Nber Working Paper Series
Nber Working Paper Series
Wolfgang Keller
I would like to thank Sourafel Girma for providing some regression results. I have also benefited from
conversations with Bob Baldwin and Elhanan Helpman, as well as from comments by Sam Kortum and
Maurice Schiff. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
© 2001 by Wolfgang Keller. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may
be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
International Technology Diffusion
Wolfgang Keller
NBER Working Paper No. 8573
October 2001
JEL No. F1, F2, O3, O4
ABSTRACT
I discuss the concept and empirical importance of international technology diffusion from the
point of view of recent work on endogenous technological change. In this literature, technology is viewed
as technological knowledge. I first review the major concepts, and how international technology diffusion
relates to other factors affecting economic growth in open economies. The following main section of the
paper provides a review of recent empirical results on (i) basic results in international technology
diffusion; (ii) the importance of specific channels of diffusion, in particular trade and foreign direct
investment; (iii) the spatial distribution of technological knowledge, and (iv) other issues.
Wolfgang Keller
Department of Economics
University of Texas
BRB 3.152
Austin, TX 78712
and NBER
keller@eco.utexas.edu
1. Introduction
accumulation of physical and human capital matters as well, but that cannot
2001, Prescott 1988). If the rate of technical change differs across countries, this
technologies (ICTs) have been developed relatively fast in the United States
(U.S.), for example, and this might explain why the U.S.’ lead in per capita
income over Japan has increased from 10% in 1990 to 20% by 1999.
Recent work has shown, however, that the major sources of technical
instead, they lie abroad (Eaton and Kortum 1999, Keller 2001a).2 The
capita income in the world. Because most developing countries spend relatively
2Eaton and Kortum (1999) estimate for example that foreign research accounts for 87% of
productivity growth in France (Table 5). See section 3 for further results.
2
diffusion is at the heart of the recent ''digital divide'' discussion, for example--the
widespread fear that the development of the Internet might not lead to
distribution.
While it has been recognized since the classic ‘Solow residual’ paper
(Solow 1957) that rates of factor accumulation do not account for the major part
of economic growth, the view that technological change has both domestic and
foreign sources is less common. Arguably, the rapidly rising level of economic
increases does indeed lie in purely domestic activities, such as the learning effects
foreign and domestic firms. The greater importance of technology adoption from
This paper takes a look at the evidence to expand on these ideas. In the
provide some references to the underlying theories; the sections that follow are
3
In section 5, I review the evidence on the heterogeneity of diffusion across
this has changed over time. In section 8 I discuss some evidence on major
Finally, section 9 summarizes the major findings, suggests directions for future
2. Conceptual issues
ten years ago (Aghion and Howitt 1992, Grossman and Helpman 1991, Romer
3 See Grossman and Helpman (1995) and Aghion and Howitt (1998) for broader overviews. I will
also discuss some related work on learning-by-doing and human capital accumulation that falls
into the broad category of models of knowledge accumulation.
4 See Romer (1990). Many of these ideas have been discussed in the literature before; important
contributors include Paul David, Giovanni Dosi, Robert Evenson, Jan Fagerberg, Richard Nelson ,
Keith Pavitt, Nathan Rosenberg, Vernon Ruttan, Luc Soete, Sidney Winter, Larry Westphal, and
others (see Fagerberg 1994 and Evenson and Westphal 1995 for overviews). What distinguishes
the recent work is that it includes fully specified general equilibrium models. This means that
these technology effects can in principle be simulated and estimated in a well-defined framework.
4
2. The return to investments towards new technology are partly private and
processes.
Out of these, points 1 and 2 are key for my purposes. The first characteristic
means that technological knowledge can serve users beyond those who are
currently employing it without raising the costs to the original set of users. Other
authors have coined the terms ‘perfectly expansible’ (David 1992) and ‘infinitely
distinguishes knowledge from rival factor inputs such as human and physical
capital; the latter can only be used by one firm at a time, or put differently, the
marginal costs to use the same factor for a second firm are infinite.
investments implies that while there is a force that might be strong enough to
sustain the private incentive to innovate (the private return, which is often a
firms and individuals external to the inventor by adding to their knowledge base
(the public return). These benefits are usually called knowledge spillovers. An
example is that the design of a new product might speed up the invention of a
competing product, because the second inventor can learn from the first by
5
My survey of international technology diffusion is largely an analysis of the
productivity.
such technology means that a blueprint is known not only to a firm in the country
where the blueprint was first developed (or firms, if there are domestic
of domestically known product designs. This assumption captures the idea that
creating a new product becomes easier as the number of already known product
6
spillovers raise the productivity of domestic inventive activity. It might be called
an active spillover, in the sense that the foreign blueprint becomes part of the
domestic R&D laboratories’ stock of knowledge that can be actively used to invent
new products.
intermediate goods. The idea is that employing the foreign intermediate good
involves the implicit usage of the design knowledge that was created with the
intermediate good costs less than its opportunity costs—which include the R&D
an importing country has indirect access to the results of foreign R&D, the
spillovers? Clearly, the latter might be related to international trade and foreign
international trade and FDI. For instance, the volume of international trade
7
between two countries is declining with bilateral geographic distance (see Leamer
and Levinsohn 1995). This suggests that to the extent that passive spillovers are
as well.
sufficient for spillovers of the active kind. The technological knowledge that
allows the inventor to produce a new product (or operate a new process) is often
infinitely expansible, in the above sense. What governs the access to this
technological knowledge, or, put differently, what are the major determinants of
as patents that allow the owner to exclude others from using the blueprint
codified in the blueprint can diffuse in any way and pattern in which a file on a
computer disk can be distributed. And since the late 20th century, it can be sent at
very low cost over computer networks to even remote places in the world.
Should one therefore expect that active technology spillovers are, in the
absence of legal constraints, global? Not necessarily. Consider first that from the
point of view of the inventor, the leaking out of knowledge to others is the
8
licensing contract, the inventor has the incentive of keeping the knowledge secret.
who have the technological knowledge and others who do not, this could make it
more difficult for the inventor to prevent knowledge spillovers from occurring.
