CH 6 Cost, Prduction
CH 6 Cost, Prduction
Chapter 6
The theory of the firm I:
Production, costs, revenues
and profit
Higher level topic
This chapter and the next are concerned with the behaviour of firms. Much of firm behaviour depends on the
type of market structure within which the firm operates, which will be studied in Chapter 7. The present chapter
introduces the fundamental concepts necessary to analysing firm behaviour: production, costs, revenues and profit.
6.1 Production in the short run: the • The long run is a time period when all inputs
can be changed. Using the example above, in this
law of diminishing returns time period the firm can build new buildings and
factories and buy more heavy machinery; it can
All firms use inputs (or resources, or factors of change all of its inputs. In the long run the firm has
production) to produce output. The quantities of no fixed inputs; we say all inputs are variable.
inputs needed to produce output is determined by a
technical relationship explaining why firms behave the Note that the short run and the long run do not
way they do. This technical relationship depends on a correspond to any particular length of time. Some
distinction between the short run and the long run. industries may require months to change their fixed
inputs while others may require years.
The short run and the long run
Total product, marginal product and
! Distinguish between the short run and long run in the average product
context of production.
! Define total product, average product and marginal
The difference between the short and long run is the product, and construct diagrams to show their relationship.
following:
• The short run is a time period during which at Understanding and illustrating total,
least one input is fixed and cannot be changed marginal and average product curves
by the firm. For example, if a firm wants to increase In this section, we will study the relationship between
output, it can hire more labour and increase inputs and output in the short run. Since we are
materials, tools and equipment, but it cannot studying the short run, we know the firm has both
quickly change the size of its buildings, factories fixed and variable inputs. For simplicity, let’s consider a
and heavy machinery. As long as these inputs are hypothetical firm that uses only two inputs, land and
fixed, the firm is operating in the short run. labour, where land is the fixed input and labour is the
25
units of output
20
units of output
TP
15
TP
10
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 0
units of variable input (labour) units of variable input (labour)
units of output
increasing decreasing negative
6 marginal marginal marginal
5 product product product
4
units of output
3
2
1 AP AP
0
-1 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 0 MP
-2 units of variable input MP
-3 units of variable input (labour)
(labour)
(b) Marginal and average product curves based on data of Table 6.1 (d) Marginal and average product curves
labour gets bigger and bigger. When 4 workers are the tenth and eleventh workers that we see in
employed, marginal product, equal to five units of part (b).1
output, is maximum.
• Decreasing marginal product. When labour units The relationship between the marginal
are between 4 and 9, the marginal product of labour and average product curves
is decreasing (and positive, or greater than zero), Average product also rises at first and then falls
as we see in part (b). Here, the addition to total (see Figure 6.1(b)). Note the relationship between
product made by successive units of labour becomes the average and marginal product curves: when the
smaller and smaller. marginal product curve lies above the average product
• Negative marginal product. At 8 and 9 units of curve (MP > AP), average product is increasing; and
labour, total product is maximum, as we see in when the marginal product curve lies below the average
part (a), and the ninth unit of labour adds zero product curve (MP < AP), average product is decreasing.
units of output; the marginal product of the ninth This means the marginal product curve always intersects
unit of labour is zero, shown in part (b). Beyond the average product curve when this is at its maximum. The
9 units of labour, total product begins to fall and reason lies in the mathematical relationship between
corresponds to the negative marginal product of the average and marginal values of any variable.
1 The mathematically inclined student will note that the marginal Therefore, with increasing marginal product, MP increases (Figure
product, measuring the change in total product arising from an 6.1(b)) because the slope of the TP curve is increasing (Figure 6.1(a)).
additional unit of labour, is the slope of the total product curve. (The With decreasing marginal product, MP falls because the slope of the TP
slope is here interpreted in the mathematically correct way, referring to curve decreases. When 9 units of labour are employed, the slope of the
the change in the vertical axis divided by the change in the horizontal TP curve is 0 (i.e. the marginal product of the ninth worker is zero) and
axis; see ‘Quantitative techniques’ chapter on the CD-ROM, page 19.) beyond that the MP, or the slope of the TP curve, becomes negative.
Units of labour 1 2 3 4 5
(variable input)
2 Define (a) total product, (b) marginal product, (d) With how many units of the variable input
and (c) average product. do we see the beginning of diminishing
returns (diminishing marginal product)?
3 Why does marginal product reach a point when
Show this in your diagram.
it begins to decrease?
(e) With how many units of the variable
4 What happens to average product when
input do we see the beginning of negative
MP > AP? When MP < AP?
returns? Show this in your diagram.
5 Copy the following table, then fill in the missing
(f) Explain the relationship between the average
figures to show production in the short run.
product and marginal product curves.
Units of Total product Marginal Average 7 Copy the following table, then fill in the missing
variable product product figures to show production in the short run.
input (labour)
0 0 Units of Total product Marginal Average
variable product product
1 10 input (labour)
2 22
0 –
3 35
1 3
4 46
2 5
5 54
6 59 3 4
7 61 4 3
8 60 5 2
6 Using the information in question 5: 6 0
(a) Plot the total product, marginal product 7 –1
and average product curves. 8 –3
Units of Total product Marginal Average ! Distinguish between explicit costs and implicit costs as the
variable product product
two components of economic costs.
input (labour)
Suppose you had a job with a salary of £60 000 a year, Fixed, variable and total costs in the
which you decided to quit to open your own business. short run and long run
You estimate that your entrepreneurial talent you are
putting into your business is worth £45 000 a year. ! Explain the distinction between the short run and
You set up your office in a spare room of your house the long run, with reference to fixed costs and variable
that you used to rent out for £4000 a year. Further, costs.
you borrow £30 000, for which you are paying interest
of £2000 a year, and use the borrowed amount to The distinction between fixed inputs and variable
buy supplies and materials. You also hire an assistant inputs discussed on page 139 in connection with the
whom you pay £18 000 a year. Your explicit, implicit short and long run leads us to a distinction between
and economic costs are: fixed and variable costs:
Implicit costs • Fixed costs arise from the use of fixed inputs.
£60 000 (opportunity cost of your foregone Fixed costs are costs that do not change as output
salary) changes. Examples of fixed costs include rental
+£45 000 (opportunity cost of your payments, property taxes, insurance premiums
entrepreneurial talent) and interest on loans. They do not increase if the
+£ 4 000 (opportunity cost of foregone rental firm produces more output, and do not decrease if
income from your spare room) it produces less. Even if there is zero output, these
£109 000 payments still have to be made in the short run.
Fixed costs arise only in the short run, as in the long
Explicit costs run there are no fixed inputs.
£ 2 000 (interest on your loan) • Variable costs arise from the use of variable inputs.
+£30 000 (purchase of supplies and materials) These are costs that vary (change) as output
+ £18 000 (assistant’s salary) increases or decreases, therefore they are ‘variable’.
£50 000 An example is the wage cost of labour. To produce
more output, the firm hires more labour, and has
Similarly, average total costs are the sum of average Drawing the short-run cost curves
fixed costs plus average variable costs: In this section, we will draw diagrams of a firm’s total,
ATC = AFC + AVC average and marginal costs. Let’s continue with our
example of the data in Table 6.1 (page 140), and assume
Marginal costs that the farm incurs fixed costs of €200 per week (for
Marginal cost (MC) is the extra or additional cost of rent for the land), and that the cost of labour is €100
producing one more unit of output. It tells us by how per worker (per unit of labour) per week. We now have
much total costs increase if there is an increase in all the information we need to calculate the firm’s
output by one unit. It is calculated by considering the short-run production costs, which appear in Table 6.3:
change in total cost (TC) resulting from a change in
output. In addition, it can be calculated by considering • Columns 1 and 2 contain the same data on total
the change in total variable cost (TVC) that results product and corresponding labour input that appear
from a change in output. The reason why the two in Table 6.1.
• Column 3 shows the farm’s total fixed cost (TFC) of ∆TVC = ∆TC. (You can confirm this by comparing
€200; this payment has to be made even when total the figures in column 4 with those in column 5.)
product is zero.
• Column 4 shows the farm’s total variable cost, All the cost information of Table 6.3 is shown
which is the number of workers (from column 2) graphically in Figure 6.2 (a) and (b). (Parts (c) and
times €100 per worker. (d) show cost curves in the general case for a firm
in the short run.) Both parts (a) and (b) measure costs on
• Column 5 calculates total cost, which is the sum of
the vertical axis, and units of output on the horizontal
total fixed cost (column 3) plus total variable cost
axis. Part (a) illustrates the three total cost curves (TFC,
(column 4).
TVC, TC), and part (b) the three average cost curves
• Column 6 shows average fixed cost, obtained by (AFC, AVC, ATC) and the marginal cost (MC) curve.
dividing total fixed cost (column 3) by the number
of units of output (column 1). In part (a):
• Column 7 calculates average variable cost, obtained
by dividing total variable cost (column 4) by the • The TFC curve is parallel to the horizontal axis, as
number of units of output (column 1). it represents a fixed amount of costs that do not
change as output changes.
