Handbook of Production Economics Subhash C. Ray (Editor)
Handbook of Production Economics Subhash C. Ray (Editor)
com
https://ebookmeta.com/product/handbook-of-production-
economics-subhash-c-ray-editor/
OR CLICK HERE
DOWLOAD EBOOK
Handbook of
Production
Economics
Handbook of Production Economics
Subhash C. Ray • Robert G. Chambers •
Subal C. Kumbhakar
Editors
Handbook of Production
Economics
123
Editors
Robert G. Chambers
Subhash C. Ray
Department of Agricultural and
Department of Economics
Resource Economics
University of Connecticut
University of Maryland
Storrs, CT, USA
College Park, MD, USA
Subal C. Kumbhakar
Department of Economics
Binghamton University
Binghamton, NY, USA
This Springer imprint is published by the registered company Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.
The registered company address is: 152 Beach Road, #21-01/04 Gateway East, Singapore 189721,
Singapore
Preface
In recent years, the neoclassical theory of production seems to have lost its appeal
among academics and graduate students in microeconomic theory courses. Students
in standard economics doctoral programs only receive the minimal exposure to
production and cost functions necessary for an exposition of the theory of markets
en route to the ultimate goal of game theory, experimental economic issues, and
strategic behavior. For example, only 40 of the 971 pages of the Microeconomic
Theory book by Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green (1995) are devoted to production,
cost minimization, and profit maximization. While a student admittedly has learnt
the basic theory of producer behavior in their “Intermediate Micro Theory” courses,
more advanced concepts like Allen-Uzawa partial elasticities of substitution are
not covered either at undergraduate or at graduate level. An average student
never sees a transcendental logarithmic (Translog) or a Generalized Leontief cost
function in class. Yet, the latter half of the twentieth century was an era of
spectacular development in production theory within economics. The 1951 Cowles
Foundation anthology Activity Analysis of Production and Allocation edited by
Koopmans remains one of the richest collection of essays in economic theory.
Appearing at about the same time, the duality theory of Hotelling, Roy, Hicks,
Samuelson, and Shephard opened up novel ways of analyzing the production
technology through cost, revenue, and profit functions. These topics are rarely
covered in microeconomics courses, although these topics are covered in the two-
volume Production Economics: A Dual Approach to Theory and Applications edited
by Fuss and McFadden (1978). In the meantime, Nerlove used the dual cost function
to empirically estimate the parameters of a Cobb Douglas production function using
data for electric utilities in the USA (1965). Emergence of generalized cost functions
(like the Translog, the Generalized Leontief, and the Generalized CES) liberated
the empirical analyst from the confines of Cobb Douglas, Leontief, or the CES
specifications and enriched both economic theory and econometric analysis in equal
measures. These seem to be history now. By the last decade of the past century,
interest in production theory had clearly waned. Resurgence of identification of
production function in the recent literature mostly focuses on the primal Cobb-
Douglas production function – completely bypassing the duality literature.
Papers included in this three-volume handbook focus on both theoretical con-
cepts and empirical issues from neoclassical production economics. Each of the
chapters is intended to provide a state-of-the-art survey on a specific topic in
v
vi Preface
Volume 1
Part I Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
vii
viii Contents
Volume 2
13 Market Structures in Production Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 537
Devin Garcia, Levent Kutlu, and Robin C. Sickles
14 Production Under Uncertainty . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 575
Robert G. Chambers
15 Dynamic Analysis of Production . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 611
Spiro E. Stefanou
16 Cost, Revenue, and Profit Function Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 641
Levent Kutlu, Shasha Liu, and Robin C. Sickles
17 Scale Elasticity and Returns to Scale . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 681
Victor V. Podinovski and Finn R. Førsund
18 Nonconvexity in Production and Cost Functions: An
Exploratory and Selective Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 721
Walter Briec, Kristiaan Kerstens, and Ignace Van de Woestyne
19 Index Numbers and Productivity Measurement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 755
D. S. Prasada Rao
20 Conceptualization and Measurement of Productivity Growth
and Technical Change: A Nonparametric Approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . 821
Subhash C. Ray
21 Modeling Technical Change: Theory and Practice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 871
Subal C. Kumbhakar
22 Economics of Externalities: An Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 925
Jean-Paul Chavas
23 Shadow Pricing in Production Economics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 951
Rolf Färe, Shawna Grosskopf and Dimitris Margaritis
24 Capacity and Capacity Utilization in Production Economics . . . . . . 1001
Dale Squires and Kathleen Segerson
25 Aggregation of Efficiency and Productivity: From Firm to
Sector and Higher Levels . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1039
Valentin Zelenyuk
Contents ix
Volume 3
Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1787
About the Editors
xi
xii About the Editors
xv
xvi Contributors
Contents
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
An Overview of Neoclassical Production Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
The Primal Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
The Dual Perspective . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
Restricted Profit Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
The Search for a Practical Production Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
The Cobb-Douglas Production Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24
The Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) Production Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
Homothetic and Non-homothetic CES Production Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
Additive Implicit Multiple Input Production Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30
Constant Ratio of Elasticities of Substitution (CRES) Production Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . 32
Indirect Production Function: An Aside . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
Additive Implicit Indirect Production Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
Flexible Functional Forms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41
Appendix 1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
Appendix 2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44
Appendix 3 Elasticity of Substitution Derived from the Dual Cost Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45
Cross-References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47
We thank Chuang Li for his technical assistance in preparing the final version of this manuscript.
R. G. Chambers
Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Maryland,
College Park, MD, USA
e-mail: rchamber@umd.edu
S. C. Ray ()
Department of Economics, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT, USA
e-mail: subhash.ray@uconn.edu
Abstract
To emphasize the nexus between the theory and the empirics of production, this
chapter is split into two parts. The first presents a brief overview of the state of
neoclassical production theory as it exists in the third decade of the twenty-first
century. The second part presents an overview of the history of the development
of functional forms for the production function.
Keywords
Introduction
This handbook is divided into two volumes. The first volume focuses on theoretical
issues of production economics. The second volume focuses on empirical applica-
tions of the theories to applied production analysis. This split, hopefully, clarifies the
presentation. In practice, however, no such clear separation exists. Throughout its
history, production theory has responded to empirical exigency. An early exemplar
is von Thünen’s [25] induction of the principle of diminishing marginal returns from
records for his farming estate. So, too, are the Cobb and Douglas [6] development
of their production function to fit observed trends in US macroeconomic data and
Gorman’s [10] theorem on the aggregation of fixed factors of production.
To emphasize this nexus between production theory and production empirics,
we split this volume’s introductory chapter into two parts. The first presents a brief
overview of the state of neoclassical production theory as it exists in the third decade
of the twenty-first century. The second part presents an overview of the history of
the development of functional forms for the production function
Neoclassical theory gradually emerged from classical economics during the last
quarter of the nineteenth century. And, as illustrated by Marshall’s Principles, the
early twentieth-century discussions of producer behavior were heavily sprinkled
with neoclassical notions such as marginal productivity (returns), marginal cost,
and diminishing marginal returns. Often, these ideas were not wholly original to
neoclassical thinkers. For example, classical writers had recognized the principle
of diminishing returns. But they often attributed it to different causes (e.g.,
deteriorating quality of inputs) than the neoclassical school. What distinguished the
early neoclassical writers was their emphasis on the marginal principle defined in
terms of identical units of inputs and outputs.
As the economic analysis of productions systems developed, it became increas-
ingly evident that identical was to be interpreted in the narrowest possible terms
to mean identical in all aspects (e.g., quality, time, place, state of nature, etc.).
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 5
1 Atroughly the same that Abramovitz [1] wrote, Schultz [21] articulated the idea that an ideal
input-output formula would have measured output growth completely explained by measured input
growth. If that could be achieved, it would suggest that a complete economic explanation of output
growth had been accomplished. Schultz [21], in a footnote, attributed the idea to Zvi Griliches,
who was a graduate student at the time.
6 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
For an arbitrary space, X, its dual space, X∗ , is defined as the space of linear
operators for X. An important property of finite dimensional real spaces, denoted by
RM , is that they are self-dual in the sense that RM∗ = RM and RM∗∗ = RM . Thus,
as purely mathematical objects, an M−dimensional vector of quantities, denoted
z ∈ RM , and an M−dimensional vector of prices, q ∈ RM , are both recognizable
as linear operators. The market value of bundleM∗ z ∈ RM is given by the linear
function of quantities m qm zm for prices q ∈ R . But because the dual space of
RM∗ is RM , the same market value of z ∈ R can
M also be interpreted as the linear
function of prices m zm qm for quantities z ∈ RM∗∗ .
Originally, economists focused their attention on value maximization viewed as
a problem of choosing quantities
to optimize market values of commodity bundles.
That placed the focus on m qm zm viewed as a linear function of quantities. It was
only with the development of the theory of optimization in the decades following
World War II that researchers apprehended and exploited the analytic advantages of
viewing m zm qm as a linear function of prices. The quantity-based approach was
identified with the primal terminology and the price-based approach with the dual
approach.
It is to be emphasized that the analytic difference between the two approaches is
one of perspective and technique. The same substantive results are available from
either approach. However, the dual approach quickly proved particularly popular
because it offered an econometrically advantageous way to model production
systems.
The discussion that follows first considers the primal approach. Then the model
is generalized and analyzed from a dual perspective. A brief demonstration of how
the general model can accommodate both long-run and short-run producer behavior
follows.
Prior to roughly 1970, the approach that economists used to analyze productive sys-
tems closely followed Samuelson’s [18] classic treatment of the profit-maximizing
firm. Competitive profit-maximizing producers were modeled as facing a technolog-
ical constraint treated typically as a smooth transformation or production function,
and programming techniques were used to characterize profit-maximizing solutions
and to make inferences about producer responses to price perturbations.
Let x ∈ RN + , y ∈ R+ , w ∈ R++ , and p ∈ R++ denote, respectively, a vector
M N M
of inputs, a vector of outputs, the input price vector, and the output price vector.
We denote by t (x, y) a function of inputs and outputs that is nondecreasing in y
and nonincreasing in x such that x can produce y if and only if t (x, y) ≤ 0. Posed
formally, the producer’s problem is to choose (x, y) to
max p y − w x : t (x, y) ≤ 0 . (1)
(Here, and in what follows, x y for x, y ∈ RN denotes the usual inner product,
n xn yn .) The Lagrangian associated with this problem is written
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 7
L (x, y, w, p, λ) = p y − w x − λt (x, y)
∇y L = p − λ∇y t (x, y) = 0,
∇x L = −w − λ∇x t (x, y) = 0,
∇λ L = −t (x, y) = 0.
Fig. 1 (a): Input equilibrium (b): Output equilibrium (c): Efficient production
8 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
⎡ ⎤
∇yy t (x, y) ∇yx t (x, y) ∇y t (x, y)
H = − ⎣ ∇xy t (x, y) ∇xx t (x, y) ∇x t (x, y) ⎦
∇y t (x, y) ∇x t (x, y) 0
be negative semi-definite. Then under the assumptions that (a) the first-order
conditions are satisfied, (b) the second-order conditions are satisfied, and (c) the
conditions of the implicit function theorem are met, optimal producer behavior is
differentially characterized by
⎡ ⎤ ⎡ ⎤
dy (p, w) dp
⎣ dx (p, w) ⎦ = −H −1 ⎣ −dw ⎦ , (2)
λ̂ (p, w) 0
where y (p, w) and x (p, w) denote, respectively, optimal (profit-maximizing)
supply and derived demand (for inputs) vectors, λ (p, w) denotes the optimal value
of the Lagrangian multiplier, and λ̂ (p, w) = d ln λ (p, w) .
Using assumptions (a)–(c) and (2) establishes that:
Behavioral Prediction (1) ∂ym∂p(p,w)
m
≥ 0, m = 1, 2, . . . , M;
Behavioral Prediction (2) ∂xn∂w
(p,w)
n
≤ 0, n = 1, 2, . . . , N;
Behavioral Prediction (3) ∂ym∂p
(p,w)
k
= ∂yk (p,w)
∂pm , k, m = 1, 2, . . . , M;
∂xj (p,w)
Behavioral Prediction (4) ∂xn∂w
(p,w)
j
= ∂wn , j, n = 1, 2, . . . , N ; and
∂x (p,w)
Behavioral Prediction (5) ∂ym∂w
(p,w)
j
= − j∂pm , m = 1, 2, . . . , M,
j = 1, 2, . . . , N.
Because the objective function for the profit-maximizing firm is linear in (p, w)
and t (x, y) is independent of (p, w) , any solution to the problem, y (p, w) and
x (p, w) , for (p, w) must also be a solution for (μp, μw) where μ > 0, whence
y (μp, μw) = y (p, w) and x (μp, μw) = x (p, w) . Combined with Behavioral
Predictions (1) − (5), zero-degree homogeneity summarizes the core results for
neoclassical production theory. Producers do not suffer from money illusion, profit-
maximizing supplies slope upward in their own prices, profit-maximizing demands
slope downward in their prices, and in a smooth world differential supply and
demand adjustments possess an essential symmetry. A number of related results,
for example, the Le Chatelier principle relating long- and short-run supply respon-
siveness, follow from suitable modifications of these basic techniques.
Some comments are relevant: First, the setting of the problem and the assumed
motivation behind producer behavior are key to its analysis. Assuming that produc-
ers are price takers and small relative to the market eliminates the possibility for
strategic interactions that would complicate analyses. Second, assuming producers
are profit seekers lets them be modeled “as if” they solve a maximization problem
with a clearly articulated objective function and constraints. Optimal or rational
behavior is then identified with conditions required for profit maximization. And,
more suggestively, producers are said to be “in equilibrium” if their behavior is
consistent with that optimum. As Samuelson [18] explained, the resemblance
to physical systems being “in equilibrium” when entropy is maximized is not
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 9
accidental. Neither is the fact that the tools of analysis, variational techniques
applied to differentiably smooth systems, closely parallel those used in classical
thermodynamics.
Consequently, equilibrium behavior is described primarily in terms of condi-
tions which the physical technology must satisfy in an optimum. Marginal rates
of transformation and marginal rates of substitution, which characterize trade-
offs between inputs and outputs internal to the technology, must be equated
to real market prices. Moreover, maxima (at least local) are distinguished from
inflection points or minima by conditions that the technology must satisfy (see
the second-order conditions). Again the resemblance to classical mechanics and
thermodynamics is not accidental. And once these conditions are assured, producers
can be shown to behave in a manner that accords with the most familiar parables of
microeconomic theory as captured by Behavioral Predictions (1) and (2) and zero-
degree homogeneity.
Third, optimal producer behavior is characterized in infinitesimal terms. To
be sure, directional results are obtained, but they only strictly apply in tiny
neighborhoods of the identified equilibria. Individuals are modeled “as if” they will
perceive and respond (smoothly) to even the tiniest perturbations in market prices.
And to make inferences about how individuals respond to discrete changes, these
differential results must be augmented by a combination of integral analysis and the
correspondence principle.
In this section, we continue to treat producers who are profit maximizers and face
given prices and a technological constraint. But we alter the framing of the problem
and its mathematical analysis.
We now model the producer’s technological constraints as a closed and nonempty
subset of M-dimensional real space, T ⊂ RM , that we shall refer to interchangeably
as the technology set or the technology. We relax the distinction between inputs and
outputs and work instead with net outputs (netputs for short) denoted as z ∈ RM .
Using netputs accommodates the possibility that in differing circumstances the same
commodity can function variously as an input or an output.
The technology set, T ⊂ RM , is defined as
T = z ∈ RM : z is technically feasible .
2 This raises a semantic point. One often reads or hears references to individuals or firms facing
different technologies. For example, a hand-push, reel lawn mower and a self-propelled lawn
mower might be referred to as two different technologies for cutting grass. This is not our
interpretation of T , which we take to encompass all technically feasible activities. In what follows,
we shall discriminate between different productive activities (e.g., growing wheat as opposed to
producing steel) not as different technologies but as different production processes that fall in T .
10 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
one functioning as an output. That role can change. Figure 2 illustrates one possible
T . Netput prices are denoted as q ∈ RM++ .
We now show that the behavioral predictions for producers derived indirectly
from t (x, y) via H and the Lagrangian approach can be deduced directly from the
following postulates:
Postulate (a) Producers face competitive pricing for netputs.
Postulate (b) Producers are profit maximizers.
Postulate (c) Finite solutions exist for
π (q) ≡ max q z : z ∈ T (3)
z
for all q ∈ RM
++ .
In what follows, we refer to π (q) as the profit function. More formally, it is the
support function for T [17, p. 28]. Let
Z (q) = arg max q z : z ∈ T
3A correspondence represents a point to set mapping. Thus, Z (q) ⊂ RM denotes the set of profit-
maximizing solutions associated with the point q ∈ RM . We use the correspondence notation to
remind the reader that profit maximization problems may have multiple, global solutions.
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 11
manifest the familiar adage that “only real prices matter” in making economic
choices.
Because z (q o ) , z (q ∗ ) ∈ T , the definition of π (q) ensures that π (q o ) =
q z (q o ) ≥ q o z (q ∗ ) and π (q ∗ ) = q ∗ z (q ∗ ) ≥ q ∗ z (q o ) . These inequalities,
o
which characterize maxima, are the fundamental source of the behavioral results
that follow. Geometrically, they require for all q ∈ RM++ that z (q) ∈ T and that
T fall in the half-space z ∈ R : q z ≤ q z (q) generated by the hyperplane with
M
normal q that passes through z (q) . Visually, that translates into a hyperplane with
normal q being tangent to T (from above) at z (q) .
Adding the inequalities and rewriting gives4
z qo − z q∗ q o − q ∗ ≥ 0. (4)
zm q o − zm q ∗ o
qm ∗
− qm ≥ 0.
π q o ≥ q o z q ∗
⇓
π qo ≥ π q∗ + z q∗ qo − q∗ , (5)
where the second inequality follows by adding zero in the form of π (q ∗ ) −q ∗ z(q ∗ )
to the right-hand side of the first inequality. In words, expression (5) requires that
any element of Z (q) must belong to the subdifferential correspondence for π (q) ,
which we denote by ∂π (q) ⊂ RM , at q ∗ [13, p. 220].
4 Samuelson [18, pp. 80–1] established an equivalent result in the one-output, multiple-input case.
5 But not the only one. Another stronger notion of monotonicity is that q ≥ q ⇒ z q ≥
z(q). This version implies cyclical monotonicity but is not implied by cyclical monotonicity. One
intuitive way to discriminate between the two notions of monotonicity is that cyclical monotonicity
means that price and quantity movements are positively correlated. The stronger notion requires
that any price increase be matched by all quantities at least weakly increasing.
12 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
∂π (q)
zm (q) = , m = 1, 2, . . . , M
∂qm
Fig. 3 (a): Gradients as unique tangents for smooth function (b): Elements of subdifferential for
nonsmooth function
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 13
true role T , and its representations play in economic analysis. Clearly, producers
must understand the details of T if they are to prove successful. On the other hand,
production economists are not themselves producers. Their job is to develop models
that accurately depict producer behavior. And that requires an understanding of the
characteristics of T that play an essential role in conditioning that behavior but not
of all of its technical details.
Our arguments have shown that, as a mathematical object, π (q) is positively
homogeneous and convex (sublinear) as a function of q ∈ RM ++ . Under weak
continuity restrictions, those properties ensure that π (q) is the support function
for the closed, convex subset T̄ of RM [17, Theorems 13.1 and 13.2], [13, Theorem
C.3.1.1] given by
q̄, q̂ = z ∈ RM : q̄ z ≤ π (q̄) ∩ z ∈ RM : q̂ z ≤ π q̂
and in all other half-spaces z ∈ RM : q z ≤ π (q) generated by the remaining q ∈
RM++ . Because q̄, q̂ , as Fig. 5 illustrates, and these other half-spaces are closed
convex, T̄ must be as well. Moreover, as is visually apparent from Fig. 5, z̃ ≤ z ∈ T̄
Fig. 5 Constructing T̄
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 15
Fig. 6 Non-convex T
16 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
The following theorem presents the basic duality results that establish the
equivalence of approaching the firm’s problem either via π (q) or via T and then
developing π (q).
In many practical settings, working with set-based concepts can prove challeng-
ing. And cardinal functional representations of T then prove attractive. Define
z
γ (z) = inf λ > 0 : ∈T
λ
as the gauge function for T . Figure 8 illustrates γ (z) visually as the maximal radial
expansion of z that is consistent with z/λ remaining technically feasible. If z ∈ T ,
it’s geometrically obvious from Fig. 8 that γ (z) ≤ 1. Conversely, if γ (z) ≤ 1,
then by the definition of γ (z) , z ≤ z/γ (z) ∈ T under free disposability of netput.
Hence, if T is neoclassical, γ (z) is a complete function representation of T in the
sense that
18 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
t (z) ≡ γ (z) − 1.
Adopting this interpretation and applying the indication property, problem (3) can
be reformulated in equivalent mathematical programming terms as
π (q) = max q z : γ (z) ≤ 1
z
q z
≤ π (q) for all q ∈ RM
++ , z ∈ R .
M
γ (z)
Therefore,
q z
≤ γ (z) for all q ∈ RM
++
π (q)
so long as γ (z) and π (q) > 0. (When T exhibits constant returns to scale, T is a
cone, so that both γ (z) and π (q) equal zero.) Thus, if Z (q) = ∅, it must be true
z
that there exists z (q) such that q z (q) = π (q) γ (z) so that the upper bound of πq(q)
in the inequality must be achieved. Hence,
q z
γ (z) = max
q∈RM
++
π (q)
= max q z : π (q) ≤ 1 , (6)
q∈RM
++
where the normalization after the second equality follows from the homogeneity of
degree zero in q of the objective function. Thus,
and
γ (z) = max q z : π (q) ≤ 1 .
q∈RM
++
T ∗ = q ∈ RM
++ : π (q) ≤ 1 .
And, although we do not present a formal demonstration, it also follows that π (q)
has a natural interpretation as the gauge function for T ∗ that is associated with a
neoclassical T .
20 R. G. Chambers and S. C. Ray
As was shown earlier, z ∈ ∂π (q) implies z ∈ Z (q), so that z ∈ Z (q) requires that
q support the graph of γ from below at that z. (In other words, market price ratios
are equated to marginal rates of substitution (transformation).) Going the other way,
Shephard’s lemma shows that if market price ratios are equated to marginal rates of
substitution (transformation), then z ∈ Z (q) . This is a generalization of the familiar
envelope theorem that can be cast more formally as saying that Z (q) and
Q (z) = arg max q z : π (q) ≤ 1 ,
the set of price-dependent netput supplies, are (lower) inverses of one another.
Shephard’s lemma links multiplicity of solutions to the profit-maximizing
problem to the smoothness properties of γ (z) and π (q) . To illustrate, suppose
that ∂π (q ∗ ) is a nonsingleton set so that at q ∗ , π (q ∗ ) possesses a continuum of
supporting hyperplanes. Geometrically, this is manifested by π (q ∗ ) being kinked
as illustrated in Fig. 10. By Shephard’s lemma, that implies that q ∗ must be a
supporting hyperplane to γ (z) for all z ∈ ∂π (q ∗ ) . That can be true only if γ (z) is
linear over that continuum of z. Conversely, if γ (z) is kinked at z∗ , z∗ must provide
a supporting hyperplane to π (q) over a continuum of q. In short, flats in primal
space map into kinks in dual space, and kinks in primal space map into flats in dual
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 21
space, and vice versa. It follows that γ (z) is strictly convex in z if and only if π (q)
is strictly convex in q.
Apart from the slight difference in their domains, RM versus RM ++ , γ (z) and
π (q) , as mathematical objects, are both positively homogeneous and convex (sub-
linear) functions. That they should be derivable from similar calculating formulae
should not be surprising. The recognition, however, that they are essentially natural
inverses of one another for neoclassical technologies is fundamental and reflects the
mathematical principles behind Theorem 1. In fact, the first formal demonstration
of a duality between a dual economic object (a cost function) and a primal
representation of the technology (a distance function) due to Shephard [22] assumed
virtually the same structure as Theorem 2. Ultimately, however, the analytic message
is the same. If there exists a netput supply system, z (q) , which satisfies the usual
neoclassical postulates of homogeneity of degree zero (absence of money illusion),
upward-sloping output supplies, and downward-sloping demand, there must exist a
neoclassical technology that is consistent with it.
We close this section with Fig. 11 that illustrates the triadic relationship between
T , π (q) , and γ (z).
To this point, all M netputs have been treated as freely variable in solving the
profit maximization problem. Thus, π (q) represents a long-run profit function.
Economists, however, are frequently interested in examining short-run behavior that
is characterized by some of netputs being fixed. Two important cases in analyses that
maintain a split between inputs and outputs are offered by the cost function
c (w, y) = min w x : (x, y) ∈ T
x
Fig. 11 A triad of
production relations
R (p, x) = max p y : (x, y) ∈ T .
y
Both the cost and the revenue function are manifestations of the more general
notion of a restricted (short-run) profit function. Restricted profit functions give the
maximal profit available conditional on holding a subvector of z fixed. Partition z
as z = z0 , z1 , where z0 ∈ RN with N < M and z1 ∈ RM−N . We refer to z0 as
variable netputs and z1 as (potentially) fixed netputs. Given this partition
π (q) = max q 0 z0 + q 1 z1 : z0 , z1 ∈ T
z0 ,z1
= max max q 0 z0 : z0 , z1 ∈ T + q 1 z1 ,
z1 z0
where the second equality follows by Bellman’s Principle, which in the current
setting simply means that long-run profit maximization always implies variable
profit maximization. Defining the variable profit function as
π 0 q 0 , z1 ≡ max q 0 z0 : z0 , z1 ∈ T ,
z0
it is easy to identify c (w, y) with the case where z0 = −x and z1 = y and R (p, x)
with z0 = y and z1 = x.
It is immediate from preceding developments that π 0 q 0 , z1 is positively homo-
geneous and convex in q 0 and that variable-profit-maximizing netputs z0 q 0 , z1
satisfy z0 q 0 , z1 ∈ ∂π 0 q 0 , z1 (where the subdifferential is understood to be
in terms of q 0 ). Moreover, a suitably modified version of Theorem 1 implies the
existence of a closed convex T 0 z1 ⊂ RN
1 Neoclassical Production Economics: An Introduction 23
T 0 z1 = z0 ∈ RN : q 0 z0 ≤ π 0 q 0 , z1 for all q 0 ∈ RN
++ .
Making these arguments only requires modifying our previous notation, and so we
do not pursue it here. Straightforward corollaries, therefore, are as follows: c (w, y)
is positively homogeneous and concave in w, the subdifferentials of −c (w, y) in
w represent minus cost-minimizing demands, and those demands are downward
sloping in their own input prices; R (p, x) is positively homogeneous and convex
in p, the subdifferentials of R (p, x) represent revenue-maximizing supplies, and
those supplies are upward sloping in their own prices.
From the functional equation
π (q) = max π 0 q 0 , z1 + q 1 z1 ,
z1
π q̂ ≥ q̂ 0 z0 q̂ 0 , z1 (q̃) + q̂ 1 z1 (q̃)
whence
π q̂ − π (q̃) ≥ π 0 q̂ 0 , z1 (q̃) − π 0 q̃ 0 , z1 (q̃) + q̂ 1 − q̃ 1 z1 (q̃) . (8)
Figure 12 illustrates. Expression (8) confirms that z1 (q) belongs to the subdifferen-
tial of π (q) in the subvector q 1 and that the short-run profit function and π (q) are
tangent to one another when z1 is evaluated at z1 (q) .
Setting q̂ 1 equal to q̃ 1 , so that only variable netput prices change, gives
π q̂ − π (q̃) ≥ π 0 q̂ 0 , z1 (q̃) − π 0 q̃ 0 , z1 (q̃) .
Fig. 12 Le Chatelier
principle
ln Yt −ln Lt
= 14 ; 1899 ≤ t ≤ 1922
ln Kt −ln Lt (9)
⇒ ln Yt = 34 ln Lt + 14 ln Kt
Discovering Diverse Content Through
Random Scribd Documents
von
ANTON BÖTTCHER
Ingenieur
Unter Mitwirkung von Ingenieur G. Frasch
XV u. 500 Seiten. gr. 8o, mit 492
Textabbildungen, 41 Tabellen und 48 Tafeln
2 Bände — Text- und Tafelband — in
Leinwand gebunden Preis M. 25.—.
Der Eisenbau
Ein Handbuch für den
Brückenbauer und den
Eisenkonstrukteur
von
LUIGI VIANELLO
Mit einem Anhang: Zusammenstellung aller
von deutschen Walzwerken hergestellten -
u. -Eisen
Professor D. MAZZOTTO
Deutsch bearbeitet von J.
Baumann
XXIV. 368 S. mit 235 Textabbildungen und
einem Vorwort von R. Ferrini.
(Schwachstromtechnik in Einzeldarstellungen
Bd. II.) Preis M. 7.50.
Die Dampfturbine
Ein Lehr- und Handbuch für
Konstrukteure und Studierende
von
WILH. H. EYERMANN
Ingenieur
Technische
Wörterbücher
in Einzelbänden für jedes
Spezialgebiet der Technischen
Industrie.
Deutsch – Englisch –
Französisch – Russisch –
Italienisch – Spanisch.
Alle 6 Sprachen in einem Bande nach
besonderem System nebeneinander
angeordnet.
2. Elektrotechnik
3. Dampfkessel,
Dampfmaschinen und
Dampfturbinen
4. Explosionsmotoren und
Explosionsturbinen
5. Automobile.
Jeder Band bildet ein in sich
abgeschlossenes Ganzes und ist einzeln
käuflich.
Die Vorzüge der inneren Einrichtung, die diese
»Illustr. Techn. Wörterbücher« gegenüber
bestehenden Methoden auszeichnen, bestehen darin,
daß:
I. Jeder Band des Unternehmens nur ein
Spezialgebiet der Technik umfaßt.
II. jedem Wort (Begriff oder Gegenstand), soweit
möglich, dessen bildliche Übersetzung in Form
der Skizze, der Formel, des Symbols, also in einer
allen Ländern verständlichen Universalsprache
beigegeb. ist.
Deutsch — Englisch —
Französisch — Russisch —
Italienisch — Spanisch
zu gebrauchen, so daß durch die erwähnte
grundsätzliche Abweichung von der bisherigen
lexikalischen Einrichtung
ein Band der Illustrierten Technischen
Wörterbücher 30 zweisprachige Wörterbücher
alten Systems ersetzt.
1.D. The copyright laws of the place where you are located also
govern what you can do with this work. Copyright laws in most
countries are in a constant state of change. If you are outside
the United States, check the laws of your country in addition to
the terms of this agreement before downloading, copying,
displaying, performing, distributing or creating derivative works
based on this work or any other Project Gutenberg™ work. The
Foundation makes no representations concerning the copyright
status of any work in any country other than the United States.
1.E.6. You may convert to and distribute this work in any binary,
compressed, marked up, nonproprietary or proprietary form,
including any word processing or hypertext form. However, if
you provide access to or distribute copies of a Project
Gutenberg™ work in a format other than “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or
other format used in the official version posted on the official
Project Gutenberg™ website (www.gutenberg.org), you must,
at no additional cost, fee or expense to the user, provide a copy,
a means of exporting a copy, or a means of obtaining a copy
upon request, of the work in its original “Plain Vanilla ASCII” or
other form. Any alternate format must include the full Project
Gutenberg™ License as specified in paragraph 1.E.1.
• You pay a royalty fee of 20% of the gross profits you derive
from the use of Project Gutenberg™ works calculated using the
method you already use to calculate your applicable taxes. The
fee is owed to the owner of the Project Gutenberg™ trademark,
but he has agreed to donate royalties under this paragraph to
the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive Foundation. Royalty
payments must be paid within 60 days following each date on
which you prepare (or are legally required to prepare) your
periodic tax returns. Royalty payments should be clearly marked
as such and sent to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation at the address specified in Section 4, “Information
about donations to the Project Gutenberg Literary Archive
Foundation.”
• You comply with all other terms of this agreement for free
distribution of Project Gutenberg™ works.
1.F.
Most people start at our website which has the main PG search
facility: www.gutenberg.org.