From the point of view of the learner, international contacts make it easier to
importing, exporting, or FDI might also help to establish and sustain channels of
conditions.7
Polanyi’s view, knowledge is to some extent tacit because the person who is
9
knowledge is only partially codified because it is impossible or at least very costly
to do so.
Teece (1977), for instance, finds that the non-codified part of the costs of
projects, he estimates that the costs of the transfer were on average almost 20%
knowledge (software expert systems do just that), and the costs of doing this has
fallen in some areas over recent years. However, also more recent analysis has
that tacit knowledge can be passed on only “by example from master to
9For transferring machinery equipment technology, this share was 36% (Teece 1977, 248).
Teece’s estimates are a lower bound for technology transfer to less developed countries, as his
sample includes to two-thirds relatively advanced countries. He lists the following types of costs
(245-6): pre-engineering of technological exchanges, costs associated with transferring the
process/product design and the associated engineering, R&D personnel costs during the transfer
phase, pre-start-up training and excess manufacturing costs. Teece also shows suggestive
evidence on when these costs are particularly high or low, for instance in relation to similar
production experience (-) or general level of development (-).
10
No doubt, the quality of communication between persons at different
fact that it is costly for people to move in geographic space, this suggests that the
knowledge spillovers (e.g., Griliches 1995). The former are productivity spillovers only in a
measurement sense, because they occur solely because, for example in computing the productivity
of the intermediate good-using industry, one does not properly take account of the high quality of
the intermediate good. This leads to an overestimate of the productivity of the intermediate-using
industry. Major reasons for that are unavailable, or slowly adjusted price indices. By contrast,
knowledge spillovers are ‘true’ spillovers in the sense that they involve a positive externality. In
practice, it has been difficult to separate these two types of spillovers empirically. Because passive
spillovers as characterized above involve the purchase of goods, they might involve often an
element of rent spillovers. Productivity calculations are also complicated by the need to do this in
a way that accounts for new goods (see Feenstra, Markusen, and Zeile 1994).
11
Alternative views include Mankiw (1995) and Parente and Prescott (2000)
firms and individuals in all countries. Their explanations for differences in per
capita income across countries differ though. In Mankiw’s view, the explanation
and human capital.12 Recent analysis suggests that this hypothesis is difficult to
maintain (Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare 1997, Hall and Jones 1999). Instead, a
large part of cross-country differences in income per capita have to do with total
differences in the availability of rival factors. Instead, the main cause of cross-
12 It often involves noting that rich countries have higher-quality capital than poorer countries.
Differences in technological knowledge are thereby subsumed into differences in the quality of
capital goods. For example, Mankiw (1995, 281) argues that countries share the same production
function, but “when an economy doubles its capital stock, it does not give each worker twice as
many shovels. Instead, it replaces shovels with bulldozers”. Following this line of argument leads
to an analysis of growth from an accounting perspective. It is not very helpful, though, for
explaining the fundamental causes of growth and income differences. See also Romer (1992).
13 See also Prescott (1998) and Easterly and Levine (2001), as well as other contributions at the
12
differences play a certain role, it seems at this point ambitious to show that policy
differences are the central reason for cross-country TFP differences. There are
plenty of instances where linking TFP differences to the activities of lobbies, state
knowledge is global and countries differ in their resistance to adopt it, then TFP
whereas human capital is embodied, tacit, and local knowledge. This might be a
technology diffusion, I highlight in the following that not all growth effects that
13
have been discussed in this context have to do with international technology
diffusion.
autarky to the other of full integration, can have important implications for a
might reduce the monopoly power of domestic firms, thereby affecting pricing
behavior and the efficiency with which domestic resources are utilized (Tybout
2000 discusses the evidence). Clearly, this effect is not related to technological
might lead to changes in a country’s growth rate. Young (1991) for instance
develops a model with two countries, North and South, that each produces a
15 For simplicity, I focus here on international trade, but analogous arguments apply as well to
FDI and other forms of international economic activity.
16
Instead, this mechanism is similar to the “nontechnological” and “policy” determinants of TFP
that are emphasized in Solow (2001) and Klenow (2001), respectively; it is also related to Parente
and Prescott’s (2000) main thesis.
14
range of products. A country’s growth rate is determined by the prevailing level of
The potential for learning-by-doing is high for more recently invented products
while for older products, learning-by-doing effects are exhausted. Young shows
that trade liberalization might slow down the rate of growth in the South relative
Ch.6) show that such results can be obtained also in models of endogenous
technical change. Assume that there are two final goods, X and Y, produced with
varying factor intensity, plus an R&D activity that produces inputs for the X good.
allows the production of more output with the same amount of inputs. In this
lowers the relative price of good Y (that is, it again depends on comparative
(and the R&D laboratories) and into the Y sector. As a consequence, growth slows
down relative to before. The opposite occurs if trade liberalization lowers the
15
Trade liberalization might have important growth effects through changes
that shows this to be the case (see also the overview in Tybout 2000, pp.37-38). It
is worth emphasizing, though, that these particular models do not involve the
international diffusion of technology. This is clear from the fact that it is possible
to find a tax and subsidy policy that affects the domestic resource allocation in
just the same way as trade liberalization does, and which therefore has the same
growth effects. 17 These models highlight the fact that there might be growth
effects from trade liberalization that are not related to international technology
diffusion. Arguably, one might expect the diffusion effects associated with
countries. I will discuss the available evidence below. In any case, insofar as what
country’s growth rate and welfare relative to autarky: access to more, rather than
less, knowledge, just like more choices, should leave a country at least weakly
better off.
technology.
17
The standard mechanisms of international technology diffusion are not present in either
Grossman and Helpman’s or Young’s model. In the former model, neither are the specialized
intermediate inputs internationally tradable, nor are there domestic learning effects from foreign
R&D. In the latter model, each country’s stock of knowledge depends only on its range of
production; there is no direct link between domestic and foreign stocks of knowledge. Moreover,
the learning-by-doing stages that the North has passed through are not transferable: they have to
be repeated by the South.