• Column 8 shows average total cost, obtained by
dividing total cost (column 5) by the number of • The TVC curve shows that TVC increases as output
units of output (column 1): alternatively, average increases. However, it does not increase at a constant
total cost is the sum of AFC plus AVC. rate; this is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns.
• Column 9 shows marginal cost, obtained by • The TC curve is the vertical sum of TFC and TVC,
dividing the change in total cost (from column 5) by and so the vertical difference between TC and TVC
the change in the number of units of output (from is equal to TFC.
column 1); for example, when total cost increases
from €200 to €300, so that ∆TC = 100, TP increases In part (b):
from 0 to 2 units of output, so that ∆Q = 2. Dividing • The AFC curve indicates that AFC falls continuously
100 by 2, we obtain MC = 50. Marginal cost can also as output increases, because it represents the
be calculated as the change in total variable cost amount of fixed costs (TFC) divided by an ever
divided by the change in total product, because growing quantity of output.
1200
TC TC
1000
TVC TVC
800
costs
costs
600
400
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 0 output, Q
output, Q
160
150 MC
140
130
120 MC
110 ATC
100
90 costs
costs
80 AVC
70
60 ATC
50
40 AVC
30
20
10 AFC AFC
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 0 output, Q
output, Q
(b) Average cost and marginal cost curves based on the data (d) Average cost and marginal cost curves
of Table 6.3
• The three remaining curves, AVC, ATC and MC, test scores, which applies equally well here). When
though they are different from each other, all follow marginal cost is below average variable cost (MC <
the same general pattern: at first they fall, they AVC), average variable cost is falling; when marginal
reach a minimum, and then they begin to rise.2 cost is above average variable cost (MC > AVC), then
average variable cost is rising. The same applies to
• The ATC curve is the vertical sum of AFC and AVC,
the relationship between marginal cost and average
and so the vertical difference between the ATC and
total cost: when MC < ATC, ATC is falling, and when
the AVC curves at any level of output is equal to AFC.
MC > ATC, ATC is rising.
• The MC curve intersects both the AVC and ATC curves
at their minimum points. The reason is the same
The U-shapes of the AVC, ATC and MC curves are due
as in the case of marginal and average products,
to the law of diminishing returns. We will discover
discussed on page 141 above (recall the example of
why in the next section.
2The mathematically inclined student may note that marginal cost (MC ) (page 141), the slope is interpreted in the mathematically correct way; see
represents the slope of the total cost (TC ) curve. (Again, as with MP and TP footnote 1.)
MP
0 Shifts in the cost curves (supplementary
units of variable input (labour)
material)
The cost curves shift in response to two factors:
changes in resource prices, or changes in technology.
If resource prices increase, an increase in costs of
MC
costs (AVC, MC)
3 Another which is average variable cost. When the units of labour are few, AVC is
way to see this numerically is to consider the average product
figures in Table 6.1. We know that each unit of labour costs €100, i.e. €100 = high; as the labour units increase AVC falls, and after reaching a minimum,
cost per unit of labour. If we divide 100 by average product, we have: AVC begins to rise, thus resulting in the U-shaped curve.
cost per unit of labour
= variable cost per unit of output,
output per unit of labour
cost
AVC1
AVC AVC
AFC1
AFC AFC
0 0
output output
To calculate costs, it is only necessary to remember 6 In your diagram for question 2(b), explain
and understand the relationships between the various what is represented by (a) the vertical
cost concepts we have studied above: TC = TFC + TVC; distance between ATC and AFC, and
dividing through by Q we obtain average costs, where (b) the vertical distance between ATC
ATC = AFC + AVC. Finally, marginal cost is ∆TC/∆Q, and AVC.
or ∆TVC/∆Q. You will have several opportunities to 7 How does the law of diminishing marginal
calculate costs both in this chapter and the next. product affect the shape of the marginal cost
To calculate costs from a diagram, we simply curve?
read off the information appearing in the
8 Why does marginal cost intersect both average
graph, and apply the same principles as above
variable cost and average total cost at their
to calculate the cost variable or variables we are
minimum points?
interested in.
9 Draw two diagrams showing the relationships
between the AP and MP curves, and the AVC
Test your understanding 6.4 and MC curves. How are the product curves
related to the cost curves? What accounts for
1 For question 5 of Test your understanding 6.1,
this relationship?
suppose that the price of labour is $2000 a
month per worker and fixed costs are $1500 10 (Optional) Using diagrams, show how (a) a
a month. Calculate TFC, TVC, TC, AFC, AVC, fall in insurance premiums, and (b) a fall in
ATC and MC up to the point of maximum wage rates would affect the positions of the
total product (61 units of output). AFC, AVC, ATC and MC curves of a firm.
long run all its inputs, then output should also double;
there should be constant returns to scale. Why
does it happen that output can sometimes increase
Production in the long run: returns to scale more than or less than in proportion to the
increase in inputs? We will discover the answer
! Distinguish between increasing returns to scale, decreasing when we consider costs of production in the long
returns to scale and constant returns to scale. run below. For now, it is important that you do
not confuse decreasing returns to scale, discussed
Let’s examine the long-run relationship between here, with diminishing returns (page 142).
inputs and output. An important point to bear in Diminishing returns occur only in the short
mind is that in the long run, there are no fixed inputs. run, because they show what happens to output as
All inputs are variable. We are interested in seeing a variable input is added to a fixed input. Decreasing
what happens to output when the firm changes all of returns to scale can occur only in the long run,
its inputs. There are three possibilities, explained using showing what happens to output when all inputs are
the example in Table 6.4: variable.
Land (1st input) Labour (2nd input) Output with constant Output with increasing Output with decreasing
returns to scale returns to scale returns to scale
1 acre 5 workers 100 units of output 100 units of output 100 units of output
2 acres 10 workers 200 units of output 250 units of output 150 units of output
4 in the long run. When the long-run curve is downward sloping, there will
While a decision to produce a particular level of output in the long run
involves selection of the firm scale that minimises costs for that level of always be a larger firm size that can achieve lower average costs than the
output, the firm will not necessarily be operating at the lowest possible short-run minimum (i.e. SRATC2 achieves lower average costs than point b
cost on the SRATC curve of its choice. In Figure 4.5(b), say a firm wants to on SRATC1); and when the long-run curve is upward sloping, there will
produce output Q1; it will then choose to be on SRATC1 at point a, which always be a smaller firm size that can achieve lower average costs than
is the point where SRATC1 just touches the long-run curve, corresponding the short-run minimum. There is only one SRATC curve whose minimum
to output level Q1. But the point of minimum average cost on SRATC1 is coincides with the long-run minimum, and that is SRATCm, shown in bold
point b, representing output Q2, not point a. Therefore, minimum average in Figure 6.5(b).
cost in the short run is not necessarily the same as minimum average cost
5It may be noted that economies of scale actually have a broader meaning input proportions are fixed, whereas in economies of scale it is possible to
than increasing returns to scale. The reason is that in returns to scale, have varying input proportions.
economies diseconomies
of scale of scale
constant returns
to scale
LRATC tourism industry
Travelplanet.pl and Invia are two Polish online tourism
companies that are planning to merge. A merger takes
place when two (or more) companies join together and
form a single company. The aim of the merger is to
0 Qmes Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 obtain economies of scale through their co-operative
output, Q interactions. The merger will result in the biggest online
tourism company in Central Eastern Europe.
(b) Few large firms
Source: Adapted from ‘Travelplanet.pl closer to merging with
average total cost
LRATC
Applying your skills
1 Using a diagram, show how a merger of two
0 Q1 Qmes companies can result in economies of scale.
output, Q
2 Explain the possible sources of economies of
scale arising from the merger.
(c) Natural monopoly
average total cost
10
2 Given the following price and quantity data
5 for a product, calculate total revenue, marginal
P = AR = D revenue and average revenue.
0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Q Price ($) 5 5 5 5 5
-5 Quantity (thousand units) 0 1 2 3 4
MR
3 Plot the data for total, marginal and average
Figure 6.8 Total, marginal and average revenue curves when price revenue you calculated in question 2.
varies (the firm has some control over price)
Positive and negative economic profit (c) Negative economic profit (loss)
implicit costs loss
! Explain that economic profit is profit over and above (including (£19 000)
normal profit, and that the firm earns normal profit when payment for
economic profit is zero.8 economic costs = entrepreneurship)
opportunity costs (£109 000) total
! Explain the meaning of loss as negative economic profit revenue
arising when total revenue is less than total cost. explicit costs
(£140 000)
(£50 000)
Economic profit can be positive, zero or negative.
Positive economic profit is also known as supernormal Figure 6.9 Illustrating economic profit (positive and negative) and
profit, or abnormal profit, because it involves profit normal profit
over and above normal profit. If economic profit is zero,
the firm is earning normal profit. And if economic profit Figure 6.9(b) shows a firm making zero economic
is negative, the firm is making a loss. To summarise: profit. The firm’s total revenue has fallen to £159 000,
which is equal to its economic costs; therefore, the
Economic profit can be positive, zero or negative. firm is earning normal profit. The firm in this situation
will not shut down even though it is earning zero
Positive economic profit: TR > economic cost; the economic profit, because it is earning normal profit;
firm earns supernormal profit (or abnormal profit). its revenue is enough to cover all opportunity costs
Zero economic profit: TR = economic cost; the firm (including entrepreneurship).
earns normal profit. In Figure 6.9(c) the firm is earning negative economic
profit (loss). Total revenue has fallen to £140 000, of
Negative economic profit: TR < economic cost; the which £50 000 is used to cover explicit costs, and there
firm makes a loss. are £90 000 left over to go toward covering implicit
costs. However, this is not enough, as implicit costs are
We can see these relationships in Figure 6.9. In £109 000. Therefore, the firm is making an economic loss
Figure 6.9(a) the firm’s total revenue is £180 000. of £19 000, and will shut down (go out of business) as
Implicit costs = £109 000, explicit costs = £50 000, soon as it is able to do so (we will see how in Chapter 7).
and the sum is economic costs of £159 000. Economic Table 6.7 summarises the cost, product, revenue and
profit is therefore £21 000 (= £180 000 − £159 000). profit concepts we have studied.
8
Profit over and above normal profit is positive economic profit, since
negative economic profit refers to loss. See also footnote 7.
Implicit cost The income sacrificed by a firm that uses a resource it owns.
Economic cost The sum of explicit and implicit costs, also equal to the firm’s
total opportunity costs.
Total fixed cost (TFC) Costs that do not change as output changes; arise from the use
of fixed inputs.
Total variable cost (TVC) Costs that vary (change) as output changes; arise from the use of
variable inputs.
Total cost (TC) The sum of fixed and variable costs. TC = TFC + TVC
Average fixed cost (AFC) Fixed cost per unit of output. TFC
AFC =
Q
Average variable cost (AVC) Variable cost per unit of output. TVC
AVC =
Q
Average total cost (ATC) Total cost per unit of output. ATC = AFC + AVC
Marginal cost (MC) The change in cost arising from one additional unit of output. ∆ TC ∆ TVC
MC = =
∆Q ∆Q
Long-run average total cost A curve showing the lowest possible average cost that can be
(LRATC) curve attained for any level of output when all of the firm’s inputs are
variable.
Product concepts
Total product (TP or Q) The total amount of product (output) produced by a firm.
Marginal product (MP) The additional product produced by one additional unit of ∆TP
MP =
variable input. ∆ units of variable input
Revenue concepts
Total revenue The total earnings of a firm from the sale of its output. TR = P × Q
Marginal revenue The additional revenue of a firm arising from the sale of an ∆ TR
MR =
additional unit of output. ∆Q
Profit concepts
Economic profit Total revenue minus economic costs (or total opportunity costs,
or the sum of explicit plus implicit costs).
costs, revenues
costs, revenues
c TR a
a TR
f a
d b
b
0 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q 0 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q 0 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q
Figure 6.10 Profit maximisation using the total revenue and total cost approach when the firm has no control over price
between TR and TC is largest. This occurs at Q 2, where difference between total revenue and total cost is
profit is the vertical distance between points c and d. largest. Part (a) shows the case of a profit-making
(You can see that profit levels a – b and e – f are smaller). firm; profit is maximised at output level Qπmax. At
In part (b), the firm produces at Q2 where TR = TC, points a and b where the TC curve intersects the
indicating zero economic profit (the firm earns normal TR curve, economic profit is zero (the firm would
profit). At all other levels of output, TC > TR. In part (c) be earning normal profit). In part (b) there is no
there is no Q where TR > TC, therefore we look for the level of output where TR > TC; therefore, this firm
Q where the difference between TC and TR is smallest. can only make a loss. Loss is minimum at output
This is at Q2, where the firm makes a loss (negative level Qlmin.
economic profit) of a – b. In the event that you are asked to find the profit-
Figure 6.11 illustrates the case of a firm that does maximising level of output and the amount of
have control over price, showing its total revenue profit (or loss) made by a firm based on data on
curve (as in Figure 6.8(a)), together with a total cost total costs and revenues, you must first calculate the
curve (as in Figure 6.2(c)). The method of finding amount of profit (or loss) that results at each level
the firm’s maximum profit is exactly the same as of output (using the profit = TR – TC principle), and
above. We look for the level of output where the then determine which profit level is largest or which
0 Q max Q 0 Q1min Q
Figure 6.11 Profit maximisation using the total revenue and total cost approach when the firm has control over price
MC
Theory of knowledge
Higher level
• Exam practice: Paper 1, Chapter 6
" HL topics (questions 6.1–6.8)