasing institutionalization of and 232; international influence 89, 234;
36; internal issues 28 vulnerability index development 49;
security agenda: defining a 28–32; vulnerability to climate change 86
fragmented application 27 small state security, focus of analyses 6
Security Cooperation Organization (SCO) small state vulnerabilities: literature review
9 26–7; review of 32–4
security governance, Baltic perspective small states: definitions 5–9, 242;
123–4 disproportionate role 247; economic
security organizations, characteristics advantages 59; prostitution of sovereign
29–30 rights 247; specific challenges for 32–4;
self-sufficiency 73 vulnerability to organized crime 248
Senegal 103 smallness, benefits of 34
Sepos, A. 174 smuggling 38, 70, 150
September 11 terrorist attacks (9/11): social cohesion, and resilience 59
Danish response 103; as example of big- societal security: advantages 73; Baltic
state power imposition 73; and Indian perspective 123; concept development
concerns with Islamist terrorism 208; 68; concepts and principles 71–2; a
and the re-labelling of terrorism 29; and critique 74–6; and human security
Index 263
doctrine 67–8; military perspective 67; environment 99–101; widening of
Norwegian definition 69–70; practical security scope 100
agenda setting 69–71; practical Switzerland 59
difficulties 75–6; practical implications
72–4; relevance for small states 71–4; vs Taiwan 35, 205
social security 67; theoretical origins Tamil Tigers (LTTE) 208–10
and comparisons 66–8; transnational tax havens 170–1, 175, 179–80, 243
nature of many challenges 70, 73 technology, and small state vulnerability
soft security 39, 99–100, 103, 106, 117, 33
118–19, 120, 123, 133, 134, 140, 154, terrorism 70; Bush administration’s
160 re-labelling 29; European micro-state
Solomon Islands 248 perspective 171, 179; Finnish
Somalia 37 perspective 98; Indian perspective 208;
Somaliland 242 in Malaya 204; Nordic perspective 97;
South Asian Association for Regional small states’ vulnerability to 33; and
Cooperation (SAARC) 209 societal security expertise 71; Swedish
South-East European Stability Pact 140 perspective 100; and tourism 33;
South Vietnam 205 Western Balkan perspective 137; see
South Yemen 242 also September 11 terrorist attacks
sovereignty, key capacity of 242 Third World 8
Soviet Union 4, 96, 98, 104, 149, 152 Thorhallsson, B. 115
Spain 59, 176 Thucydides 3
Sri Lanka: as bulwark against Soviet and tourism 74, 242; Caribbean perspective
Chinese encroachment 205; Chinese 247; climate change and 86; European
investments 209; external sources of micro-state perspective 170, 171, 172,
insecurity and coping strategies 208–9; 176, 178–9; and risk 34, 74; terrorism
independence 207; intermestic security and 33
challenges 210; LTTE insurgency trade agreements 4, 154, 159, 216
208–10; Norwegian peace brokering trade dependence, and vulnerability 54
106; official language 207; Peace Zone traditional security establishments,
initiative 209; relations with India growing tendency to challenge 30
208–9; SAARC membership 209; Transcaucasian Federated Soviet Socialist
sources of ethnic conflict 207; state and Republic (TcFSSR) 156
nation-building issues 206–8 Transnistria 33, 150–3, 155, 160–1, 169
St Lucia 246–7 Tsie, B. 197
St Vincent 246 tsunami, Indian Ocean see Asian tsunami
state extantism 242 Turkey 133, 156, 158–60, 170
statehood, importance of 242 Turks and Caicos Islands 248
Stojarová, V. 135 Tuvalu 243, 246, 249
Stoltenberg Report 96, 106
strategic options: hard security and inter- Undén Plan 107
state diplomacy 35–7; practical United Kingdom (UK): Caribbean
perspective 39–41; wider security and perspective 231, 246; Congress of
new institutional roles 37–9 Vienna recognition 3; Mediterranean
sub-national jurisdictions 242, 244, 248–9 bases 177; military expenditure 131;
subversion 27, 33, 69 Norwegian military relationship 101;
Sudan 106 Sierra Leone intervention 36
Suharto 215 United Nations (UN): Conference on the
Sukarno 215 Human Environment 81; and the Cyprus
supply constraints, for small states 48 problem 174; decolonization role 4;
Sutton, P. 168 development role 49, 52, 58; East Timor
Sweden: EU membership 99; GHG and Kosovo roles 36; and environmental
reductions 90; military strength 107; security 81; establishment and
norm entrepreneurship 88–9; security development 4; European micro-states
264 Index
United Nations (UN) continued organized crime 248; relationship to size
perspective 169, 176–7; examples of 52; term analysis 47; trade dependence
intervention by 36; Iceland joins 170; and 54
and the Indian Ocean Zone of Peace
209; Liechtenstein joins 171; Wahid, Abdurrahman 215
membership and micro-state definitions Waltz, K.N. 6
169; Moldovan perspective 153; Nordic war crimes, Western Balkan perspective
perspective 97–8, 101, 107; Security 134, 141
Council 83; security role 39; war on drugs 232, 235
Singaporean perspective 215–16; Sri war on terror 29
Lankan perspective 208 Warrington, E. 168–9
United States (US): Baltic perspective 117, Wæver, O. 28, 69, 74
121; bandwaggoning opportunities 35, Western Balkan security environment:
96, 178; costs of the drugs sector 233; civil security threats 138; corruption and
examples of intervention by 35; organized crime 134–5; demographic
Georgian perspective 155–8, 159; and trends 133; economic and social threats
the GUAM grouping 159; impact on 135–7; hard security vs soft security
small state security 245; Nordic threats 133; military expenditure 131;
perspective 96, 101, 104, 106–7; national responses to security threats
offshore activities 244; and small state 141–2; regional analysis 130–3; regional
security 9, 73; vulnerability to climate cooperation 140–1; role of NATO and
change 85 the EU 138–9; state weaknesses 134;
terrorism 137; vulnerability to
Vatican City State 167–9, 172–6, 179 environmental threats and natural
Väyrynen, R. 8 hazards 138
violence 28–9, 33, 67, 81, 229, 232; Western Balkans: global corruption
environmental conflict discourse 82; Sri rankings 136; population growth rates
Lanka 208 133; regional analysis 130; selected
Vital, D. 8, 220 basic indicators 132; unemployment
vulnerability: commodity volatility and 56; figures 137; see also individual states
components 54–7; to disasters 56; to Wivel, A. 169
environmental threats 84–5; export World War II 32, 96, 116, 152, 176, 211,
composition and 55–6; geography and 248
56, 85; indices 49, 50, 51, 52, 54, 55;
market concentration and 55; to Zanzibar 242

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy