Chapter 2
Chapter 2
also represent the perfect substitutes preferences, as would any other monotonic
transformation of u(x1, x2), as would any other monotonic transformation of u(x1, x2).
In general, preferences for perfect substitutes can be represented by a utility
function of the form u(x1, x2) = ax1 + bx2
With a and b are some positive numbers measuring the “value” of goods 1 and 2 to
the consumer. And the slope of a typical indifference curve is given by −a/b
UTILITY FUNCTION- PERFECT
COMPLEMENTS
• Pick a bundle of goods such as (10, 10). If we add one more unit of
good 1 we get (11, 10)
min{10,10} = min{11,10} = 10
• In general, a utility function that describes perfect-complement
preferences is given by u(x1, x2) = min{ax1, bx2}
UTILITY FUNCTION- QUASILINEAR
PREFERENCES
where c and d are positive numbers that describe the preferences of the consumer
This measures the rate of change in utility (ΔU) associated with a small change in
the amount of good 1 (Δx1). Note that the amount of good 2 is held fixed in this
calculation.
=>
MARGINAL UTILITY AND MRS
• Consider a change in the consumption of each good, (Δx1, Δx2), that keeps
utility constant—that is, a change in consumption that moves us along the
indifference curve. Then we must have:
• In the diagram, the bundle of goods that is associated with the highest
indifference curve that just touches the budget line is labeled (x1*, x2*). The
choice (x1*, x2*) is an optimal choice for the consumer.
• The indifference curve that intersects or lies above the budget line cannot
represents the optimal choice.
OPTIMAL CHOICE
More than one tangency: In this case, there are three tangencies, but only two
optimal points, so the tangency condition is necessary but not sufficient
CONSUMER DEMAND
• The optimal choice of goods 1 and 2 at some set of prices and income
is called the consumer’s demanded bundle. In general when prices
and income change, the consumer’s optimal choice will change.
• The demand function is the function that relates the optimal choice-
the quantities demanded- to the different values of prices and
incomes.
CONSUMER DEMAND- PERFECT
SUBSTITUTES
• If p2 > p1, then the slope of the budget line is flatter than the slope of the
indifference curves. In this case, the optimal bundle is where the consumer
spends all of his or her money on good 1.
• If p1 > p2, then the consumer purchases only good 2.
• If p1 = p2, there is a whole range of optimal choices- any amount of goods 1
and 2 that satisfies the budget constraint is optimal in this case.
CONSUMER DEMAND- PERFECT
SUBSTITUTES
• In the case of a neutral good the consumer spends all of her money
on the good she likes and doesn’t purchase any of the neutral good.
The same thing happens if one commodity is a bad.
• If commodity 1 is a good and commodity 2 is a bad:
x1= m/p1
x2 = 0
CONSUMER DEMAND- DISCRETE GOODS
• Discrete goods: In panel A the demand for good 1 is zero, while in panel B one
unit will be demanded.
• If the price of good 1 is very high, then the consumer will choose zero units of
consumption; as the price decreases the consumer will find it optimal to consume
1 unit of the good
CONSUMER DEMAND- CONCAVE
PREFERENCES
• Similarly, the fraction of his income that the consumer spends on good 2 is d/(c +
d).
IMPLICATIONS OF MRS CONDITION
• Price ratios measure marginal rates of substitution is very important, it means that we
have a way to value possible changes in consumption bundles.
• Since prices measure the rate at which people are just willing to substitute one good
for another, they can be used to value policy proposals that involve making changes
in consumption.
• If we observe one choice at one set of prices we get the MRS at one consumption
point. If the prices change and we observe another choice we get another MRS. As
we observe more and more choices we learn more and more about the shape of the
underlying preferences that may have generated the observed choice behavior.