0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views46 pages

Topic 5 Demand

The document discusses the concept of demand in economics, focusing on deriving demand curves, the effects of income changes, and the impact of price increases on demand. It explains how demand functions can be derived using different utility functions and how changes in income and prices affect consumer choices. Additionally, it highlights the distinction between normal and inferior goods and the effects of substitution and income on demand.

Uploaded by

ronnie56
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
11 views46 pages

Topic 5 Demand

The document discusses the concept of demand in economics, focusing on deriving demand curves, the effects of income changes, and the impact of price increases on demand. It explains how demand functions can be derived using different utility functions and how changes in income and prices affect consumer choices. Additionally, it highlights the distinction between normal and inferior goods and the effects of substitution and income on demand.

Uploaded by

ronnie56
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPTX, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 46

Topic 5

Demand

I have enough money to


last me the rest of my
life, unless I buy
something.
Jackie Mason

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Topic 5 Outline
4.1 Deriving Demand Curves
4.2 Effects of an Increase in Income
4.3 Effects of a Price Increase

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Motivating example: Paying Employees
to Relocate
• Background:
– International firms are increasingly relocating workers
throughout their home countries and internationally.
– Firms must decide how much compensation to offer
workers to move.

• Question:
– Do firms’ standard compensation packages
overcompensate workers by paying them more than
necessary to induce them to move to a new location?

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Deriving Demand Curve
• Ceteris paribus, a change in the price of a good will cause
a movement along the demand curve.
• As we saw this in topic 2:

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Deriving Demand Curves
• In topic 4, we used calculus to maximize consumer utility
subject to a budget constraint.
– This results is finding the consumer’s system of
demand functions for the goods.
• Example: q1 = pizza and q2 = burritos
– Demand functions express these quantities in terms of
the prices of both goods and income:
q1 Z ( p1, p2 ,Y )
q2 B( p1, p2 ,Y )
– Given a specific utility function, we can find closed-form
solutions for the demand functions.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Example: Deriving Demand Curves
• Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) utility function:
1

U (q1, q2 ) (q1  q ) , 0  1
 
2

• Budget constraint:
Y  p1q1  p2q2
• With the techniques in topic 4, we obtain the demand
functions resulting from this constrained optimization
problem:
Yp1  Yp2 
q1  1  1  q2  1 
p1  p2 p1  p21 

• Demand is a function of prices and income.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Example: Deriving Demand Curves
• Cobb-Douglas utility function:
U (q1, q2 ) q1aq21 a

• Budget constraint:
Y  p1q1  p2q2
• Thee demand functions that result from this constrained
optimization problem are:
Y Y
q1 a q2 (1  a )
p1 p2
• With Cobb-Douglas utility, demand of a good is a function of
only the good’s own-price and income.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Deriving Demand Curves
• Figure below shows the demand curve under Cobb-Douglas
preferences, i.e. q1= aY/p1, holding Y fixed and varying p1.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Deriving Demand Curves
• Figure below shows the demand curve under perfect
substitutes preferences when i = j =1, holding Y fixed and
varying p1.

MRS = 1 < p1/ p2 so q1* = 0

MRS = 1 = p1/ p2 so 0 ≤ q1* ≤ Y/ p1


MRS = 1 > p1/ p2 so
q1* = Y/ p1

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Demand Functions for Five Utility
Functions

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.1 Deriving Demand Curves Graphically
• As the price of beer falls, the MRT changes and the budget constraint
pivots out around the point where the consumer only buys the other
good.

– This traces
out the
points along
the demand
curve.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Effects of a
Budget Increase
• Income increases do not
change the MRT
• The budget set expands
through a series of parallel
shifts.
– This traces out points
along the Engel curve.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Effects of a Budget Increase: An
example
• Mahdu views Coke and Pepsi as perfect substitutes. In
addition, he likes them equally.
• The price of a can of Coke, p, is less than the price of a
can of Pepsi, p*.
– What does Mahdu’s Engel curve for Coke look like?
– How much does his weekly cola budget have to rise for
Mahdu to buy one more can of Coke per week?

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Effects of a
Budget
Increase: An
example
• As Mahdu’s
income increases,
the budget
constraint shifts
out
– This traces out
points along
the Engel
curve in.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Quasi-linear Indifference Curves

x2 Each curve is a vertically shifted


copy of the others.
Each curve intersects
both axes.

x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x2

x1
~
x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
x2

y Engel
curve
for
good 1
x1 ~ x1*
x1
~
x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility y Engel
x2 curve
for
good 2
x2*

x1
~
x1
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility y Engel
x2 curve
for
good 2
x2*
y Engel
curve
for
good 1
x1 ~ x1*
x1
~
x1
4.2 Effects of an Increase in Income
• An increase in an individual’s income, ceteris paribus,
causes a shift of their demand curve.
– An expansion of demand (a shift away from the origin)
if the good is a normal good
– A contraction (a shift toward the origin) if the good is
inferior.
• A change in income prompts the consumer to choose a
new optimal bundle.
• The result of the change in income and the new utility
maximizing choice can be depicted in three different ways.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Effects of an Increase in Income

1. Income-consumption curve: using the consumer


utility maximization diagram, connects optimal
consumption bundles as income varies

2. Shifts in demand curve: using the demand diagram,


shows how quantity demanded changes for a given
price of the good

3. Engel curve: shows the relationship between income


and quantity demanded [positive for normal goods,
inverse for inferior]

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Consumer Theory and Income
Elasticities
• Recall the income elasticity of demand from topic 3:
percentage change in quantity demanded Q / Q Q Y
“xi”   
percentage change in income Y / Y Y Q

• Normal goods, have a positive income elasticity.

– Luxury goods are normal goods with an income


elasticity greater than 1.
– Necessity goods are normal goods with an income
elasticity between 0 and 1.
• Inferior goods (no value judgment intended) have a
negative income elasticity

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Examples of Income Elasticities
• Some of the better-known examples of inferior goods are
starchy foods such as potatoes and cassava, which very
poor people eat in large quantities because they are cheap
but nutritious
• Bezmen and Depken (2006) estimated that pirated goods
are inferior: A 1% increase in per capita income leads to a
0.25% reduction in piracy
• Income elasticity for beer is 0.88 and that for wine is 1.38,
according to estimates for the average American consumer

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Your turn
• Suppose that an individual allocates his or her entire
budget between two goods, food and clothing. Can
both goods be inferior?

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Income-Consumption Curve and
Income Elasticities
• The shape of the income-consumption curve (ICC) for two
goods tells us the sign of their income elasticities.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.2 Income-Consumption Curve and
Income Elasticities
• Some goods can be both
normal and inferior,
depending on an
individual’s income level
– E.g. Fast-food meals.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Effects of a Price Increase
• Ceteris paribus, an increase in the price of a good has two
effects on an individual’s demand, one obvious, the other
not so much:
1. Substitution effect: the consumer substitutes away
from the now more expensive good.
2. Income effect: the consumer’s purchasing power has
decreased.
Why? They would need more income to buy the
same bundle as before
• The total change in quantity demanded is the sum of the
substitution and income effects.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects
• The direction of the substitution effect is always negative.
– When the price increases, individuals consume less of
the now more expensive good
• The direction of the income effect depends upon whether
the good is normal or inferior
– When the good is normal, the income effect is negative

– When the good is inferior, the income effect is


positive
• When the income and substitution effect go in opposite
directions the total effect is ambiguous

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects: An
example
• Jackie’s choice between music tracks and live music:
• U = q10.4q20.6 ; live music p2 = £1, music tracks p1 = £0.5
• Suppose the price of music tracks rises to £1 => Jackie’s
budget constraint pivots inward
• Jackie’s opportunity set is smaller; she has fewer bundles
of music tracks and live music to chose from
• Because her utility is Cobb-Douglas we know

