Block 3
Block 3
Block 3
Ordinal Approach
141
Theory of
Consumer
BLOCK 3 PRODUCTION AND COSTS
Behaviour
Block 3 develops the theory of the firm and explains the laws that are observed
in course of production. This will enable you to know how firms combined
inputs such as capital, labour and raw materials to produce goods and services
in a way that minimises costs of production. In this process various concepts
like production function, Iso product curves, Iso-cost lines etc have been
explained.
The block comprises four units. Unit 7 throws light on production function
with one variable input, and discusses the law of variable proportions. Unit 8
deals with the Properties of isoquants and optimal combination of factors and
producer’s equilibrium. The economic region of production and ridge lines and
the expansion path have also been discussed. Unit 9 covers the production
function in the event all the inputs vary and hence application of returns to
scale. Unit 10 discusses the cost side of production considering different types
of costs.
142
UNIT 7 PRODUCTION WITH ONE
VARIABLE INPUT
Structure
7.0 Objectives
7.1 Introduction
7.2 Total, Average and Marginal Products
7.3 Total, Average and Marginal Product Curves
7.4 The Law of Variable Proportions: Returns to a Factor
7.4.1 The Three Stages of Production
7.4.2 Explanation of Increasing Returns
7.4.3 Explanation of Constant Returns
7.4.4 Explanation of Diminishing Returns
7.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to :
state the concept of total product, average product and marginal product;
explain the nature and relationship of total, average and marginal product
curves;
analyse the operation of the law of variable proportions; and
identify the three stages of production.
7.1 INTRODUCTION
For the purpose of production, we require a combination of various inputs or
factors of productions. It is only with the joint efforts of these inputs (like
labour, machines, land, raw materials etc.) that output is produced. Normally,
production is carried out under conditions of variable proportions which
implies that the rate of input quantities may vary. Fixed proportions production
means that there is only one ratio of inputs that can be used to produce a good.
For example, only one driver can work one truck. In this case, the ratio of
driver and truck is technologically determined and is fixed. It is beyond the
capabilities of the producer to change it. However, the ratio of land and labour
in agriculture can be changed and is thus regarded as variable. In the short run,
not all inputs are variable. In the long run, however, all inputs are variable and
the ratio of inputs may also vary. This is the case of technological Progress. In
this unit, we shall focus only on short run production. In the short run, for the
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi. 143
Production purpose of analysis, it is often assumed that only one input is variable and all
and Costs other inputs are fixed. We shall follow this convention.
APL =
MPL=
This proposition is, in fact, true of all marginal and average relationships.
146
Production with One
Variable Input
Fig 7.1: Production with one variable input (labour). In the upper part of the figure, the
total product curve (TP) of labour is shown. The lower part of the figure shows how
average product curve (AP) of labour and marginal product curve (MP) of labour are
obtained with the help of information contained in the upper part
ii) When marginal product is zero, total product curve reaches its highest
point. It may be noted that when eighth unit of labour input is employed,
marginal product of labour becomes zero and total product is at the
maximum.
iii) Thereafter, marginal product of labour is negative and total product curve
has a downward slope which means that total product falls.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) The marginal product is greater than average product when average
product is falling.
ii) As long as marginal product is rising, total product curve will
continue to rise.
2) Discuss the relationship between the marginal and average product
curves.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
147
Production
and Costs
7.4 THE LAW OF VARIABLE PROPORTIONS:
RETURNS TO A FACTOR
Knowledge regarding the conditions of production reveals that as more and
more of some input is employed, all other input quantities being held constant,
normally marginal and average product (of the variable input) increase upto a
point. Thereafter, marginal product starts declining and this pulls down the
average product also. In the production process generally land, capital
equipment and buildings remain fixed in the short run while quantities of
labour and raw materials can be conveniently varied. However, we may
consider a case where amount of capital is fixed and the quantity of labour is
increased.
i) In this case, initially the marginal product of labour will increase as its
amount is increased and the marginal product will also pull up average
product with it. In this situation, total product increases at an increasing
rate.
ii) If the variable input, say, labour is further increased, marginal product
stops increasing after a point. Therefore, the rate of increase of total
product also shows a tendency to fall.
iii) Ultimately marginal product turns negative and this causes a fall in total
product itself.
Since in the short run, changes in technology are ruled out, the tendency of
marginal product to decline after a point is inevitable. This statement of trends
in marginal product in response to changes in the quantities of a variable factor
applied to a given quantity of a fixed factor is called the law of diminishing
returns. It is also called the law of variable proportions because it predicts the
consequences of varying the proportions in which factors of production are
used. we can sum up the law of variable proportions as follows:
“As equal increments of one input are added, the inputs of other
productive services being held constant, beyond a certain point the
resulting increments of product will decrease, i.e, the marginal product
will diminish.”
The law of variable proportions can be easily followed with the help of Table
7.1 and Fig. 7.1 which has been drawn on the basis of illustration given in
Table 7.1. In Table 7.1, it has been assumed that capital is a fixed factor and its
quantity remains unchanged at 5 units. Labour is the variable factor and its
quantity increases from 1 to 10. It can be seen from Table 7.1.
i) As the amount of labour employed increases, the total output also
increases until the seventh unit of labour is employed. Initially the
increase in output takes place at an increasing rate because marginal
product rises. This tendency is observed upto the point E where marginal
product reaches a maximum. At point E, which is the point of inflexion,
the rate of increase in total product switches from increasing to
decreasing because marginal product begins to diminish. However,
average product continues to increase until it reaches a maximum at point
F on total product curve (point J on average product curve).
ii) When the amount of labour is further expanded, total product continues
to increase though at a diminishing rate. Both marginal product and
148
average product remain positive, but both continue to diminish. Production with One
Eventually, total product reaches a maximum at point G and the marginal Variable Input
product becomes zero (note point K in Fig. 7.1 b). The average product,
however, remains positive but continues to diminish.
iii) Any attempt to increase output beyond this point by employing more
units of labour will not be fruitful. In fact, it will be counter-productive
because marginal product is negative which implies that total product
diminishes.
Product curves such as the one shown in Fig. 7.1 are general representations of
production function with fixed and variable inputs. To illustrate particular
instances, similar product curves could be drawn, though each different from
others in some way. The stage of increasing marginal product may be long or
brief or can be totally absent. Moreover, when marginal product diminishes,
the rate at which it happens may be different in each case. Table 7.2 sums up
the law of variable proportions.
Table 7.2: Properties of Product Curves
Marginal Average
Total Product Figure 7.1
Product Product
Stage I
first increases at Increases Increases to point E
increasing rate
reaches a
maximum and continues
diminishing at points G and
then starts
becomes zero K
diminishing
Stage III
diminishes is negative continues to right of points
diminishing J and K
149
Production Stage I is characterised particularly by the rising average product. In our
and Costs example, Stage I occurs when labour is employed from 1 to 4 units. In Stage 1,
total product first increases at an increasing rate and thus marginal product
rises. It reaches a maximum at labour input of 3 units. When fourth unit of
labour input is employed, diminishing returns set in implying that total product
increases at a diminishing rate and the marginal product falls.
In Stage II, total product increases at a diminishing rate and thus both marginal
product and average product decline. Marginal product being below the
average product, pulls the latter down. The right-hand boundary of Stage II is
at maximum total product where marginal product reaches zero. In our
example, Stage II ranges from 4 to 8 units of labour.
In Stage III, total product falls and marginal product is negative. In our
example, stage III occurs when labour is employed in excess of 8 units.
Actual Stage of Operation
The rational producer will operate in Stage II. It is not difficult to follow why
production will not be done in Stage III. In Stage III, less output is produced by
using more of the variable input which means that production costs would be
higher in Stage III than they were in Stage II. Obviously, any rational producer
will always avoid such inefficiencies in the use of production inputs.
In Stage I, average product of the variable input is increasing. Therefore, if the
amount of variable input is doubled, the output more than doubles and the unit
cost of producing output decreases. If a firm is operating in a competitive
market, it would avoid producing in this stage because by expanding output it
reduces the unit costs while the price it receives remains same for each
additional unit sold. This means that total profits increase if production is
expanded beyond the region of rising average product.
To sum up we can say: Initially, the variable factor-labour is not able to use all
the capacities of the fixed factor, hence MP and AP remain low. For instance,
one worker may not be able to make full use of the potential of a one hectare
plot of land. But two workers, together are is a better position to work on that
field. Hence rise in MP as Labour increases from 1 to 2.
Thus, any rational producer will operate in the second stage only when the law
of diminishing marginal return operates. This is why the law of variable
proportions is also called the Law of Diminishing Marginal Returns to a factor.
7.6 REFERENCES
1) Robert S.P rindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 7.2.
3) A.Kontsoyianmis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Press Ltd.,
Second Edition, 1982/, Chapter 3.
4) John P Gould and Edward P Lazar, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 6.
155
UNIT 8 PRODUCTION WITH TWO
VARIABLE INPUTS
Structure
8.0 Objectives
8.1 Introduction
8.2 Production Function
8.3 What are Isoquants?
8.3.1 Definition
8.3.2 Types of Isoquants
8.3.3 Isoquants Map
8.3.4 Assumptions of Isoquants
8.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
know the meaning and nature of isoquants;
find out the level at which output will be maximised subject to a given
cost;
find the point on the isoquant where cost will be minimised; and
describe the nature of optimal expansion path both in long run and short
run.
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi.
156
Production with Two
8.1 INTRODUCTION Variable Inputs
As stated in Unit 7, production requires the use of certain resources often
called factors of productions or inputs. When resources are broadly defined,
they are known as factors of production and classified as labour, land and
capital. The relationship between the inputs to the production process and the
resulting output is described by a production function. In this unit we shall start
with a definition of production function and then proceed to discuss the
concept of isoquants. This will be followed by a discussion on the economic
region of production and then, finally, on how the optimum combination of
factors and producer’s equilibrium is obtained.
The production function describes the laws of production, that is, the
transformation of factor inputs into products (outputs) at any particular
period of time. Further, the production function includes only the technically
efficient methods of production. This is because no rational entrepreneur
will use inefficient methods.
For the sake of simplicity, we may assume that there are two inputs, labour (L)
and capital (K). We can, then, write the production function as
Q = F (L,K)
This equation relates the quantity of output Q to the quantities of the two
inputs, labour and capital.
A popular production function in economics is Cobb Douglas production
function which is given as
Q=
A special class of production functions is linear homogenous production
function. In this case, when all inputs are expanded in the same proportion,
output expands in that proportion. In this case, Cobb Douglas production
function becomes
Q=
i.e. = 1–
Here we can see that when labour and capital
=A[
157
Production
and Costs
8.3 WHAT ARE ISOQUANTS?
8.3.1 Definition
An isoquant is the locus of all the combinations of two factors of
production that yield the same level of output.
From Table 8.1, it is clear that all the three processes yield the same level of
output, that is, 100 units of X. The first process is clearly capital-intensive.
Since we assume possibilities of factor substitution, we find that there are two
more processes available to the firm and in each of them factor intensities
differ. The third process is the most labour-intensive or the least capital-
intensive. Graphically, we can construct an isoquant conveniently for two
factors of production, say labour and capital. One such isoquant is shown in
Fig. 8.1. It has been constructed on the basis of information provided in
Table 8.1.
Fig. 8.1: This figure shows that at point A, B and C same level of output (=100 units) is
obtained by using different combinations of labour and capital. Curve p
158 is known as isoquant
8.3.2 Types of Isoquants Production with Two
Variable Inputs
1) Convex isoquant
2) Linear isoquant
3) Input-output isoquant
The traditional economic theory has mostly used the convex isoquant as shown
in Fig. 8.1. However, the isoquant can assume some other shapes depending on
the degree of the substitutability of factors. The two other possible production
isoquants are linear isoquant and input-output isoquant.
Linear Isoquant: In case of perfect substitutability of the factors of
production, the isoquant will assume the shape of a straight line sloping
downwards from left to right as in Fig. 8.2. In Fig. 8.2 it is shown that when
quantity of labour is increased by RS, the quantity of capital can be reduced by
JK to produce a constant output level, i.e., 50 units of X. Likewise, on
increasing the quantity of labour by ST, it is possible to reduce the quantity of
capital by KL, and on increasing the quantity of labour by TU, quantity of
capital can be reduced by LM for producing 50 units of X. Since in respect of
labour RS = ST = TU and in respect of capital JK = KL = LM, it is clear that a
constant quantity of labour substitutes a constant quantity of capital. It implies
that a given commodity can be produced by using only labour or only capital
or by infinite combinations of labour and capital. In the real world of
production, this seldom happens. Therefore, a linear downward sloping
isoquant can be taken only as an exception.
Fig. 8.2: In the case of perfect substitutability of factors of production, the isoquant
becomes a straight line and is, therefore, known as linear isoquant
Fig. 8.3: If factors of production can be used only in a fixed proportion, the isoquant is
‘L’ shaped and is known as an input-output isoquant
Fig. 8.4: When a number of isoquants are depicted together, we get an isoquant map
Fig. 8.6: Two Isoquants representing different output levels. A higher isoquant depicts a
higher amount of output
Fig. 8.7: No two isoquants intersect one another because each isoquant depicts a different
level of output
Fig. 8.8: An isoquant is covex from below because the marginal rates of technical
164 substitution tends to fall
If the factors of production are perfect substitutes, the marginal rate of Production with Two
technical substitution between them would be constant and the isoquant will be Variable Inputs
linear and sloping downwards from left, to right as in Fig. 8.2. In the case of
strict complementarity, that is, zero substitutability of the factors of production
the isoquant will be right angled or we may say that it will assume the shape of
‘L’ as in Fig. 8.3. However, the linear and right angled isoquants are the
limiting cases in the production processes.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) In case of perfect substitability of the factors of production, the
isoquant is convex from below.
ii) Isoquants are positively sloped.
iii) A higher isoquant represents a larger output.
iv) No two isoquants intersect each other.
2) Define isoquant. Discuss its properties.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
3) Discuss the possible shapes which the isoquants may assume depending
on the degree of substitutability.
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
......................................................................................................................
165
Production Suppose the output represented by isoquant is to be produced. For producing
and Costs this quantity, a minimum of amount of capital is required because any
smaller amount will not allow the producer to attain the level of output.
With amount of capital, amount of labour must be employed. In case
the producer uses an amount of labour less than together with amount
of capital, his output level would be lower than the one represented by isoquant
. This is quite normal, because use of inputs in smaller amounts would yield
a smaller output. But combining labour input in an amount larger than
with amount of capital would also result in output smaller than that is
represented by the isoquant . In order to maintain the level of output with
a larger labour input, capital input also in a larger amount has to be used.
Obviously, this is something which no rational producer would attempt
because it involves uneconomic use of resources.
Fig. 8.9: Area enclosed within the upper side line OK and the lower side lint OL indicates
the economic region of production
The firm or the producer has to purchase factors or inputs from the market.
How the prices of labour and capital are determined in the market is not our
present concern. Moreover, the firm is in no position to influesence the input
prices unless it is a monopsonist or oligopsonist. In other words, prices of
labour and capital have to be taken as given by the firm operating in a
competitive factor market. Let us now suppose that the firm’s total cost outlay
on labour and capital is Rs. 1000. The firm is free to spend this entire amount
on labour or capital or it may spend it on a combination of both labour and
capital. In Fig. 8.10, we have shown that if the firm chooses to spent the entire
amount of Rs. 1,000 on labour input, it can employ amount of labour, and
if the entire amount is to be spent on capital, it can get amount of capital.
The straight line is an isocost line representing all the combinations of
capital and labour which the firm can obtain for Rs. 1,000. In the figure, the
length of is twice the length of which means that the price of a unit of
labour is half that of a unit of capital. The slope of the line shows the
ratio of input prices. Hence, the slope of an isocost line is (w/r), which is the
ratio of the price of labour (w) to the price of capital (r) when X-axis denotes
labour input and Y-axis denotes capital input. We can thus generalise that for
any isocost line which is always linear because the firm has no control over the
167
Production prices of inputs and the prices remain the same, no matter how much quantity
and Costs of these inputs, the firm buys,
Slope = = = / =
Fig. 8.10: Isocost Lines - A higher cost line indicates a higher cost
This property of an isocost line is similar to that of the budget line of the
consumer. However, there is an important difference between the two lines.
Since the consumer’s budget is invariably fixed, he has a single budget line.
The firm generally has no such constraint and thus has more than one isocost
lines. In Fig. 8.10, we have shown three isocost lines. There can be many more
of them corresponding to firm’s cost outlay plans to attain various output
levels.
An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher costs; the one closer
to the origin reflects lower costs.
In this section, we shall explain how a producer maximises his output for a
given cost. Suppose the producer’s cost outlay is C and the prices of capital
and labour are r and w respectively. Subject to these cost conditions, the
producer would attempt to attain the maximum output level.
Let KL isocost line in Fig. 8.11 represent the given cost outlay at input prices r
and w. , and , are isoquants representing three different levels of output.
It may be noted that P3 level of output is not attainable because the available
factor resources (various labour-capital combinations represented by isocost
line KL) are insufficient to reach that output level. In fact, any output level
beyond isocost line KL is not attainable. The producer, however, can attain any
output level in the region OKL, but that would not require all the resources
168
(labour and capital inputs) that are available to the producer for his cost outlay.
Therefore, in the case of a given cost, the producer’s attempt would be to reach Production with Two
the isoquant which represents the maximum output level. The producer can Variable Inputs
operate at points such as R and T. At these two points, the combinations of
labour and capital to produce level of output are available for a given cost
represented by isocost line KL. In contrast, at point S, the combination of
labour and capital available for the same cost (as it is also on isocost line KL)
enables the producer to reach isoquant which represents an output level
higher than that represented by . Since at point S on isoquant is jus tangent
to isocost line, a greater output than is not obtainable for the given level of
cost. A lesser output is not efficient because production can be raised without
incurring additional cost. Hence, the optimal combination of factors of
production, viz., capital and labour is of capital plus of labour as it
enables the producer to reach the highest level of production possible given the
cost conditions.
Fig. 8.11: With the given cost line KL, the highest isoquant that a producer can reach is
P2. Point S on this isoquant, therefore, indicates producer’s equilibrium
The above proposition should be obvious to those who have studied the theory
of consumer behaviour. At the same time, the reason that lies behind it must be
followed carefully. Let us suppose that the producer wishes to produce at point
T. The marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for capital indicated by
the slope of tangent AB at point T is relatively high. Suppose K is equal to 3
and L is equal to 1. Thus, the slope of tangent AB is 3:1 which implies that at
point T one unit of labour can replace 3 units of capital. However, the relative
factor price indicated by the slope of KL is less, say, 0.7:1 which means that
the cost of 1 unit of labour is the same as the cost of 0.7 unit of capital.
Therefore, it would be rational on the part of the producer that he substitutes
labour for capital so long as the marginal rate of substitution of labour for
capital is not equal to the factor price ratio, that is, the ratio of the price of
labour to the price of capital. At point R, the opposite situation prevails
because the marginal rate of technical substitution is less than the factor price
ratio.
169
Production
and Costs
The producer maximises output for a given cost (reaches equilibrium)
only when the marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for
capital is equal to the ratio of the price of labour to the price of capital.
Thus,
= =
This can be easily followed graphically. In Fig. 8.12, we have a single isoquant
P which denotes the desired level of output, but there is a set of isocost lines
representing various levels of total cost outlay. An isocost line closer to origin
indicates a lower total cost outlay. The isocost lines are parallel and thus have
the same slope w/r because they have been drawn on the assumption of
constant prices of factors.
Fig. 8.12: To obtain a level of production indicated by isoquant P, the minimum cost that
must be incurred is given by point E on the isocost line K2L2. Therefore, point E indicates
the point of producer’s equilibrium
It may be noted that isocost line is just not relevant because the output
level represented by the isoquant P is not producible by any factor combination
available on this isocost line. However, the P level output can be produced by
the factor combinations represented by the points F and G which are on isocost
line . Alternatively, the producer can attain the P level output by the
170
factor combination represented by the point E which is on isocost line . Production with Two
Since the isocost line is closer to the origin as compared to the isocost Variable Inputs
line , it represents relatively lower cost. Therefore, by moving either from
F to E or from G to E, the producer attains the same output level at a lower
cost. The producer thus minimises his costs by employing OB amount of
capital plus OA amount of labour determined by the tangency of the isoquant P
with the isocost line L2. Points representing factor combinations below E
are certainly preferable because they represent lower costs but they cannot be
considered as they cannot help in producing the output level represented by the
isoquant P. Points above E represent higher costs. Hence, point E denotes the
least cost combination of the factors, viz., labour and capital for producing
output shown by isoquant P. This discussion thus leads us to the principle that
in the case of producer’s equilibrium, the marginal rate of technical
substitution of labour for capital must be equal to the ratio of the price of
labour to the price of capital. We can now sum up the whole discussion as
follows:
Fig. 8.14: Expansion path in the case of linear homogeneous production function is a
straight line
Fig. 8.15: Expansion path in the short run in the case of linear
homogeneous production function
173
Production ii) The area between ridge lines constitutes the Stage II of production
and Costs for both resources.
iii) An isocost line represents various combinations of input that may
be purchased for a given amount of expenditure.
iv) An isocost line farther to the right reflects higher cost.
v) Every point on the expansion path denotes an equilibrium point of
the producer.
vi) The line formed by connecting the points determined by the
tangancy between the successive isoquants and the successive
iocost lines is the firm’s expansion path.
2) Explain the condition of a producer’s equilibrium.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) Suppose that = Rs. 10, = Rs. 20 and TO (total outlay) = Rs. 160.
i) What is the slope of the isocost ?
ii) Write the equation of the isocost?
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) Explain the significance of tangency between an isoquant and an isocost
line.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Explain why, for a least cost combination of inputs, a firm requires that
the marginal rate of technical substitution be equal to the input ratio.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
6) What is meant by a firm’s expansion path? Distinguish between the
expansion path in respect of a linear homogeneous production function
from the expansion path in respect of a non-linear production function.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
174
Production with Two
8.8 LET US SUM UP Variable Inputs
The unit begins with the concept of Production function which refers to
functional relationship between inputs and output. This is followed by the
definition of an isoquant and the explanation of three types of isoquant- (i)
convex isoquant, (ii) linear isoquant, and (iii) input-output isoquant. The
properties of isoquants are: (i) isoquant are negatively sloped (ii) a higher
isoquant represents a larger output, (iii) no two isoquants intersect or touch
each other, and (iv) isoquants are convex to the origin. From here we proceed
to a discussion of the concept of the economic region of production and ridge
lines. The next section is devoted to a discussion of the optimum combination
of factors and producer’s equilibrium. In this section, we first consider the
concept of isocost lines and then consider (i) maxmisation of output for a given
cost, and (ii) minimisaton of cost for a given level of output. The last section of
the chapter discusses the optimal expansion path for a firm both under long run
and short run.
8.9 REFERENCES
1) Robert S Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfld and Prem L Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Section 5.1 and Section 5.3.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth Edition, 2010), Chapter 7, Section 7.1, Section 7.3 and
Section 7.4.
3) A.Koutsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Ltd., Second
edition, 1982). Chapter 3.
4) John P. Gould and Edward P. Lazear, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 7.
175
UNIT 9 RETURNS TO SCALE
Structure
9.0 Objectives
9.1 Introduction
9.2 Concept of Returns to Scale
9.2.1 Increasing Returns to Scale
9.2.2 Constant Returns to Scale
9.2.3 Diminishing Returns to Scale
9.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to :
state the concept of returns to scale;
distinguish between the stage of increasing, constant and diminishing
returns to scale; and
explain the concepts of economies and diseconomies of scale (both
internal and external).
9.1 INTRODUCTION
Sometimes to increase the level of output, all factors are increased
simultaneously and factor proportions are held constant. This is known as
expansion in scale. In this context, three phases of production are discussed:
increasing returns to scale, constant returns to scale, and diminishing returns to
scale. Expansion of scale confers a number of economies i.e. advantages on the
firm – both internal and external. Internal economies, in turn, can be divided
into real internal economies of scale and pecuniary internal economies. If the
scale of production is continuously expanded, a stage of internal diseconomies
of scale sets in i.e. after a certain point, increase in production is less than
proportionate increase in the factors of production. In this unit, we propose to
discuss all these issues. We shall also explain the concept of external
economies and external diseconomies.
*Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi.
176
Returns to Scale
9.2 CONCEPT OF RETURNS TO SCALE
When all the factors of production (labour, capital, etc.) are increased in the
conditions of constant techniques, three possibilities arise:
1) Output increases in a greater proportion as compared to the increase in
the factors of production. This is the case of increasing returns to scale.
2) Output increases in the same proportion as the increase in the amount of
the factors of production. This is the case of constant returns to scale.
3) Output increases in a smaller proportion as compared to the increase in
the amounts of the factors of production. This is the case of diminishing
returns to scale.
We can illustrate these three situations with the help of numerical examples as
follows:
OUTPUT SCHEDULE-1
Input-X Input -Y % Change in Output % Change in
Inputs Output
2 4 100 1000 -
4 8 100 3000 200
8 16 100 10000 233
16 32 100 35000 250
OUTPUT SCHEDULE-3
Input-X Input -Y % Change Output % Change in
in Inputs Output
2 4 100 1000 -
4 8 100 1800 80
8 16 100 2500 39
16 32 100 3000 20
It would be observed that the total output at all stages increases less
proportionately than the increase in inputs.
Fig. 9.1: Increasing returns to scale output increases in a greater proportion than the
increase in the factors of production
For example, if factors are doubled the output is more than doubled. In other
words, to double the quantity of the output, it is not necessary to double the
quantity of the factors of production. This can be understood with the help of
Fig. 9.1. In this figure P1, P2, P3, P4 are isoquants. They show 10, 20, 30, 40
units of output respectively. OS is the scale line which is cut by the isoquants
at unequal distances. In the figure, it can be seen that cd < bc < ab < oa. This
means that to enable the firm to rise from isoquant P1 to P2 (so that production
increases from 10 to 20 units), the amount of factors of production required is
178 less than the amount required to produce the initial l0 units of output.
Similarly, to increase the output further by 10 units so as to reach isoquant P3, Returns to Scale
the amount of factors of production required is less than the amount required to
produce the earlier 10 units of output as bc < ab. This position seems to hold
true till isoquant P4. There are three main factors which account for increasing
returns to scale:
1) Indivisibility: The most important reason of increasing returns to scale is
the ‘technical and managerial indivisibilities’. The meaning of an
indivisible factor of production is that there is a certain minimum size of
the factor and even if it is large in relation to the size of the output, it has
to be used (i.e., it cannot be divided). For example, even if only 10-15
letters are to be despatched from an office, it would be necessary to keep
a typewriter. It is not possible to purchase only half the typewriter since
only a small number of letters have to be typed daily. We would,
therefore, say that typewriter is not divisible. In a similar way, plants and
managerial services in modern factories are not divisible. Accordingly,
when the scale of production is enlarged initially, there is no equi-
proportionate increase in the demand for the factors of the production.
2) Specialisation: Chamberlin does not regard indivisibility as an important
cause of ‘increasing returns to scale’. According to him, the main reason
of increasing returns to scale is specialisation. When due to division of
labour, workers are given jobs according to their ability, their
productivity increases while cost declines. According to Donald S.
Watson, acknowledgement of this fact contradicts the assumption that the
ratio of different factors of production remains constant. Accordingly, he
casts doubts whether specialisation can be regarded as leading to
increasing returns to scale. The importance of specialisation can be
accepted only if we assume that although an increase by an equal amount
in quantity of labour and capital employed is necessary for an expansion
in scale, this increase does not mean the doubling or trebling their units
employed but it does mean an increase in their fixed money cost. But this
can lead to technical changes and it is very much possible that increasing
returns emerge not due to an expansion in scale but due to technical
reasons.
Empirical evidence suggests that the phase of constant returns is a fairly long
one and is observed in the case of a number of commodities. In a scientific
sense, constant returns to scale implies that when the quantity of the factors of
production is increased in such a way that the ratio of the factors remains
unchanged, output increases in the same proportion in which the factors are
increased. In other words, when the quantity of the factors is doubled, the
output also doubles. Such a production function is often called linear
homogeneous production function or homogeneous production function of the
first degree. The phase of constant returns to scale can be understood with the
help of Fig. 9.2. In this figure, when the firm goes from isoquant P3 to P4, or
179
Production from isoquant P4 to P5 or from isoquant P5 to P6, constant returns to scale are
and Costs obtained. The fact cd = de = ef on the scale line indicates this phenomenon.
The question that now arises is what are the reasons which account for constant
returns to scale. Generally when inefficiencies of production on a small scale
are overcome and no problems regarding technical and managerial
indivisibilities remain, expansion in scale leads to a situation where returns
increase in the same proportion as the factors of production. Some economists
are of the view that when benefits of specialisation of a factor in the unit of
production are small or when such benefits have already been reaped at a small
level of production, then for a considerable period of time, production
increases according to the law of constant returns to scale.
Economists have argued that if the factors of production are perfectly divisible,
the production function must exhibit constant returns to scale. In their opinion,
if constant returns to scale does not prevail in some industries, it is because in
these industries either due to scarcity or indivisibility of some factors, it is not
possible to vary all them in the same proportion. Indivisibility of a factor often
results in its under-utilisation at lower levels of output. When a producer for
obtaining a larger output increases quantities of other factors, the amount of the
lumpy factor which had not been fully utilised at lower levels of output, will
not be increased. These economists do not think that economies of scale will be
available when the factors of production are perfectly divisible. They however,
stress the role of optimum factor proportionality in production. When factors of
production are perfectly divisible, they can be increased or decreased in such
amounts that an optimum proportion between factors is achieved. The output
can be increased or decreased by increasing, or decreasing the amounts of the
factors in the optimum proportion without any economies or diseconomies of
scale which means that constant returns to scale will necessarily prevail.
181
Production
and Costs
9.3 ECONOMIES AND DISECONOMIES OF
SCALE
Expansion of the scale confers a number of economies on the firm. Some of
these are in ‘real terms’ while others are in ‘pecuniary terms’. Economies that
are obtained in production work, marketing, management, transport, etc. are in
real terms, while economies that are obtained in terms of, say, purchase of
inputs at wholesale rate, availability of finance at lower rate of interest, saving
on advertisement costs, etc. are in money terms. Then, there are certain
economies that do not accrue to the firm whose scale of operation is large but
accrue to certain other firms which benefit from the large scale of this firm.
9.5 REFERENCES
1) Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh edition, 2009), Chapter 5,
Secton 5.4.
2) Dominick Salvotore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Press, Fifth edition, 2010) Chapter 7, Section 7.5.
3) A. Koutsoyianms, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillan Press Ltd,
Second edition, 1982) Chapter 3.
4) John P. Gould and Edward P Lazear, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996), Chapter 8, Section 8.6.
187
UNIT 10 THE COST OF PORDUCTION
Structure
10.0 Objectives
10.1 Introduction
10.2 The Concept of Costs
10.2.1 Private Costs and Social Costs
10.2.2 Money Cost: Explicit and Implicit Costs
10.2.3 Real Costs
10.2.4 Sunk Cost and Incremental Cost
10.2.5 Economic Cost and Accounting Cost
10.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost
10.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you should be able to:
state the various concepts of costs like private cost, social cost, money
cost, sunk cost, economic cost, accounting cost etc.;
188 *Dr. V.K. Puri, Associate Professor of Economics, Shyam Lal College (University of Delhi) Delhi.
differentiate between short-run and long-run cost functions; The Cost of
Production
know the difference between fixed cost and variable cost and the nature
of total cost curve;
explain the concept of average fixed cost, average variable cost, average
total cost and marginal cost and nature of these curves;
discuss the relationship between marginal cost curve and average cost
curve;
appreciate the difference between short-run and long-run cost curves; and
10.1 INTRODUCTION
The decision of a firm regarding production of a good depends on two factors:
First, the demand for the good, and second, the cost of production of the good.
Accordingly, the concept of cost of production is basic to the understanding of
the price theory and requires a thorough discussion. A price taker firm wishes
to maximise its profits will be able to do so if it is able to minimise its costs.
Obviously a firm is interested in minimising what economists call the private
cost. The concept of social cost that is being often referred to in the context of
social welfare is not relevant for the theory of firm. However, it is necessary to
understand the distinction between the concepts of the private cost and the
social cost. In economic analysis, we often distinguish between money cost and
the opportunity cost. From analytical point of view both the concepts are
relevant and thus must be understood carefully. The concept of money cost
may be interpreted from the point of view of an accountant or an economist.
The two approaches differ on the treatment of implicit costs.
After settling these conceptual issues in the theory of costs, one has to analyse
the nature of costs in both the short-run and the long-run. In the short-run since
we have some fixed inputs and some other inputs are variable, one has to draw
the distinction between the fixed costs and the variable costs. However, in the
long-run because the amounts of all the inputs can be varied, all costs are
considered together. Finally, the theory of costs attempts to explain as to how
cost changes occur in response to changes in the size of production. In the last
two units we have discussed the theory of production at some length. This
discussion should help us to understand that the cost changes depend largely on
how changes in production take place as a result of changes in the amounts of
inputs.
189
Production firm’s both explicit and implicit costs, all such costs are taken into account
and Costs which are external to the ‘narrow economy’ of the firm.
Private costs: Every firm requires various inputs to produce a good. In order
to secure a command over these inputs, the firm has to pay some price for each
of these inputs. In common parlance, the amount of money so paid is known as
cost. Economists, however, include in the private cost not only the expenditure
incurred by the producer on purchasing (or hiring) of factors of production (or
inputs) from the market, but also the imputed cost of all those services which
the producer himself provides. The private cost of production of any output
may thus be defined as either the purchase or the imputed value of all
productive services used in producing the output and is equivalent to the total
monetary sacrifice of the firm made to secure it.
Generally, economists include the following expenditures in the cost: (i) cost
of the raw materials, (ii) wages of the labourers, (iii) interest payments on
capital loans, (iv) rent of the land and the buildings, (v) repairing costs of
machines and depreciation, (vi) tax payments to the government and local
bodies, (vii) imputed wage payment to the producer for the work performed by
him, (viii) imputed interest payment for the capital invested by the producer
himself, (ix) rent of land and buildings owned by the producer himself and (x)
normal profits of the firm.
This shows that three types of expenditures are included in the private
cost: (i) the purchase price of the factors of production employed in the
production process, (ii) imputed price of the resources provided by the
producer himself, and (iii) normal profits.
Social costs: Social costs differ from private costs on account of two reasons:
First, externalities are not included in private costs. For example, a factory
located in the residential area by polluting the atmosphere will expose the
residents of the colony to various ailments and will thereby raise their medical
expenditures. Though these costs are quite relevant from the point of view of
the society, they will never be considered by the firm as part of its costs.
Secondly, market prices of goods may not reflect their social value and
thus there may be divergence between private and social costs. The
imposition of government taxes, subsidies, and controls of various kinds distort
free market prices. Further, prices of factors of production may overstate or
understate the opportunity cost of using those factors. In heavily populated
countries where widespread disguised unemployment is to be found in the
agricultural sector, the industrial wage often exceeds the opportunity cost of
the labour which is drawn from the agricultural sector. In computing the social
costs, adjusted market prices for goods and factors of production are used.
While the adjusted prices for factors of production are called shadow prices,
the adjusted prices for goods are termed as social prices.
1) The income statement shows the flow of sales, cost, and revenue
over the year or accounting period. It measures the flow of money
into and out of the firm over a specified period of time.
2) The balance sheet indicates an instantaneous financial picture or
snapshot. It is like a measure of the stock of water in a lake. The
major items are assets, liabilities and net worth.
193
Production 10.2.6 Historical Cost and Replacement Cost
and Costs
The historical cost is the cost that was actually incurred at the time of
the purchase of an asset. As against this, replacement cost is the cost
that will have to be incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., replacement
cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same type).
These two costs differ because of changes in prices over a period of time.
Naturally, if prices remain unchanged over time, both the costs will be the
same. But this seldom happens. Accordingly, historical cost and replacement
cost of an asset always differ. If the price rises over a period of time,
replacement cost will be higher than the historical cost. On the other hand, if
the price of the asset declines over a period of time, replacement cost will be
lower than the historical cost.
Because of the requirements of tax laws and the laws governing financial
reporting to shareholders, accountants generally express many costs in terms of
the actual or historic costs paid for the resources used in the production process
in accordance with the convention of financial accounts. However, both
economists and accountants agree on the fact that for decision making
purposes, it is not the historical cost that is relevant but the replacement cost.
This is due to the reason that for all decision making purposes, it is the
‘current’ (or the replacement) cost that is important and not the cost that was
incurred some years earlier at the time of the purchase of the asset.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Externalities are not a part of private cost ( )
ii) Implicit costs are the costs associated with the use of firm’s own
resource ( )
iii) Retrospective costs are relevant for decision making ( )
iv) Accountants tend to take a retrospective look at the firm’s finances
( )
v) Economists are concerned with opportunity costs ( )
vi) The historical cost is the current cost of the new asset of the same
type ( )
2) Explain the difference between explicit cost and implicit cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
3) Distinguish between private cost and social cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
194
4) What is the difference between sunk cost and incremental cost? The Cost of
Production
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
5) Explain the difference between economic cost and accounting cost.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
Total fixed cost is the total expenditure by the firm on fixed inputs.
From Table 10.3, it is clear that the total fixed cost of the firm remains constant
at Rs. 240 irrespective of the level of output. In our illustration, output varies
from 1 unit to 6 units, but the total fixed cost remains 240 in each case. Even
when the firm stops production altogether, implying that output is at zero level,
the total fixed cost remains unchanged. The firm’s total fixed cost function is
shown in Fig. 10.1.
Fig. 10.1 : Total Fixed Cost curve is parallel to X axis as total fixed cost remains the same
for all levels of output
Since higher output levels require greater utilisation of variable inputs, they
mean higher total variable cost. Table 10.3 shows that the total variable cost of
the firm increases as its output increases. However, when the firm stops its
production altogether, it does not require any variable input and, therefore, its
total variable cost is zero. Fig. 10.2 shows the firm’s total variable cost
function. Notice one peculiar feature of TVC – initially it rises sharply, then,
there is a moderation in its rate of rise and ultimately it resumes rising at a
faster pace.
198
The Cost of
Production
Fig. 10.2 : Total Variable Cost Curve rises from left to right
Fig. 10.3: Total Cost curve is obtained by adding the total fixed cost to total variable cost
199
Production In Fig. 10.4, all the three cost functions discussed above (total fixed cost
and Costs function, total variable cost function and total cost function) have been shown
together. Cost functions, when depicted graphically, are often called cost
curves.
Fig. 10.4 : Total Fixed Cost, Total Variable Cost and Total Cost
In Fig. 10.4, TFC is the total fixed cost curve. Since it is parallel to X-axis, it
indicates that whatever be the level of output the total fixed cost remains the
same (i.e., it does not change in response to a change in the level of
production). TC is total cost curve. It indicates the sum of total fixed cost and
total variable cost for the various output levels. If the level of production is to
be raised, the use of variable inputs will have to be increased and this will push
up the costs. The rising total cost curve TC from left to right (the positive slope
of TC curve) indicates this fact. The vertical distance between the total cost
curve TC and the total fixed cost curve TFC indicates total variable cost. For
example, if the firm wishes to produce OQ units of output, the total variable
cost will be GQ – MQ = GM and if the level of output is OR, the total variable
cost will be HR – NR = HN. The total variable cost has been depicted by the
curve TVC in Fig. 10.4. This is parallel to the total cost curve TC and the
vertical distance between the two curves (TC and TVC) indicates total fixed
cost.
Check Your Progress 2
1) Indicate the following statements as true (T) or false (F):
i) Cost function explains the relationship between product and costs
( )
ii) In the long run all factors are variable ( )
iii) Fixed cost is also known as supplementary cost ( )
iv) Total variable cost is the total expenditure by the firm for fixed
input ( )
2) Define and distinguish between long run cost function and short run cost
function.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
200 .....................................................................................................................
3) Distinguish between fixed cost and variable cost. The Cost of
Production
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
4) Define total fixed cost and total variable cost and trace the nature of the
total cost curve.
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
.....................................................................................................................
AFC =
201
Production A mere look at Table 10.4 will show how the average fixed cost declines with
and Costs a rise in the level of output. When the firm produces only 1 unit, average fixed
cost is Rs. 240. As the ouput is expanded, there is a sharp decline in average
fixed cost and it is as low as Rs. 40 when 6 units of the commodity are
produced.
The fact that average fixed cost must decline with increases in output can be
easily understood with the help of average fixed cost curve in Fig. 10.5. In this
figure, when output is 1 unit, the average fixed cost is Rs. 240. When the
output is increased to 3 units and then to 6 units, average fixed cost declines
first to Rs. 80 and then to Rs. 40.
The average fixed cost curve (AFC) is a rectangular hyperbole because
multiplication of average fixed cost with the quantity of output produced
always yields a fixed value (the area under the curve is always same and
is equal to the total fixed cost).
AVC=
In fact, the average variable cost curve (AVC) gives us the same
information in money terms that we obtain from the average product
curve of the variable factor in physical terms.
Fig. 10.7: Average Total Cost curve is obtained by dividing total cost by the output
We can understand the shape of average total cost curve ATC better with the
help of average variable cost curve AVC and average fixed cost curve AFC
drawn in Fig. 10.8. Since the ATC curve is obtained by vertically summing up
the AVC and AFC curves, when both AVC and AFC curves slope downward,
the ATC curve also slopes downwards. The point R on the AVC curve shows
the minimum average variable cost. After this point, the average variable cost
starts increasing and thus the AVC curve is sloping upward. However, the fall
in the average fixed cost more than compensates for the rise in average variable
cost. Hence, the ATC curve slopes downward. Since at point T on the AVC
curve the rate of increase of the average variable cost is the same as the rate at
which the average fixed cost falls corresponding to this level of output, average
total cost is minimum at this output level. As the level of output increases
beyond this point, the average variable cost rises far more rapidly than the rate
at which average fixed cost falls. Therefore, the ATC curve slopes upward.
Fig. 10.8: Average total cost is the vertical sum of AFC and AVC
0 240 0 -
1 360 120 120
2 400 160 40
3 420 180 20
4 452 212 32
5 520 280 68
6 660 420 140
Since fixed cost remains unchanged in the short run, marginal cost can also be
defined as the increase in total variable cost consequent upon a small increase
in output. From Table 10.5, we learn that the variable cost of producing 2 units
is Rs. 160 and that of 3 units Rs. 180. The marginal cost, thus, will be
Rs. 180 – Rs. 160 = Rs. 20.
The marginal cost (MC) curve as it would be clear from Fig. 10.9 is U-shaped.
This implies that the marginal cost curve MC first slopes downward and then at
the point where marginal cost is minimum, it starts sloping upward because
marginal cost after decreasing with increases in output at low output levels,
increases with further increases in output. The shape of marginal cost curve is
in fact attributable to the law of variable proportions. According to the law of
variable proportions, the marginal product of the variable input rises at low
output levels and then falls with the expansion in output. Hence, the marginal
cost curve will first fall and then rise. There are two important points to
remember about the marginal cost curve:
i) The MC curve reaches its minimum point before the ATC and the AVC
curves reach their minimum points; and
205
Production ii) When the MC curves rises, it cuts the AVC and the ATC curves at their
and Costs minimum points.
206 Fig. 10.10: MC curve intersects both AVC curve and ATC curve at their minimum points
The reason for the above stated relationship between the MC curve and the The Cost of
ATC curve is simple. So long as the MC curve lies below the ATC curve, it Production
pulls the latter downwards; when the MC curve rises above the ATC curve, it
pulls the latter upwards. Consequently, marginal cost and average total cost are
equal where the MC curve intersects the ATC curve. Further when output is
small, marginal cost remains lower than average total cost; but when output is
expanded, marginal cost exceeds average total cost. Thus, it is natural that the
MC curve intersects the ATC curve at its minimum point.
Another important feature of the relationship between MC and AC curves is
that MC is affected only by variable costs. Fixed costs do not affect marginal
costs. This can be proved algebraically as follows:
MCN = TCN – TCN-1
= (TFCN + TVCN) – (TFCN-1 + TVCN-1)
Since, TFCN will always be equal to TFCN-1 we can also state as follows:
MCN = TFCN + TVCN – TFCN-1 – TVCN-1
= TVCN – TVCN-1
This proves that MC is affected only by TVC and not by TFC.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Indicate the following statement as true (T) or false (F):
i) Average fixed cost curve is a rectangular hyperbole ( )
ii) Average variable cost curve is the reciprocal of the average variable
factor productivity curve ( )
iii) The average total cost curve has inverted U shape ( )
iv) When the MC curve is below the AC curve, the latter rises ( )
2) What is average cost? What is the nature of the average total cost curve?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Define and distinguish between average cost and marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) Explain the relation between the average cost and the marginal cost. How
is it possible that the marginal cost continues to rise while average cost
declines?
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
207
Production 5) The following table gives information on total cost, total fixed cost and
and Costs total variable cost for a firm for different levels of output:
Output 0 1 2 3 4 5 6
208
The Cost of
Production
Fig. 10.11 : Long-run average cost curve envelopes short-run average total cost curves
Theoretically speaking, the long-run average cost (LAC) curve touches the
short-run average total cost (SATC) curves on their minimum points.
Geometrically this is possible only under those circumstances when the
tendency of constant returns to scale prevails. It is due to the fact that initially
increasing returns to scale and after some time diminishing returns to scale
prevail in the production process that the LAC curve touches the lowest SATC
curve at its minimum point. In the phase of increasing returns to scale when
average total cost is falling, the LAC curve touches the SATC curves to the left
of the minimum points of the SATC curves and in the phase of diminishing
returns towards the right of minimum points of these curves. In Fig. 10.11, the
curve LAC touches the SATCb curve at its minimum point K, the SATCa curve
towards the left of its minimum point (at L) and the SAT Cc curve towards the
right of its minimum point (at M).
209
Production
and Costs
210
10.6.3 Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve The Cost of
Production
After having understood the meaning of short-run marginal cost, it is not
difficult to understand what long-run marginal cost is. Long-run marginal cost
designates the change in total cost consequent upon a small change in total
output when the firm has ample time to accomplish the output changes by
making the appropriate adjustments in the quantities of all resources used,
including those that constitute its plant. As can be seen, this definition of long-
run marginal cost is practically the same as the definition of short-run marginal
cost given by us earlier. The only difference between the two is that whereas in
the short-run the existing plant will continue to be used for affecting an
increase in output, in the long-run the plant itself will be changed.
As far as the relationship between the long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve is concerned, it is precisely the same as exists between
the short-run marginal cost curve and the short-run average total cost curve.
This would be clear from a mere glance at Fig. 10.13.
211
Production
and Costs
Fig. 10.14: Equality of SMC and LMC on use of an optimum size plant
To find out why SMC and LMC must be equal at the level of output OQ1, let
us consider the implications of a small change in the output by a small amount.
For instance, let us take the level of output OQ2. At this output level, short-run
average cost will be greater than long-run average cost (SAC > LAC). In other
words, short-run total cost is greater than long-run total cost (STC > LTC).
When output rises from the level OQ2 to the level OQ1 the short run total cost
becomes equal to the long-run total cost. If the level of output is raised to OQ3
then since SAC is greater than LAC at this output, STC will also be greater
than LTC. In other words, when output level is raised beyond OQ1, we find
that SMC exceeds LMC. Actually as we move from OQ2 to OQ1, we find that
rate of decline in SMC is declining. In fact, beyond OQ1, it stands rising. On
the other hand, LMC keeps falling over the entire range. Therefore, between
OQ1 and OQ3 SAC is rising and LAC is falling.
On practical considerations, the equality of short-run marginal cost and the
long-run marginal cost is very significant for a firm. If the firm has to increase
the level of output only by a very small amount whether it continues to employ
the existing plant and changes only the quantity of the variable resources or
makes a small change in the size of the plant, the results are the same.
Therefore, from the point of view of the firm, both the methods are equally
correct.
Check Your Progress 4
1) Indicate the following statements as True (T) or False (F):
i) There is no need to distinguish between fixed costs and variable
costs in the long-run. ( )
ii) Long-run average cost curve envelopes the short-run average total
cost curves. ( )
iii) Long-run marginal cost curve cuts the long-run average cost curve
from below at the latter’s lowest point. ( )
212
2) Discuss the nature of the long-run average cost curve. The Cost of
Production
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
3) Discuss the concept of long period economic efficiency.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
4) What is the relationship between long-run marginal cost curve and long-
run average cost curve.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
5) Discuss the relationship between long-run marginal cost and short-run
marginal cost.
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
..................................................................................................................
10.8 REFERENCES
1) Robert S. Pindyck, Daniel L. Rubinfeld and Prem L. Mehta,
Microeconomics (Pearson Education, Seventh Edition, 2010). Chapter 6,
Section 6.1, 6.2, 6.3 and 6.4.
2) Dominick Salvatore, Principles of Microeconomics (Oxford University
Presss, Fifth Edition, 2010). Chapter 8, Section 8.1, 8.2, 8.3, 8.4 and 8.5
213
Production 3) A. Kountsoyiannis, Modern Microeconomics (The Macmillion Press
and Costs Ltd., Second edition, 1982), Chapter 4.
4) John P. Gould and Edward P. Lazear, Microeconomic Theory (All India
Traveller Bookseller, Sixth edition, 1996). Chapter 8.
5) Ahuja H.L., Advanced Economc Theory (S.Chand & Company Ltd., New
Delhi 2001), Chapter 20 Page 396-439.
214
GLOSSARY
Average Product : Total product divided by the number of units of
the input used is average product.
Accounting Cost : Accounting cost refers to actual expenses of the
firm plus depreciation charges for capital
equipment.
Barter : Exchange of goods/services against other
goods/services.
Budget Line : The Budget Line, also called as Budget
Constraint shows all the combinations of two
commodities that a consumer can afford at
given market prices and within the particular
income level.
Comforts : Goods which are used for increasing our
productive capacity and for making our lives
more comfortable.
Consumption : Using up of Utility of goods in the satisfaction
of a want.
Change in Demand : Shift of the entire demand of curve.
Change in Quantity : Movement on a demand curve itself caused by
Demanded a changes in the price of the commodity in
question.
Contraction in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied because of a
fall in the price of the commodity.
Curvilinear Supply : The supply curve which is not a straight line.
Curve
Cardinal Utility : The Cardinal Utility approach is propounded
by neo-classical economists, who believe that
utility is measurable, and the customer can
express his satisfaction in cardinal or
quantitative numbers, such as 1, 2, 3 and so on.
