Macro II
Macro II
EQUILIBRIUM INCOME
DETERMINATION
1.1.The Components of Income
When judging whether the economy is doing well or poorly, it is
natural to look at the total income that everyone in the economy
is earning(GDP).
GDP measures two things at once:
-the total income of everyone in the economy and
-the total expenditure on the economy’s output of goods
and services
We can compute GDP for this economy in one of two ways:
-by adding up the total expenditure by hhds or
-by adding up the total income (wages, rent, and profit)
paid by firms.
Generally, the GDP or income has four components:
consumption (C),
investment (I),
government purchases (G) and
net exports (NX).
and
AD
MPC C = a + b(Y- 7ࡄ
MPC
a+I+G
a Y
The two curves slope upward because higher income leads to
higher consumption and thus higher planned expenditure. The
slopes of both lines are the MPC.
This can be proved by taking the first order derivative of both
functions since the first order derivative is the slope of a
function.
So the slope of AD curve and the slope of the consumption
function is the MPC which is denoted by change in consumption
due to change in income
We are emphasizing this point since we are going to compute or
estimate the impact of any change in govnt expenditure in terms
of the value of mpc. These types of impacts can easily be
estimated from the graphical presentation of a concept known as
Keynesian cross both of which are again related to the
equilibrium condition.
Equilibrium will be found when the desired amount of output
demanded by all the agents in the economy exactly equals the
amount produced in a given time period. This means the economy
is in equilibrium when actual aggregate demand equals planned
aggregate demand.
Actual aggregate demand = Planned aggregate demandY = AD
The equilibrium will be defined at the point where the planned
aggregate demand curve given by
intersects the curve given by Y = AD.
The graphical representation of the equilibrium is known as the
"Keynesian cross" because of the crossing of the upward sloping
AD curve and the 450 line. It is important to know that the
intersection of these two lines yields the equilibrium level of
national income.
In the figure the 45o line serves as a reference line that translates
any horizontal distance into an equal vertical distance. The 450
line allows us to compare a given level of actual GDP and AD on
the vertical axis. Thus, anywhere on the 450 line, the level of AD
is equal to the level of output. If they are not equal, firms will
adjust output.
Figure 1.2: Keynesian Cross and the equilibrium
AD Y = AD
Y1
AD1
AD* A
AD2
Y2
450
Y2 Y* Y1 Income, output Y
Firms produce the exact same level of output next period
and every period after that as long as AD=actual GDP i.e.
AD=Y. For this reason, this level of output is called the
equilibrium level of output (or national income) i.e., the level
of output (or national income) at which there is no tendency
to change. For instance, at point A, both output and
aggregate demand are equal, Y* = AD*. These values are
equilibrium output and equilibrium aggregate demand,
respectively. when there is any deviation from the
equilibrium, the equilibrium output would be achieved
through inventory adjustments.
The change in inventories is the signal upon which firms base
their decision of whether to increase or decrease production
The Keynesian cross shows how income Y is determined for
any given levels of planned investment (I) and fiscal policy
variables, G and T. We can use this model to show how income
changes when one of these exogenous variables changes.
Example; Suppose the consumption function and the investment
is given as follows with no government intervention:
C=100+0.75Y; I=150, Where, the investment (I) is autonomous.
a) Find the aggregate demand function
b) Find the equilibrium level of income
c) Find the equilibrium level of aggregate demand
d) Find the equilibrium level of consumption
e) Draw the graph showing the consumption function
and the aggregate demand function with correct
labeling
1.3.Fiscal policy and Multipliers
There are two major government fiscal policy instruments in the
commodity market.
government purchase and
government tax revenue
• Any change in these variables has a multiplied effect on real
factors such as output
• The factors which show the r/p b/n the changes in the
instrument and the effect are known as multipliers
• Thus, the corresponding multipliers are known as government
purchase multiplier and tax multiplier
1. 3.1.Government Purchase multiplier
If government purchases rise by ∆G, then the planned aggregate demand schedule
shifts upward by ∆G, as shown in the figure 1.3 below.
The line ‘Y = AD’ is a 450 line, the triangle ‘ABC’ is an isosceles triangle with side AC and
side BC being equal.
The change in output (∆Y) is equal to the distance BC, since BC is equal to AC. But the
change in government expenditure (∆G) is equal to distance BD. Thus, the change in
output (∆Y) exceeds the change in government expenditure (∆G) by the distance DC.
Thus, the change in government expenditure (∆G) has a multiplier effect on output.
The ratio is called the government purchase multiplier; and it tells us the factor by
which income rises in response to a unit increase in government purchases.
An implication of the Keynesian cross is that the government purchases multiplier given
by ( ) is larger than one.
Figure 1.3: Change in Government expenditure & Aggregate Demand
AD Y=AD
AD2
B
∆G
∆Y D
AD1
A
C
0 ∆Y
45 Y
AD1 = Y1 AD2 = Y2
Why does fiscal policy have a multiplier effect on income?
According to the consumption function, higher income causes higher
consumption.
increase in government purchases raises income, it also raises
consumption, which further raises income of producers of the
consumption goods, and so on.
i. e. G Y C Y C Y……………
The process of the multiplier begins when expenditure rises by which
implies that income rises by as well. This increase in income in turn raises
consumption by MPC times .
This increase in consumption raises AD and income once again.
This second increase in income of MPC( ) again raises consumption by MPC
(MPC ), which again raises AD and income, and so on.
We can, thus, write this process compactly as follows:
- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - (1.6)
Note that the expression on the right hand side of the multiplier is an
example of infinite and decreasing geometric series with the common ratio
‘r’ given as follows.
Note also that the sum of such geometric series is obtained using the following
formula.
Sn = where G1 is the first observation of the series. Since G1 =1 and r = MPC,
the sum of this series can be solved as follows: ------------- (1.7)
Mathematical proof: infinite geometric series
Let Sn = 1+ MPC + MPC2 +… (1)
Multiply both sides of this equation by MPC:
MPC (Sn ) = MPC + MPC2 + MPC3 +… (2)
Subtract the second equation from the first: Sn - MPC (Sn ) = 1
Sn(1 -MPC) = 1
Dividing both sides by (1 -MPC) we obtain: Sn =
We can also derive the multiplier from our national income
Y a b(Y T ) I G
identity or from the AD model,
Assuming that T and I are constant and by taking total
differentiation of the above identity, we would get:
dY = b(dY) + dG
dY -b(dY) = dG (1 – b) dY = dG
Dividing1 both sides by (1 – b)dG
dY/dG = where b = MPC.
1 b
Y 1 1
Y G Where, b = dC/ dY = MPC
G 1 b 1 b
The value of MPC lies between zero and one i.e. 0<MPC<1. Hence, the value of
expression (1-MPC) is positive and the value of or
is always positive and greater than one.
Thus, a change in government expenditure ( ) brings about a larger change in
output ( ) given by 1 1
G > G , since > 1.
1 MPC 1 MPC
1. 3.2.Tax multiplier
AD Y=AD
AD2
B MPC*∆T
∆Y
D AD1
A
C
0 ∆Y
45 Y
AD1 = Y1 AD2 = Y2
From this identity, we can conclude that when government expenditure and
taxes increase by the same amount, income changes by an amount equal to
the change in government purchase or the tax revenue. Since the change in
income is exactly equal to the government purchase, the multiplier is equal to
one. This multiplier is called the balanced budget multiplier.
Example: Given consumption function (C), investment (I) and government
expenditure (G) as follows (the values are in millions birr): C=50+0.8Yd, I=100,
G=130 and if Yd =Y-T
a. Calculate the equilibrium level of output and consumption if the tax is equal to T=80
b. Calculate government purchase multiplier and interpret the result
c. Calculate government tax multiplier and interpret the result
d. Calculate the change in output and the new equilibrium output if
government expenditure increases by 50 units
e. Calculate the change in output and the new equilibrium output if
government increases tax by 10 units
f. Graphically demonstrate the changes owing to the two policy changes
g. Calculate the change in output and the new equilibrium output if both
government purchase and government tax increases by 20 units
simultaneously.
CHAPTER 2
CONSUMPTION SPENDING
2.1. Definition and Concepts of Consumption
The economy can be taken as the combination of several sectors. These
sectors can be hhd sector, business sector, gvrnt sector and foreign sector.
All of these sectors demand gds and srvcs from the economy.
The AD for all of them includes consumption of hhd sector (C), investment
spending of business sector (I), gvt spending (G) and net of exports (NX)
which is the difference between export and import (X – M).