• Her optimal bundle before the price rise is q1*=24 and


q2*=18, and after is q1**=12, q2**=18.
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects: An
example
• The decrease in q1 from 24 to 12 is the total effect from the
rise in the price of music tracks
• We can decompose the total effect into a substitution effect
and an income effect
• One method for doing this is to clean the income effect by
compensating Jackie income so her utility stays constant
• Then we find her quantity demanded under this
compensated change in the price.
• The income effect is the difference holding the prices
constant

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects: An
example
• Beginning from budget
constraint , an
L 1

increase in the price of


music tracks rotates
budget constraint into
L2 .
– The total effect of this
price change, a
decrease in quantity of
12 tracks per quarter,
can be decomposed
into income and
substitution effects
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects: An
example
• Because the income effect is negative, we can infer that
music tracks is a normal good
• In addition, that means the total effect is unambiguously
negative: Jackie buys fewer music tracks when their price
rises
• But what
about live music?

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Another example: Income Effect
with Perfect Complements
• Kathy loves having apple pie à la mode (with one scoop of
vanilla ice cream on top). That is, she consumes apple pie
and vanilla ice cream in fixed proportions
• At the initial prices, she consumed two pieces of pie per
week
• After the price of pie rises, she chooses to consume only
one piece of pie
• Let’s show on a graph the substitution, income, and total
effects of the price change

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Another example: Income Effect
with Perfect Complements
• Beginning from budget
constraint L1, an
increase in the price
of pie rotates budget
constraint into
L2 .
– The total effect of this price
change with perfect
complements equals the
income effect
– With perfect complements
there is no substitution
effect
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects
with an Inferior (Giffen) Good
• If a good is inferior, the income effect and the substitution
effects move in opposite directions
• For most inferior goods, the income effect is smaller than
the substitution effect, so the total effect remains negative,
i.e. the demand decreases when the price increases
• However, for Giffen goods, the income effect more than
offsets the substitution effect and demand increases when
the price increases
• Let’s see this at work in the case of Ximing, who spends
his money on rice, an inferior good, and all other goods.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
4.3 Income and Substitution Effects
with an Inferior (Giffen) Good
• Beginning from budget
constraint L , a
1

decrease in the price


of rice pivots the
budget constraint into
L2 .
– The total effect of this
price change is a
decrease in the
demand of rice because
the negative income
effect outweighs the
substitution effect

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Your turn
• Place the following goods in the table below according to
the size of the income and substitution effect you would
expect after a price increase
Income effect
Small Large

Small
Substitution
effect
Large

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Compensated Demand Curve
• We have constructed a demand curve by seeing how the
quantity purchased changes as the product price
changes while allowing utility to vary
• This is sometimes called the Marshallian demand curve, or
the uncompensated demand curve.
• Alternatively, we could derive the compensated demand
curve by holding utility constant as the price changes, so
that the change in the quantity demanded reflects only the
pure substitution effect
• This is also called the Hicksian demand curve

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Hicksian Demand Curve

• We cannot observe the compensated demand curve


directly because we do not observe utility levels
• Because the compensated demand curve reflects only
substitution effects, the Law of Demand must hold: The
compensated demand for a good is decreasing in its price
• One way to derive the compensated demand curve is to
use the expenditure function where E is
the smallest expenditure that allows the consumer to
achieve utility level given market prices.

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Compensated Demand Curve: An
example
• Consumer with Cobb-Douglas utility U = q1a q21 - a
• We’ll use the Lagrange method to solve the expenditure-
minimizing problem:

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
• FOCs

• Use the first two to obtain

• Plugging this back

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Going back to our compensated
demand question

• In the particular case a = 0.4

Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved
Motivating example solution
• Relocate from Seattle to London
• Budget line in Seattle is Ls
Worker buys s. Utility is I .
1

• Housing is relatively more


expensive in London. Budget
line L .is steeper
L

• Worker consumes l and


utility is I .
2

• Firm just needs to compensate


the worker with L* to induce
them to move. Worker
consumes l* and utility is I 1.
• Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy