ssrn-4763347
ssrn-4763347
ssrn-4763347
Abstract
Spot bitcoin ETFs have been recently approved in the U.S., increasing retail and insti-
tutional investors’ attention to the crypto space. Still, empirical evidence on whether
Bitcoin is an asset that protects investors against inflation is still inconclusive. To
contribute to this debate, we analyze the effect of inflation shocks on bitcoin returns
through the estimation and inference of Vector Autoregressive Models (VARs). Unlike
previous research on the topic, we identify inflation shocks as surprises in the US’s
CPI and Core PCE announcements: the difference between the announced inflation
and the analysts’ consensus. The results, based on monthly data between August 2010
and January 2023, indicate that bitcoin returns increase significantly after a positive
inflationary shock, corroborating empirical evidence that Bitcoin can act as an inflation
hedge. However, we observe that bitcoin’s inflationary hedging property is sensitive
to the price index – it only holds for CPI shocks – and to the period of analysis —
the hedging property stems primarily from sample periods before the increasing in-
stitutional adoption of BTC (“early days”). Thus, the inflation-hedging property of
Bitcoin is context-specific and is likely to be diminishing as adoption increases. This
research contributes to the still under-explored strand of literature that analyzes the
hedging and safe-haven properties of Bitcoin and benefits asset managers, investors,
and monetary authorities.
∗
E-mail address: haroldrodriguez152@hotmail.com.
†
Corresponding author. E-mail address: jefferson.colombo@fgv.br. ORCiD: https://orcid.org/
0000-0001-7221-8074. We appreciate comments from Thorsten Beck (discussant), Rodrigo de Oliveira
Leite, João Marco Braga da Cunha, Marcel Ribeiro, Alexandre Ludolf, Fernando Chague, and participants
at the 1st Elsevier Finance Conference (Rio de Janeiro, 2023). An earlier version of this paper has been
granted 1st place in the CFA Society Brazil award for Best Monographs in Finance (2023). Jéfferson Colombo
gratefully acknowledges financial support from the National Council for Scientific and Technological Develop-
ment (CNPq, Grant #313033/2022-6) and the Silicon Valley Community Foundation through the University
Blockchain Research Initiative (UBRI, Grant #2022-199610).
2 Methodology
2.1 VAR model
To capture the dynamics of the variables and deal with the potential endogeneity in their
relationships, we use a VAR framework (Sims, 1980), which is reliable in describing, sum-
marizing, and forecasting macroeconomic data (Stock and Watson, 2001).
Specifically, let y1 , y2 , . . . , yT be multivariate time series, with yt = (y1t , y2t , . . . , ykt )′ . A
VAR model of order p, in its basic form, can be expressed as follows:
Where Yt is modeled as a function of the mean term µ and in terms of the past and
present of the innovation vector Ut .
Furthermore, the MA representation of yt can be found by pre-multiplying Yt by a matrix
J = [IK : 0 : . . . : 0] of dimension (K × Kp). Here, µ = Jµ, Φi = JAi J ′ , and ut = JUt .
∞
X ∞
X
yt = JYt = Jµ + Φi ut−i = µ + Φi ut−i (5)
i=0 i=0
The challenge of estimating these parameters incurs the same difficulties as obtaining
the parameters of the primitive model from the reduced model. This methodology does not
permit estimation in cases of underidentification, where the number of equations is fewer
than the number of unknowns. To identify the system written in MA form, we estimate each
Serial autocorrelation. To address the threat of serial autocorrelation, which has the
potential to compromise the integrity of impulse response functions, the authors employ the
Ljung and Box (1978) test. The number of lags, denoted as h, is determined by the Schwert
(1989) criterion. In short, the null hypothesis posits that residuals up to the h-th lag exhibit
white noise characteristics. When rejected, it implies that at least one autocorrelation is
statistically different from zero. In such a case, the model must be rejected, prompting a
re-specification and re-estimation of the VAR (Lütkepohl, 2011).
3 Data
This study utilizes monthly data from August 2010 to January 2023 (150 observations).
The beginning of this time frame stems from the earliest available data on Bitcoin trading
prices. The variables used in this study (in stationary form) are the following: returns on
S&P500 ( Ret SP500), Gold (Ret Gold), and bitcoin ( Ret BTC); first differences of the
US 1y interest rates (Dif US 1Y) and the VIX (Dif VIX); and surprise inflation (Surp Inf).
Table I describes and details the variables considered in this study.
Our framework for variable selection, estimation, and inference is similar to Choi and
Shin (2021), but we introduce modifications to enhance the identification of inflation shocks.
These adjustments are inspired by the work of Kuttner (2001), Romer and Romer (2004), and
Nakamura and Steinsson (2017), and the specification proposed by Lowenkron and Garcia
(2007). Particularly, as described in Table I, we include in the VAR system inflation surprises
estimated as the difference between the actual (CP It ) and the expected (Et−1 (CP It )) CPI
MoM (also CPI YoY and Core PCE MoM in further analyses). With such refinements,
Note: The subscript t (t − 1) denotes, except for Surp Inf , the closing price of the asset/index
on the day (previous day) of the official inflation rate announcement.
equaled zero. This discrepancy may be attributed to differing criteria, such as composition
and disclosure dates (the PCE announcement occurs after the CPI release for the same period
of reference; thus, market agents update beliefs following any surprise in CPI). We can see
in the figures that the dispersion of surprises is larger for CPI MoM and CPI YoY than for
PCE MoM. Furthermore, surprises in CPI are positively skewed – i.e., extreme values are
more common in the right tail (positive ones).
Another important issue to discuss is the timing and correlation of these surprises. Fig-
ure A2 shows the actual, forecast, and surprise (actual - forecast) values for our baseline
measure of inflation (CPI MoM, Panel A) and for the further analyses (CPI YoY, Panel B,
and PCE MoM, Panel C). We can observe from the Figure that average surprises are close
to zero; however, positive surprises started to become more frequent in the recent period,
starting in the middle of 2021, following a supply-side disruption brought by COVID-19.3
Such a pattern is more pronounced in the CPI MoM and CPI YoY, suggesting that positive
surprises in CPI are incorporated in PCE forecasts, reducing the forecast error in the latter
3
On May 12, 2021 (reporting inflation from April 2021), the actual CPI MoM came on 0.8%, while the
expected inflation was 0.2%. Such a surprise of 0.6 p.p. is the largest value in our sample period. After that,
market agents witnessed a sequence of positive unexpected inflation values that made the FOMC start, on
March 16, 2022, eight successive increases in the policy rate.
Note: This table provides statistics for all series covering the period from 2010:08 to 2023:01.
The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the series was derived from returns (differences) calculated
within one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements.
inflation index.
Finally, Figure A3 plots the three surprise measures and shows the correlation coefficient
among them: the contemporaneous linear association is stronger for the pair CPI MoM-CPI
YoY (0.63), but almost uncorrelated on the pairs CPI MoM-PCE MoM (0.12) and CPI YoY-
PCE MoM (0.02). Such evidence reinforces that markets adapt expectations and reduce the
forecast error for the PCE, whose announcement date always occurs later than the CPI.
Finally, Figure A4 shows the cross-correlation among each surprise pair, and again shows a
clear pattern for CPI MoM-CPI YoY: the correlation coefficient is a lot stronger in t0 (i.e.,
their contemporaneous values). On the other hand, the relationship between CPI and PCE
is noisier, showing that the correlation is near zero for contemporaneous values and for other
lead-lag relationships.
4 Empirical Results
4.1 Baseline model
Figure 1 depicts the main empirical results of this study, considering the CPI MoM as the
underlying index to calculate the inflation surprises. Specifically, the Figure shows the cumu-
4
Defined by the Schwert (1989) criterion.
10
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of the six
variables to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01. The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the series
was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in one-day windows around monthly CPI
MoM announcements. The horizontal axes show the number of months after the impulse.
The baseline, entire period results highlight further similarities in the behavior of BTC
and GOLD. Firstly, both assets exhibit an initial negative effect, with Bitcoin displaying a
5
Figure C1 in Appendix C plots the entire set of impulse response functions for a comprehensive picture.
6
Relative to BTC, The COIRFs suggest a similar, albeit less pronounced, response in gold returns to
inflation shocks, indicating that the returns of both assets react in the same direction but with different
intensities.
11
Note: This figure shows forecast error variance decomposition (FEVD) of Bitcoin and gold for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01. The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the series
was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in one-day windows around monthly CPI
MoM announcements. The horizontal axes show the number of months after the impulse.
12
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01. The Ret prefix indicates that the series was
constructed from returns calculated in one-day windows around monthly CPI YoY announce-
ments. The horizontal axes show the number of months after the impulse.
13
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01. The Ret prefix indicates that the series
was constructed from returns calculated in one-day windows around monthly Core PCE MoM
announcements. The horizontal axes show the number of months after the impulse.
14
15
16
17
References
Al-Yahyaee, K. H., Mensi, W., and Yoon, S.-M. (2018). Efficiency, multifractality, and the
long-memory property of the bitcoin market: A comparative analysis with stock, currency,
and gold markets. Fin. Res. Lett., 27:228–234.
Alvarez, F., Lucas, Jr, R. E., and Weber, W. E. (2001). Interest rates and inflation. Am.
Econ. Rev., 91(2):219–225.
Armantier, O., Bruine de Bruin, W., Topa, G., van der Klaauw, W., and Zafar, B. (2011).
Inflation expectations and behavior: Do survey respondents act on their beliefs? SSRN
Electron. J.
Baum, C. F. (2013). Var, svar and vecm models. Boston College, Spring.
Beaudry, P. and Portier, F. (2006). Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. Am.
Econ. Rev., 96(4):1293–1307.
Binder, C. and Kamdar, R. (2022). Expected and realized inflation in historical perspective.
J. Econ. Perspect., 36(3):131–155.
Blau, B. M., Griffith, T. G., and Whitby, R. J. (2021). Inflation and bitcoin: A descriptive
time-series analysis. Econ. Lett., 203(109848):109848.
Bomfim, A. (2003). Pre-announcement effects, news effects, and volatility: Monetary policy
and the stock market. J. Bank. Financ., 27(1):133–151.
Bouri, E., Gupta, R., Tiwari, A. K., and Roubaud, D. (2017a). Does bitcoin hedge global
uncertainty? evidence from wavelet-based quantile-in-quantile regressions. Fin. Res. Lett.,
23:87–95.
18
Choi, S. and Shin, J. (2021). Bitcoin: An inflation hedge but not a safe haven. Fin. Res.
Lett., 46(102379):102379.
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M., and Evans, C. L. (2005). Nominal rigidities and the
dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J. Polit. Econ., 113(1):1–45.
Cochrane, J. H. and Piazzesi, M. (2002). The fed and interest rates—a high-frequency
identification. Am. Econ. Rev., 92(2):90–95.
Coibion, O. (2012). Are the effects of monetary policy shocks big or small? Am. Econ. J.
Macroecon., 4(2):1–32.
Colombo, J., Cruz, F., Paese, L., and Cortes, R. (2021). The diversification benefits of
cryptocurrencies in multi-asset portfolios: cross-country evidence. Available at SSRN
3776260.
Colombo, J. A. and Yarovaya, L. (2024). Are crypto and non-crypto investors alike? evidence
from a comprehensive survey in brazil. Technology in Society, page 102468.
Conlon, T., Corbet, S., and McGee, R. J. (2021). Inflation and cryptocurrencies revisited:
A time-scale analysis. Econ. Lett., 206(109996):109996.
Corbet, S., Larkin, C., Lucey, B. M., Meegan, A., and Yarovaya, L. (2020). The impact of
macroeconomic news on bitcoin returns. Eur. J. Fin., 26(14):1396–1416.
Enders, W. (2008). Applied econometric time series. John Wiley & Sons, New York, USA.
Farka, M. (2009). The effect of monetary policy shocks on stock prices accounting for
endogeneity and omitted variable biases. Rev. Financ. Econ., 18(1):47–55.
Fleming, M. J. and Remolona, E. M. (1999). Price formation and liquidity in the us treasury
market: The response to public information. J. Finance, 54(5):1901–1915.
19
Gimenes, A. D., Colombo, J. A., and Yousaf, I. (2023). Store of value or speculative in-
vestment? market reaction to corporate announcements of cryptocurrency acquisition.
Financial Innovation, 9(1):123.
Hanson, S. G. and Stein, J. C. (2015). Monetary policy and long-term real rates. J. Financ.
Econ., 115(3):429–448.
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., and Taylor, A. M. (2017). Macrofinancial history and the new
business cycle facts. NBER Macroecon. Annu., 31(1):213–263.
Kurov, A., Olson, E., and Zaynutdinova, G. R. (2022). When does the fed care about stock
prices? J. Bank. Financ., 142(106556):106556.
Kuttner, K. N. (2001). Monetary policy surprises and interest rates: Evidence from the fed
funds futures market. J. Monet. Econ., 47(3):523–544.
Li, X. and Wang, C. A. (2017). The technology and economic determinants of cryptocurrency
exchange rates: The case of bitcoin. Decis. Support Syst., 95:49–60.
Ljung, G. M. and Box, G. E. P. (1978). On a measure of lack of fit in time series models.
Biometrika, 65(2):297–303.
Lütkepohl, H. (2005). New introduction to multiple time series analysis. Springer, Berlin,
Germany.
Maneejuk, P., Pirabun, N., Singjai, S., and Yamaka, W. (2021). Currency hedging strategies
using histogram-valued data: Bivariate markov switching GARCH models. Mathematics,
9(21):2773.
Matkovskyy, R. and Jalan, A. (2020). Bitcoin vs inflation: Can bitcoin be a macro hedge?
evidence from a quantile-on-quantile model. SSRN Electron. J.
20
Pyo, S. and Lee, J. (2020). Do FOMC and macroeconomic announcements affect bitcoin
prices? Fin. Res. Lett., 37(101386):101386.
Rigobon, R. and Sack, B. (2003). Measuring the reaction of monetary policy to the stock
market. Q. J. Econ., 118(2):639–669.
Rigobon, R. and Sack, B. (2004). The impact of monetary policy on asset prices. J. Monet.
Econ., 51(8):1553–1575.
Romer, C. D. and Romer, D. H. (2004). A new measure of monetary shocks: Derivation and
implications. Am. Econ. Rev., 94(4):1055–1084.
Schwert, G. W. (1989). Tests for unit roots: A monte carlo investigation. J. Bus. Econ.
Stat., 7(2):147–159.
Weber, M., Gorodnichenko, Y., and Coibion, O. (2022). The expected, perceived, and
realized inflation of u.s. households before and during the COVID19 pandemic. Technical
Report 29640, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
21
Note: This figure shows the frequency distribution graphs of the unexpected component of
inflation calculated in one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM (top left graph), CPI YoY
(top right graph), and Core PCE MoM (bottom graph) announcements. The sample period
covers from 2010:08 to 2023:01. The horizontal axes represent different intervals/values of
surprise inflation.
22
1.50
Observed CPI (%, MoM)
Forecasted CPI (%, MoM)
1.00
0.50
Avg. = 0.21
0.00
-0.50
-1.00
1.50
Surprise CPI (p.p., MoM)
1.00
0.50
0.00
Avg. = -0.00
-0.50
-1.00
0 011 3 4 5 6 8 9 0 1 3
201 2, 2 201 201 201 201 201 201 202 202 202
13, 1 10, 12, 11, 09, 08, 10, 08, 07, 06,
Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb
1.00
Observed PCE (%, MoM)
Forecasted PCE (%, MoM)
0.50
Avg. = 0.16
0.00
-0.50
1.00
Surprise PCE (p.p., MoM)
0.50
0.00
Avg. = -0.02
-0.50
0 011 3 4 5 6 8 9 0 1 3
201 2, 2 201 201 201 201 201 201 202 202 202
13, 1 10, 12, 11, 09, 08, 10, 08, 07, 06,
Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb
23
10.00
Observed CPI (%, YoY)
Forecasted CPI (%, YoY)
8.00
6.00
4.00
0.00
0.00
Avg. = 0.02
-0.50
0 011 3 4 5 6 8 9 0 1 3
201 2, 2 201 201 201 201 201 201 202 202 202
13, 1 10, 12, 11, 09, 08, 10, 08, 07, 06,
Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb
Note: Subfigures (a), (b), and (c) show the observed and the forecasted U.S. Consumer Price
Index (CPI, %, Year-over-Year) for each release of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).
Actual data is seasonally adjusted for MoM comparisons (not seasonally adjusted for YoY
comparisons) and comes from the BLS, and forecasts are obtained at Investing.com. The lower
part of the figure shows the time series of the Surprise component (difference between the
observed, actual inflation, and the analysts’ forecast). Covered CPI (PCE) announcements
range from August 13, 2010 (August 30, 2010), to January 12, 2023 (Jan 27, 2023).
24
1.00
Surprise CPI (p.p., MoM)
Surprise PCE (p.p., MoM)
Surprise CPI (p.p., YoY)
0.50
0.00
-1.00
0 1 3 4 5 6 8 9 0 1 3
201 201 201 201 201 201 201 201 202 202 202
Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb May Aug Nov Feb
Note: The upper part of this figure shows the observed and forecasted U.S. Consumer Price
Index (CPI, %, Year-over-Year) for each release of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).
Actual data is seasonally adjusted for MoM comparisons (not seasonally adjusted for YoY
comparisons) and comes from the BLS, and forecasts are obtained at Investing.com. The lower
part of the figure shows the time series of the Surprise component (difference between the
observed, actual inflation, and the analysts’ forecast). Covered CPI (PCE) announcements
range from August 13, 2010 (August 30, 2010), to January 12, 2023 (Jan 27, 2023).
