Mode Split
Mode Split
Modal Split
Introduction
The third stage in travel demand modeling is modal split. The trip matrix or O-D
matrix obtained from the trip distribution is sliced into number of matrices
representing each mode. First the significance and factors affecting mode choice
problem will be discussed. Then a brief discussion on the classification of mode
choice will be made. Two types of mode choice models will be discussed in detail.
The binary mode choice and multinomial mode choice. The chapter ends with some
discussion on future topics in mode choice problem.
This model has both advantages and dis advantages for crime analysis. At a
theoretical level, it is the most developed of the four stages since there has been
extensive research on travel mode choice. For crime analysis, on the other hand, it
represents the ‘weakest link’ in the analysis since there is very little available
information on travel mode by offenders. Since researchers cannot interview the
general public in order to document crimes committed by respondents or, in most
cases, even interview offenders after they have been caught, there is very little
information on travel mode by offenders that has been collected.
Consequently, we have to depend on the existing theory of travel mode choice and
adapt it intuitively to crime data. The approach is solely theoretical and depends on
the validity of the existing theory and on the intuitiveness of guesses. Hopefully, in
the future, there will be more information collected t ha t would allow the model to
be calibrated against some real data. But, for the time being, we are limited in what
can be done.
Mode choice
The choice of transport mode is probably one of the most important classic models
in transport planning. This is because of the key role played by public transport in
policy making. Public transport modes make use of road space more efficiently than
private transport. Also they have more social benefits like if more people begin to
use public transport, there will be less congestion on the roads and the accidents will
be less. Again in public transport, we can travel with low cost. In addition, the fuel
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
is used more efficiently. Main characteristics of public transport is that they will
have some particular schedule, frequency etc.
On the other hand, private transport is highly flexible. It provides more comfortable
and convenient travel. It has better accessibility also. The issue of mode choice,
therefore, is probably the single most important element in transport planning and
policy making. It affects the general efficiency with which we can travel in urban
areas. It is important then to develop and use models which are sensitive to those
travel attributes that influence individual choices of mode.
Theoretical Background
The theoretical background behind the mode split module is presented first. Next,
the specific procedures are discussed with the model being illustrated with data from
Baltimore County.
The key aim of mode choice analysis is to distinguish the travel mode that travelers
(or, in the case of crime, offenders) use in traveling between an origin location and
a destination location. In the travel demand model, the choice is for travel between
a particular origin zone and a particular destination zone. Thus, the trips that ar e
distributed from each origin zone to each destination zone in the trip distribution
module ar e further split into distinct travel modes. With few exception s, the
assumption behind the mode split decision is for a two-way trip. That is, if an
offender decides on driving to a particular crime location, we normally assume that
this person will also drive back to the origin location. Similarly, if the offender takes
a bus to a crime location, then that person will also take the bus back to the origin
location. There are, of course, exceptions. A ca r thief ma y take a bus t o a crime
location, then steal a car and drive back. But, in general, without information to the
contrary, it is assumed that the travel mode is for a round trip journey.
where ‘f’ is some function of the benefits and the costs. The benefits have to do with
the advantages in traveling to a particular destination from a particular origin while
the costs have to do with the real and perceived costs of using a particular mode.
Since the benefits of traveling a particular destination from a particular origin are
probably equal, the differences in utility between travel modes essentially represent
differences in costs. Thu s, equation below breaks down to:
If different travel modes (e.g., driving, biking, and walking) ar e each represented
by a separate utility cost function, then they can be compared:
where Utility cost 1 through Utility costL represents L distinct travel modes, cost 1
through cost k represent k cost components an d ar e variables, an d F1 through FL
represent L different utility function s (one for each mode).
There are several observations that can be made about this representation. First, each
of the cost components can be applied to all modes. However, the cost components
are variables in that the values may or may not be the same. For example, if cost 1 is
the operating cost of traveling from an origin t o a destination, the cost for a driver
is, of course, a lot higher than for a bus passenger since the latter person shares that
cost with other passengers. Similarly, if cost 2 is the travel time from a particular
origin zone to a particular destination zone, then travel by private automobile may
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
be a lot quicker than by public bus. As mentioned, time differences can be converted
in to costs by applying some type of hourly wage/price to the time. To take one more
example, for driving mode, there could be a cost in parking (e.g., in a central business
district); for transit use, on the other hand, this cost component is zero. In other
words, each of the travel modes has a different cost structure. The same costs can be
enumerated, but some of them will not apply (i.e., they have a value of 0).
Second, the costs can be perceived costs a s well a s rea l costs. For example, a
number of studies have demonstrated that private automobile is seen as far more
convenient to most people than a bus or train (e.g., see Schnell, Smith, Dimsdale,
and Thrasher, 1973; Roemer and Sinha , 1974; WASH COG, 1974; Carnegie-Mellon
University, 1975; Johnson, 1978; Levine and Wachs, 1986b). ‘Convenience’ is
defined in terms of ease of access and effort involved in travel (e.g., how long it
takes to walk to a bus stop from an origin location, the number of transfers that have
to made to reach a final destination, and the time it takes to walk from the last bus
stop to the final destination). While it is sometimes difficult to separate the effects
of convenience from travel itself, it is clear that most people perceive this as
dimension in travel choice. In t urn, convenience can be converted in to a monetary
value in order to allow it to be calculated in a cost equation, for example how much
people are willing to pay in time savings to yield an equivalent amount of
convenience (e.g., asking how many more minutes in travel time by bus a n
individual would be willing to absorb in order to give up having to drive).
On the other hand, at an individual level, the costs are specific to the individual. For
example, travel time differences between car and bus can be converted into an hourly
wage using the individual’s income; someone making $100,000 a year is going to
price that time savings differently than someone making only $25,000 a year. Fourth,
a more controversial point, the specific mathematical function that ties the costs
together into a particular utility function may also differ. Typically, most travel
demand models have assumed t ha t a similar mathematical function is used for all
travel modes; this is the negative exponential function described below (Domencich
and McFadden , 1975; Ortuzar an d Willumsen, 2001). However, there is no rea son
why different function s cannot be used. Thus, the equation s above identify different
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
function s for the modes, F1 through F L. One can thin k of this in terms of weights.
Each of the different mathematical function weigh t the cost components differently.
A good mode choice should include the most important of these factors.
The advantage is that these models could be very accurate in the short run, if public
transport is available and there is little congestion. Limitation is that they are
insensitive to policy decisions example: Improving public transport, restricting
parking etc. would have no effect on modal split according to these trip-end models.
(1)
where tijv is the in-vehicle travel time between i and j, t ijw is the walking time to and
from stops, tijt is the waiting time at stops, Fij is the fare charged to travel
between i and j, ϕj is the parking cost, and δ is a parameter representing comfort and
convenience. If the travel cost is low, then that mode has more probability of being
chosen. Let there be two modes (m=1,2) then the proportion of trips by mode 1 from
zone i to zone j is(Pij1) Let cij1 be the cost of traveling from zone i to zone j using the
mode 1, and cij2 be the cost of traveling from zone i to zone j by mode 2,there are
three cases:
(2)
This functional form is called logit, where cij is called the generalized cost and β is
the parameter for calibration. The graph in figure 1 shows the proportion of trips by
mode 1 (Tij1∕T ij) against cost difference.
No matter how the utility function s are defined, they have to be combined in such a
way as to allow a discrete choice. That is, a n offender in traveling from zone A to
zone B makes a discrete choice on travel mode. There may be a probability for travel
by each mode, for example 60% by ca r and 40% by bus. But, for an individual, the
choice is car or bus, not a probability. The probabilities are obtained by a sample of
individuals, for example of 10 individuals 6 went by car and 4 went by bus. But,
still, at the individual level, there is a distinct choice that was made.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
Multinomial Logit Function
where PijL is the probability of using a mode for any particular trip pair (particular
origin and particular destination) L is the travel mode, Cij is the cost of traveling from
origin zone i to destination zone j, e is the base of the natural logarithm, an d $ is a
coefficient. Several observations can be made about this function. First, each travel
mode, L, has its own costs and benefits, and can be evaluated by itself. That is, there
is a distinct utility function for each mode. This is the numerator of the equation, e
(-$C ijL). However, the choice of any one mode is dependent on its utility value
relative to other modes (the denominator of the equation). The more choices t ha t ar
e available, obviously, the less likely an individual will use that mode. But the value
associated with the mode (the utility) does not change. As mentioned above, we
generally assume that the benefit of traveling between any two zones is identical for
all modes and, hence, any differences a r e du e t o costs.
Second, the mathematical form is the negative exponential. The exponential function
is a growth function in which growth occurs at a constant rate (either positive -
growth, or negative - decline). The use of the negative exponential assumes that the
costs are related to the likelihood as a function that declines at a constant rate. It is
actually a ‘disincentive’ or ‘dis \count’ function rather than a utility function, per se.
That is, as the costs increase, the probability of using that mode decreases, all other
things being equation. Still, for historical reasons, it is still called a utility function.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
Where: the terms are the same as in previous except the function, FL, is some
function that is specific to the travel mode, L. The numerator is defined as the
impedance of mode L in traveling between two zones i and j, while the denominator
is the sum of all impedances.
Notice that the ratio of the cost function for one mode relative to the total costs is
also the ratio of the impedance for mode L relative the tot a l impedance. The tot a l
impedance was defined previously as the disincentive to travel a s a function of
separation (distance, travel time, cost). We see that the share of a particular mode,
therefor e, is the proportion of the total impedance of that mode. This share will vary,
of course, with the degree of separation. For any given separation, there will usually
be a different share for each mode. For example, at low separation between zones
(e.g., zones that are next to each other), walking and biking ar e much more attractive
than taking a bus or a train and, perhaps even driving. At greater separation (e.g.,
zones t ha t ar e 5 miles apart), walking and biking are a l most irrelevant choices
and the likelihood of driving or u sing public transit is much greater. In other words,
the share that any one mode occupies is not constant, but varies with the impedance
function.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
Why then can’t we estimate the mode split directly at the trip distribution stage? If
the trip distribution function is:
where TijL is the number of trips between two zones, i and j, by mode L, P i is the
production capacity of zone i, Aj is the attraction of zone j, " an d $ are constants
that are applied to the productions and attractions respectively, 8 an d J ar e
‘finetuning’ exponents of the productions and attractions respectively, an d IijL, is the
impedance of using mode L to travel between the two zones? The answer is, yes, it
could be calculated directly. If IijL was a perfectly defined mode impedance function
(with no error), then the mode share could be calculated directly at the distribution
stage instead of separating the calculations into two distinct stages. The problem,
however, is that the impedance functions are never perfect (far from it, in fact) and
t ha t re-scaling is required both to get the origin s and destinations balanced in the
trip distribution stage and to ensure that the probabilities in equation above add to
1.0.
The next question is what types of travel costs are there that define impedance? As
mentioned above, there ar e real a s well as perceived costs that affect a travel mode
decision. Some of these can be measured easily, while others are very difficult
requiring detailed surveys of individuals. Among these costs are:
Some of these costs can be measured and some cannot. For example, the value of
travel time can be inferred from the median household income of a zone for
aggregate analysis or from the actual household income for individual-level analysis.
Parking can be averaged by zone. Insurance costs can be estimated from zone
averages if the da t a can be obtained. Many perceived costs also can be measured.
Convenience, for example, could be measured from a general survey. The fear of
being ca ugh t can be inferred from the amount of surveillance in a zone (e.g., the
number of police personnel, security guards, security cameras). Even though it may
be a difficult enumeration process, it is still possible to mea sure these costs and
come up with some a verage estimate. Other perceived costs, on the other hand, may
not be easily measured. For example, the fear an offender belonging to one gang has
about retaliation from another gang is not easily measured. Similarly, the costs in
moving stolen goods by a thief is not easily measured; one would need to know the
location of the distributors of these goods. In practice, travel modelers make simple
assumption s about costs because of the difficult y in measuring many of them. For
example, travel time is taken as a proxy for all the operating costs. Parking costs can
be incorporated through simple assumption s about the distribution a cross zones
(e.g., zones within the central business distract - CBD, ar e given an average high
parking costs; zones that are central, but not in the CBD, are assigned moderate
parking costs; zones t ha t ar e suburban ar e assigned low parking costs). It would
be just too time consuming to document each and every cost affecting travel
behavior, particularly if we are developing a model of offender travel.
The aggregate approach will measure costs by averages. Thus, a typical equation for
driving mode might be:
Where: Tij is the average travel time between two zones, i and j, an d Pij is the average
parking cost for parking in zone j. Notice that there a r e a limited number of variables
in an aggregate model (in this case, only two) and t ha t the assigned average is for
an entire zone. Notice also that the parking cost is applied only to the destination
zone. It is assumed that any traveler will pay t ha t fee in that zone irrespective of
which origin zone he/she came from.
A disaggregate approach can allow more cost components, if they are measured.
Thus, a typical equation for driving mode might be:
where Tijk is the travel time for individual k between two zones, i and j, Pij is the
average parking cost for parking in zone j, Cijk is the convenience of traveling to
zone j from zone i for individual k , CMijk is the comfort and privacy experienced by
individual k in traveling from zone i to zone j, and Sijk is the perceived safety
experienced by individual k in traveling from zone i to zone j. Notice that there ar e
more cost variables in the equation and t ha t the model is targeted specifically to the
individual, k . Two individuals who live next door to each other and who travel to
the same destination may evaluate these components differently. If these individuals
have substantially different incomes, then the value of the travel time will differ. If
one values privacy enormously while the other doesn’t, then the cost of driving for
the first is less than for the second. Similarly, convenience is affected by both travel
time and the ease of getting in and out of vehicle. Finally, the perception of safety
ma y differ for these two hypothetical individuals. There ar e many studies t ha t
have documented the significant role played by safety in affecting, particularly,
transit trips (Levine and Wachs, 1986b).
In other words, the aggregate approach applies a very elementary type of utility
function whereas the disaggregate approach allows much more complexity and
individual variability. Of course, one has to be able to measure the individual cost
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
components, a difficult task under most circumstances. There is also a question about
which approach is more accurate for correctly forecasting actual mode splits.
Historically, most Metropolitan Planning Organizations have used the aggrega t e
method because it’s easier. However, more recent research (Domin cich and
McFadden, 1975; Ben-Akiva and Lerman, 1985; McFadden, 2002) has suggested
that the disaggregate modeling may be more accurate. At the very minimum, the
disaggregate is more amen able to policy interpretations because it is more
behavioral. If one could interview travelers with a survey, then it is possible to
explore the variety of cost factors that affect a decision on both destination and mode
split, and a more realistic (if not unique) utility function derived. Bu t, as mentioned
above, with crime trips, this is very difficult, if not impossible, to do. Consequently,
for the time being, we’re stuck with an aggregate approach towards modeling the
utility of travel by offenders.
Relative Accessibility
For this version of Crime Stat, an approximation to a utility function was created.
The approach is to estimate a relative accessibility function and then apply that
function to the predicted trip distribution. The relative accessibility function is a
mathematical approximation t o a utility function, rather than a measured utility
function by itself. Because the cost components cannot be measured, at least for
offenders, we use an inductive approach. Reasonable assumptions are made and a
mathematical function is found that fits these assumptions. It is a plausible model,
not an analytical one. The plausibility comes by making reasonable assumptions
about actual travel behavior. One can assume that walking trips will occur for short
trips, say under two miles. Bicycle trips, on the other hand, could occur over longer
distances, but will still be relatively short (also, there is always the risk of traffic on
the safety of bicycle trips). Transit trips (bus and train) will be used for moderately
long distances but require an actual transit network. Finally, driving trips are the
most flexible because they can occur over any size distance and road network. They
are less likely to be used for very short trips, on the other hand, due to rea sons
discussed above.
First, define the modes. In the CrimeStat mode split routine, up to five different
modes ar e allowed. These have default names of “Walk”, “Bike”, “Drive”, “Bu s”,
and “Train”. The user is not required to use these names nor all five modes. Clearly,
if there is not a train system in the study area, then the “Train” mode does not apply.
Travel modelers use variations on these, such as “drive alone,” carpool”,
“automobile”, “motor cycle”, and so forth.
Second, define the target proportions. These are the expected proportions of travel
for each mode. Where would such proportions come from? There have been many
studies of driving and transit behavior, but relatively few studies of bicycle and
pedestrian use (Turner, Shunk, and Hottenstein, 1998; Schwartz et a l, 1999; Porter,
Suhrbier and Schwart z, 1999). There ar e not simple tables that one can look up
default values. To solve this problem, examples were sough t from different size
metropolitan area s. Estimates of travel mode share for all trip purposes (work and
non-work) were obtained from1) Ottawa (Ottawa , 1997); 2) Portland (Portland,
1999); and Houston4 . Table below shows the estimated shares. The Houston da t a
does not include walking and biking shares, and transit trips ar e not distinguished
by mode in the Port land an d Ottawa data.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
Example:
The total number of trips from zone i to zone j is 4200. Currently all trips are made
by car. Government has two alternatives- to introduce a train or a bus. The travel
characteristics and respective coefficients are given in table below. Decide the best
alternative in terms of trips carried.
Solution
o First, use binary logit model to find the trips when there is only car and
bus. Then, again use binary logit model to find the trips when there is
only car and train. Finally compare both and see which alternative carry
maximum trips.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
o Cost of travel by car=ccar = 0.05 × 25 + 0.2 × 22 + 0.2 × 6 = 6.85
o Cost of travel by bus=cbus = 0.05 × 35 + 0.04 × 8 + 0.07 × 6 + 0.2 × 8 =
4.09
o Cost of travel by train=ctrain = 0.05 × 17 + 0.04 × 14 + 0.07 × 5 + 0.2 × 6
= 2.96
o Case 1: Considering introduction of bus, Probability of choosing
Example:
Let the number of trips from zone to zone j is 5000, and two modes are available
which has the characteristics given in Table below. Compute the trips made by mode
bus, and the fare that is collected from the mode bus. If the fare of the bus is reduced
to 6, then find the fare collected.
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
= 2.08
= 2.18
Probability of choosing mode car (Equation) =
= 0.52
Probability of choosing mode bus (Equation) =
= 0.475
Proportion of trips by car =
Tijcar = 5000 * 0.52 = 2600
Proportion of trips by bus =
= 2400*9 = 21600
Advanced Transportation Planning / MSc
Lecture 6 Prof. Dr. Zainab Alkaissi
When the fare of bus gets reduced to 6,
Cost function for bus=
= 1.88
Probability of choosing mode bus (Equation) =
= 0.55
Proportion of trips by bus =
= 5000*0.55 = 2750
= 2750*6 = 16500