Econ 281 Chapter05
Econ 281 Chapter05
1
Chapter 5 – The Theory of Demand
3
Y (units)
Demand and Optimal Choice
PX = 4
0 XA=2 XB=10 X (units)
4
Y (units)
Demand and Optimal Choice
•
•
PX = 4 PX = 2
0 XA=2 XB=10 20 X (units)
5
Y (units) 5.1 The Price Consumption Curve
10
Price consumption curve
•
• •
PX = 1
PX = 4 PX = 2
0 XA=2 XB=10 XC=16 20 X (units)
6
Example: Individual Demand Curve for X
PX
PX = 4 •
PX = 2 •
PX = 1 • U increasing
X
XA=2 XB=10 XC=16 7
5.2 Deriving the Demand Curve
2) Pxx + Py(Px/Py)x = I
Pxx + Pxx = I
3) x= I/2Px
9
Specific Demand Example
Let U=xy, therefore MUx=y and MUy=x
Let income=12, Py=1.
Graph demand as Px increases from $1 to $2 to
$3.
Step 1: Pxx+Pyy=I
Pxx+y=12
Step 2: MUx/MUy=Px/Py
y/x=Px 10
Demand Example
Step 1: Pxx+y=12
Step 2: y=Pxx
Step 3: Pxx+Pxx=12
x=6/Px
X(1)=6
X(2)=3
X(3)=2 11
PX Demand Example
PX = 3 •
PX = 2 • U increasing
PX = 1 •
X
2 3 6 12
Y (units)
Demand, Choice and Income
At a given income, a consumer maximizes
using tangency as seen below:
10
I = 10
0 XA=2 XB=10 X (units)
13
Y (units)
Demand, Choice, and Income
I=12
I = 10
0 XA=2 20 X (units)
14
XB=3
Y (units) 5.3 The Income Consumption Curve
10
Income consumption curve
•
• •
0 20 X (units)
15
The Income Consumption & Demand Curves
Y (units)
I=92
I=68
U3
U2
Income consumption curve
I=40
U1
0 X (units)
10 18 24
PX
$2
I=40 I=68 I=92
10 18 24
X (units) 16
The income consumption curve for good x also
can be written as the quantity consumed of good
x for any income level. This is the individual’s
Engel Curve for good x.
When the income consumption curve is
positively sloped, the slope of the Engel
curve is positive.
17
I ($)
“X is a normal good”
Engel Curve
92
68
40
0 10 18 24 X (units)
18
• If the income consumption curve shows that the
consumer purchases more of good x as her income
rises, good x is a normal good.
• Equivalently, if the slope of the Engel curve is
positive, the good is a normal good.
0 X (units)
13 16 18
I ($)
200
X (units) 21
13 16 18
5.5 Substitution and Income Effects
When the price of a good decreases, two
effects occur:
1) The good is cheaper compared to other
goods; consumers will substitute the
cheaper good for more expensive goods
2) Consumers experience an increase in
purchasing power similar to an increase
in income
22
Definition: As the price of x falls, all else
constant, purchasing power rises. This is called
the income effect of a change in price.
23
As the price of x falls, all else constant, good x
becomes cheaper relative to good y. This change in
relative prices alone causes the consumer to adjust
his/ her consumption basket. This effect is called the
substitution effect.
The substitution effect always is negative
Usually, a move along a demand curve will
be composed of both effects.
Graphically, these effects can be
distinguished as follows…
24
Y (units)
Example: Normal Good: Income and
Substitution Effects
BL2
BL1 Let Px decrease
A
• C
B
•
• U1
U2
BLd
Substitution
Income
0 X (units)
XA XB XC
25
Y (units) Example: Inferior Good: Income and Substitution
Effects
BL2 “X is an inferior good”
C
A • BL1
• U2
B BLd
• U1
Income
Substitution
0 XA XC XB X (units)
26
Finding the DECOMPOSITION Budget Line
A Slope of Bd = -Px2/Py
• C
•
• B U2 BLd
Substitution U1
Income
0 X (units)
XA XB XC
28
Steps to Finding Substitution and Income Effects:
4) Solve:
a) Substitution Effect: xB-xA
b) Income Effect: xC-xB
30
31
Solving for x:
x = 1/(Px2)
x = 1/(0.5)2
x=4
Pxx + Pyy = 10
0.2(25) + (1)y = 10
yC =5
33
3) What are the substitution and income effects
that result from the decline in Px?
Decomposition basket (New Prices, Old Utility)
Tangency:
MUx/MUy = Px/Py
1/x1/2 = .2
xb=25
U = 2x1/2 + y
12 = 2(25)1/2 + y
yB = 2
Substitution Effect: xB-xA = 25 - 4 = 21
Income Effect: xC-xB = 25 - 25 = 0
34
Giffen Goods
If a good is so inferior that the net effect of a price
decrease of good x, all else constant, is a decrease in
consumption of good x, good x is a Giffen good.
Substitution
0 X (units)
XC XA XB
36
The individual’s demand curve can be seen as the individual’s
willingness to pay curve.
On the other hand, the individual must only actually pay the
market price for (all) the units consumed.
For example, you may be willing to pay $40 for a haircut, but
upon arriving at the stylist, discover that the price is only $30
Q* Quantity39
Efficiency of the Equilibrium Quantity
Price Consumer Surplus = area of triangle
$16 =1/2bh
=1/2(16-8)(10)
=40
Consumer
Surplus (This calculation
Only works for
$8
A linear demand
curve)
10 Quantity40
Consumer Surplus Example 1
P=20-Q
10=20-Q
10=Q, Craig buys 10 model cars
O X (units)
44
Y (units) Equivalent Variation
Q
-A change in the price of x shifts BL1 to BL2
D
• -Consumption moves from point A to point C
-A BL at old prices that would make the equivalent
N
•A move to the new utility is parallel to BL1
C
• U2
-NQ represents the money
equivalent to a price change,
resulting in consumption at D
(if Py=1)
U1
BL2
BL1
O X (units)
45
Y (units) Compensating and Equivalent Variation
Q
-Here a price DECREASE
D occurs
N
• -MN is the max amount a
consumer would PAY for this
•A B price decrease
M • U2
-NQ is the amount a
consumer would be PAID
C
• instead of a price decrease
U1
BL2
BL1
O X (units)
46
CV and EV Steps
1) Calculate ORIGINAL and NEW consumption
points that maximize utility. (Use tangency
condition.)
2) Calculate ORIGINAL and NEW utility.
3a) Compensating Variation:
With ORIGINAL UTILITY and NEW PRICES,
minimize expenditure ECV
CV=I-ECV
3b) Equivalent Variation:
With FINAL UTILITY and ORIGINAL PRICES,
minimize expenditure EEV 47
EV=E -I
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Hosea’s utility demand for mini xylophones and
yogurt (x and y) is represented by U=x2+y2
MUx=2x MUy=2y.
O X (units)
51
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Compensating variation: at the new prices (budget line
parallel to the new budget line), minimize expenditure to
achieve the original utility.
MUx/Px=MUy/Py
2x/1=2y/1
X=Y
U=x2+y2
80=x2+x2
40=x2
401/2=x
401/2=y 52
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Compensating variation: at the new prices (budget line
parallel to the new budget line), minimize expenditure to
achieve the original utility.
401/2=x
401/2=y
PxX+PyY=I
X+Y=I
2(401/2)=I
12.65=ECV
53
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Compensating variation: the maximum amount a
consumer will pay to receive a price discount
CV=Original I-ECV
CV=20-12.65
CV=7.35
54
Y (units) Equivalent Variation
Q
Given the old prices, minimize expenditure
D to achieve the new utility
•
N
•A
B
• U2
U1
BL2
BL1
O X (units)
55
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Equivalent variation: at the old prices (budget line
parallel to the old budget line), minimize expenditure to
achieve the new utility.
MUx/Px=MUy/Py
2x/2=2y/1
X=2Y
U=x2+y2
200=4y2+y2
40=y2
401/2=y
2(401/2)=x 56
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Equivalent variation: at the old prices (budget line
parallel to the old budget line), minimize expenditure to
achieve the new utility.
401/2=y
2(401/2)=x
PxX+PyY=I
2X+Y=I
2(2(401/2))+401/2=I
31.62=EEV
57
Consumer Surplus Example 2
Equivalent variation: the minimum amount a
consumer would have to be paid to be as well off
as a price decrease
EV=EEV-Original I
EV=31.62-20
EV=11.62
However,
If the income effect is zero, CV=CS=EV
-ie: Quasi-Linear Utility functions.
59
COMPENSATING VARIATION:
EQUIVALENT VARIATION:
Final Utility and old prices
60
In the economy, each market has many individuals
demanding a good
Each individual maximizes their own utility when
deciding on the amount they will buy
Each individual has a maximum price they will pay
and a maximum amount of the item they would want
Ie: I’d pay $5 per episode of House, up to 20
episodes…how much would you pay?
The sum of individual demand creates market
demand 61
Consider the following individuals’ demand for Sushi:
Price $1 $2 $3 $4
Craig’s 8 6 4 2
Demand
Kristy’s 6 3 0 0
Demand
Total 14 9 4 2
Demand 62
Price
Market Demand
$4 •
DK DC
$2 • • •
DM
O 6 9 63
2 3 Sushi
Algebraically the demand curves are as follows:
10 2 P when P 5
QC ( P) {
0 when P 5
9 3P when P 3
Qk ( P) {
0 when P 3
These combine to give us :
19 5 P when P 3
Qm ( P) {10 - 2P when 3 P 5
0 when P 5 64
Price
Market Demand
In section A of market demand, Qm=Qc+QK.
(it is important to add the normal form:
Q=f(P), not the inverse form: P=f(Q).)
In section B of market demand, Qm=QC.
$4 •
$2 • • •
DM
DK DC
O 6 9 65
2 3 Sushi
P P P
Q = 10 - p
10
Q = 10 - p Q = 20 - 5p Q = 30 - 6p
4
Q Q Q
Consumer 1 Consumer 2 Aggregate demand
67
Assume:
“Labor” includes all work hours when the consumer is
earning income. (L hours per day at wage rate w per
hour. Let w = $5)
U= U(y,l)
68
The composite good, y, has price py = $1
•Daily income = wL
The budget line gives all the combinations of y
and l that the consumer can afford.
If l = 24, y = 0
If l = 0, y = 120
Slope of budget line is -$5.
max U U ( y, l )
l
s.t. 24 L l
s.t. y Lw 69
Y (units) Labour and Leisure
600
w=25
As wage is increasing, a consumer’s
maximization may cause him/her to increase
480 w=20 or decrease leisure:
360 w=15
w=10
240
••
120
w=5
•
•
•
O
Leisure (l) 70
The substitution effect leads to less leisure
and more labor as w increases.
U3
•C
240 W=15 B
• •A
Income
120
•24
Substitution
12 13 14 15 Leisure (hours)
Substitution Effect (LB-LA) Income Effect (LC-LB) 73
Chapter 5 Key Concepts
Deriving Demand
Price Consumption Curve
Demand Curve
Income Consumption Curve
Engel Curve
Substitution and Income Effects
Decomposition Budget Line
Consumer Surplus
74
Chapter 5 Key Concepts
Compensating & Equivalent Variation
Market Demand
Labor and Leisure
Backwards Bending Labor Supply
75