16
3. International technology diffusion: basic
magnitudes
the importance of international technology diffusion. The first and largest set of
relate TFP to measures of domestic (R) and foreign R&D (S) activities
ln TFPct = α c + α t + β r ln Rct + β s ln S ct + ε ct ,
where c indexes country and t subscripts time; αc and αt make for a generalized
and time-varying intercept, and εct is an error term. The definition of S, the term
S ct = ∑ ω cht S ht ,
h≠c
where ωcht is a bilateral weight that captures the relative importance of R&D in
(1992) and Coe and Helpman (1995), have employed import shares shares as
17
weights. Depending on the particular channel of technology diffusion that
authors analyze, also FDI or other weights have been employed (see section 4
below).
omitted variables might be causing biases. The work in this literature varies in
the extent to which the authors address these potential problems. At its best, this
and foreign R&D. Coe and Helpman (1995) estimate for their sample of 22
countries, and 23% for the G-7 countries.19 The corresponding elasticities with
respect to foreign R&D are about 12% and 6%, respectively. Thus, for the 15
smaller countries, the effect from foreign R&D is larger than that from domestic
R&D, with a factor of about 1.5. The share of about 20% for foreign R&D in the
total elasticity effect for the G-7 countries is similar to Keller’s (2001c) estimate in
his analysis of the G-7 countries plus Sweden using data at the industry level. By
contrast, Park (1995) in his analysis of aggregate data for ten OECD countries
(including the G-7) estimates that foreign R&D accounts for about two thirds of
19 These are Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, the United Kingdom, and the United States.
18
the total effect of R&D on productivity (domestic R&D elasticity of 7%, foreign
In a series of papers, Eaton and Kortum (1997, 1999) and Eaton, Gutierrez,
arrive at a framework that can be estimated, Eaton and Kortum have to make
with a Pareto distribution, while the distribution of the time until it has diffused
the context of a given model. Eaton and Kortum’s empirical results are thus
Eaton and Kortum’s work shows that the pay-off to this can be high. Their
framework allows not only studying the reduced-form relationship between R&D
and productivity, but also the models’ predictions for the transitional adjustment
path to the long-run equilibrium (Eaton and Kortum 1997). They also examine
the effects of changes in economic policy (Eaton, Gutierrez, and Kortum 1998),
and Eaton and Kortum (1999) model R&D and the diffusion of knowledge
together with the related activity of international patenting. With regard to the
20 This is as in the ‘quality-ladder’ model of Aghion and Howitt (1992); see also Howitt (2000).
19
presents results based on data for the G-5 countries around the year 1988. Eaton
and Kortum estimate that the part of productivity growth that is due to domestic
as opposed to foreign R&D is between 11% and 16% in Germany, France, and the
U.K.; it is around 35% for Japan, and about 60% for the United States (1999,
Table 5).
Eaton and Kortum’s work based on general equilibrium models, Keller studies
discussed above, Keller (2001a,b) estimates the TFP effect of foreign R&D jointly
with the importance of one or more channels of diffusion for foreign R&D. One
can view this as estimating the weights ω of the foreign R&D variable together
with the parameter β that measures the TFP elasticity. Estimating the weights
instead of assuming particular weights that are taken from data tables means to
Keller (2001a) estimates that between 1983 and 1995, the contribution of
technology diffusion from G-5 countries is on average almost 90% of the total
These are Australia, Canada, Denmark, Finland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Spain, and
21
Sweden.
20
This shows that irrespective of which particular approach is taken, the
international technology diffusion primarily occurs. I first look at work that has
Trade
Coe and Helpman (1995) are the first to provide evidence on the
recent theory. Using the spillover regressions framework shown on p.16 with
bilateral import shares as weights, these authors examine two predictions. First,
(an import composition effect). Second, for a given composition of imports, these
22This would be very important for less developed countries. Primarily due to the much greater
difficulty in obtaining comparable and high-quality data for less developed countries, there is a
relative paucity of results in this regard. See, however, Coe, Helpman, and Hoffmaister (1997),
Connolly (1998), and Mayer (2001), as well as the discussion below.
21
authors analyze whether a country’s productivity is higher, the higher is its
overall import share. Coe and Helpman’s regression results suggest that there is
support for both predictions. The authors conclude that international R&D
spillovers are related to the composition of imports, and that the overall level of
and Hoffmaister (1997) find similar effects in their analysis of foreign technology
By contrast, Eaton and Kortum (1996) find that once distance and other
influences are controlled for, bilateral imports do not help to predict bilateral
model. Moreover, Keller (1998) repeats the Coe and Helpman (1995) regressions
with counterfactual ‘import’ shares.24 For there to be strong evidence for trade-
effect from foreign R&D when bilateral import shares are employed, but no
strong effect when counterfactual ‘import’ shares are used. Keller finds similarly
actual import shares are used. He concludes that, on the basis of their analysis,
Coe and Helpman’s claim cannot be upheld: the import composition of a country
has not a strong influence on the regression results. 25 Keller’s (1998) results have
led some to doubt the importance of trade for international technology diffusion.
23 Nadiri and Kim (1996) show results from estimating cost functions in OECD countries; their
approach also uses the bilateral-imports weighted spillover variable.
24 That is, instead of bilateral import shares, Keller (1998) uses counterfactual (or, made-up)
22
More recent work has strengthened the evidence for import-related
suggest that import composition might not matter for technology diffusion if
countries’ import patterns are more or less symmetric, but they do matter if
countries receive a relatively high share of its total imports from one particular
country—such as is the case for Canada, for example, which imports about 80%
Moreover, Xu and Wang (1999) show that the import composition effect is
goods trade. Xu and Wang show that if the weights in the construction of the
foreign R&D variable S are capital goods import shares, one obtains an R2 of
77.1%, versus 74.9% with Keller’s (1998) counterfactual shares, and 70.9% in Coe
and Helpman (1995). Also Lumenga-Neso, Olarreaga, and Schiff (2001) have
26 As Coe and Hoffmaister (1999) emphasize, Keller (1998) creates his counterfactual ‘import’
shares in a way that makes their variance across different simulations rather small, and values
higher than 0.3 are essentially never obtained. Thus, his import shares are not fully random in
that sense. This was first pointed out in 1996 by an anonymous referee at the European Economic
Review to both Keller and the editor, Elhanan Helpman. Keller’s (1998) paper includes therefore
results with the unweighted sum of foreign R&D as well. These do not support the Coe and
Helpman (1995) claim that international R&D spillovers are related to the composition of imports
either, which is Keller’s (1998) point (see his Table 2). In a different context, Keller (1997b, 2000)
shows that certain randomizations of import shares lead to equally strong empirical results as
those based on observed imports, while others do not. He also discusses the relationship between
random import shares and unweighted sum-of-foreign-R&D regressions. Coe and Hoffmaister
(1999) show that for three types of randomizations of import shares, the Coe and Helpman (1995)
framework does not lead to a finding of international R&D spillovers. This means that the
bilateral import shares have some power.
23
revisited the results of Coe and Helpman (1995) and Keller (1998). Instead of
well. This captures the case that even if some country c imports only from some
other country h, for instance, the former might still gain access to technology
from countries other than h—if country h has in turn imported from those other
countries before. Using this variable, Lumenga-Neso, Olarreaga, and Schiff find
number of other studies (see the following section, section 6, and section 9).
citations and bilateral imports. This result is consistent with imports contributing
Two recent papers by Eaton and Kortum (2001a,b) also focus on the
combine the structure of technology diffusion and growth in Eaton and Kortum
(1999) with that of the Ricardian trade model due to Dornbusch, Fischer, and
24
Samuelson (1977). A country’s productivity level is related to its implicit access to
goods is relatively high. Eaton and Kortum (2001a) use this framework to predict,
might at the same time increase the likelihood of active knowledge spillovers.
This would also allow the estimation of the relative importance of active and
Bernard and Jensen (1996)--using U.S. data--, and Clerides, Lach, and Tybout
(1998)--using data from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco--have used micro data
paper finds robust evidence that past exporting experience (Granger-) causes
25
taken into account. Thus, the available evidence does not point to strong
learning-through-exporting effects.27
Other mechanisms
from one country to another (e.g., Carr, Markusen, and Maskus 2001), making it
countries with the same R&D weighting approach that Coe and Helpman (1995)
and Keller (1998) use for imports. Lichtenberg and van Pottelsberghe de la
Potterie (1996) find that a country’s outward FDI gives access to foreign
technology. At the same time, they do not find significant effects from inward
FDI. Baldwin, Braconier, and Forslid (1999) find some positive inward FDI
spillover effects in their industry-level study, but overall, the results are mixed.
To some extent, this might have to do with the fact that good data on bilateral
FDI is available to a much lesser extent than for trade. Therefore, the two above
26
accounts. However, good measures of multinational activity, such as subsidiary
GDP, sales, or its number of employees, are related to FDI stocks derived from
outward FDI and productivity growth in the host country. His analysis covers
total manufacturing between 1966 and 1994 for 40 countries, of which about half
are more and half are less developed countries. Xu finds generally a positive
correlation between productivity growth and the ratio of subsidiary value added
to host country GDP. This effect is stronger and more robust in the more
As the availability of micro data has become greater, the study of FDI
spillovers has increasingly turned to it. Aitken and Harrison (1999) examine data
relationship of increased FDI presence and TFP of domestic plants. This can be
competitors are structurally weak, if the estimation fails to fully control for this
29One important reason for this is that FDI does not necessarily involve net flows of capital,
because the latter can be raised in local capital markets.
27
Aitken and Harrison note, their analysis may fail to capture the long-run effects
of FDI (p.617). 30
Girma and Wakelin (2001) use micro-data from the U.K. Census of
Production to study the effects of inward FDI in the United Kingdom. The
authors focus on the electronics industry between 1980 and 1992. Girma and
industry (and also by foreign investor country). Other variables are FDI in a given
geographic region within the U.K., and FDI in a given two-digit industry. The first
tests for intra-industry FDI spillovers, the second and third for FDI spillovers
positive productivity effect from Japanese and Other foreign FDI, but not from
U.S. FDI. There is also evidence in support of FDI spillovers from technological
proximity, but no evidence that within-region spillovers are stronger than those
across regions.31
Haskel, Pereira, and Slaughter (2001) use the same database, but add both
more years and plants from all of manufacturing to the sample. They confirm the
Girma and Wakelin (2001) findings that technological proximity seems to matter
30 FDI presence in Aitken and Harrison (1999) is measured as the share of employment of
foreign-owned firms in total employment. This variable can change without a change in
employment by foreign-owned firms. Aitken and Harrison report, however, that including foreign
employment and domestic employment separately in the regression leads to similar results
(p.610). This point applies also to the studies by Girma and Wakelin (2001) and Haskel, Pereira,
and Slaughter (2001), discussed below. I have not seen a discussion of this point in the latter
papers, so I assume that it does not alter the results there either.
31 Jaffe, Trajtenberg, and Henderson (1993) as well as Adams and Jaffe (1996) find evidence that
distance matters for domestic technology diffusion. To be consistent with that, Girma and
Wakelin’s result might have to be interpreted as saying that conditional on technology coming
from abroad, geographic distance within a country does not matter. See also section 6 below.
28
for FDI spillovers, whereas geographic proximity within the U.K. does not. By
contrast, Haskel, Pereira, and Slaughter (2001) estimate positive spillovers from
U.S. and French FDI, whereas Japanese FDI is here negatively correlated with
productivity growth.32
in the Czech Republic between 1995 and 1998.33 Unlike the other studies,
find positive spillovers from inward FDI into the Czech Republic; however, there
is a robust effect if the FDI variable is interacted with the firm’s own R&D
32 The differences in results relative to Girma and Wakelin (2001) could be in part related to
differences in the estimation technique. Girma and Wakelin favor a variant of the Olley and Pakes
(1996) technique, whereas Haskel, Pereira, and Slaughter (2001) employ a time differencing
approach. The former method is conceptually more appealing, but it also requires making more
specific assumptions that are difficult to test. Based on supplemental results for the Girma and
Wakelin study using the time differencing method—provided to me by Sourafel Girma--, I can
compare their FDI spillover results using the modified Olley and Pakes technique with those
based on time differencing. At a 5% significance level, there are qualitative differences in 3 out of
10 of the key estimated coefficients in their Table 7. This does not settle the question of which
estimates are closer to the true parameters. However, in my view it suggests that to examine
whether some of the assumptions in the Olley and Pakes framework can be tested or generalized
is an interesting research project.
33 The data comes from two surveys of the Czech Statistical Office. Because there is relatively little
to medium range of the distribution of skill intensities (skilled to unskilled workers); this seems to
be not the plants with the highest absorptive capacity. Kinoshita (2000) also distinguishes FDI
spillover effects for domestically-owned from those for foreign-owned firms, finding that only the
former benefit. It would be interesting to see whether this also holds in the UK sample.
29
Globermann, Kokko, and Sjöholm (2000) analyze 220 patent applications
by Swedish MNEs and non-MNEs in the year of 1986. These applications contain
patent citations that the authors relate to both inward FDI from the cited
robust correlation between outward FDI and patent citations—not only for
MNEs, but also for non-MNEs--, whereas there is none on the inward side.
citations between the U.S. and Japan.35 While Branstetter (2001a) can measure
FDI only by establishment counts, he can control for the firms’ R&D spending,
which is a plus (see above). The data also allows him to distinguish product
-from other subsidiaries. Branstetter finds that more FDI is associated with more
patent citations, both from U.S. firms to Japanese firms and vice versa.
Communication patterns
which has made it easier to outsource certain stages of production. This suggests
more important role today than it used to. At the same time, this does not
30
necessarily mean that person-to-person communication patterns have become
aspatial, for at least two reasons. First, remote communication might only be an
Keller (2001a,b) uses the imperfect proxy of bilateral language skills in the
that differences in communication patterns might have quite strong effects. For
instance, if the share of English speakers in Spain (at 17%) would rise to the level
of the share of English speakers in the Netherlands (at 77%), Keller (2001a)
estimates that for Spain, this would be equivalent to a 15% boost of technology
technology diffusion
technology diffusion simultaneously, the majority of them still examines only one
31
channel in isolation.36 As documented by Kraay, Isoalaga, and Tybout (2001),
firms do not typically engage in one type of international activity by itself; rather,
they are engaged in several of them. Kraay, Isoalaga, and Tybout use information
(1998), the data comes from three panels of firms in Morocco, Mexico, and
economic interactions on the firm’s marginal cost or the quality of the good that
among the G-7 countries finds significant effects for imports, inward FDI, as well
than 50% of the total effect to imports, and the remainder to equal parts to FDI
for instance, Keller (2001a) reports that about 80% of all manufacturing R&D is
industries that account for a substantial part of all R&D, some authors have
36See, however, Globermann, Kokko, and Sjöholm (2000) and Lichtenberg and van Pottelsberghe
de la Potterie (1996), who both analyze trade and FDI.
32
restricted their analysis right from the start to such ‘high-technology’ industries
(e.g., Bernstein and Mohnen 1998). Other authors have tried to compare the
magnitude of effects across industries. These studies fall primarily into the
A first set of papers, including Coe, Helpman, and Hoffmaister (1997) and
Wang 1999, discussed in section 4 above). Using foreign knowledge stocks that
Coe, Helpman and Hoffmaister (1997) find stronger and more robust evidence
for North-South spillovers using machinery and equipment import data (SITC
(2001) argues that this includes still many consumption and equipment goods
that are unlikely to lead to much technology diffusion. His focus on machinery
using the variable based on all SITC imports (Meyer 2001, Tables 6,8). 38
37 Connolly (1998) in her cross-country growth analysis of innovation and imitation uses the SITC
specialized machinery imports--at the three- and four-digit SITC level—to productivity at the two-
and three-digit ISIC class level.
33
panels of twelve manufacturing industries. Eight of these twelve industries
account for only about 20% of all manufacturing R&D, whereas—as mentioned
earlier--the remaining four industries make up for the remaining 80%. Keller
estimating that the elasticity of TFP with respect to R&D there is only about 70%
of the average elasticity for all twelve industries. In his study of trade and
from above, Blyde (2001) finds stronger effects from OECD imports than from
Latin American imports. He attributes this result primarily to the fact that OECD
imports.
greatly in strength across different set of goods. Another literature has started to
ICTs might have strong productivity effects in other industries, perhaps even
abroad. Gera, Gu, and Lee’s (1999) estimates of technology spillovers from the
U.S. to Canada suggest that technology spillovers embodied in ICT imports from
the U.S. have about four times the effect on labor productivity in Canadian
different sources of R&D: domestic R&D as well as foreign R&D, both in the same
34
inter-industry technology flows, his findings suggest that the importance of
foreign R&D outside the industry itself is as important for productivity as the
technology diffusion
Henderson (1993), Irwin and Klenow (1994), Jaffe and Trajtenberg (1998), Eaton
citations with that of the cited patents in the United States. Their key finding is
that U.S. patents are significantly more often cited by other U.S. patents than
they are cited by foreign patents. Branstetter (2001b) uses R&D and patenting
data on U.S. and Japanese firms to compute weighted R&D spillover stocks
39 See also the evidence on spillovers in technologically proximate fields in the section on FDI
above.
