Ini Blue Carbon Report Paper
Ini Blue Carbon Report Paper
*
Director, Economic Analysis, Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions, Duke University
†
Director, Ocean and Coastal Policy, Nicholas Institute
‡
Associate in Research, Economic Analysis, Nicholas Institute
§
Policy Research Associate, Nicholas Institute
April 2011
NI R 11-04
Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions
Report
NI R 11-04
March 2011
*
Director, Economic Analysis, Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions, Duke University
†
Director, Ocean and Coastal Policy, Nicholas Institute
‡
Associate in Research, Economic Analysis, Nicholas Institute
§
Policy Research Associate, Nicholas Institute
With special contributions by science team advisors Christopher Craft (Indiana University),
Stephen Crooks (ESA PWA), Daniel Donato (University of Wisconsin-Madison), James
Fourqurean (Florida International University), Boone Kauffman (U.S. Forest Service),
Núria Marba (Institut Mediterrani d’Estudis Avançats), Patrick Megonigal (Smithsonian
Environmental Research Center), and Emily Pidgeon (Conservation International)
We are grateful to the Linden Trust for Conservation and to Roger and Victoria Sant for their financial support
of these efforts. We particularly wish to thank Roger Ullman and Vasco Bilbao-Bastida of the Linden Trust
for their substantive insights on these issues as well as participants in a workshop on the biophysical processes
underlying the blue carbon issue held at Duke University on November 10–11, 2010. We appreciate the data
and methodological contributions of Duke faculty members Patrick Halpin, Randall Kramer, and Jeffrey
Vincent. We would like to thank Brent Sohngen of Ohio State University for facilitating access to land value
data from the Global Trade Assessment Project (GTAP). Additional thanks go to Steven Rose of the Electric
Power Research Institute (EPRI) and Rashid Hassan of the University of Pretoria for providing feedback on data
options. David Cooley and Alexis Baldera provided research assistance, Melissa Edeburn copyedited the report,
and Paul Brantley provided editorial support and document formatting. Any mistakes are the authors’ alone.
NICHOLAS INSTITUTE
FOR ENVIR ONMENTAL POLICY SOLUTIONS
Contents
Executive Summary ES-1
1. Introduction 1
14. Conclusions 36
References 38
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Executive Summary
Coastal habitats worldwide are under increasing threat of destruction through human activities such as farming, aqua-
culture, wood harvest, fishing, tourism, marine operations, and real estate development. This loss of habitat carries with
it the loss of critical functions that coastal ecosystems provide: support of marine and terrestrial species, retention of
shorelines, water quality, and scenic beauty, to name a few. These losses are large from an ecological standpoint, but they
are economically significant as well. Because markets do not easily capture the values of ecosystem services, those who
control coastal resources often do not consider these values when choosing whether to clear habitat to produce goods
that can be sold in the marketplace. This market failure leads to excessive habitat destruction. As a result, scientists,
policymakers, and other concerned parties are seeking ways to change economic incentives to correct the problem.
One possibility for changing the economic calculus is to connect coastal ecosystems monetarily to the role they play in
the global carbon cycle and the climate system. In many cases, coastal habitats store substantial amounts of carbon that
can be released as carbon dioxide upon disturbance, thereby becoming a source of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.
Global efforts to reduce GHG emissions, principally emission trading systems or “carbon markets,” create a potentially
large economic incentive to convince the holders of coastal ecosystems to avoid habitat conversion and thus lessen the
likelihood that ecosystems will change from GHG sinks to sources.
A critical question is whether monetary payments for blue carbon—carbon captured and stored by coastal marine and
wetland ecosystems—can alter economic incentives to favor protection of coastal habitats such as mangroves, seagrass
meadows, and salt marshes. This idea is analogous to payments for REDD+ (reduced emissions from deforestation and
degradation), an instrument of global climate policy that aims to curtail forest clearing, especially in the tropics. Like
payments for REDD+, incentives to retain rather than emit blue carbon would preserve biodiversity as well as a variety
of other ecosystem services at local and regional scales.
This report produces a first-order assessment of whether payments for blue carbon protection—money received for
carbon emissions avoided by not converting coastal ecosystems—can provide economic incentives strong enough to
substantially curtail existing rates of habitat loss. This report answers these questions first at a broad level, with a global
view of current conditions, threats, and opportunities. It then focuses on the economic prospects for mangrove pro-
tection, which our initial assessment suggests may have the highest potential from biophysical, economic, and policy-
readiness perspectives.
Soil organic carbon is by far the biggest carbon pool for the focal coastal habitats. In the first meter of sediments alone,
soil organic carbon averages 500 t CO2e/ha (tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent per hectare) for seagrasses, 917 t CO2e/
ha for salt marshes, 1,060 t CO2e/ha for estuarine mangroves, and nearly 1,800 t CO2e/ha for oceanic mangroves.2 In
relative terms, about 95% to 99% of total carbon stocks of salt marshes and seagrasses are stored in the soils beneath
them. In mangrove systems, 50% to 90% of the total carbon stock is in the soil carbon pool. The rest is in living biomass,
such as woody vegetation.
Even though the total land area of mangroves, coastal marshes, and seagrasses is small compared with land in agriculture
or forests, the carbon beneath these habitats is substantial. If released to the atmosphere, the carbon stored in a typical hect-
are of mangroves could contribute as much to GHG emissions as three to five hectares of tropical forest. A hectare of intact
coastal marsh may contain carbon with a climate impact equivalent to 488 cars on U.S. roads each year. Even a hectare of
seagrass meadow, with its small living biomass, may hold as much carbon as one to two hectares of typical temperate forest.
1. 1 tonne (t) = 1 metric ton = 1 megagram (Mg) = 1,000 kg. The abbreviations Mt and Gt refer to the megatonne (1 million tonnes)
and the gigatonne (1 billion tonnes), respectively.
2. These values are global mean estimates for seagrass and salt marsh ecosystems, whereas they are weighted averages for each type
of mangrove across four global regions (tropical Americas, tropical Asia, tropical Africa, and the subtropics).
Nicholas Institute
ES-1
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
For centuries, salt and other tidal marshes have been diked and drained, primarily for agricultural or salt production.
In the process, carbon from the previously inundated soils is directly exposed to oxygen and subsequently emitted as
carbon dioxide into the atmosphere, where it can persist for decades. Although significantly slowed by environmental
laws in developed countries, salt marsh conversion continues unabated in other settings.
The conversion of mangrove forests to agriculture or aquaculture has been widespread. In the case of shrimp farming,
substantial carbon emissions are released through the excavation of mangrove soils to depths of about one meter. As
with drained marshes, the carbon in these mangrove soils oxidizes following disturbance and continues to do so for
decades following habitat conversion. Even when mangroves are exploited for forestry, and not excavated, the death of
living mangrove biomass can lead to soil erosion, subsequent releases of carbon into the water column, and ultimately
releases of carbon into the atmosphere.
Water quality impairment, generally from excess nutrients or sediments from terrestrial sources, is a leading cause of
seagrass habitat destruction. Direct impacts, such as dredging (for example, for harbor creation and channel deepen-
ing), trawling, and anchoring also take their toll on seagrass beds. Seagrass death can lead to the erosion of submerged
carbon-rich soils into the water column, which in turns allows the oxidation and release of carbon dioxide into the
atmosphere.
With regard to carbon stocks at risk, we make a first-order assumption that the first meter of soil is disturbed when
coastal habitats are converted or damaged. On the basis of the rough estimates of global conversion rates and those
of carbon loss, we find that the annual mitigation potential across the three habitat types is roughly between 300 and
900 million t CO2e, approximately equal to the annual CO2 emissions from energy and industry for Poland and for
Germany, respectively. Potential emissions from mangrove habitat loss comprise over half of that total mitigation.
The estimates found in this analysis are far larger than the few published studies that have assessed the climate impact
of the destruction of coastal habitats. These studies have put this impact at 76 million t CO2e per year for mangroves
and salt marshes and at 3.4 million t CO2e/year for mangroves and seagrasses. This research focused only on the very
small sequestration flux that is lost when the ecosystem is destroyed. We estimate, for the first time, the substantially
greater emissions released from the pools of previously sequestered carbon stored in the biomass and soil of seagrass,
salt marsh, and mangrove ecosystems.
According to carbon-loss analyses, the majority of biomass and soil carbon in the top meter of soil is emitted in the
years and decades following conversion of the focal ecosystems. As a marine ecosystem, the carbon release proceeds
most quickly for disturbed seagrass meadows. The time path release of soil carbon is similar for salt marshes and man-
groves. Typically, arboreal systems, mangrove biomass is also considerable, and the bulk of it is emitted immediately
when burned.
The absence of mechanisms to pay landowners, managers, or governments to protect the carbon stored in coastal habi-
tats greatly undermines incentives to protect the habitats. The cost of habitat protection can be high and would include
the costs of creating and managing protected areas and of improving water quality and, in particular, the opportunity
Nicholas Institute
ES-2
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
costs of forgone alternative uses (for example, aquaculture and development). With increasing world population and
per capita consumption and without a mechanism to pay land managers for the carbon value of habitat protection, the
pace of habitat destruction is likely to continue.
Economic incentive mechanisms for GHG emission reductions could help remedy this situation. One such mechanism,
emissions trading and the creation of “carbon” markets, has been operating throughout the world since the adoption of
the Kyoto Protocol by the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, but the role for terrestrial (for
example, forest) carbon reductions is very limited and that for carbon in coastal habitats is nonexistent. Recent efforts
appear to be creating a global market opportunity for reduced emissions from deforestation and degradation (called
“REDD+” in the global climate policy discussions). Although mangrove protection could conceivably be included in
REDD+, it is unclear whether REDD+ or other proposed protocols would include carbon in coastal habitats, especially
in soils, an omission that could result in failure to protect some of the largest and most vulnerable carbon stocks on
Earth.
The costs of avoiding habitat conversion need to be considered to fully evaluate the economic potential of blue carbon
payments to protect habitat. They may include the costs of establishing and managing a protected area, whether it be
terrestrial or marine, as well as the opportunity costs of protection, which represent the most profitable alternative
(converted) use of a hectare of habitat and which are generally the largest component of protection costs. These costs
of protection vary greatly across countries and regions. On average, costs are highest for protection of salt marshes,
because they tend to be found in temperate, developed countries. The study finds illustrative cases of when carbon
revenue potential would appear to outweigh protection costs.
Investors in blue carbon emission reductions will likely focus their efforts on countries that appear to have the least
expensive reductions, though countries with large-scale mitigation potential may have lower transaction costs. Of the
top 25 countries in terms of mitigation potential, Senegal is found to have the cheapest reductions (break-even cost of
less than $2 per tonne) and Columbia, the most expensive (greater than $11 per tonne). Five of the top seven countries
with the lowest break-even prices are in tropical Africa. In addition to having the highest gross returns for blue carbon,
Africa enjoys the lowest costs of protection worldwide. At $15/t CO2e, every tropical African country with mangroves,
except one, demonstrates net returns of over $10,000 per hectare.
With respect to mitigation potential, tropical Asia is clearly the most prominent region for mangrove protection. Four
of the top five countries with the highest biophysical mitigation potential—Indonesia, Malaysia, Papua New Guinea,
and Vietnam—are in southeast Asia, and together they constitute about half of global potential. That potential is driven
mainly by Indonesia, whose annual mitigation potential is about one-third the worldwide total. The average break-even
Nicholas Institute
ES-3
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
price for Indonesia is about $4 per tonne of emissions avoided, which is eighth lowest of all country-specific estimates.
We combine the break-even prices and mitigation quantities to construct an emission reduction supply curve for
avoided mangrove destruction (Figure ES-1), which roughly captures the quantity of mitigation that countries could
provide if they were compensated at levels sufficient to cover their habitat protection costs. Assuming mean cost lev-
els, we see that at a carbon price of $4/t CO2e, about 40 million tonnes of mitigation might be supplied. At $6/t CO2e,
another 20 million tonnes might be achieved, pushing the total to 60 million tonnes. At $8/t CO2e, the total supplied
could approach 80 million tonnes. Under the high-cost scenario, only 10 million tonnes and 45 million tonnes t CO2e
are supplied at carbon prices of $4 and $8, respectively. However, under the low-cost scenario, a carbon price of merely
$2/t CO2e is necessary to secure 80 million tonnes of mitigation.
In many ways, payments for blue carbon are simply a means to reward habitat protection, particularly for fragile and
threatened coastal ecosystems such as mangroves. At $4–$8/t CO2e, the mean case would supply 400,000 to 800,000
hectares of protected mangrove habitat per year, whereas the high-cost case would yield 100,000 to 450,000 hectares.
Overall, if blue carbon offsets were to gain value, a carbon price of $15/t CO2e might not be unreasonable and would be
sufficient to protect all mangrove habitat considered here, even assuming high protection costs. However, implementing
protection activities involves transaction costs (measurement, monitoring, accounting, and distribution) that, although
not monetized in this study, must eventually be factored in.
Figure ES-1. Mitigation-potential supply functions for low-cost, mean, and high-cost scenarios.
$25
Low Cost
$20
Mean
Breakeven
C
price
($/tCO2e)
High cost
$15
$10
$5
$0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Annual
Mi@ga@on
Poten@al
(millions
tCO2e)
Nicholas Institute
ES-4
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
1. Introduction
Coastal habitats worldwide are under increasing threat of destruction through human activities such as farming, aqua-
culture, wood harvest, fishing, tourism, marine operations, and real estate development. This loss of habitat carries
with it the loss of critical functions that coastal ecosystems provide: support of marine and terrestrial species, retention
of shorelines, water quality, and scenic beauty, to name a few. These losses are large from an ecological standpoint, but
they are economically significant as well (Barbier 2007). Because markets do not easily capture the values of ecosystem
services, those who control coastal resources often do not consider these values when choosing whether to clear habitat
to produce goods that can be sold in the marketplace. This market failure leads to excessive habitat destruction. As a
result, scientists, policymakers, and other concerned parties are seeking ways to change economic incentives to correct
the problem.
One possibility for changing the economic calculus is to connect coastal ecosystems monetarily to the role they play in
the global carbon cycle and the climate system. In many cases, coastal habitats store substantial amounts of carbon that
can be released as carbon dioxide upon disturbance, thereby becoming a source of greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.3
Global efforts to reduce GHG emissions, principally emission trading systems or “carbon markets,” create a potentially
large economic incentive to convince the holders of coastal ecosystems to avoid habitat conversion and thus lessen the
likelihood that ecosystems will change from GHG sinks to sources.
A critical question is whether monetary payments for blue carbon—carbon captured and stored by coastal marine and
wetland ecosystems—can alter economic incentives to favor protection of coastal habitats such as mangroves, seagrass
meadows, and salt marshes. This idea is analogous to payments for REDD+ (reduced emissions from deforestation and
degradation), an instrument of global climate policy that aims to curtail forest clearing, especially in the tropics. Like
payments for REDD+, incentives to retain rather than emit blue carbon would preserve biodiversity as well as a variety
of other ecosystem services at local and regional scales. Success will hinge on structuring the incentives to avoid negative
impacts on the well-being of local populations who depend on these resources for their livelihoods.
This report produces a first-order assessment of whether payments for blue carbon protection—money received for
carbon emissions avoided by not converting coastal ecosystems—can provide economic incentives strong enough to
substantially curtail existing rates of habitat loss. We pursue this task by asking and answering several questions:
This report answers these questions first at a broad level, with a global view of current conditions, threats, and oppor-
tunities. It then focuses on the economic prospects for mangrove protection, which our initial assessment suggests may
have the highest potential from biophysical, economic, and policy-readiness perspectives.
3. The focus here is on carbon dioxide because methane, a more potent GHG with 25 times the global warming potential of carbon
dioxide, is emitted in relatively small quantities in these saline habitats due to the presence of sulfates. Moving down the salinity
gradient from saltwater to freshwater, methane emissions gradually increase and can be substantial in freshwater wetland systems.
Nicholas Institute
1
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Source: Seagrasses (version 2.0) of the global polygon and point dataset compiled by UNEP World Conservation Monitoring Centre (UNEP-WCMC), 2005. For
further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
Source: Saltmarsh (version 1.0) of the provisional global point dataset developed jointly by UNEP-WCMC and TNC. This dataset is incomplete.
Nicholas Institute
2
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Source: Mangroves (version 3.0) of the global polygon dataset compiled by UNEP World Conservation Monitoring Centre (UNEP-WCMC) in collaboration with the
International Society for Mangrove Ecosystems (ISME), 1997. For further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org. Mangroves of Western Central Africa
raster dataset processed from Landsat imagery, circa 2000. Compiled by UNEP World Conservation Monitoring Centre (UNEP-WCMC), 2006. For further informa-
tion, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org. East African mangroves extracted from version 4.0 of the polygon dataset compiled by UNEP World Conservation
Monitoring Centre (UNEP-WCMC), 2006. For further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
4. Due to the limitations of geospatial data sets, our estimates of mangrove areas include brackish estuarine environments, but our
estimates of salt marsh area do not. Mangroves have a different classification system than that for marshes, so that not all estuarine
mangroves are in brackish environments.
Nicholas Institute
3
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
To date, the best geospatial data are for mangroves. Whereas country-level estimates are unavailable for seagrasses and
salt marshes, a 2007 report from the FAO provides area estimates for all mangrove countries in the world from 1980 to
2005. The report’s estimates of total global mangrove area are 18.8 Mha, 16.9 Mha, 15.74 Mha, and 15.2 Mha for 1980,
1990, 2000, and 2005, respectively. These estimates equate to annual mangrove loss rates of 0.99%, 0.70%, and 0.65%
for the 1980–1990, 1990–2000, and 2000–2005 periods, respectively. In comparison, a study using satellite data has
estimated that the total extent of mangroves was only 13.8 Mha in 2000 (Giri et al. 2011). Wide discrepancies between
some of this study’s data and the FAO data on mangrove coverage in the 12 countries that constitute about 70% of
world’s mangrove extent (Figure 4) indicate that additional mangrove mapping is needed. Nevertheless, all datasets
indicate substantial declines in mangrove habitats worldwide.
Figure 4. Mangrove area and loss rates for the 12 countries with the most mangrove area.
4.5
4.0
1980
FAO
1990
FAO
3.5
2000
FAO
2005
FAO
Mangroves
(Mha)
il
a
a
e
sia
lia
ico
ria
sia
ba
sh
ar
az
ne
di
qu
nm
de
ra
Cu
ge
ne
ay
ex
In
Br
ui
bi
st
la
Ni
al
M
do
ya
G
am
Au
ng
M
ew
M
In
oz
Ba
a
N
M
pu
Pa
Using the mangrove data from FAO, we calculated average annual loss rates for the 1990–2005 period for all the man-
grove countries of the world. The results are mapped in Figure 5. Of the 104 mangrove countries, 15 experienced habitat
loss at a rate above 2% per year. These countries included Honduras, the Dominican Republic, and several countries in
central and west Africa. Twenty-three countries, including mangrove-rich Indonesia, Papua New Guinea, Vietnam, and
Mexico, fell into the 1% to 2% loss-rate category. Overall, the highest number of countries showed rates between 0% and
1%. During the period, mangrove area actually increased in a few countries, most importantly Cuba and Bangladesh,
the ninth and eleventh most mangrove-rich countries, according to Figure 4.
The main anthropogenic drivers of mangrove conversion are fairly well known, namely agriculture, aquaculture, wood
harvests, and urban and tourism development (FAO 2007; Spaulding et al. 2010). What is not as well understood is the
proportion of mangrove losses that can be attributed to each of those drivers in different parts of the world. Using data
sources from the 1980s and 1990s, one study determined that global mangrove area losses are due principally to shrimp
culture (38%), wood harvests (26%), fish culture (14%), diversion of freshwater (11%), land reclamation (5%), herbi-
cides (3%), and agriculture (1%) (Valiela et al. 2001). Analyzing satellite data for the 1975–2005 period for countries and
portions of countries in the Indian Ocean region affected by the 2004 tsunami, other researchers came to starkly differ-
ent conclusions (see Figure 6) (Giri et al. 2008). In their study region, on average, 82% of mangrove deforestation was
found to be caused by agriculture; 12% was due to aquaculture, and 2%, to urban development. Although agricultural
expansion was the key driver, causes of mangrove loss varied considerably by country. For instance, 63% and 41% of
habitat loss in Indonesia and Thailand, respectively, were attributed to aquaculture, whereas 20% of mangrove defores-
tation in Malaysia was related to urban development. This study does not elucidate whether key drivers have changed
over time, so whether aquaculture has become more important than agriculture in recent years is unclear. Moreover,
loss drivers in regions of the world outside the study area may have different relative contributions. Overall, drivers often
vary geographically and temporally, and more research is needed to discern their relative impacts.
Nicholas Institute
4
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 6. Percentage of mangrove loss attributed to drivers for countries and portions of countries in the 2004 tsunami-
affected region, 1975–2005.
Average
Sri
Lanka
India
Bangladesh
Burma
Indonesia
Malaysia
Thailand
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
.
Source: Giri et al. 2008.
5. These systems store carbon, which if disturbed is returned to the atmosphere in the form of carbon dioxide (CO2). We use CO2
equivalent as units of measure here because of the emphasis on carbon in the climate system and the fact that the potential payment
schemes discussed in the report are based on CO2 equivalent units.
6. In the case of mangroves, carbon burial rates seem to be keeping pace with sea level rise, but if this rise were to outstrip the eleva-
tion of the sediment surface, the seaward and landward margins of the mangrove forest would retreat landward because the mangrove
Nicholas Institute
5
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Mangrove ecosystems are classified on the basis of geomorphological differences as oceanic—fringing, or occurring
along the sea—or as estuarine—deltaic, or growing where river deltas meet saltwater bodies. Two other classes of man-
grove—basin and dwarf—are not very abundant and therefore are not included in this analysis.
For marshes, we present estimates for salt marshes only because of limitations in geospatial data for brackish marshes,
which occur in mixed freshwater-saltwater environments and which also are likely to be important stores of blue carbon.
Given this study’s focus on marine and coastal systems, freshwater marshes are likewise not included in the analysis.
Seagrass meadows are ecological communities whose species compositions vary within and across regions. They are
reported here as one system type across their range because knowledge about the carbon pools for various seagrass
assemblages is insufficient to differentiate them.
Annual carbon sequestration rates vary little across the three coastal habitats but vary greatly within each habitat type.
Both marshes and mangroves average between 6 tonnes and 8 tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) per hect-
are per year, whereas seagrasses tend to sequester carbon at a somewhat lower rate of approximately 4 t CO2e/ha/yr.
These rates are about two to four times greater than global rates observed in mature tropical forests (1.8–2.7 t CO2e/
ha/yr) (Lewis et al. 2009). The amount of carbon held in living biomass is much more variable among the habitat types;
seagrasses contain 0.4–18.3 t CO2e per hectare, and salt marshes, on average, a few times higher than that at 12–60 t
CO2e/ha. Mangrove forests, which can grow up to 40 meters tall (Spaulding 2010), clearly lead in this area and maintain
237–563 t CO2e per hectare in living biomass.
Table 2. Global averages and standard deviations of carbon sequestration rates and global ranges for the main carbon
pools, by habitat type. Only the top meter of soil is included in the soil carbon estimates.
Habitat type Annual carbon Living biomass Soil organic carbon
sequestration rate (t CO2e/ha) (t CO2e/ha)
(t CO2e/ha/yr)
Seagrass 4.4 ± 0.95a 0.4–18.3b 66–1,467c
Salt marsh 8.0 ± 8.5d 12–60e 330–1,980f
Estuarine mangroves 6.3 ± 4.8g 237–563h 1,060h
Oceanic mangroves 6.3 ± 4.8g 237–563h 1,690–2,020h
Sources: (a) Duarte et al., in press; (b) Duarte and Chiscano 1999; N. Marba and J.W. Fourqurean, pers. comm.; (c) Duarte and Chiscano 1999; N. Marba and J.W.
Fourqurean, pers. comm.; (d) Morgan and Short 2002; PWA and SAIC 2009; Yu and Chmura 2009; Brevik and Homburg 2004; Bridgham et al. 2006; Chmura et al.
2003; Choi and Wang 2001; Choi and Wang 2004; Connor et al. 2001; Craft and Richardson 1998; Duarte et al. 2005; Giani et al. 1996; Hussein et al. 2004; Johnson
et al. 2007; Mudd et al. 2009; Nellemann et al. 2009; PWA and SAIC 2009; (e) Morgan and Short 2002; Bridgham et al. 2006; Yu and Chmura 2009; (f ) Bridgham et
al. 2006; PWA and SAIC 2009; adapted from Chmura et al. 2003; (g) Bouillion et al. 2009; Bridgham et al. 2006; Chmura et al. 2003; Duarte et al. 2005; Fujimoto et
al. 1999; Jennerjahn and Ittekkot 2002; Nellemann et al. 2009; PWA and SAIC 2009; Twilley et al. 1992; (h) D.C. Donato and J.B. Kauffman, pers. comm.
Soil organic carbon is by far the biggest carbon pool for all the focal coastal habitats. In the first meter of sediments
alone, soil organic carbon averages 500 t CO2e/ha for seagrasses, 917 t CO2e/ha for salt marshes, 1060 t CO2e/ha for
estuarine mangroves, and nearly 1800 t CO2e/ha for oceanic mangroves. In relative terms, about 95% to 99% of total
carbon stocks of salt marshes and seagrasses are stored in the soils beneath them, while in mangrove systems, 50% to
90% of the total carbon stock is in the soil carbon pool; the rest is in living biomass. These numbers represent the carbon
storage for only the first meter of soil depth in order to facilitate consistent comparisons among habitat types and in
recognition of the fact that the top meter of carbon is most at risk after conversion. There can be great variability in the
depth of the organic rich sediments underlying these habitats (some reach depths of several meters), yet most have at
least a meter. Salt marshes can harbor up to six meters of carbon-rich deposits (Chmura 2009); the common soil depths
for estuarine and oceanic mangroves are three meters or more and one to two meters, respectively. Seagrass meadows
sit on top of about one meter of organic soil, on average.
Even though the total land area of mangroves, coastal marshes, and seagrasses is small compared with land in agricul-
ture or forests, the carbon beneath these habitats is substantial. If released to the atmosphere, the carbon stored in a
typical hectare of mangroves could contribute as much to GHG emissions as three to five hectares of tropical forest with
non-peat soils, which are common in the Amazon and upland areas of other tropical regions (IPCC 2007; Malhi 2009).
Tropical forests with peat soils, like those found in coastal lowlands in Indonesia and Malaysia, may range from 2,000–
4,500 t CO2 per hectare (with about 60% to 80% of the total stock contained in the soil)7 and may be roughly equal to
species need to maintain their preferred hydroperiod (Alongi 2008; Gilman et al. 2008).
7. Only includes top meter of soil for consistent comparison (Murdiyarso et al. 2010).
Nicholas Institute
6
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
mangroves in terms of emission potential per hectare. A hectare of intact coastal marsh may contain carbon with a
climate impact equivalent to 488 cars on U.S. roads each year (U.S. EPA 2005). Even a hectare of seagrass meadow, with
its small living biomass, may hold as much carbon as one to two hectares of typical temperate forest (Smith et al. 2006).
Figure 7. Global averages for carbon pools (soil organic carbon and living biomass) of focal coastal habitats. Tropical
forests are included for comparison. Only the top meter of soil is included in the soil carbon estimates.
Seagrasses
Salt Marsh
Estuarine Mangroves
Oceanic Mangroves
The carbon pool estimates for estuarine and oceanic mangroves presented above are global averages from four regions—
tropical Americas, tropical Africa, tropical Asia, and the subtropics—and are weighted by areal extent. On average,
biomass carbon is greatest in tropical Asian mangroves (563 t CO2e/ha) and lowest in subtropical stands (237 t CO2e/
ha). Data on estuarine mangroves is limited and thus there is no estimated variation in soil organic carbon across the
four regions. In the top meter of soil, oceanic mangroves in tropical Africa and the subtropics have, on average, about
20% more carbon than those in the tropical Americas and tropical Asia.
As noted above, the coastal ecosystems store substantial amounts of carbon, primarily in their soils. But simply sum-
ming up all the carbon stored in these systems would overestimate the stock of carbon at risk of release. To estimate
just that portion of the stock, we must determine what portion of the habitats is at risk for conversion and, if converted,
what portion of the carbon stock in the converted area is at risk of release. This calculation provides an estimate of the
biophysical mitigation potential, which is the tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalents whose release could be avoided
through interventions such as payments for blue carbon.
With regard to carbon stocks at risk, we make a first-order default assumption that the first meter of soil is disturbed
when coastal habitats are converted or damaged. Although salt marshes and mangroves often have more than one meter
of organic soil beneath them and may be affected when the habitat is converted to another land use, we assume that all
carbon stored below one meter remains unreleased. Our one-meter assumption may seem conservative. But other forms
of conversion—for example, agriculture that does not require deep cultivation and development (roads, buildings) that
encases below-ground carbon with impermeable or semi-permeable surfaces—may put less than one meter’s worth
of carbon at risk of release. Thus, the estimate of the depth of the carbon at risk, which is activity- and site-specific, is
highly uncertain. Local assessment should use more specific data to refine our assumption.
Regardless of the exact depth of carbon at risk, habitat conversion releases to the atmosphere previously stored carbon
as carbon dioxide, from both biomass and soil, and, because the living matter is no longer active, abruptly stops annual
carbon sequestration. If planted with annual crops, the soil could continue to accumulate carbon, albeit at a much
slower rate. If planted with perennial crops, both soil carbon and aboveground carbon could continue to accumulate.
Nicholas Institute
7
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
In Table 3, the total carbon at risk is the average amount of soil carbon held in the top meter plus the biomass. It ranges
from 949 t CO2e for salt marshes to 1762 t CO2e for mangroves. Note that, for mangroves, we use a weighted average of
carbon stocks for oceanic and estuarine mangroves (estuarine mangroves cover more land area) across the four man-
grove regions. To be conservative, we use the low end of the habitat extent for seagrasses and mangroves. By multiplying
the current habitat extent, we arrive at the total carbon stock at risk, which adds up to nearly 45 billion tonnes of CO2e
across all three systems of interest. For context, this total amount of carbon at risk in these habitats is approximately one
and a half times the annual global emissions of carbon dioxide from all industrial emissions.8 Annual estimated blue
carbon losses, of course, are much smaller, as shown in Table 3.
Table 3. Estimates of total carbon at risk (both biomass carbon and soil organic carbon) in top meter of sediments
beneath coastal habitats. Mha = million of hectares; Gt CO2e = gigatonnes (billions of tonnes) of carbon dioxide equivalents.
Habitats Soil organic Total carbon Current Total carbon LOWER annual C loss HIGHER annual C loss
carbon per unit per unit area habitat stock at risk (biophysical mitigation (biophysical mitigation
area (t CO2e/ha) (t CO2e/ha) extent (Mha) (Gt CO2e) potential) @ 0.7% rate (Gt CO2e) potential) @ 2% rate(Gt
CO2e)
Seagrass 500 511 30 15.3 0.11 0.31
Salt marsh 917 949 5.1 4.8 0.03 0.10
Mangroves 1,298 1,762 13.8 24.3 0.17 0.49
Total 48.9 44.5 0.31 0.89
To account for the fraction of habitat currently at risk for conversion, we draw from the loss rates in the previously
noted literature (see Table 1). These rates are expressed on an annual basis as it is most intuitive to focus on risk of con-
version in one year. Moreover, this basis aligns with how carbon crediting would work—getting credit for a mitigating
action taken at a given point in time and properly accounting for the time profile of emissions to follow (see below).
We calculate lower- and upper-end annual mitigation potential by multiplying total habitat mitigation by the loss rates
of 0.7% and 2% per year, respectively. The resulting values are estimates of lifetime carbon losses for each hectare of
converted habitat in a year.9 Thus, annual mitigation potential across the three habitat types is found to lie roughly
between 300 million t CO2e and 900 million t CO2e, approximately equal to the annual CO2 emissions due to human
activity (except for land use change) for Poland and for Germany, respectively.10 Potential emissions from mangrove
loss comprise about 55% of the total.
Our mitigation potential estimates are far larger than the few published estimates of the climate impact of coastal habitat
destruction. Previous studies have put this impact at 76 million t CO2e per year for mangroves and salt marshes and
at 3.4 million t CO2e/year for mangroves and seagrasses (Bridgham et al. 2006; Pidgeon 2009). These studies focused
only on the small sequestration flux that is lost when the ecosystem is destroyed, whereas we estimate the substantially
greater emissions released from the pools of previously sequestered carbon stored in the biomass and soil of seagrass,
salt marsh, and mangrove ecosystems.
The current state-of-the-science estimate for global anthropogenic CO2 emissions (including land use change) is about
34 billion t CO2 for 2009 (Friedlingstein et al. 2010). The annual mitigation potential for the focal coastal habitats, at cur-
rent conversion rates, is approximately 0.9% to 2.6% of that global figure. Our annual estimates for blue carbon losses are
8% to 22% of the estimated average of land-use change emissions for the 2000–2009 period (4.0 ± 2.6 billion t CO2e/yr).
Limitations of geospatial data for coastal habitats dictate what we can say about mitigation potential for the focal
coastal habitats. Salt marsh habitat is not well mapped, and precise global and regional area estimates do not yet exist.
Estimates for the six global regions that seagrasses inhabit can be bracketed by the parameters in Gattuso et al. (2006)
and the lower and upper bounds on total global seagrass area (30 Mha and 60 Mha, respectively). In Figure 8, we see that
tropical Asia contains the greatest share (about 41%) of the biophysical mitigation potential, followed by the temperate
northern hemisphere (nearly 23%).
8. For 2009, CO2 emissions associated with fossil fuel use and cement production were 30.8 billion t CO2e (Friedlingstein et al. 2010).
9. If conversion rates are in some sort of steady state, “annual” estimates not only capture future lifetime losses for what is converted
this year, but also roughly capture what is actually going into the atmosphere from all conversions, past and present.
10. These emissions are for 2007 (Boden et al. 2010).
Nicholas Institute
8
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 8. Biophysical mitigation potential (carbon stock at risk of release at a conversion rate of 0.7%) of seagrass eco-
systems. Two estimates, derived from lower- and upper-bound estimates of total global seagrass area (30 Mha and 60 Mha,
respectively) are shown for each region.
250
Mi:gaiton
Poten:al
(million
tCO2e)
100
50
-‐
s
n
sia
al
re
re
ica
ric
ea
ob
he
he
l A
an
er
Gl
l
A
isp
isp
ica
m
rr
ica
m
l A
ite
op
e
op
ica
ed
H
H
Tr
Tr
N.
S.
M
op
te
te
Tr
ra
ra
pe
pe
m
m
Te
Te
Source: Authors.
In contrast with the salt marsh and seagrass habitat areas, mangrove habitat area has been quantified by the UN Food
and Agriculture Organization (FAO) at the country scale, allowing us to explore mitigation potential and other ques-
tions relevant to this analysis at that level of resolution. A further adjustment is made to account for different drivers of
mangrove habitat loss. As reported in Figure 6, over 90% of mangrove destruction is attributable to either agriculture
or aquaculture (Giri et al. 2008). In a similar vein, another analysis (Valiela et al. 2001) indicates that approximately
90% of habitat loss is due to aquaculture, wood harvests, or agriculture-related factors. Although urban development
and other activities also contribute to habitat conversion, we focus on lands at risk for conversion to agriculture or
aquaculture and lands overexploited for wood. Real estate development and other urban uses may imply very high land
values that could make habitat protection uneconomical relative to other lands (see Section 10). Therefore, we reduce
the mitigation potential of all mangrove countries by 10% to reflect the assumption that agriculture, aquaculture, or
forestry cause about 90% of mangrove loss. In Figure 9, the blue bars represent the total mitigation potential, and the
green bars indicate estimates that have been scaled back by 10%. Because of the country-level FAO mangrove data, we
are able to calculate annual loss rates for each country. We used the 1990–2005 period, which we consider the most
pertinent to the potential loss rate in the future. To our knowledge, no dataset details mangrove area for all mangrove
countries after the year 2005. As Figure 9 shows, Indonesia alone accounts for about one-third of the global mitigation
potential of 160 million t CO2e per year. Mexico accounts for more than 10% of that potential, and Papua New Guinea,
a little less than 10%.
Nicholas Institute
9
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 9. Biophysical mitigation potential for mangrove protection by key countries. These top 12 countries for man-
grove mitigation potential are sorted according to current total stocks of stored carbon and current conversion rates. Total
mitigation potential is scaled back to the potential for lands at risk for conversion to agriculture or aquaculture or to overex-
ploitation of wood harvest.
70
30
20
10
-‐
s
a
e
a
n
sia
ico
sia
es
au
m
ar
ne
ne
bi
on
ta
na
at
nm
iss
ne
ay
ex
kis
pi
ui
Le
St
et
-‐B
al
lo
M
do
ilip
ya
G
Pa
d
Vi
rra
M
Co
ea
ew
In
M
ite
Ph
in
Sie
Un
a
N
Gu
pu
Pa
Figure 10 indicates how many of the 104 mangrove countries worldwide belong to each annual mitigation potential
category. Because the costs of protecting habitat and the transaction costs of avoiding conversion projects will vary
across countries, it may be useful for project investors to have an idea of the size of the mitigation market at different
mitigation levels relative to the number of countries that make up that market. Just over half of mangrove countries
have a relatively modest mitigation potential of less than 1 million t CO2e/yr, while about 23% have no potential because
their mangrove loss rate is near zero (for example, Nigeria) or negative (for example, Bangladesh). Approximately 80%
of global potential resides in the few countries whose annual mitigation potential is over 3 million t CO2e; over 55% of
that potential resides in the seven countries with at least 5 million t CO2e. Distribution of the relative proportions of
total mangrove carbon at risk is somewhat more evenly distributed. Almost 30% of carbon at risk belongs to countries
with low mitigation potential (<1 million t/CO2e/yr), about 20% to countries with intermediate potential (1–3 million
t/CO2e/yr), and 50% to countries with high potential (>3 million t/CO2e/yr). This final metric indicates that mitigation
potential could rise substantially in countries that currently show low potential if their mangrove habitat loss rates were
to increase, whether due to a new loss driver or to better data collection. Overall though, both Figure 9 and Figure 10
highlight the fact that much of the opportunity for blue carbon may lie in a small group of countries.
Nicholas Institute
10
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 10. Biophysical mitigation potential for mangrove ecosystems worldwide. The biophysical mitigation potential
shown here is based on current stored carbon stocks and current conversion rates. Bars represent the percentage of man-
grove countries, the percentage of total mitigation potential, and the percentage of total mangrove carbon at risk in each
annual mitigation potential category (for example, 1–500,000 t CO2e/yr).
60%
Percent,
countries
Percent,
Total
Mi.ga.on
Poten.al
50%
Percent,
Total
Mangrove
Carbon
at
Risk
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Nega.ve
Zero
1-‐500K
500K-‐1mill
1mill-‐3mill
3mill-‐5mill
>5mill
Annual
Mi.ga.on
Poten.al
(tCO2e/yr)
Each habitat is modeled in essentially the same way. We assume that the habitat is converted or damaged in year zero,
and we model the release of carbon from the soil and biomass over a 25-year horizon. We use the values for biomass and
soil organic carbon that were presented above. On the basis of guidance from collaborators and the scientific literature,12
we assign exponential decay functions and associated half-lives for biomass and for soil organic to each habitat type.
For the intertidal systems (salt marshes and mangroves), we assume that the top meter of soil is either excavated or
drained during the habitat conversion and that all of that soil is equally exposed to oxygen. The excavation of man-
grove soil would be standard procedure in construction of aquaculture ponds; salt marshes are likely to be diked and
drained in their conversion to cropland. The assumption of one meter is a rough approximation of an average depth of
soil disturbance across many types of habitat-destroying actions. We use a half-life of 7.5 years for both mangrove and
marsh soil carbon and one-half year for the decay of salt marsh biomass. Regarding mangrove biomass, we assume that
mangroves are burned when the habitat is converted, resulting in an immediate release of the majority (75%) of the
biomass carbon to the atmosphere. Mangrove biomass includes both aboveground and belowground biomass, because
roots could be uplifted, exposed, and burned away just like the trunk and branches of the trees during excavation. The
remaining 25% of biomass is left to rot, which we approximate with a decay half-life of 15 years.
11. An exponential decay function may approximate this physical process, especially using the concept of half-life that denotes the
time required for the carbon pool to fall to one-half of its initial value. For example, if 100 t CO2 is exposed to conversion and it is
assumed to have a half-life of 5 years, at year five, 50 tons will remain; at year ten, 25 tons will remain; at year fifteen, 12.5 tons will
remain.
12. Marshes: Huang et al. 2010; C. Craft and P. Megonigal, pers. comm. Mangroves: D.C. Donato and J.B. Kauffman, pers. comm.
Seagrasses: J. Fourqurean and N. Marba, pers. comm.
Nicholas Institute
11
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
As a submerged ecosystem, seagrass meadows are subject to different stressors, but the carbon loss process is modeled
similarly. The main mechanisms of habitat destruction are excavation or mechanical damage, as through dredging or
trawling, and vegetative death resulting from degraded water and sediment quality. In the first case, we assume that
the top 50 centimeters (cm) of soil would be immediately washed away and that the decomposition of the rest of the
soil organic matter (another 50 cm) would occur in place. Limited evidence suggests that all seagrass carbon would
be converted to carbon dioxide and be released to the atmosphere at the same rate, whether buried or on the surface.
In the case of vegetative death, organic matter would decompose in place, and its carbon would make its way to the
atmosphere. We apply decay half-lives of about 100 days (0.27 years) to the seagrass biomass carbon and one year to
the soil organic carbon.
Additive to the stream of carbon emissions are the annual carbon sequestration or burial rates of intact habitats (Table
2). If the habitat were to be destroyed, carbon burial would cease because living matter would die. But habitat protec-
tion allows the process to continue apace. Whereas the quantity of avoided carbon emissions declines over the 25-year
time horizon (and disappears in the case of faster-decaying biomass), carbon sequestration is assumed to continue at a
constant annual rate, as the living matter continues to photosynthesize and fix carbon, a portion of which is stored in
the soil each year. A process in these habitats that runs counter to sequestration from a climate protection standpoint
is the release of methane (CH4), a greenhouse gas that has 25 times the global warming potential of carbon dioxide.
Methane release is not an issue for seagrass meadows, but small amounts of methane appear to be emitted from the
intertidal systems each year. Thus, in our modeling, ongoing methane emissions equivalent to 0.4 t CO2e/ha and 1.85 t
CO2e/ha are subtracted each year from the creditable avoided emissions for salt marshes and mangroves, respectively.13
Figure 11. Release of carbon to atmosphere from converted oceanic mangrove habitat in tropical Asia. The release is
based on the assumption that only the top meter of soil is disturbed and reflects an exponential decay function whereby
soil organic carbon has a half-live of 7.5 years. It is assumed that 75% of the biomass carbon is emitted immediately through
burning and that the remaining 25% decays with a half-life of 15 years.
2500
Soil
Organic
Carbon
2000
Biomass
Carbon
tCO2e/ha
1500
1000
500
0
0
5
10
15
20
25
Years
For illustration, we briefly describe and present values for the modeling of carbon loss in mangroves in tropical Asia,
which contains about half of the world’s mangrove forests (FAO 2007). We assume that on conversion to a shrimp
operation, soil in the top 100 cm layer is excavated and banked and that the soil carbon and biomass decomposition
processes begin immediately.14 Figure 11 presents the decay curves for the soil organic carbon and biomass carbon. The
precipitous drop in biomass carbon in the first year is due to the assumption that 75% of it is burned away on habitat
conversion. Decay of the remaining biomass carbon is much slower, and 8% of it remains at the end of the 25-year
period. Some of the soil carbon remains after 25 years as well. Overall, carbon stocks are reduced from 3,098 t CO 2e/
ha and 3,743 t CO2e/ha to 1,059 t CO2e/ha and 2,172 t CO2e/ha for oceanic and estuarine mangroves, respectively (see
Table 4). As a result, annual carbon losses average 82 t CO2e/ha/yr (2.6% rate) and 59 t CO2e/ha/yr (1.6% rate) for the
13. Salt marshes: Poffenbarger et al. Forthcoming. Mangroves: Krithika et al. (2008). For mangroves, we use the mean of 1.85 t CO2e/
ha/yr calculated from a range of 0-10.75 t CO2e/ha/yr adapted from Krithika et al. 2008.
14. All carbon stock values associated with mangroves as well as the best professional judgment regarding CO2 decay rates are sourced
to D.C. Donato and J.B. Kauffman, pers. comm.
Nicholas Institute
12
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
two mangrove types. To arrive at the total creditable carbon, we add these avoided carbon emissions to the annual
carbon sequestration rate for Southeast Asian mangroves (6.32 t CO2e/ha/yr) for each year of the study period, and we
subtract the annual effect of methane emissions (1.0 t CO2e/ha/yr).
Table 4. Carbon pool values and losses for destroyed oceanic and estuarine mangroves in the Southeast Asia/
Indo-Pacific region.