25
0.50 0.50
Cross-correlations of Shock_CPI_MoM and Shock_CPI_YoY
0.00 0.00
-0.50 -0.50
-1.00 -1.00
-10 -5 0 5 10
Lag
Note: This Figure shows the cross-correlation among each pair of computed inflation surprise
(difference between the observed, actual inflation, and the analysts’ forecast): CPI MoM-PCE
MoM (Panel A), CPI YoY-PCE MoM (Panel B), and CPI MoM-CPI YoY (Panel C). The Y-
axis shows the linear correlation coefficient that ranges from -1 to +1. The X-axis presents the
lags and leads that are symmetrical and range from one to ten. The red vertical line emphasizes
the contemporaneous linear correlation coefficient (lead/lag equals zero). Covered CPI (PCE)
announcements range from August 13, 2010 (August 30, 2010), to January 12, 2023 (Jan 27,
2023).
26
Note: This table shows the results of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test for the Model
with different specifications. The sample period covers from 2010:08 to 2023:01. The Ret (Dif)
prefix indicates that the series was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in one-day
windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements. The maximum number of lags considered
for implementing the test is 13 and is defined by the Schwert criterion (1989). *, **, and ***
denote statistical significance at 1, 5, and 10%, respectively, and lead to the rejection of the null
hypothesis indicating the non-existence of a unit root. The Lags column reports the optimal
number of lags following the Akaike information criterion (AIC).
27
Model Test stat. Critical value (5%) p-value Degrees of freedom Assessment
VAR(6) 264.8 290.0 0.277 252 Accept H0
VAR(7) 265.5 251.3 0.012 216 Reject H0
VAR(8) 265.5 212.3 0.000 180 Reject H0
Note: This table shows the results of the Ljung and Box test (1978) for the Model with different
VAR orders. The sample period covers from 2010:08 to 2023:01. The maximum number of
lags considered for implementing the test is 13 and is defined by the Schwert criterion (1989).
QLB statistic values lower than the critical values lead to the acceptance of the null hypothesis
and indicate that the residual autocorrelation up to the maximum number of lags is zero,
considering a 95% confidence interval.
Lag Ret SP500 Dif VIX Surp Inf Dif US 1Y Ret Gold Ret BTC
1 0.120 0.233 0.233 0.235 0.077 0.077
2 0.207 0.185 0.185 0.152 0.068 0.008
3 0.631 0.157 0.157 0.158 0.158 0.032
4 0.242 0.223 0.223 0.206 0.206 0.169
5 0.197 0.197 0.273 0.120 0.107 0.034
6 0.271 0.334 0.076 0.076 0.011 0.093
Note: This table shows the results of the stability diagnosis test applied to the VAR(6) model.
The sample period covers from 2010:08 to 2023:01. The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the
series was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in one-day windows around monthly
CPI MoM announcements. The values reported correspond to the eigenvalues (in modulus)
associated with each model lag. Values lower than 1 mean that they are inside the unit circle,
which highlights the stability of the model.
28
29
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of the six
variables and their 95% confidence bands for the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01.
The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the series was constructed from returns (differences) cal-
culated in one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements. The units of the
horizontal axes are months.
30
VAR(9)
VAR(12)
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01 for the Model with alternative lags. The Ret
prefix indicates that the series was constructed from returns calculated in one-day windows
around monthly CPI MoM announcements. The units of the horizontal axes are a month.
31
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01 for the Model with the following temporal
ordering: Dif U S 1Y , Surp Inf , Ret SP 500, Dif V IX, Ret Gold and Ret BT C. The Ret
(Dif) prefix indicates that the series was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in
one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements. The units of the horizontal axes
are a month.
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01 for the Model with the addition of a linear
trend component in the specification. The Ret prefix indicates that the series was constructed
from returns calculated in one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements. The
units of the horizontal axes are a month.
32
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2010:08 and 2020:01 (114 observations). The Ret prefix indicates
that the series was constructed from returns calculated in one-day windows around monthly
CPI MoM announcements. The units of the horizontal axes are a month.
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) of Bitcoin
and gold to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation and their 95% confidence bands for
the sample period between 2014:01 and 2023:01 (109 observations). The Ret prefix indicates
that the series was constructed from returns calculated in one-day windows around monthly
CPI MoM announcements. The units of the horizontal axes are a month.
33
Note: This figure shows cumulative orthogonal impulse response functions (COIRFs) and their
95% confidence bands for the sample period between 2010:08 and 2023:01 for the Model with
the inclusion of the actual inflation series (Act Inf ). The Ret (Dif) prefix indicates that the
series was constructed from returns (differences) calculated in one-day windows around monthly
CPI MoM announcements. The units of the vertical axes correspond to the intensity of the
series’ response to the one-standard-deviation shock in inflation (actual inflation). The units
of the horizontal axes are a month.
34
Note: This table shows statistics for all series covering different sampling periods. The Ret
(Dif) prefix indicates that the series was derived from returns (differences) calculated within
one-day windows around monthly CPI MoM announcements.
35