40 Patenting data by technological field allows Branstetter to compute weights that are increasing
in the similarity of two firms’ patenting activities; this captures the idea that R&D expenditures of
35
Branstetter finds that within-country spillovers are much stronger than between-
by Eaton and Kortum (1999) and Jaffe and Trajtenberg (1998) supports this
result as well.
in the semiconductor industry finds the opposite.41 These authors estimate that
for eight vintages of semiconductors introduced between 1974 and 1992, the
learning spillovers from one U.S. firm to another U.S. firm are not significantly
stronger than those between an U.S. firm and a foreign firm. The different results
which are identified from the effects of cumulative production on market shares,
could also be due to the market structure of the semiconductor industry, which
had only relatively few firms that were located primarily in the U.S. and in Japan
geographic effects in technology diffusion beyond the basic “border effect”. The
another firm is more likely to generate spillovers, the closer the two firms are in technology space
(see Jaffe 1986).
41 Learning-by-doing spillovers are most closely related to human capital models (e.g. Lucas 1988,
1993), not to models of endogenous technological change. However, it is not clear that empirical
analysis has been able to separate one from the other so far. I thus include the following
discussion.
42 In particular, the effects captured by Irwin and Klenow are much broader than the notion of
36
estimating whether there is geographic decay in the strength of technology
spillovers, Keller (2001a,b) has done this for OECD countries. For example, if
diffusion, then technology created in the U.S. should have a stronger influence on
productivity in Canada than in Germany; and the latter effect should in turn be
1970 and 1995. He relates productivity in nine mostly smaller OECD countries to
R&D conducted in the G-5 countries, and allows for the possibility that the
strength of the R&D effects are conditional on a country’s bilateral distance to the
h≠c
Here, Rh is R&D in the G-5 country h, and Dch is the geographic distance between
countries c and h. The vector X is a set of other variables that help to control for
for δ> 0, variation in productivity levels is best accounted for by giving a lower
weight to R&D conducted in countries that are located relatively far away,
whereas if δ=0, then geographic distance and relative location do not matter.
43See also Bottazzi and Peri’s (1999) analysis of geographic effects in the diffusion of technology
among European regions.
37
What is the magnitude of this effect? The exponential specification allows
true, it implies that for instance Australia, with its remote geographic location
among the G-7 countries, which account for about 90% of the world’s R&D
kilometers.
is only the first step, of course. The question is, why does distance matter? At a
Thus it is important to see whether the geography effect can be related to the
above.
38
equation on page 36. According to his analysis, each channel individually has a
imports, FDI, and communication are considered together with distance, Keller
does not estimate a geographic localization effect anymore.44 This suggests that a
substantial portion of the distance effect in technology diffusion, and may be all
over time
standards (e.g., Feenstra 1995). International trade has been growing faster than
income, and transport costs for goods have been falling. Multinational activity
has been growing faster than trade, spurred in part by the development of new
What does this mean for technological diffusion? Is there now a common
pool of global technology, and distance is, as some have suggested, “dead”? The
44 Keller’s (2001b) results suggest that communication patterns are particularly effective in
accounting for the geographic localization effect (see his Table 7). This, however, might be specific
to the particular sample, where Japan is located most remotely and communicates the least
according to Keller’s data.
45 See also Sjöholm (1996) who finds that bilateral geographic distance between Sweden and other
countries has no robust effect on the number of citations in Swedish patent applications, once
differences in bilateral international trade have been controlled for.
39
recent papers by Keller (2001a,b) provide some initial evidence on this. He
has changed over time. Keller finds that the absolute value of the distance
parameter has fallen substantially between the mid-1970s and the 1990s. This is
consistent with a strong decline over time in the degree to which technology is
technology diffusion
There are big differences in the degree of success that countries have in
adopting foreign technology. Another strand of the literature has therefore asked
what the major determinants of successful technology diffusion from abroad are.
(convergence) over time. There are some preliminary findings suggesting that
between the years 1983 and 1995, technology diffusion from the G-7 countries
had stronger effects on growth in the relatively rich than in the poorer countries
(Keller 2001d). This might in part explain the trend towards income divergence
emphasized are human capital (Nelson and Phelps 1966) and R&D (Cohen and
40
Levinthal 1989). Both are associated with the notion of absorptive capacity, the
idea that a firm or country needs to have a certain type of skill in order to be able
to successfully adopt foreign technological knowledge.46 This can be, first of all,
another factor, first emphasized by Cohen and Levinthal (1989): a firm might
need to invest itself into R&D. These authors argue that this is critical to enabling
the firm to understand and evaluate new technological trends and innovations,
Along these lines, Eaton and Kortum (1996) find that inward technology
country’s human capital. Xu (2000) provides evidence suggesting that the reason
why relatively rich countries benefit from hosting U.S. multinational subsidiaries,
while poorer countries do not as much has to do with a threshold level of human
capital in the host country. Caselli and Coleman (2001) use data on imports of
industry, so that computer technology comes necessarily from abroad. They find
that computer imports are positively correlated with measures of human capital,
which is consistent with the results by Eaton and Kortum (1996) and Xu (2000).
In these three papers, the measures of human capital have only a quantity
population. Hanushek and Kimko (2000) have recently argued that the quality
41
dimension of human capital is at least as important. Their results using
standardized science and engineering test scores for around thirty countries
seems to bear this out. I expect that as test score data becomes available for a
larger set of less developed countries, it will be able to show that science and
(see also Kinoshita 2000, discussed in section 4 above). Griffith, Redding, and
Van Reenen (2000a) use industry-level data from twelve OECD countries for the
years 1974 to 1990 to study what are the main determinants of productivity
defined as TFP relative to TFP in the leader country; this is a measure of the
potential for productivity catch-up. Griffith, Redding, and Van Reenen (2000a)
find that subsequent TFP growth is negatively related to the productivity gap,
47These authors also find that interacting human capital with the productivity gap leads to a
smaller effect.
42
9. Summary and implications
While we know today much more than we did merely a couple of years ago, there
are only few results that are solidly established at this point. To date, different
answers; some of the results that I have reviewed above might still be overturned,
and many important topics have not been considered yet at all. Nevertheless, I
will try to draw some general lessons from what we know right now.
origin, I am not aware of studies that did not find international sources to be
important.48 The evidence so far suggests that the relative importance of foreign
technology in most less developed countries is at least 90%, and probably higher.
48
Does this matter relative to analyses that emphasize differences in the endowment with quality-
adjusted capital (Mankiw 1995) or in policies towards technology adoption (Parente and Prescott
2000)? It is true that at a given point in time, the process of international technology diffusion
must manifest itself in cross-country technology differences, which translate into income
differences. That all approaches will in the end lead to some statistics in the national income
accounts is not surprising—after all, each of them tries to explain GDP. The important questions
are rather: which framework is helpful for thinking about productivity growth, and which is useful
to guide economic policy towards raising productivity growth.
43
automatic, merely a function of what Gerschenkron (1962) has called economic
by the extent and the way in which firms of different countries engage in
diffusion early on. I think that the refinements of R&D spillover regressions in
response to the papers by Coe and Helpman (1995) and Keller (1998) now point
While the evidence using micro data is much weaker, especially on learning
Olarreaga, and Schiff (2001), indicate that there might be much to be learned
from future work that studies the full dynamics of trade and technology diffusion
mixed. The result that FDI does not necessarily lead to strong positive spillovers
is a sensible one. After all, a cornerstone of the theory of FDI says that firms
ventures or technology licensing because FDI helps to keep the private return to
44
In general, the evidence for positive effects from inward FDI is stronger for
more developed than for less developed countries. This might have to do with the
fact that outsourcing of relatively low-skill activities is more likely for North-
South FDI than for North-North FDI (e.g., Hanson, Mataloni, and Slaughter
2001). The former could have a lower learning potential than the latter, not
necessarily because the activities are different as such, but because they are
integrated with the host country economy to different degrees (in terms of
backward and forward linkages).49 At any rate, the fact that the only study of
those discussed above finding positive effects from inward FDI in a non-OECD
important.
view not been analyzed to a sufficient degree yet. In part, this seems to have to do
with a paucity of relevant data. This channel is also difficult to separate from
trade and FDI, because the ease of communication is affecting the likelihood of
trade relations, for example. To some extent, the relatively large contribution of
49 The processing plants along the U.S.-Mexican border (maquiladoras) might be a good example
of FDI with relatively few backward and forward linkages.
45
The literature on technology spillovers has moved increasingly away from
model is not easy, but I believe that the returns from doing this would be high.
diffusion across different sets of products varies: for certain types of high-tech
strong as for the average manufacturing good, ceteris paribus. However, it is also
true that price deflators for R&D-intensive products are, due to fast-rising
product quality, particularly hard to calculate. While it is plausible that active and
passive spillovers associated with high-tech products are larger than those
spurious.
further analysis. As the recent debate on whether advances in ICTs have raised
the structural rate of growth in the U.S. and elsewhere has begun to illustrate, the
itself--by Girma and Wakelin (2001) and Haskel, Pereira, and Slaughter (2001) is
46
Work on the level of geographic localization of technology diffusion has
set of countries, which would allow to forecast what will happen to the world’s
distribution of income. The same is true for the result by Keller (2001a,b) that
technology has become less localized. It is important to find out whether that has
happened only among OECD countries, or also in a broader set of countries: has
We also know very little right now about what are the primary causes that
have led to this lower degree of knowledge localization among OECD countries.
Learning more about these causes is important for thinking about what kind of
narrow or broad the concept of knowledge diffusion is. Patent citations are the
narrowest measure that has been used, which is followed by patents or patent
between foreign R&D and productivity. The least narrow notion of technology
47
related to productivity (e.g., the share of foreign-owned employment in total
patent citation. All other measures might pick up also market-based technology
transactions (such as royalty payments and licensing fees) and, probably more
effects are not externalities, and they might have different welfare implications.
citing another patent, is a strategic decision of the firm. Even if this is not an
issue, as long as a large part of knowledge is tacit, patent statistics will necessarily
more than the pure externality effect, patent statistics might capture less than
technology diffusion is not available, there are good reasons for applying different
50 It is also worth keeping in mind that the number of patent applications differs across countries
because the propensity to patent seems to differ across countries. For example, Eaton and Kortum
(1996) scale down the number of Japanese patents by a factor of 4.9 for this reason, an approach
that is widely used in the literature. The value of 4.9 is based on a 1992 working paper by Okada.
48
Second, a promising development for future empirical work on
(firm or plant) level data sets. At times, there are sometimes exaggerated
that are often present in industry- and aggregate-level analysis. Other issues
foreign ownership and productivity as evidence for FDI spillovers would be just
discussed above indicate, however, micro-level data can help to take a major step
forward. The biggest contribution of micro-level data sets comes in my view from
technology diffusion that reach their full potential involve probably modeling the
Third, the evidence reviewed above indicates that micro-level studies paint
could be because the former avoid certain biases (see above); it might also have to
do with the fact that data on the learning effort of host country firms has typically
not been available. A third reason could be that micro-level studies so far are not
externalities between firms. That is, so far the micro evidence is based on ‘no-
49
externality’ models. Future empirical work will hopefully employ models where
matter of theory. At the same time, the empirical analysis should avoid picking up
spurious effects.
What are the policy implications of this literature? The evidence is not
strong enough yet to provide support for specific policy measures, such as a
would require more agreement on quantitative effects than there is right now. At
this point, the results suggest that the international dimension of technological
country.
technology diffusion has been increasing with the level of economic integration in
The implication for less developed countries would not be that a turn towards
50
operating in an international economic environment differ across countries, this
suggests to investigate further the major reasons for this—what works, and why?
foreign investment regime are conducive to these learning effects. However, the
evidence suggests that the latter are quite difficult to pin down. For one, it does
Rather, the goods characteristics are only part of what is important. India, for
import substitution policy, but their quality was low compared to international
standards. In contrast, South-East Asian countries such as Hong Kong and South
standards through ongoing interaction with foreigners. Local efforts are clearly
necessary for successful technology adoption as well. At the same time, the
knowledge discovery for firms that cannot be had from interacting only with
51
Bibliography
Adams, J. and A. Jaffe (1996), ''Bounding the effects of R&D: An investigation
using matched establishment-firm data'', RAND Journal of Economics 27: 700-
721.