Oceanic mangroves Estuarine mangroves
(t CO2e/ha) (t CO2e/ha)
Total carbon stored before conversion 3,098 3,743
Aboveground biomass 352 352
Belowground biomass 211 211
Total biomass 563 563
Soil C: <100 cm (disturbed) 1,690 1,060
Soil C: >100 cm (undisturbed) 845 2,120
Biomass C remaining after 25 yrs 46 46
Soil C (<100 cm) remaining after 25 yrs 168 105
Total C remaining after 25 yrs 1,059 2,172
Blue carbon is not currently covered by the UNFCCC and therefore not included in a carbon market. Countries are not
required to account for it, and they are neither responsible for any increased emissions from blue carbon, nor can they
benefit financially from blue carbon emission reductions or restoration (for example, through the CDM). As a result,
economic incentives are tilted in favor of converting blue carbon habitats to alternative uses—such as aquaculture,
agriculture, and real estate development—from which parties can generate profits. But the UNFCCC is now negotiat-
ing a successor agreement to the Kyoto Protocol, which expires in 2012. The framework for the successor agreement
was initially structured at the UNFCCC’s Fifteenth Conference of Parties (COP 15) in Copenhagen in 2009, but it was
not accepted by the UNFCCC until the following year’s COP 16 in Cancún, which produced the so-called Cancún
Agreement. The Cancún Agreement is a somewhat general document; details are to be ironed out before it takes effect.
The Cancún Agreement, blue carbon, and the possible applicability of REDD+ provisions
The Cancún Agreement could eventually include blue carbon in UNFCCC-covered activities. Leading up to COP
16 in December 2010, a group of 55 marine and environmental stakeholders representing 19 countries prepared an
15. The Kyoto Protocol was ultimately ratified by all of the developed countries, with the exception of the United States, that initially
signed the agreement. Some of the world’s largest emitters, such as China and India, were not required to assume binding emission
reduction commitments owing to their then-status as developing countries. And some of the countries that did assume such com-
mitments—Canada, for example—appear unlikely to meet those commitments by the end of 2012.
Nicholas Institute
13
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
open statement (Blue Climate Coalition 2010) calling on the UNFCCC to take up the following considerations in its
deliberations:
• Include the conservation and restoration of mangrove, saltwater marsh, seagrass, and kelp ecosystems in
strategies for climate change mitigation and adaptation;
• Establish a global Blue Carbon Fund for the protection and management of these important coastal ecosystems;
• Include blue carbon sinks in national REDD+ strategies and greenhouse gas accounting; and
• Support coordinated scientific research to better quantify blue carbon’s role in climate mitigation, including
the development of protocols and methodologies for monitoring, reporting, and verification of coastal and
marine carbon sinks.
Aside from the statement, several side events at the Cancún meetings were specifically dedicated to informing the
negotiating community on blue carbon potential.16
The Cancún meeting did produce an agreement on the basic framework for moving the climate negotiating process
beyond the Kyoto Protocol expiration date (2012) (UNFCCC 2010). Moreover, provisions on reduced emissions from
deforestation and degradation (REDD+) were a substantial component of the Cancún Agreement. These provisions
established a set of principles guiding REDD+; a defined scope of potentially covered activities; safeguards for environ-
mental integrity, biodiversity, governance, and rights of local populations; and funding mechanisms for planning and
implementation.
In the Cancún Agreement, the scope of REDD+ is defined along the following activities: reducing emissions from
deforestation and forest degradation, conserving forest carbon stocks, sustainably managing forests, and enhancing
forest carbon stocks. These activities reference only forests, so what do they mean for blue carbon? Answering this
question is difficult because the agreement does not define forests—a task left to future deliberations, presumably with
guidance from the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC).17 But it is conceivable—and many observers
surmise—that forests could include mangroves, as they have above-ground woody vegetation. Inclusion of salt marshes
and sea grasses, however, would presumably require a significant broadening of the terms agreed at Cancún. This inclu-
sion could be part of efforts to seek a broader platform for emissions and sequestration activities from all land uses
(forest, agriculture, grasslands, wetlands). This platform is referred to in some quarters as agriculture, forest, and land
use (AFOLU).
Another critical issue is which carbon pools would count under REDD+, and most relevant for blue carbon, is whether
the soil carbon pool (or just the aboveground biomass pool) would be included. Much of the emphasis on deforesta-
tion and forest degradation focuses on carbon above ground, rather than below ground. As the data throughout this
report suggest, exclusion of belowground carbon from recognition would substantially undercut blue carbon mitigation
potential. Again, inclusion/exclusion of soil carbon is a detail that remains undefined by the broad strokes of the Cancún
Agreement—a detail to be resolved in post-Cancún deliberations.
Blue carbon under the CDM?
Another possibility would be for blue carbon to be included under the project-based Clean Development Mechanism.
Indeed, a methodology for mangrove restoration has recently been proposed for inclusion as an afforestation/refores-
tation (AR) activity under the CDM.18 Although inclusion under the CDM could be a start for those seeking market
incentives for blue carbon, the opportunities are limited on a couple fronts. First, the proposed methodology applies to
mangroves only; salt marshes and sea grasses would not appear to qualify. Second, the proposed qualifying AR activity
is restoration; the much larger avoided emissions through protection of blue carbon stocks would remain outside the
mechanism. Again, the parallel with forests is worth noting, as forest carbon coverage under CDM is limited to affores-
tation/reforestation. The inclusion of incentives for much larger-scale forest protection (emissions from deforestation
and degradation) was the impetus for efforts to include REDD+ in the Cancún Agreement outside of the CDM. As with
forests, limiting blue carbon to the restoration activities possibly covered under the AR provisions CDM would provide
positive, but small, incentives to substantially change the blue carbon balance.
Nicholas Institute
14
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Voluntary markets
Outside the auspices of the UNFCCC and other compliance systems, the market for voluntary reductions offers oppor-
tunities to incentivize carbon activities. Although not required by law to do so, some parties will pay for emission
reductions to offset emissions from their own activities or simply as an act of good corporate or individual stewardship.
Another motive for some buyers in the voluntary carbon market is to create a hedge against the possibility that they
may one day be subject to compliance obligations. Voluntary payments for emission reductions may one day count as
an early compliance action.
At this stage, blue carbon does not trade on voluntary markets. But it might with efforts to propose and develop meth-
odologies for inclusion in voluntary market systems such as the Voluntary Carbon Standard (VCS), Climate Action
Reserve (CAR), or American Carbon Registry (ACR), all of which consider land use and forest practices as potentially
creditable activities. These systems expand the suite of creditable activities beyond the narrow boundaries of CDM
to include not only afforestation/reforestation, but also REDD+ and improved forest management. In doing so, they
increase the possibility that blue carbon might be included in them.
Compliance market prices reflect current prices on the exchanges on which EU ETS, CDM, and RGGI credits are
traded. The UNFCCC markets are the highest on the board, trading between about $18 for CDM credits to about $24
19. Smaller regional compliance markets exist in Australia (New South Wales) and Canada (Alberta), but they are in Kyoto Protocol
signatory countries, so they are at least indirectly linked to the UNFCCC.
20. See Governors’ Climate and Forests Task Force, http://www.gcftaskforce.org/.
21. Under RGGI, in the case of a stage-two trigger event (when the 12-month rolling average allowance price is equal to or greater than
$10 in 2005 dollars), GHG reduction credits resulting from any mandatory carbon-constraining program outside the United States or
certified through the UNFCCC will be eligible for up to 10% of compliance obligation. The general provision on international offsets
is in the Model Rule, Section XX-10.3(a)(2)(i)(b). http://www.rggi.org/docs/Model%20Rule%20Revised%2012.31.08.pdf.
Nicholas Institute
15
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
for regular EU allowances. RGGI allowances are about an order of magnitude smaller than the UNFCCC-related mar-
kets, reflecting differences in the scope and relative stringencies of the two regulations. RGGI applies only to electric
power plants in the northeastern United States, and compliance obligations are not much different from those in a
business-as-usual scenario, making marginal abatement costs low.
Credits on the voluntary market typically trade at prices lower than those found in compliance markets (the exception
is RGGI) and at roughly a third or fourth of those in the UNFCCC markets, according to the most recent survey evi-
dence. However, some credits on the voluntary market trade at a premium relative to the rest of the voluntary market,
especially if the credits are compliant with what the market perceives to be higher standards of performance in terms
of stringency of carbon reduction requirements or the inclusion of other desirable attributes such as biodiversity co-
benefits or protection of human rights.
The economic model begins with the quantification of the GHG benefit—emissions that would be avoided and seques-
tration maintained through a blue carbon project that protects one of the focal coastal habitats. The GHG benefit fluxes
of blue carbon avoided-conversion projects take this general form:
where i is the habitat type and t is time, expressed in years; CS is the annual carbon sequestration rate, which continues
!
as the habitat is retained; AvCO2 is the CO2 emissions
!"! !"#"$%& !"#$ avoided
!" ∗ !"#$% from the
!"#2!" ! habitat’s conversion; and M represents the
2 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! =
annual methane emissions that continue to be emitted 1 + ! !as the habitat remains intact. Methane emissions reduce the
!!!
GHG benefits of protecting habitat but tend to be small relative to the magnitude of the carbon sequestration rate and
especially the avoided CO2 emissions in conserved saltwater habitats. All quantities are expressed in CO 2 equivalent
units.322 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! > !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#! + !""#$%&'(%) !"#$#!
Thus, the annual GHG benefit fluxes are characterized as temporal flows, reflecting the dynamic nature of post-con-
version GHG emission rates. Rates of carbon sequestration and methane emissions could also fluctuate temporally,
4 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! + !" !"#$%&! > !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#! + !""#$%&'(%) !"#$#!
though they are assumed here to be constant annual rates. All fluxes are computed on a per-hectare basis. As quantita-
tive understanding of the relevant processes improves, complicating factors, such as sea level rise, could be integrated
into the modeling of the GHG fluxes.
GHG benefits flows are monetized by multiplying the annual GHG fluxes by a stream of expected carbon prices ($/t
CO2e) over a time horizon of length n. The resulting cash flow streams are then discounted using a financial discount
1 !"! !"#"$%& !"#$ = !"!" + !"#$2!" − !!"
rate (d) to arrive at present !"value estimates for the blue carbon (BC) value of an avoided conversion project:
!
!"! !"#"$%& !"#$!" ∗ !"#$% $/! !"2! !
2 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! =
1+! !
!!!
The results provide a measure of the present value of a stream of monetary flows to land managers for keeping blue
3 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! > !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#!
carbon intact and for receiving the market rate for the emissions avoided over time.
We consider two types of comparison that can be conducted to determine whether blue carbon payments are sufficient
4 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! + !" !"#$%&! > !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#!
22. All carbon (C) fluxes are multiplied by 3.67 to be expressed in CO2 equivalent units. All methane fluxes are multiplied by 25,
which is the IPCC global warming potential value for methane to make one tonne of methane equivalent in radiative-forcing value
to one tonne of CO2.
Nicholas Institute
16
1 !"! !"#"$%& !"#$!" = !"!" + !"#$2Green Payments for Blue Carbon
!" − !!"
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
!
to incentivize protection of the focal coastal habitats.!"In∗ !"#$%
!"! !"#"$%& !"#$ the first, the estimated
$/! !"2! ! blue carbon values will be compared to
2 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%! =
the costs to protect that habitat. This comparison will
1 + be! !the emphasis of the analysis in the following sections, which
!!!
will demonstrate that an avoided conversion would be economically viable if:
The results of this comparison indicate whether blue carbon payments would be sufficient to promote the protection of
4 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$%
the coastal ! + !" !"#$%&
habitat in question, ! >of
irrespective !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#
the values of other
! ecosystem services (ES) provided. This finding gives
us a useful first indication of the economics of blue carbon. If the carbon payments alone can cover the costs, they can
be influential in protecting these ecosystems even without explicitly considering other ecosystem services. These results
1 !"! !"#"$%& !"#$!" = !"!" + !"#$2!" − !!"
will allow us to identify specific habitats and locations where conservation and restoration efforts will be most economi-
cally beneficial. The main point with equation (3) is to see whether new markets or funds that would pay land managers
to avoid GHG releases through habitat ! conversion could make a difference for some coastal habitats.
!"! !"#"$%& !"#$!" ∗ !"#$% $/! !"2! !
2 !"#$ !"#$%& !"#$% =
A second comparison would !
incorporate the estimated
1 + ! values,
! where available, of other ecosystem services provided
!!!
by the intact ecosystem. These ES values could be varied across habitats and regions and could be greater than the blue
carbon value. They show that the social returns of protecting coastal habitats extend beyond simply the blue carbon
value.3 The overall ES values of
!"#$ !"#$%& !"#$% the habitat are compared to the protection costs. Thus, avoided conversion projects would
! > !"#$%&$'#( !"#$#!
be economically justified if:
In this comparison, we would ascertain whether the total ecosystem value (blue carbon payments plus other ES values)
is great enough to exceed the various costs of protecting the habitat. This analysis would allow us to consider the effect
of other incentives that could be combined with payments for blue carbon.
One difficulty in making this comparison is that ES values will often be location-specific and, as a result, values esti-
mated in a study for one salt marsh may not be readily applicable to other salt marshes. In contrast, the blue carbon
value (GHG reduction) is a global service, meaning that the avoided emission of a tonne of carbon dioxide has the
same value no matter where the service occurs.23 Because ES values for each habitat may not be generalizable to broader
scales, as implied in equation (4), we do not add them to the blue carbon value in the following analysis. Relevant eco-
system services and their values are discussed in Section 11.
Gross blue carbon values would be zero at a price of $0/t CO2e, but they would begin to rise at varying slopes as the
carbon price rises. In Figure 12, we present global blue carbon value streams for each focal habitat and divide mangroves
into oceanic and estuarine types. The mangrove values are based on weighted averages of biomass and soil carbon across
the four mangrove regions. Because regional data on carbon pool estimates for seagrasses and salt marshes are lacking,
these values are assumed to represent those systems worldwide.
23. Another important difference between blue carbon value and other ES services is that the latter are often scale-dependent. That
is, the per-hectare value of the ecosystem may change when the habitat area in question increases or decreases. The blue carbon value
is independent of scale because each avoided CO2 emission performs the same level of climate stabilization service.
24. Some readers may consider a real rate of discount of 10% to be on the high side, but we believe this rate better reflects the time pref-
erences and risks associated with investments in developing countries, where many of the blue carbon mitigation opportunities exist.
Nicholas Institute
17
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Gross returns for mangrove avoided-conversion projects would be the most attractive returns for the three coastal habi-
tats modeled. The present value per hectare exceeds $10,000 at carbon prices of about $8/t CO2e for oceanic mangroves
and about $11/t CO2e for estuarine mangroves; salt marshes and seagrasses do not reach $10,000/ha until carbon prices
approach $20/t CO2e. Seagrasses have much less carbon in the first meter of soil than salt marshes, but that carbon
returns to the atmosphere much more quickly when seagrasses are disturbed; thus, emission reductions accrue faster.
As a result, seagrasses have approximately the same blue-carbon benefit curve as salt marshes do.