C a cYd ; a 0, 0 c 1………………………………………2.2
For example, a linear consumption function with MPC of 0.75 indicates that 75
percent of the income of the household will be devoted to consumption and
autonomous consumption of 500 birr indicates that even if income is zero, the
households will consume 500 birr.
This condition can be specified as: C = 500 + 0.75Yd.
I) Properties of Keynesian Consumption Function
Pn P0 (1 i ) n
Where Pn is the amount one gets at the end of ‘n’ years at market rate of interest
The present value given by ‘Po’ is obtained by solving for ‘Po’ from equation
above. The general formula for the present value of future income is given as
Pn
follows: P0
(1 i ) n
The above equation shows that the present value and market rate of interest
are inversely related. This means that higher interest rates leads to lower
Solution:
For party ‘A’, since the PV of the return from the investment is less than the amount of
money required, which is the cost of the investment (8,000 < 10,000), it is proper not to
invest.
For party ‘B’, since the PV of the benefit or the return is larger than the cost (80,000 >
70,000) it is preferable to invest the resource or the money.
For party ‘C’, since both the PV of the return and the cost are equal (6,000 = 6,000), it is the
same for the party to invest or not. From the point of view of producers it may be advisable
to invest with the argument that the party will accumulate experience; however, from the
point of view of national economy it is better not to invest and rather to save the money to
provide the fund for some other alternative investments.
b. Marginal Efficiency Criterion
Marginal efficiency of capital (r) is the rate of interest, which equates the cost
of the project and the discounted value of the future income stream
associated with the project.
Then, the discount rate (r) will be compared with the market or banks Interest
rate (i), which is the cost of or the return on saving.
If the discount rate (r) is greater than the market or banks interest rate (i), it
means that the money put into the investment is increasing itself by larger rate
through returns from the investment products than it brings if we save in
banks or than the rate we should pay if we borrow the money for the
investment.
ii) Non–Profit Motives
• The most important non – profit motive is the welfare reason or humanitarian issues.
Individuals and NGOs spend their resources on investment to benefit a community
from the return from the investments.
• There is national or political obligation on the government of a country to spend on
some investment activities in providing the society with some basic infrastructure
such as road, schools and health infrastructures. The later usually accounts for a
considerable proportion of government expenditure (G) in national income identity or
GDP.
3.2. Investment Demand and Saving Curve
3.2.1.Investment Demand
When the government investment increases, the government either cut its saving
(shifting saving curve from S1 to S1) as money moves to the investment or the
government increases borrowing. Both borrowing and reduction in saving pushes
the interest upward (from r1 to r2) making the borrowing expensive for private
investors. So, private investors cut their investment spending from I 1 to I2. This is
also contributed to by increased private saving attracted by higher interest income.
3.2.2. Investment demand and Saving Relationships
Investment spending is on the demand side where as saving is on the supply side of
investment and finance sectors.
Investment is determined by the level of supply of the investment resources which is
saving.
Level of saving determines the level of interest rate, which is the cost of borrowing or
the opportunity cost of investment.
The higher the saving, the lower the interest rate will be and the more the investment
expenditure will be since the cost of borrowing or opportunity cost of investing their
money (foregone interest income) will be lower.
Saving is known as supply of loanable fund whereas the interest rate is known as the
price of the loan. Thus, the larger the supply of the fund, the lower its price will be
and so the higher the demand (investment) will be.
Higher interest rate discourages investment since cost of borrowing or opportunity
cost of investment is high.
Figure 3.4: Investment demand and saving curves
The Figure depicts that the equilibrium level of investment and saving is equal
to I*; (I = S) defined at the point of intersection between the saving and the
investment curves.
The larger the saving the smaller the consumption will be.
Lower consumption level again implies lower demand for the products of different
investment activities and other national products. This discourages further investment
and reduces aggregate demand and national output or national income. This can
easily be seen in the following national income identity:
Y GDP = C + I + G + X – M
Excessive saving reduces the value of ‘C’ and this discourages investment leading to
smaller value of ‘I’. Both of these impacts of excessive saving by households finally
lead to lower level national income.
Y = GDP = C + I + G + X – M.
This is what is known as the paradox of thrift or the paradox of saving where it
affects the national income negatively even if it is expected to improve national
income by encouraging investment.