Consumer Equilibrium : The point at which a consumer
reaches optimum utility, or satisfaction, from
the goods and services purchased, given the
constraints of income and prices.
Constant Returns to : Constant returns to scale implies that when all
Scale inputs are increased in a given proportion,
output increases in the same proportion.
Complementary : It is the commodity whose demand is directly
Commodity related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Demand : The amount of goods which the buyers are
ready to buy, per period of time, at a given
price per unit.
215
Production Dependent Variable : A variable which changes only with the change
and Costs in the independent variable.
Decrease in Supply : The decrease in quantity supplied at a given
price of the commodity.
Diminishing Returns to : Diminishing returns to scale refers to the case
Scale when output grows proportionally less than
input.
Economic Laws : Statements of tendencies. They depict the
standardised or generalised response of
economic units to different forces and stimuli.
Exchange Value : The price which an item commands in the
market.
Elasticity of Demand : It quantifies the strength relationship between
the quantity demanded of commodity and the
price of the commodity or income of the
consumer or price of another commodity which
is related to the commodity in question.
Elasticity of Supply : The responsiveness of quantity supplied to a
given percentage change in the price of the
commodity.
Extension in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied due to a rise in the
price of the commodity.
External Economies : When a firm enters production, it obtains a
number of economies for which the firm’s own
strategies/policies are not responsible. These
are economies external to the firm.
External Diseconomies : When the scale of operations is expanded,
many such diseconomies accrue that have no
particular ill-effect on the firm itself but their
burden falls on the other firms. These are
known as external diseconomies.
Economic Cost : Economic cost refers to cost to a firm utilising
economic resources in production including
opportunity cost.
Explicit Cost : Explicit costs arise from transaction between
the firm and other parties in which the former
purchases inputs or services for carrying out
production.
Flow Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a period of time.
Goods : Items which have a utility or can be used for
the production of other goods or services.
Giffen Good : A good where higher price causes an increase
in demand (reversing the usual law of demand).
The increase in demand is due to the income
effect of the higher price outweighing the
216
substitution effect.
Historical Cost : Historical cost is the cost that was actually Glossary
incurred at the time of purchase of an asset.
Inductive Reasoning : The technique of analysis in which factual
information is used to discover the behaviour
pattern of different economic units in response
to various forces and stimuli.
Inferior Commodity : A commodity in which there is an inverse
(Good) relationship between the income of the
consumer and quantity demanded of a
commodity.
Income Elasticity of : It is the responsiveness of demand to a given
Demand proportional change in the income of the
consumer.
Inequalities of Income : The distribution of income among different
income groups of an economy.
Increase in Supply : The rise in quantity supplied at a given price of
the commodity.
Income Effect : A change in the demand of a good or service,
induced by a change in the consumers’ real
income. Any increase or decrease in price
correspondingly decreases or increases
consumers’ real income which, in turn, causes a
lower or higher demand for the same or some
other good or service.
Isocost Line : An isocost line represents various combinations
of inputs that may be purchased for a given
amount of expenditure.
Isoquant : An isoquant is the of all the combination of two
factrors of production that yield the same level
of output.
Increasing Returns to : Increasing returns to scale refer to the case
Scale when output grows proportionally more than
inputs.
Internal Economies : Those economies that accrue to a firm on
expansion of its own size are known as internal
economies.
Internal Diseconomies : When the scale of production is continuously
expanded, a point is reached where the increase
in production becomes less than proportionate
to the increase in the factors of production. As
this point, internal diseconomies set in.
Implicit Cost : Implicit costs are the costs associated with the
use of firm’s own resources. Since these
resources will bring returns if employed
elsewhere, their imputed values constitute the
implicit costs.
Incremental Cost : An incremental cost is the increase in total
costs resulting from an increase in production
or other activity
217
Production Luxuries : Goods which are meant for status or social
and Costs standing.
Law of Supply : It shows the direct relationship between the
price of a commodity and its quantity supplied,
other factors influencing supply (except price
of the commodity) remaining constant.
Law of Diminishing : As more units of an input are used per unit of
Returns time with fixed amounts of another input, the
marginal product of the variable input declines
after a point.
Linear Homogeneous : When output increases in the same proportion
Production Function in which inputs are increased, the production
function is linear homogeneous. For example, if
218
Normative Economics : That part of economic analysis which is Glossary
concerned with what ought to be, and the way it
can be achieved by changing the existing
situation.
Ordinal Utility : The Ordinal Utility approach is based on the
fact that the utility of a commodity cannot be
measured in absolute quantity. However, it will
be possible for a consumer to tell subjectively
whether the commodity gives more or less or
equal satisfaction when compared to another.
Optimality : The point where maximum possible output is
being achieved given the use of different
factors of production.
Private Goods : Goods whose availability can be restricted to
selected users. It is divisible in that sense.
Production Possibility : A graphic representation of the combinations of
Curve maximum amounts of goods X and Y which
can be produced with the given productive
resources of the economy and under certain
other simplifying assumptions.
Public Goods : Goods or services whose availability cannot be
restricted to selected users only. The benefits of
the goods are indivisible and people cannot be
excluded.
Positive Economics : That part of economic reasoning which covers
what is, without going into its desirability or
otherwise, and without suggesting ways for
changing the existing state of affairs.
Price Effect : The impact that a change in its price has on the
consumer demand for a product or service in
the market. The price effect can also refer to the
impact that an event has on something’s price.
The price effect is a resultant effect of the
substitution effect and the income effect.
Point of Inflexion : The point where total product stops increasing
at an increasing rate and begins increasing at a
decreasing rate is called the point of inflexion.
Production Function : The technical law which expresses the
relationship between factor inputs and output is
termed production function.
Rectangular Hyperbola : It is a curve in which every rectangle drawn
with one corner on the curve has the same area.
Ridge Lines : The lines forming the boundaries of the
economic region of production are known as
the ridge lines.
219
Production Replacement Cost : Replacement cost is the cost that will have to
and Costs be incurred now to replace that asset (i.e., the
replacement cost is the current cost of the new
asset of the same type).
Stock Variable : A variable which can be measured only with
reference to a point of time.
Supply : The quantity of goods which the sellers are
ready to sell, per unit of time, at a given price
per unit.
Substitution Effect : It shows how with a change in the price of a
commodity, prices of other commodities
remaining unchanged, a consumer substitutes
one commodity for the other.
Substitute Commodity : It is the commodity whose demand is inversely
related to the demand of the commodity in
question.
Supply Schedule : A table having two columns, one showing
different prices of the commodity and the other
showing quantities supplied during a given
period at each of these prices.
Supply Curve : A curve showing the relationship between price
of a commodity and its quantity supplied
during a given period, other factors influencing
supply remaining unchanged.
Sub-optimality : It is a point where optimality has not been
achieved, i.e. output is less than the possible
maximum given the use of the resources.
Sunk Cost : Sunk cost is a cost that has already been
incurred and can’t be recovered.
Technology : The method employed to produce a commodity
or service.
Total Utility : The total satisfaction derived from all the units
of an item.
Use Value : Utility of goods.
Utility : The want satisfying capacity of goods. It is the
service or satisfaction an item yields to the
consumer.
220
Glossary
SOME USEFUL BOOKS
1) Kautsoyiannis, A. (1979), Modern Micro Economics, London:
Macmillan.
5) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi.
221