Oceanic mangroves tend to accrue greater blue carbon benefits than estuarine mangroves because their carbon stocks
in the first meter of soil are much larger; biomass carbon is assumed to be the same in both types. However, estuarine
mangroves often have deeper organic soils and would close the gap with oceanic mangroves if the disturbance went
much deeper than one meter. Positing a deeper disturbance would also raise salt marsh returns because salt marshes
can have several meters of organic soil beneath them. In contrast, seagrass meadows have about one meter of soil on
average and thus would have the same gross returns even if the disturbance exceeded one meter in depth.
Figure 12. Gross financial returns to avoided conversion projects for the three habitat types over a range of carbon prices
($0–$30/t CO2e). Values were calculated using equation [2], with a time horizon of 25 years and a discount rate of 10%. These
values do not account for project costs.
$40,000
Mangroves
-‐
Oceanic
$35,000
Mangroves
-‐
Estuarine
$30,000
Salt
Marsh
$25,000
Seagrass
PV
$/ha
$20,000
$15,000
$10,000
$5,000
$0
$0
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
Source: Authors.
Figure 13 reports blue carbon values for the two mangrove types in four regions. The figure legend lists the mangrove
systems in decreasing order of their potential blue carbon values. Oceanic mangroves in tropical Africa and tropical
Asia have the highest, and more or less equal, returns, though the subtropical and tropical Americas are not far behind
(note that the lines for “Oceanic – Africa” and “Oceanic – Asia” in Figure 13 almost overlap). Within mangrove types,
the largest gap in values is that between Asian and subtropical estuarine mangroves. This gap is driven wholly by dif-
ferences in biomass carbon because the data show estuarine soil carbon stocks as constant across regions. Overall, all
oceanic mangrove systems show greater blue carbon values than estuarine systems because the mangrove systems have
higher carbon density in their first meter of soil. All mangrove values are notably higher than salt marsh values, as seen
in Figure 12.
Nicholas Institute
18
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 13. Gross financial returns to avoided conversion projects for mangroves in different regions. These values are
calculated with same parameters as in Figure 12. The regions of Africa, Asia, and the Americas only include tropical areas and
the Subtropical region accounts for all other mangrove areas, no matter on what continent.
$40,000
Oceanic
-‐
Africa
Oceanic
-‐
Asia
$35,000
Oceanic
-‐
Subtropical
$30,000
Oceanic
-‐
Americas
Estuarine
-‐
Asia
$25,000
Estuarine
-‐
Americas
PV
$/ha
$15,000
$10,000
$5,000
$0
$0
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
Figure 14 allocates the gross returns to different carbon fluxes within each habitat type. We use the midpoint of the
carbon price range, $15/t CO2e, as an illustrative price. Again, mangroves yield the highest values; estuarine mangroves
exceed $13,000/ha and oceanic mangroves exceed $18,000/ha. At nearly $7,000/ha, seagrasses have just over half of the
revenue potential of estuarine mangroves, but lag the revenue potential of salt marshes by only 12%. With the highest
carbon burial rate, salt marshes have the greatest amount of carbon credit value attributed to carbon sequestration,
almost double that of seagrasses. The vast majority of returns for seagrasses and salt marshes, which possess only mini-
mal biomass, come from soil carbon. As a point of comparison, most of the value of avoiding the loss of tropical forests
comes from retaining aboveground biomass. Soil carbon and biomass carbon contribute fairly equally to blue carbon
value for estuarine mangroves, whereas soil carbon stocks outpace the contribution of biomass carbon for oceanic
mangroves. Exerting a small negative effect are annual emissions of methane, a low-volume but potent greenhouse gas
emitted by existing coastal wetlands. These emissions decrease the present values of blue carbon by less than 1% for salt
marshes and less than 2% for mangroves.
Figure 14. Gross carbon credit revenue potential for coastal habitats and tropical forests. Assuming a carbon price of $15/t
CO2e and mean values for carbon stocks, results are presented on a present value (PV) per hectare basis.
C
SequestraBon
Seagrasses
Soil
C
Salt
Marsh
Biomass
C
Estuarine Mangroves
Oceanic Mangroves
Tropical forest
Nicholas Institute
19
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Residential Land
$100,000
Industrial Land
Among the direct costs, we apply $232 per hectare as the upfront establishment costs to create a protected area, whether
terrestrial or marine. McCrea-Strub et al. (2011) find a range of establishment costs of $20 to $788 (2009 USD) per
hectare for small marine protected areas in the tropics, with a mean value of $232 per hectare. Regarding annual costs
involved in managing a terrestrial protected area, Balmford et al. (2003) find such costs to be about $13/ha/yr (2009
USD) near populated areas in a developing country and under $1/ha/yr for more remote regions. For the developed
world, Balmford et al. report that these running costs fell in the range of $60–$600/ha/yr. Using these numbers as a
Nicholas Institute
20
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
guide, we conservatively assign management costs according to relative national affluence by dividing countries into four
groups. Least developed countries are assumed to have annual costs of $25/ha, emerging countries to have either $50/ha
or $100/ha, and the wealthiest countries and some prosperous small island nations to have $250/ha. Because these costs
are annual, present values are calculated using a 25-year time horizon and a 10% discount rate. For example, yearly costs
of $25/ha lead to a present value of $227/ha. These costs are used for countries containing salt marshes or mangroves.
According to the scientific literature, marine protected-area management costs do not differ considerably from terres-
trial protected-area management costs. Balmford et al. (2004) report a mean of $34/ha/yr from a wide range. Marsden
and Sumaila (2010) find management costs for small marine protected areas (<3,000 ha) in Central and South America
to range between $4 and $35 per hectare. To be conservative, we apply the four-part cost groups to seagrass countries
that we used for terrestrial protected-area management costs.
Opportunity costs for the intertidal habitats—salt marshes and mangroves—are drawn from datasets from the World
Bank (World Bank 2011) and the Global Trade Assessment Project (GTAP 2007). We use the land values from these
studies as opportunity costs, which are well-approximated by land values because the stream of future economic returns
is assumed to be embedded in the value of a hectare of land. Both datasets derive land values on the basis of potential
agricultural returns for arable land. For the WB dataset, cropland wealth per hectare is calculated as the net present
value of returns from crop cultivation, using a discount rate of 10% over a 25-year horizon. These returns are calculated
as the product of rental rates and revenues from production; a constant profit margin of 30% across all considered crops
is assumed. The GTAP dataset represents estimates of the value of the land in the next best alternative to forestry, which
is typically agriculture, for countries of interest. Within each country, several forest types and the associated land rents
are provided, allowing us to compute weighted averages for land value across the relevant forest types. Thus, unlike the
WB data, GTAP does account for variation of land values within countries. We transform the GTAP values into pres-
ent value using a 10% discount rate and 25-year time horizon so as to align them with the WB data and the rest of this
analysis. Because estimating land values is an inexact science, the datasets are generally not in agreement and have very
low statistical correlation. On one hand, the WB data are somewhat higher than one might expect, especially for the
Latin American countries. On the other, the GTAP data generally seem to be on the low side.27
Because aquaculture, particularly shrimp farming, has increased in recent decades, its returns are arguably somewhat
higher than those for agriculture. To account for aquaculture’s potentially higher per-hectare returns, we increased the
WB values, which are derived from agricultural rents, by 30%. This adjustment is based on the percentage difference in
WB land values and net returns for shrimp farming for two countries, Thailand and Bangladesh, reported in Sathirai
and Barbier (2001) and Islam et al. (2005). We use values averaged from the GTAP dataset and the WB dataset (adjusted
for aquaculture returns) as mean estimates for opportunity costs for all countries.
Salt marshes often exist in developed countries, which have environmental laws that ensure their conservation or at least
replacement elsewhere if affected (for example, U.S. Clean Water Act S. 404 requires no net loss of salt marshes). Some
mangroves, such as those in the U.S. state of Florida, may enjoy this type of protection too. If so, landholders wishing to
convert wetlands to another land use would incur costs associated with adhering to the law, such as going through the
permitting process and paying for compensatory mitigation. These costs make the habitat conversion more expensive
and thus less attractive to landholders and therefore would be subtracted from the net cost of protection. The additional
legal costs of conversion could be quite high, as suggested by the admittedly scarce data on compensatory mitigation
costs related to compliance with the statute.
Opportunity costs for seagrass meadows are more challenging to ascertain. Because degraded coastal water quality
is the most significant factor in seagrass habitat loss, interventions to improve that quality would need to be charac-
terized. These interventions would most likely occur in terrestrial areas within the watershed that outflows into the
seagrass habitat. The principal options would be to reduce runoff from agricultural or urban areas by retiring cropland
or implementing best management practices (for example, for tillage or fertilizer application) on it or by constructing
wastewater treatment plants. Given differing effects of tides and differing distances of seagrass meadows from the coast,
these actions would have varying levels of effectiveness that as yet are not well-understood quantitatively.
27. For example, the land value for a hectare in Colombia is valued at $19,651 in the WB dataset but at $701 in the GTAP dataset; a
hectare in Papua New Guinea is valued at $11,922 in the WB dataset but at $290 in GTAP dataset.
Nicholas Institute
21
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
An alternative approach to assessing seagrass opportunity costs would be to exclude extractive use (for example, com-
mercial or artisanal fishing) of the seagrass areas, which would remove the main causes of mechanical damage from
anchoring, trawling, and so on. Thus, the opportunity cost would be the forgone profits from fishing the protected
seagrass areas. Ascertaining opportunity costs this way has a strong conceptual foundation (Smith et al. 2010), though
somewhat limited application to date (Adams et al. 2011; Klein et al. 2010). One recent study examining the collection
of invertebrates and fish in seagrass meadows in Indonesia found that collectors would forgo profits of about $45 to
$140 per hectare per year if they were to be displaced by the establishment of a non-extractive marine protected area
(Unsworth et al. 2010). The average across all site types was about $100/ha/yr, which yields a present value of over $900/
ha over 25 years at a 10% discount rate. We could generalize to other seagrass countries by observing that Indonesia is
in the third quartile in terms of GDP per capita in the world. Opportunity costs would likely be lower in lower-income
countries and higher in higher-income countries. This approach appears to be an appropriate first-order option for
finding opportunity costs for seagrass protection, though research that would provide empirical estimates to be placed
into our framework is needed to conduct a proof of concept.
Figure 16 presents the average estimated costs for the three cost types across the focal habitats and, for comparison, tropi-
cal forests. Management costs fall within the same general range of about $350 to $900 per hectare and are somewhat
higher for salt marshes and seagrasses because those habitats tend to occur more frequently in higher-income countries.
Management costs for tropical forest reserves are the lowest of the group for the same reason—tropical forests are pre-
dominantly found in low-income countries. As mentioned above, the same protected-area establishment cost ($232/ha)
is used for all habitat types. Due to higher land values in higher-income countries, opportunity costs are highest for salt
marshes at over $6,800/ha. Opportunity costs for mangroves are about 30% lower than those for salt marshes.28 They tend
to be lower than those for other terrestrial habitats because mangroves are limited to tropical countries, most of which are
lower income, and because the land values adjusted upward to account for aquaculture are not applicable to them (most
forests would be upland from the coast). The opportunity cost for seagrass is the lowest among the habitats because per-
hectare values for fishing are lower than those for agriculture. Of course, our estimate of opportunity cost may be a partial
value that takes into account only the opportunity costs of fisherman, and it may even understate that value. Larger-scale
approaches that seek to improve coastal water quality through changes in management of farmland or urban wastewater
would likely be much more expensive. Additional research is needed to better understand potential effectiveness and costs.
One last consideration regarding costs is that participation in a market for blue carbon reductions will involve some costs
itself. These costs include the costs of measuring, monitoring, and verifying coastal habitat loss and carbon stocks, estab-
lishing a baseline against which emission reductions are measured, making accounting adjustments that might discount
the value of credits, and enforcing contracts and monitoring transactions. These transaction costs are as yet unknown,
tend to be “up front” in nature, and should be carefully assessed before parties proceed with blue carbon projects.
Figure 16. Costs of protection (PV $/ha, 25-year horizon, 10% discount rate) for the focal coastal habitats and tropical
forest. Average costs across each habitat type are presented for each cost category. For mangroves, averages are calculated
using mangrove area weights by country.
Seagrasses
Salt Marsh
Estuarine
Mangroves
Mgmt
costs
Oceanic
Mangroves
Establishment
costs
Opportunity
costs
Tropical forest
28. There are a few exceptions. Opportunity costs for U.S. tropical forests, for example, are $3,339/ha.
Nicholas Institute
22
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
The mechanical disturbance associated with trawling can rip out both the living biomass and sediments associated
with seagrass habitats. The carbon in these habitats becomes more susceptible to suspension and can wash away,
oxidize in the water column, and ultimately release carbon dioxide to the atmosphere. In the case of vegetative death,
organic matter in the sediments decomposes in place; over 95% of its carbon returns to the water column and on to
the atmosphere within less than five years. In addition, seagrass mortality results in the loss of annual carbon seques-
tration performed by the living plants. When Mediterranean seagrass habitats are destroyed, the oxidized carbon can
result in the release to the atmosphere of more than 500 t CO2e per hectare; the forgone annual sequestration from
lost living seagrass would be approximately 4 t CO2e per hectare per year.
Actions to halt trawling over seagrass meadows would reduce seagrass mortality and the corresponding loss of soil
organic carbon and sequestration capacity. The amount of CO2 emissions avoided by such actions could potentially
be credited in a carbon payment system.
To consider the financial viability of efforts designed to stop trawling, we compare the market value of carbon that
could be emitted from seagrass loss to the costs of conserving seagrass, which may include the costs of establishing
Nicholas Institute
23
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
and managing a marine protected area as well as trawlers’ opportunity costs. The estimated mean direct cost of
establishing a marine protected area is approximately $250, and the present value of recurring costs is approximately
$2,250/ha, for a total present value cost of $2,500/ha. If the direct costs were the only relevant ones for protection
(that is, opportunity costs are zero), the break-even market price of carbon (the price at which blue carbon benefits
equal costs of conservation) would be $5.36/ t CO2e.
Figure 17. Blue carbon value for seagrass meadows compared to direct costs and overall costs of protection.
$15,000
Costs
of
Protec+on
Seagrass
$9,000
PV
$/ha
$6,000
$3,000
$0
$0
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
Nevertheless, it is likely that excluding trawling from seagrass meadows would result in lost profits for trawlers,
which would be the opportunity costs (Smith et al. 2010). This exclusion would mean that trawlers would be forced
to find other areas in which to fish, perhaps accruing greater travel costs to get to alternative areas or bringing in less
catch per unit of effort if other trawling areas are less productive. Or the exclusion could force them to quit trawling
altogether and search for alternative employment. These opportunity costs could be on the order of $4,500/ha for
a high-income country such as Spain (see Section 10), though they have been little studied to date and could vary
greatly among and within countries. In this case, overall costs of protection would be about $7,000/ha, and the car-
bon break-even price would be $15/t CO2e. Therefore avoiding destruction of seagrass habitat could be financially
attractive at carbon prices above $15/t CO2e, which is about where CDM-certified emissions reductions were trading
in early 2011.
Nicholas Institute
24
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
29. An extreme example of this phenomenon is the Yangtze River delta, where coastal wetlands has receded rapidly as riverine
sediment delivery has dropped considerably since the 1960s, mostly due to dam construction. The sediment load was 35% of the
50-year average in 2004 before the full impact of the Three Gorges Dam (Yang et al. 2006).
30. This lowering is often termed “subsidence” and is due to natural factors such as sediment-compacting tectonic activity as well
as human factors such as oil and gas withdrawal.
Nicholas Institute
25
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
resulting carbon loss could be as high as 950 t CO2e/ha; over 95% of this loss comes from the soil carbon stores.
Annual sequestration of about 8 t CO2e/ha would also be forgone. Efforts that avoided this marsh habitat loss would
allow carbon sequestration to continue and keep marsh biomass and soil carbon intact.
To assess the financial viability of efforts to stop marsh loss, we compare the blue carbon value of habitat protection
to the costs of protection. In this case, marsh habitat is sustained by a diversion structure that introduces freshwater
and sediment from the main channel of the Mississippi River into the delta. The direct costs for this structure would
be its construction costs as well as annual maintenance and operation costs. The Caernarvon Freshwater Diversion
structure was completed in 1991 at a cost of $41.1 million in 2009 USD (U.S. Army Corps of Engineers 1998). One
study estimated that the Caernarvon diversion could maintain 54,100 to 92,300 hectares of fresh and brackish marsh
(Lane 2006), making the per-hectare costs for construction between $445 and $760. Data on annual costs associated
with the Caernarvon diversion were not available, so we consider the estimated costs of construction to be a lower
bound on direct costs, as indicated by the purple horizontal line in Figure 18. If the $760 estimate reflected the only
relevant costs for implementing a water diversion structure, the break-even price would be under $1.50 t CO2e.
For a more complete assessment of costs, the opportunity cost of river diversions would be included. The wetlands
that would receive Mississippi River water may be private or public land, but in either case, raising oysters appears
to be the most profitable alternative use. Thus, the opportunity cost for protecting marsh habitat would be equal to
the value of oyster leases for those wetlands, given that the freshwater diversions would kill the oyster beds when
released. It has been estimated that the average Louisiana annual oyster lease is worth almost $589/ha (Meitrodt
and Kuriloff 2003). The present value of the estimated opportunity cost is $5,350/ha; adding that value to the direct
costs, we find the overall costs of protection to be about $6,110/ha. Weighing the blue carbon value of intact coastal
marshes against the total costs of protection yields a break-even price of $11.58/t CO2e.
Figure 18. Blue carbon value for coastal marsh compared to direct costs and overall costs of protection.
$16,000
Costs
of
Protec+on
Direct
Costs
$12,000
Coastal
Marsh
PV
$/ha
$8,000
$4,000
$0
$0
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
Nicholas Institute
26
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Carbon losses
Converting mangrove forests to shrimp aquaculture typically involves the burning of mangrove biomass, excavation
and piling of approximately the first meter of sediment, and complete alteration of the local hydrology. Mangrove
conversion of this sort results in the release of previously stored carbon into the atmosphere as gaseous CO2, from
both biomass and soil, as well as an abrupt stop to annual carbon sequestration. These emissions may amount to
roughly 1,500 to over 2,000 tonnes of CO2e. A project that avoided mangrove conversion would forgo habitat loss,
thereby allowing carbon sequestration to continue while preventing the release of carbon dioxide from the mangrove
biomass and soil. The avoided release of carbon and continued carbon sequestration associated with the project
would then potentially be creditable under a carbon payment system.
Protection of mangrove habitats would make financial sense if the revenues that could be earned from carbon
markets exceeded the costs of protection. In Figure 19, we compare the blue carbon value to the costs of protection.
We estimate the direct costs of protection by considering estimates of the costs for the establishment and ongoing
management of protected areas in coastal areas. Values from the literature indicate that these costs are about $232
and $454 per hectare, respectively. Total direct costs are $686 per hectare and are represented by the purple hori-
zontal line in Figure 19. Break-even prices, at which the financial payment from avoiding carbon releases just offsets
Nicholas Institute
27
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
the direct costs of mangrove protection, are under $1/t CO2e for both oceanic and estuarine mangroves in this case.
A more complete comparison would include the opportunity cost of protecting habitat—the financial value that
reflects the most valuable alternative use of the area. For mangroves in tropical Asia, shrimp farming is often that
use. From the literature, the net present financial value (adjusted to 2009 U.S. dollars) of shrimp farming has been
estimated at $11,735/ha (Sathirai and Barbier 2001). Adding that value to the direct costs, the overall costs of protec-
tion become $12,421/ha (red line), and break-even prices are $9.95 for oceanic mangroves and $13.00 for estuarine
mangroves. Therefore, avoiding mangrove conversion could be financially attractive to a landholder at carbon prices
above the break-even points, which are below where CDM-certified emissions reductions were trading in early 2011
(about $15–18/t CO2e).
Figure 19. Blue carbon value for oceanic and estuarine mangroves compared to direct costs and overall costs of
protection.
$40,000
Oceanic
Mangroves
$35,000
Estuarine
Mangrove
$30,000
Costs
of
Protec4on
$25,000
PV
$/ha
Direct
Costs
$20,000
$15,000
$10,000
$5,000
$0
$0
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
Compared with estuarine mangroves, oceanic mangroves would more likely be targeted for protection efforts because
positive net returns would be achieved at a lower price point. If the value of the forgone economic opportunity (for
example, beach resort development) were higher than shrimp farming, the required break-even price would be
higher as well. The opposite would be true if the forgone opportunity cost were lower.
31. Das and Vincent observe that agricultural land near the mangrove forests was worth about 173,000 rupees per hectare (in
1999), which means that “the average opportunity cost of saving a life by retaining mangroves was 11.7 million rupees per life
saved. This opportunity cost is less than the value of reductions in mortality risks implied by wage differentials in India, which
has been estimated as ranging from 13.7–14.2 million rupees to 55.5–60.6 million rupees per avoided death…”
Nicholas Institute
28
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 20 provides some insights into the economic potential of mangrove protection for blue carbon across countries
at different carbon prices. We can see that oceanic mangroves (OM in Figure 20) generally have net returns superior to
those for estuarine mangroves (EM) because they harbor greater soil carbon stocks in the top meter of sediments (see
Figure 7)—not because their protection costs (the mean values used here) are lower. We assume that these costs are the
same for both types of mangroves.
Net returns to blue carbon investments are negative in about 40% to 50% of mangrove countries at $5/t CO2e, though
those percentages drop to about 15% or less when the carbon price reaches $15/t CO2e. Although low blue carbon
value potential ($1–$10,000/ha) is common among countries at low carbon prices, the majority of countries have net
returns of at least $10,000 to $20,000/ha starting at $15/t CO2e for oceanic mangroves and at $20/t CO2e for estuarine
mangroves. High returns, those between $20,000/ha and $30,000/ha, are found for oceanic mangroves in 82% and 94%
of countries at prices of $25/t CO2e and $30/t CO2e, respectively. Estuarine mangroves are not quite as strong a return;
10% and 60% of countries are in the high-return category at those same carbon prices.
Figure 20. Mangrove country-level blue carbon results. For oceanic mangroves (OM) and estuarine mangroves (EM), the
percentages of countries with blue carbon net returns (benefits minus costs of protection) in various ranges for different
carbon prices.
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
OM
EM
OM
EM
OM
EM
OM
EM
OM
EM
OM
EM
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
We continue our assessment of mangrove blue carbon on the global scale by examining the distribution of returns
across the world. The map in Figure 21 displays the net returns per hectare (NPV$/ha) for each mangrove country at a
carbon price of $15/t CO2e; higher returns are depicted by the darker shades. We use a weighted average for mangrove
blue carbon benefits—one based on estimates of the relative proportion of oceanic and estuarine mangroves in different
regions. Overall, there appears to be economic potential for blue carbon projects worldwide; 31% and 54% of countries
show net returns of $5,000/ha to $10,000/ha and $10,000/ha to $15,000/ha, respectively. The tropical Americas tend
Nicholas Institute
29
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
to have lower returns than other regions because estimates of their opportunity costs are generally higher.32 A notable
exception is Mexico. With net returns just over $10,000/ha, it has the second highest overall mitigation potential.
Countries with subtropical mangroves, such as United States and China, have moderate returns to blue carbon invest-
ments. In the highest-return category are the majority of countries in Africa and tropical Asia, the regions with the
most mangrove blue carbon opportunity on a country-level, benefit-cost basis. This finding is partially explained by the
somewhat higher carbon pools in mangroves of those regions, though the main factor is that opportunity costs tend to
be lower, on average, in countries of these regions.
Figure 21. Net returns ($/ha) to mangrove avoided-conversion efforts per hectare for all mangrove countries of the world,
assuming a carbon price of $15/t CO2e.
We highlight the most compelling regional results for mangrove blue carbon in Figure 22. This graph displays the range
of blue carbon values for oceanic mangroves in tropical Africa over a carbon price range of $0/t CO 2e to $30/t CO2e
intersected by the range of costs of protection for the region. The top line of blue carbon value (the green triangle) rep-
resents a mangrove forest with relatively high carbon storage (50% above the mean); the bottom line represents one with
low carbon storage (50% below the mean). The mean estimate for carbon storage, which is used in Figure 21 and Figure
22, bisects the green triangle. Regarding the costs of protection (orange rectangle), the top line of costs are derived from
the average for tropical African mangrove countries from the World Bank land values as opportunity costs and the bot-
tom line from the mean of the GTAP African land values; costs of protected-area management and establishment are
the same in each case. The vast majority of the benefits triangle lies above the top line of the cost range, indicating that
the returns would generally be positive for mangrove blue carbon investments over this price range.
Break-even prices, the point at which blue carbon value equals the costs of protection, can further elucidate key thresh-
olds for blue carbon returns. When carbon stocks and costs of protection are both in the middle of the range, the break-
even price is $2.65/t CO2e. In the most optimistic scenario, carbon storage values would be high and protection costs
would be low, equating to a break-even price of $0.39/t CO2e here. On the other end of the spectrum, the least attrac-
tive scenario would involve low carbon stocks and high protection costs, and the break-even price would be $9.15/t
CO2e. Thus any carbon price above $9.15/t CO2e would result in a positive return, whether the actual mangrove carbon
storage ended up being low, high, or anywhere in between. Results for oceanic mangroves in tropical Asia are nearly
as compelling, though higher expected costs of protection for Asian countries mean a higher cost range. The resulting
break-even prices are $0.56, $4.91, and $17.37 for the most optimistic, mean, and least optimistic scenarios, respectively.
These cost-per-tonne numbers are in line with earlier country-level average cost estimates for emission reductions from
avoided deforestation in the tropics (Murray, Lubowski, and Sohngen 200933).
32. World Bank land value estimates, which are averaged with the GTAP values to calculate opportunity costs, tend to be high for
many Latin American countries.
33. Table 2.3 in that report shows carbon sequestration cost estimates from country-level research studies with average costs ranging
Nicholas Institute
30
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 22. Blue carbon results for oceanic mangroves in tropical Africa. The green triangle represents blue carbon benefits
(PV$/ha) for a range of mangrove carbon storage. The orange rectangle is the range of protection costs for the region.
$60,000
Range
of
Blue
carbon
benefits
$50,000
Range
of
Costs
of
ProtecFon
$40,000
PV
$/ha
$30,000
$20,000
$10,000
$0
$-‐
$5
$10
$15
$20
$25
$30
Carbon
price
($/tCO2e)
We turn now to results for key mangrove countries. Table 6 lists total mitigation potential and break-even price esti-
mates for the 25 countries with the largest current emissions from mangrove loss. 34 These 25 countries represent almost
92% of the global mangrove mitigation potential. For each country, the break-even price is the point at which blue
carbon value equals the cost of protection. The cost of protection is equivalent to the costs of establishing and manag-
ing protected areas plus the average of the opportunity costs derived from World Bank land values and from GTAP
land values. Annual mitigation potential for mangroves is the weighted average of oceanic and estuarine mangroves by
mangrove region. The results are for the mean estimated values of carbon storage and protection costs for each country.
A sensitivity analysis in Figure 24 provides a range of outcomes.
As indicated previously, Indonesia has the largest annual mitigation potential of any country, with nearly 30 million
tonnes of emission reductions from avoided mangrove conversion, roughly equal to the yearly emissions from all
sources (except land use) in New Zealand or Ecuador. The average break-even price for Indonesia is about $4 per
tonne of emissions avoided, which is in the top third of all country-specific estimates in Table 6. Eight countries offer
cheaper emissions reductions than Indonesia. Investors in carbon reductions will likely focus their efforts on countries
that appear to have the least expensive potential, though countries with large-scale mitigation potential may have lower
transaction costs. Overall, the cheapest reductions ($1.70 per tonne) are found in Senegal, while the most expensive are
found in Colombia ($11.31). Five of the top seven countries with the lowest break-even prices are in tropical Africa.
This result primarily reflects protection costs in Africa, which are the lowest of any region’s, but also reflects the fact
that African oceanic mangroves have the highest blue carbon values. The region with the most mitigation potential is
tropical Asia. That potential—well over half of the world’s—is largely explained by Indonesia’s contribution, but three
other tropical Asian countries are in the top five by mitigation potential: Papua New Guinea, Malaysia, and Vietnam.
from roughly $2 to $8 per tonne (2005 dollars). Subsequent supply function analysis uses more spatially refined data to show a wider
range of costs, with prices of $10 to $30 per tonne needed for large-scale global supply.
34. As with the results above, the mitigation potential estimates account for the time path of carbon release and thus have been
discounted using a 10% rate over a 25-year period. In addition, the biophysical mitigation potential estimates in Table 6 reflect
country-specific annual mangrove loss rates and have been adjusted to represent only lands that are at risk of conversion to agricul-
ture, aquaculture, or wood harvests (see Figure 9).
Nicholas Institute
31
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Table 6. Top 25 mangrove countries by break-even carbon price ($/t CO2e). Mitigation potential (t CO2e/yr) is discounted to
the present with a 10% rate as well as scaled down to represent only lands at risk from conversion to agriculture, aquaculture,
or wood harvests.
Country Break-even C Discounted Cumulative Annual mitigation Total mangrove Annual Revenue
price, avg cost mangrove mangrove revenue potential, area, 2005 (ha) potential ($/ha)
mitigation mitigation $/yr @$15/t CO2
potential potential
Senegal $1.70 1,342,843 1,342,843 $22,380,714 115,000 $194.61
We combine the break-even prices and mitigation quantities to construct an emission reduction supply curve for avoided
mangrove destruction in these 25 countries (see Figure 23). This supply curve roughly captures how much mitigation
quantity could be provided by these countries if they were compensated at levels sufficient to cover their costs of pro-
tection. These estimates are rough, because each country is treated as if it has one break-even price and one mitigation
quantity it can supply at that price. In reality, each country has its own internal supply function, reflecting its range of
protection costs and mitigation quantities, but we do not have the data to explore each country individually. Therefore,
the function in Figure 23 provides a relatively global sense of how rising levels of compensation could, on average,
bring on more countries and more mitigation. For instance, at a carbon price of $4/t CO2e, about 40 million tonnes of
mitigation might be supplied. At $6, another 20 million tonnes would come on, pushing the total to 60 million t CO2e.
At $8, the total supplied would approach 80 million tonnes. Because this supply function incorporates almost 92% of
global mangrove mitigation potential, we would not expect much change in the shape of the curve or mitigation supply
if we expanded the number of included mangrove countries.