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt (1998), Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge, MA:
MIT Press.
Aghion, P., and P. Howitt (1992), ''A Model of Growth through Creative
Destruction'', Econometrica 60: 323-351.
Aitken, B., and A. Harrison (1999), ''Do domestic firms benefit from foreign
direct investment? Evidence from Venezuela'', American Economic Review 89:
605-618.
Bernstein, J., and P. Mohnen (1998), ''International R&D Spillovers between U.S.
and Japanese R&D Intensive Sectors'', Journal of International Economics 44:
315-38.
Bottazzi, L., and G. Peri (1999), ''Innovation, Demand, and Knowledge Spillovers:
Theory and Evidence from European Regions'', CEPR Working Paper No. 2279,
London, U.K., October.
52
Carr, D., J. Markusen, and K. Maskus (2001), ''Estimating the knowledge-driven
model of the multinational enterprise'', American Economic Review 91: 693-708.
Clerides, S., S. Lach, and J. Tybout (1998), ''Is learning by exporting important?
Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco'', Quarterly
Journal of Economics 113: 903-948.
Coe, D., and A. Hoffmaister (1999), ''Are there international R&D spillovers
among randomly matched trade partners? A response to Keller'', IMF working
paper 99/18, February.
Cohen, W., and D. Levinthal (1989), ''Innovation and learning: The two faces of
R&D'', Economic Journal 99: 569-596.
Easterly, W., and R. Levine (2001), ''It’s not factor accumulation: Stylized facts
and growth models'', paper presented at the conference “What have we learned
from a decade of empirical research on growth?”, February 26, 2001, The World
Bank; forthcoming, World Bank Economic Review.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum (2001a), ''Trade in capital goods'', European Economic
Review 45 (7): 1195-1235.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum (2001b), ''Technology, geography, and trade”, mimeo,
Boston University, May.
53
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum (1999), ''International Patenting and Technology
Diffusion: Theory and Measurement'', International Economic Review 40: 537-
570.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum (1997), ''Engines of growth: Domestic and foreign
sources of innovation'', Japan and the World Economy 9: 235-259.
Eaton, J., and S. Kortum (1996), ''Trade in Ideas: Patenting and Productivity in
the OECD'', Journal of International Economics 40: 251-278.
Feenstra, R., J. Markusen, and W. Zeile (1994), ''Accounting for growth with new
inputs'', International Economic Review 35: 429-447.
Gera, S., W. Gu, and F. Lee (1999), ''Information technology and productivity
growth: An empirical analysis for Canada and the United States'', Canadian
Journal of Economics 32: 384-407.
54
Griffith, R., S. Redding, and J. Van Reenen (2000a), ''Mapping two faces of R&D:
Productivity growth in a panel of OECD industries'', mimeo, London School of
Economics, November.
Griffith, R., S. Redding, and J. Van Reenen (2000b), ''R&D and absorptive
capacity: from theory to data'', mimeo, London School of Economics, November.
Grossman, G., and E. Helpman (1991), Innovation and Growth in the World
Economy, Cambridge, MA.: MIT Press.
Hall, R., and C. Jones (1999), ''Why do some countries produce so much more
output per worker than others? '', Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83-116.
Hanushek, E., and D. Kimko (2000), ''Schooling, labor-force quality, and the
growth of nations'', American Economic Review, December.
Haskel, J., S. Pereira, and M. Slaughter (2001), ''Does inward foreign direct
investment boost the productivity of domestic firms? '', paper presented at the
NBER Summer Institute, August.
55
Jaffe, A., and M. Trajtenberg (1998), ''International Knowledge Flows: Evidence
from Patent Citations'', NBER Working Paper # 6507, April.
Keller, W. (2001d), ''Do the new information and trade links of the 1990s lead to
convergence or divergence? '', paper presented at the NBER Summer Institute,
Cambridge, MA, August.
Keller, W. (2000), ''Do trade patterns and technology flows affect productivity
growth? '', World Bank Economic Review 14: 17-47.
Keller, W. (1997b), ''How trade patterns and technology flows affect productivity
growth'', World Bank Policy Research Working Paper # 1831, September.
Kinoshita, Y. (2000), ''R&D and technology spillover via FDI: Innovation and
absorptive capacity'', mimeo, William Davidson Institute at the University of
Michigan Business School, October.
56
Kraay, A., I. Soloaga, and J. Tybout (2001), ''Product quality, productive
efficiency, and international technology diffusion: Evidence from plant-level
panel data'', paper presented at the NBER Summer Institute, July.
Leamer, E., and J. Levinsohn (1995), ''International trade theory: The evidence'',
in Grossman/Rogoff (eds.), Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3,
Elsevier: Amsterdam.
Nadiri, M.I., and S. Kim (1996), ''International R&D Spillovers, Trade and
Productivity in Major OECD Countries'', NBER Working Paper No. 5801.
Olson, M. (1982), The rise and fall of nations, New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press.
57
Parente, S., and E. Prescott (2000), Barriers to Riches, Cambridge, MA: MIT
Press.
Romer, P. (1992), ''Two strategies for economic development: Using ideas and
producing ideas'', in Summers/Shah (eds.), Proceedings of the World Bank
Annual Conference on Development Economics 1992, pp. 63-91.
Scherer, F. (1984), ''Using Linked Patent and R&D Data to Measure Interindustry
Technology Flows'', in Z. Griliches (ed.), R&D, Patents, and Productivity, The
University of Chicago for NBER, pp. 417-461.
58
Solow, R. (1957), ''Technical change and the aggregate production function'',
Review of Economics and Statistics.
von Hippel, E. (1994), ''’Sticky information’ and the locus of problem solving:
Implications for innovation'' , Management Science 40: 429-439.
Xu, B., and J. Wang (1999) ''Capital Goods Trade and R&D Spillovers in the
OECD'', Canadian Journal of Economics 32: 1258-1274.
59