Nicholas Institute
32
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Figure 23. Supply function of mitigation potential. Relates the annual mitigation potential (millions t CO2) to break-even
carbon prices ($/t CO2), accumulated across each of the key mangrove countries. As the price rises, more countries can eco-
nomically reduce emissions, and total mitigation quantity rises.
$12
COL
$10
USA
Breakeven
C
price
($/tCO2e)
$8
HND
PNG
$6
VNM
MMR
MEX
$4
TZA
IDN
y
=
2.1056e2E-‐08x
R²
=
0.91658
$2
MYS
SEN
$0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
Annual
MiIgaIon
PotenIal
(millions
tCO2e)
The supply function in Figure 23 reflects all economic and biophysical parameters at their mean values for each coun-
try. Figure 24 augments the story by showing the same “mean” supply function positioned between a version of the
function that reflects the high-end protection cost estimate for each country as well as the low-end cost estimate. The
result is quite a range of outcomes. For example, a price of $4/t CO2e is sufficient to supply around 40 million tonnes of
mitigation in the mean supply case, but only about 10 million tonnes in the high-cost case. For the same comparison
at $8/t CO2e, the mean case supplies nearly 80 million tonnes, while the high-cost case yields approximately 45 million
tonnes. The low-cost supply function estimate “peaks” at about $2 per tonne: prices above this level do not elicit more
mitigation, as all economically viable mitigation opportunities have been exhausted.
Figure 24. Mitigation potential supply functions for low-cost, mean, and high-cost scenarios. The low-cost scenario
assumes protection costs 50% lower than the mean costs. The high-cost scenario assumes protection costs 50% higher than
mean costs. The mean supply function uses mean costs (the average of World Bank and GTAP opportunity costs) and is the
same as presented in Figure 23. Both use the mean values of mangrove carbon stocks.
$24
Low
Cost
$20
Mean
Breakeven
C
price
($/tCO2e)
High
cost
y
=
3.5273e2E-‐08x
$16
R²
=
0.91226
$12
y
=
2.1056e2E-‐08x
$8
R²
=
0.91658
$4
y
=
0.3776e2E-‐08x
R²
=
0.54857
$0
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
Annual
MiIgaIon
PotenIal
(millions
tCO2e)
Shifting the focus to the total area of habitat that can be conserved, Figure 25 illustrates the quantity of habitat that
might be protected each year through payments for blue carbon to the top 25 mangrove countries. This graph provides
supply curves with the break-even prices shown on the Y-axis in Figure 24, but with millions of hectares of mangrove
Nicholas Institute
33
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
habitat at risk on the X-axis. Again, the range of supply from low- to high-cost scenarios is wide, especially at higher
levels of habitat protection. At $4 for a tonne of CO2e, the mean case would supply almost 0.4 Mha (or 400,000 hectares)
of protected mangrove habitat, whereas the high-cost case would yield less than 100,000 ha. The $8/t CO2e mark would
yield nearly 800,000 ha for the mean case and around 450,000 ha for the high-cost case. In the low-cost scenario, almost
all habitat at risk could be protected when the carbon price reaches $2. Overall, if a GHG compliance market allowing
blue carbon offsets were to come about, a carbon price of $15/t CO2e may not be unreasonable and could be sufficient
to protect all mangrove habitat considered here, even assuming high costs.
Figure 25. Mangrove habitat protection (area) supply functions for low-cost, mean, and high-cost scenarios. This figure
uses the same cost scenarios and mean mangrove carbon stock values as Figure 24. Mangrove habitat is the annual amount
of hectares at risk for conversion to agriculture, aquaculture, or wood harvests. Mha = million hectares.
$24
Low
Cost
Mean
$20
High
Cost
Breakeven
C
price
($/tCO2e)
$16
$12
$8
$4
$0
0.0
0.1
0.2
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Annual
Mangrove
Habitat
Protected
(Mha)
Nicholas Institute
34
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Areal extent
More spatially explicit datasets of areal extent, especially of seagrass and salt marsh habitats, are needed. Such datasets
are essential even for mangroves, the most data-rich of these systems. Note the wide discrepancies between the FAO
(2007) and Giri et al (2011) datasets on key countries such as Australia and Nigeria. Even if habitat areas are considered
intact (depending on mapping criteria), they may be degraded to some degree, which would affect ecosystem func-
tions, including carbon sequestration or storage. Estimating the proportion of extant habitat that is degraded would
be a next step.
• Amount of actually occurring disturbance for different drivers (we assume a disturbance depth of one meter
as a rough estimate across many driver types)
• Land values/opportunity costs
–– Among the few existing datasets based on agricultural returns, land values vary widely.
–– There is no dataset for coastal areas (worldwide or otherwise), which are perhaps the most fragile and
endangered habitats and a key to climate adaptation.
–– There has been no research in literature on opportunity costs for seagrass protection.
–– Study of local opportunities requires data for the area in question rather than the national numbers used
in this study.
• Establishment costs
–– There are limited data on protected-area establishment costs and transaction costs for blue carbon projects
and on how these costs might compare with those for other project types.
The average-cost break-even price analysis here provides a very rough first-order approximation of the economic poten-
tial for blue carbon mitigation, but it ignores much of the underlying heterogeneity of biophysical and economic pro-
cesses. Every country will have a range of conditions that will make some blue carbon emissions relatively cheap and
some blue carbon emissions relatively expensive to mitigate. Moreover, economic behavior is complicated: we cannot
simply expect all agents to go “all in” if break-even price conditions are met. More sophisticated models of supply behav-
ior at different prices are required to more realistically capture likely responses to economic incentives for blue carbon.
We need better understanding, both biophysical and economic, of habitat protection’s co-benefits—that is, ecosystem
services other than carbon storage and sequestration. These services (and especially their economic values) are often
location-specific, so additional research should be conducted across various locations and regions.
• How do these rights relate to the global politics of international carbon transfers?
• How do they affect current habitat conversion behavior?
• How can country-level institutions be designed to efficiently mobilize carbon protection?
Nicholas Institute
35
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
14. Conclusions
Because they store large amounts of carbon and are severely threatened in their natural state by the economic allure of
conversion, coastal ecosystems could be an ideal target for carbon financing. Although data on on-site carbon storage,
carbon emission profiles, and the costs of protection are somewhat elusive at this time, preliminary analysis of the type
presented here suggests that blue carbon protection could be economically viable in some important cases (mangrove
protection from agriculture and aquaculture uses in tropical Africa and tropical Asia) at the level of carbon prices we
now see in world markets (approximately $15 to $25 per tonne in the EU ETS).
Any verdict on the economic viability of blue carbon is far from complete, however. To begin with, there are no mar-
kets for credits generated by blue carbon activity. A logical venue for considering blue carbon payments would be the
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) process. At this time, the only blue carbon
activities that might be covered under UNFCCC compliance markets are mangrove restoration through the CDM and
mangrove protection under the auspices of the Reduced Emissions from Deforestation and Degradation (REDD+)
initiative advanced in the Cancún Agreement. However, even if protection is allowed under REDD+, it is unclear
whether avoided soil carbon emissions will be included, as the primary emphasis in REDD+ deliberations has been on
aboveground carbon stocks. If soil carbon is left out, the attractiveness of mangrove protection would be diminished
because a vast majority of the habitat’s carbon is stored below ground. Regardless of whether REDD+ can incorporate
mangrove protection, a broader consideration of all candidate blue carbon ecosystem types (including salt marshes and
seagrasses) and certainly an emphasis on the belowground carbon components of these ecosystems would be in order
to fully tap blue carbon mitigation potential. This broader consideration of blue carbon ecosystems could be coupled
with stakeholder-driven efforts to include all wetlands, agriculture, and all other major land uses under the auspices of
agriculture, forests, and other land uses (AFOLU) in global climate protection efforts.35
Aside from the compliance markets supported by UNFCCC action, there are other compliance markets in the United
States, Canada, Australia, and elsewhere as well as voluntary markets in which blue carbon could be considered in prin-
ciple. But as with the UNFCCC system, further work will be necessary to define the boundaries of blue carbon eligibility,
to propose methods for quantification, and to seek approval for inclusion in the market. The science on blue carbon
storage, drivers of conversion, and post-disturbance emission rates is nascent, and the available data are geographically
incomplete. More effort will be necessary to expand the knowledge set, define gaps, and characterize the uncertainty
attending serious consideration of blue carbon as a mitigation option in general. This effort will be particularly impor-
tant if blue carbon protection and restoration efforts are to be tied to markets, multilateral funds, or other institutions
in which money will change hands for specific outcomes such as tonnes of emissions avoided, carbon sequestered, or
area protected or restored.
This report has focused on the biophysical and economic potential for emission reductions from the avoided conver-
sion of blue carbon habitats. We focus on avoided conversion, which appears to have the highest potential for economic
returns in the carbon market or in payment systems emerging internationally. Current rates of habitat loss are high,
and the emissions effects are immediate. In principle, protection could be coupled with efforts to restore blue carbon
by returning some areas converted to agriculture or other uses back to native habitats that once again become net
carbon sinks and provide other ecosystem services. However, carbon removals associated with sequestration rates are
much smaller than emission reductions from avoided conversion and, as such, restoration actions would likely have
more modest economic returns, all else equal. Where habitat conversion has occurred recently and soil carbon releases
are ongoing, restoration could gain carbon credits for halting emissions. Moreover, taking land out of agricultural or
aquacultural development in places where it has already attracted migrating populations would be very difficult from
a broader economic and social perspective.
Our focus on the value of carbon and climate regulation in coastal habitats is not meant to devalue the importance of
the habitats’ many other ecosystem services, such as providing wildlife and fish habitat and maintaining water quality.
The value of these services, which are known to be substantial even if ignored by markets, may exceed both the habitats’
developed value and value as a carbon store. But carbon is where the most readily available money to pay for protection
may reside. If carbon payments create economic incentives sufficient to induce resource owners to forgo conversion or
35. See, in particular, the efforts of the Terrestrial Carbon Group to broaden the scope of land-based activities covered by interna-
tional agreements, such as the UNFCCC.
Nicholas Institute
36
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
undertake restoration efforts, these consequences are only improved by the fact that a whole range of other valuable
ecosystem services would come along for the ride.
In many ways, the blue carbon issue is in the same place that REDD+ was about five to ten years ago. There is widespread
recognition of the environmental and economic cost of coastal habitat destruction, frustration at the lack of success in
curtailing these losses through traditional conservation measures, and hope that the value of these ecosystems as a store
of carbon might align with international efforts to fight climate change and provide the economic incentives necessary
to avoid continued loss. Economic incentives for REDD+ are moving toward reality as the UNFCCC has embraced it
as part of the Cancún Agreement. For blue carbon to get to the same point as REDD+, the international community
must grasp the extent of the problem and determine whether climate policy is an appropriate means to address it. This
study, admittedly based on preliminary scientific and economic foundations, suggests that the scale of the problem is
large enough to warrant attention, that there exists a logical and synergistic tie between coastal habitat protection goals
and climate goals, and that there are economic opportunities to reduce blue carbon losses well in line with, or even less
than, the costs of many other mitigation options in the land and energy sectors.
Nicholas Institute
37
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
References
Adam, P. 2002. Salt marshes in a time of change. Environmental Conservation 29(1): 39–61.
Adams, V.M., et al. 2011. Improving social acceptability of marine protected area networks: A method for estimating
opportunity costs to multiple gear types in both fished and currently unfished areas. Biological Conservation
144(1): 350–361.
Alongi, D.M. 2008. Mangrove forests: Resilience, protection from tsunamis, and responses to global climate change.
Estuarine Coastal and Shelf Science 76(1): 1–13.
Gilman, E.L., et al. 2008. Threats to mangroves from climate change and adaptation options: A review. Aquatic Botany
89(2): 237–250.
Balmford, A., et al. 2003. Global variation in terrestrial conservation costs, conservation benefits, and unmet
conservation needs. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 100(3):
1046–1050.
Balmford, A., et al. 2004. The worldwide costs of marine protected areas. Proceedings of the National Academy of
Sciences of the United States of America 101(26): 9694–9697.
Barbier, E.B. 2007. Valuing ecosystem services as productive inputs. Economic Policy 49: 178–229.
Bell, F.W. 1997. The economic valuation of saltwater marsh supporting marine recreational fishing in the
southeastern United States. Ecological Economics 21: 243–254.
Blue Climate Coalition. 2010. Blue carbon solutions for climate change: An open statement to delegates of COP 16,
December 3. https://docs.google.com/viewer?a=v&pid=sites&srcid=ZGVmYXVsdGRvbWFpbnxibHVlY2xpbWF
0ZXNvbHV0aW9uc3xneDo2YmVjNTdjYjkxMjQ0NTM2&pli=1.
Boden, T.A., G. Marland, and R.J. Andres. 2010. Global, regional, and national fossil-fuel CO2 Emissions U.S.A. Oak
Ridge, Tennessee: Carbon Dioxide Information Analysis Center, Oak Ridge National Laboratory, U.S. Department
of Energy. doi 10.3334/CDIAC/00001_V2010.
Bouillion, S., et al. 2009. Mangroves. In The management of natural coastal carbon sinks, edited by D. Laffoley and G.
Grimsditch, 13–22. Gland, Switzerland: International Union for Conservation of Nature (IUCN).
Laffoley, D., and G. Grimsditch, eds. 2009. The management of natural coastal carbon sinks. Gland, Switzerland:
IUCN. http://www.iucn.org/what/tpas/climate/resources/publications/?uPubsID=3927.
Brevik, E.C., and J.A. Homburg. 2004. A 5,000-year record of carbon sequestration from a coastal lagoon and wetland
complex. Catena 57: 221–232.
Bridgham, S.D., J.P. Megonigal, et al. 2006. The carbon balance of North American wetlands. Wetlands, 26(4):
889–916.
Charpy-Roubaud, C., and A. Sournia. 1990. The comparative estimation of phytoplankton microphytobenthic
production in the oceans. Marine Microbial Food Webs 4: 31–57.
Chmura, G.L., S.C. Anisfeld, et al. 2003. Global carbon sequestration in tidal, saline wetland soils. Global
Biogeochemical Cycles 17(4): 1–12.
Chmura, G. 2009. Tidal salt marshes. In The management of natural coastal carbon sinks, edited by D. Laffoley and G.
Grimsditch, 5–11. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN.
Choi, Y., and Y. Wang. 2001. Vegetation succession and carbon sequestration in a coastal wetland in northwest
Florida: Evidence from carbon isotopes. Global Biogeochemical Cycles 15(2): 311–319.
Choi, Y., and Y. Wang. 2004. Dynamics of carbon sequestration in a coastal wetland using radiocarbon
measurements. Global Biogeochemical Cycles 18: GB4016.
Claudet, J., and S. Fraschetti. 2010. Human-driven impacts on marine habitats: A regional meta-analysis in the
Mediterranean Sea. Biological Conservation 143: 2195–2206.
Coleman, J.M., et al. 2008. Wetland loss in world deltas. Journal of Coastal Research 24: 1–14.
Connor, R.F., G. Chmura, et al. 2001. Carbon accumulation in Bay of Fundy salt marshes: Implications for restoration
of reclaimed marshes. Global Biogeochemical Cycles 15(4): 934–954.
Nicholas Institute
38
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Craft, C.B., and C.J. Richardson. 1998. Recent and long-term organic soil accretion and nutrient accumulation in the
Everglades. Soil Science Society of America Journal 62: 834–843.
Dahl, T.E. 2006. Status and trends of wetlands in the coterminous United States, 1998 to 2004. Washington, DC: U.S.
Department of the Interior, Fish and Wildlife Service.
Das, S., and J.R. Vincent. 2009. Mangroves protected villages and reduced death toll during Indian supercyclone.
Proceedings for the National Academy of Sciences of United States of America, 106(18): 7357–7360.
Day, J.W., et al. Pattern and process of land loss in the Mississippi Delta: A spatial and temporal analysis of wetland
habitat change. Estuaries 23: 425–438.
DeLaune, R.D., et al. 2003. Impacts of Mississippi River freshwater reintroduction on enhancing marsh accretionary
processes in a Louisiana estuary. Estuarine, Coastal and Shelf Science 58(3): 653–662.
Duarte, C.M. 1995. Submerged aquatic vegetation in relation to different nutrient regimes. Ophelia 41: 87–112.
Duarte, C.M., and C. L. Chiscano. 1999. Seagrass biomass and production: A reassessment. Aquatic Botany 65:
159–174.
Duarte, C.M., W.C. Dennison, et al. 2008. The charisma of coastal ecosystems: Addressing the imbalance. Estuaries
and Coasts 31: 233–238.
Duarte, C.M., N. Marba, et al. Forthcoming. Seagrass community metabolism: Assessing the carbon sink capacity of
seagrass meadows. Global Biogeochemical Cycles.
Duarte, C.M., J.J. Middelburg, et al. 2005. Major role of marine vegetation on the oceanic carbon cycle. Biogeosciences
2: 1–8.
Duarte, C.M., J.J. Middelburg, and N. Caraco. 2005. Major role of marine vegetation on the oceanic carbon cycle.
Biogeosciences 2: 1–8.
Duke, N.C., J.-O. Meynecke, et al. 2007. A world without mangroves? Science 317: 41–42.
Ellis, G.M., and A.C. Fisher. 1987. Valuing the environment as an input. Journal of Environmental Management 25:
149–156.
Emmer, I. 2010. A CDM A/R methodology for restoration of mangroves. Presentation, COP 16, Cancún, Mexico,
December 9. http://wetcarbon.earthmind.net/files/Mangrove-Meth-Cancun-2010.pdf.
FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization). 2005. Forest resource report. Rome: FAO.
FAO. 2007. The world’s mangroves, 1980–2005. FAO Forestry Paper 153. Rome: FAO.
Friedlingstein, P., et al. 2010. Update on CO2 emissions. Nature Geoscience 3: 811–812. doi:10.1038/ngeo1022.
Fujimoto, K., et al. 1999. Belowground carbon storage of Micronesian mangrove forests. Ecological Research 14:
409–413.
Gattuso, J.-P., B. Gentili, C.M. Duarte, J.A. Kleypas, J.J. Middelburg, and D. Antoinel. 2006. Light availability in the
coastal ocean: Impact on the distribution of benthic photosynthetic organisms and their contribution to primary
production. Biogeosciences 3: 489–513.
Gedan, K.B., B.R. Silliman, and M.D. Bertness. 2009. Centuries of human-driven change in salt marsh ecosystems.
Annual Review of Marine Science 1:117–141.
Giani, L., Y. Bashan, et al. 1996. Characteristics and methanogenesis of the Baladra Lagoon mangrove soils, Baja
California Sur, Mexico. Geoderma 72: 149–160.
Gilman, E.L., et al. 2008. Threats to mangroves from climate change and adaptation options: A review. Aquatic Botany
89(2): 237–250.
Giri, C., and J. Muhlhausen. 2008. Mangrove forest distributions and dynamics in Madagascar, 1975–2005. Sensors
8(4): 2104–2117.
Giri, C., Z. Zhu, L.L. Tieszen, A. Singh, S. Gillette, and J.A. Kelmelis. 2008. Mangrove forest distributions and
dynamics (1975–2005) of the tsunami-affected region of Asia. Journal of Biogeography 35(3): 519–528.
Giri, C., et al. 2011. Status and distribution of mangrove forests of the world using earth observation satellite data.
Global Ecology and Biogeography 20(1): 154–159.
Nicholas Institute
39
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Gonzalez-Correa, J.M., et al. 2005. Recovery of deep Posidonia oceanica meadows degraded by trawling. Journal of
Experimental Marine Biology and Ecology 320: 65–76.
Gunarwardena, M., and J.S. Rowan. 2005. Mangrove ecosystem and shrimp aquaculture in Sri Lanka. Environmental
Management 36(4): 535–550.
GTAP (Global Trade Assessment Program). 2007. Global Timber Market and Forestry Data Project (Version 5).
http://aede.osu.edu/people/sohngen.1/forests/GTM/index.htm.
Huang, Y., et al. 2009. Marshland conversion to cropland in northeast China from 1950 to 2000 reduced the
greenhouse effect. Global Change Biology 16: 680–695.
Hussein, A.H., M.C. Rabenhorst, et al. 2004. Modeling of carbon sequestration in coastal marsh soils. Soil Science
Society of America Journal 68: 1786–1795.
IISD (International Institute for Sustainable Development). 2010. Oceans Day Bulletin: A Summary Report of the
Oceans Day at Cancún 186 (1). http://www.iisd.ca/download/pdf/sd/ymbvol186num1e.pdf.
IPCC (Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change). 2007. Climate Change 2007: Synthesis Report. Valencia, Spain:
IPCC.
Islam et al. 2005. Production and economic return of shrimp aquaculture in coastal ponds of different sizes and with
different management regimes. Aquaculture International 13: 489–500.
Jennerjahn, T.C., and V. Ittekkot. 2002. Relevance of mangroves for the production and deposition of organic matter
along tropical continental margins. Naturwissenschaften 89: 23–30.
Johnson, B.J., et al. 2007. Middle to late Holocene fluctuations of C3 and C4 vegetation in a northern New England
salt marsh, Sprague Marsh, Phippsburg Maine. Organic Geochemistry 38: 398–403.
Klein, C.J., et al. 2010. Prioritizing land and sea conservation investments to protect coral reefs. PLOS One 5 (8):
e12431. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0012431.
Krithika, K., R. Purvaja, and R. Ramesh. 2008. Fluxes of methane and nitrous oxide from an Indian mangrove.
Current Science 94(2): 218–224.
Laffoley, D., and G. Grimsditch, eds. 2009. The management of natural coastal carbon sinks. Gland, Switzerland:
International Union for Conservation of Nature and Natural Resources.
Lane, R.R., et al. 2006. Wetland surface elevation, vertical accretion, and subsidence at three Louisiana estuaries
receiving diverted Mississippi river water. Wetlands 26: 1130–1142.
Lewis, S.L., et al. 2009. Increasing carbon storage in intact African tropical forests. Nature 457(7232): 1003–U3.
Lotze, H.K., et al. 2006. Depletion, degradation, and recovery potential of estuaries and coastal seas. Science
312(5781): 1806–1809.
Lynne, G.D., et al. 1981. Economic valuation of marsh areas for marine production processes. Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 8: 175–186.
Malhi, Y. et al. 2009. Comprehensive assessment of carbon productivity, allocation, and storage in three Amazonian
forests. Global Change Biology 15(5): 1255–1274.
Marba, N. 2009. Loss of seagrass meadows from the Spanish coast: Results of the Praderas project. In Global loss of
coastal habitats: Rates, causes, and consequences, edited by C.M. Duarte. (Bilbao, Spain: Fundación BBVA).
Marsden, D., and U.R. Sumaila. 2010. Investments in marine managed areas: A preliminary analysis. Science2Action.
http://www.science2action.org/files/sciencereports/individualstudies/global/globalcosteffectiveness.pdf.
McCrea-Strub, A., et al. 2011. Understanding the cost of establishing marine protected areas. Marine Policy 35 (1):
1–9.
Meitrodt, J., and A. Kuriloff. 2003. Affixing value to beds a slippery affair. Times Picayune, May 4. Accessed at http://
www.nola.com/speced/shellgame/index.ssf?/speced/shellgame/value04.html.
Morgan, P.A., and F. T. Short. 2002. Using functional trajectories to track constructed salt marsh development in the
Great Bay Estuary, Maine/New Hampshire U.S.A. Restoration Ecology 10(3): 461–473.
Nicholas Institute
40
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
Mudd, S. M., et al. 2009. Impact of dynamic feedbacks between sedimentation, sea-level rise, and biomass production
on near-surface marsh stratigraphy and carbon accumulation. Estuarine Coastal and Shelf Science 82: 377–389.
Murdiyarso, D., D. Donato, J.B. Kauffman, S. Kurnianto, M. Stidham, and M. Kanninen. 2010. Carbon storage in
mangrove and peatland ecosystems: A preliminary account from plots in Indonesia. CIFOR Working Paper 48.
Murray, B.C., R. Lubowski, and B. Sohngen. 2009. Including reduced emissions from international forest carbon in
climate policy: Understanding the economics. Report NI-R-09-03. Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy
Solutions, Duke University. http://www.nicholas.duke.edu/institute/carbon.economy.06.09.pdf.
Nellemann, C., E. Corcoran, et al. 2009. Blue Carbon: A Rapid Response Assessment. New York: United Nations
Environment Programme.
Pidgeon, E. 2009. Carbon sequestration by coastal marine habitats: Important missing sinks. In The management of
natural coastal carbon sinks, edited by D. Laffoley and G. Grimsditch. Gland, Switzerland: IUCN.
Poffenbarger H., B. Needelman, J.P. Megonigal. Forthcoming. Salinity influence on methane emissions from tidal
marshes. Wetlands.
PWA (Philip Williams & Associates, Ltd.) and SAIC (Science Applications International Corporation). 2009.
Greenhouse Gas Mitigation Typology Issues Paper: Tidal Wetlands Restoration. Report by PWA and SAIC to the
California Climate Action Registry. February 4, 2009
Sathirai, S., and E. Barbier. 2001. Valuing mangrove conservation in southern Thailand. Contemporary Economic
Policy 19 (2): 109–122.
Short, F.T., and S. Wyllie-Echeverria. 1996. Natural and human-induced disturbance of seagrasses. Environmental
Conservation 23(1): 17–27.
Smith, J.E., et al. 2006. Methods for calculating forest ecosystem and harvested carbon with standard estimates for
forest types of the United States. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Forest Service, Northeastern Research Station:
216.
Smith, M.D., et al. 2010. Political economy of marine reserves: Understanding the role of opportunity costs.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America. Washington, DC: National
Academy of Sciences.
Spaulding et al. 2010. World atlas of mangroves. London: Earthscan.
Stokstad, E. 2010. Down on the shrimp farm. Science 238: 1504–1505.
Thornton C. et al., 2003. From wetlands to wastelands: Impacts of shrimp farming. Wetland Science and Practice 20
(1): 48–53.
Twilley, R.R., R.H. Chen, et al. 1992. Carbon sinks in mangroves and their implications to carbon budget of tropical
ecosystems. Water, Air, and Soil Pollution 63: 265–288.
Unsworth, R.K.F., et al. 2010. Economic and subsistence values of the standing stocks of seagrass fisheries: Benefits of
no-fishing marine protected area management. Ocean and Coastal Management 53: 218–224.
UNEP-WCMC (United Nations Environmental Programme World Conservation Monitoring Centre) and TNC (The
Nature Conservancy). 2010. Saltmarsh (version 1.0) of the provisional global point dataset developed jointly by
UNEP-WCMC and TNC. This dataset is incomplete.
UNEP-WCMC and International Society for Mangrove Ecosystems (ISME). 1997. Mangroves (version 3.0) of the
global polygon dataset compiled by UNEP-WCMC in collaboration with ISME. For further information, e-mail
spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
UNEP-WCMC. 2006. Mangroves of Western Central Africa raster dataset processed from Landsat imagery, circa
2000. Compiled by UNEP-WCMC, 2006. For further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
UNEP-WCMC. 2006. East African mangroves extracted from version 4.0 of the polygon dataset compiled by UNEP-
WCMC, 2006. For further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
UNEP-WCMC. 2005. Seagrasses (version 2.0) of the global polygon and point dataset compiled by UNEP-WCMC.
For further information, e-mail spatialanalysis@unep-wcmc.org.
Nicholas Institute
41
Green Payments for Blue Carbon
Economic Incentives for Protecting Threatened Coastal Habitats
UNFCCC (United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change). 2010. Outcome of the work of the Ad Hoc
Working Group on long-term cooperative action under the Convention. Draft decision -/CP.16. http://unfccc.int/
files/meetings/cop_16/application/pdf/cop16_lca.pdf.
United Nations. 2011. Millennium development goals indicators. Carbon dioxide emissions by country. http://mdgs.
un.org/unsd/mdg/SeriesDetail.aspx?srid=749&crid.
U.S. Army Corps of Engineers. 1998. Caernarvon Freshwater Diversion Project. Accessed at http://www.mvn.usace.
army.mil/prj/caernarvon/caernarvon.htm.
U.S. EPA (Environmental Protection Agency). 2005. Emission facts: Greenhouse gas emissions from a typical
passenger vehicle. EPA Publication 420-F-05-004. http://www.epa.gov/oms/climate/420f05004.htm.
Valiela, I., J.L. Bowen, et al. 2001. Mangrove forests: One of the world’s threatened major tropical environments.
BioScience 51(10): 807–815.
Watson, R.A., R.G. Coles, and W.J. LeeLong. 1993. Simulation estimates of annual yield and landed value for
commercial penaeid prawns from a tropical seagrass habitat, Northern Queensland, Australia. Marine and
Freshwater Research 44 (1): 211–220.
Waycott, M., C.M. Duarte, et al. 2009. Accelerating loss of seagrasses across the globe threatens coastal ecosystems.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 106(30): 12377–12381.
World Bank. 2011. The changing wealth of nations: Measuring sustainable development in the new millennium.
Washington, DC: The World Bank.
Yang, S.L., et al. 2006. Drastic decrease in sediment supply from the Yangtze River and its challenge to coastal wetland
management. Geophysical Research Letters 33: L06408. doi:10.1029/2005GL025507.
Yu, O.T., and G.L. Chmura. 2009. Soil carbon may be maintained under grazing in a St. Lawrence estuary tidal
marsh. Environmental Conservation 36(4): 312–320.
Nicholas Institute
42
the Nicholas Institute
The Nicholas Institute for Environmental Policy Solutions at Duke University
is a nonpartisan institute founded in 2005 to help decision makers in gov-
ernment, the private sector, and the nonprofit community address critical
environmental challenges. The Institute responds to the demand for high-
quality and timely data and acts as an “honest broker” in policy debates by
convening and fostering open, ongoing dialogue between stakeholders
on all sides of the issues and providing policy-relevant analysis based on
academic research. The Institute’s leadership and staff leverage the broad
expertise of Duke University as well as public and private partners world-
wide. Since its inception, the Institute has earned a distinguished reputation
for its innovative approach to developing multilateral, nonpartisan, and
economically viable solutions to pressing environmental challenges.