Global Imbalances
Global Imbalances
Global Imbalances
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
INTRODUCTION
Economic and financial commentators agree that the domestic
financial system is broken. Their diagnoses may vary with respect to
draft.
1. Jacqueline Best, Hollowing out Keynesian Norms: How the Search for a
Technical Fix Undermined the Bretton Woods Regime, 30 REV. INT'L STUD. 383,
385 (2004).
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
Part I briefly describes the crash of 2008 and the initial U.S. and
G-20 coordinated responses. Part II then develops a sketch of the
global imbalances that create the liquidity conditions ideal for the
development of bubbles, and Part III explains how the current
international economic architecture is responsible for these
imbalances. By explaining (a) that structural imbalances in exchange
rates, trade, savings and consumption are a result of the current
structure of the international economic system; and (b) that they
contribute to excessive liquidity, which, in turn, fuels the formation
of bubbles through financial markets, the author posits that localized
regulatory fixes to risk-taking are not likely to avoid future bubbles.
Therefore, Part IV proposes a set of cooperative comprehensive
exchange rate adjustments that would limit the destabilizing effect
that accumulation of massive reserves in one currency has produced.
These adjustments could be achieved through different cooperative
mechanisms, which the author discusses. By reducing the incentives
for the formation of massive currency reserves, this change would
reduce the likelihood of excessive pools of liquidity, which, through
the operation of the international financial system, have been the
cause of worldwide economic instability. This article concludes by
highlighting that such reform can be attained only via global
macroeconomic coordination, requiring different countries to accept
certain short-term monetary, budgetary and geopolitical trade-offs if
they wish to forestall the rise of protectionism and promote a stable
international economic environment in the long run.
I. THE CRASH OF 2008 AND THE EARLY RESPONSE
The last financial crisis is American-born in more ways than one
can imagine. It was in the United States that flawed regulatory
structures, poor risk-management and innovations in securitization
(i.e., the repackaging of collateralized debt, such as mortgages,
corporate loans, credit card receivables among other financial assets
into presumably liquid securities then sold to investors throughout
the world) and derivatives (i.e., the creation of "synthetic" credit
default swaps, insurance-like contracts issued by and traded among
financial institutions containing promises to pay in the event of a
counterparty default) combined to channel easy money to the various
sectors of the economy. Residential households, commercial
businesses, consumers and, of course, financial institutions were all
participants in a bubble the likes of which we had last seen prior to
the Crash of 1929. Once expectations of ever rising real estate prices
collapsed and the crisis arrived, policy response was strong, initially
-3-
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
-4-
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
Indeed, the United States and the world economy have managed
to escape from another Great Depression, but unemployment rates
are not likely to rebound even in the medium term. Congressional
Budget Office unemployment forecasts for 2010 actually went up
from 6.1% in September 2009 to 9.0% in January 2009, a remarkable
sign of a protracted, if not fickle, economic recovery.4
Remarkably, from California to New York, from Ireland to
Spain, and from Dubai to Abu-Dhabi, the combination of free
flowing capital, financial deregulation, excessive risk-taking and now
G-20-orchestrated government bailouts has created the mother of all
moral hazards: bankers throughout the world are rewarded when
their bets are right while governments (i.e., taxpayers) absorb their
losses when they are wrong (even while they keep their bonuses).
Indeed, in the case of the United States, the current crisis is only the
last in a series of financial earthquakes where government
3. Martin Wolf, What the World Must Do to Sustain Its Convalescence, FIN.
TIMES, Feb. 2, 2010, at 13.
4. See CONG. BUDGET OFFICE, THE BUDGET AND ECONOMIC OUTLOOK:
FISCAL YEARS 2009 TO 2019, 11 (2009),
http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/99xx/doc9957/MainText.3.1.shtml.
-5-
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
7. See Rebalancing the World Economy: Japan, ECONOMIST, Aug. 13, 2009,
at 65.
8. See Never Short a Country with $2 Trillion in Reserves?,
http://mpettis.com/2010/02/never-short-a-country-with-2-trillion-in-reserves (Feb.
2, 2010).
-9-
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
9. See David Barboza, Shorting China: The Man Who Predicted Enron's Fall
Sees a Bigger Collapse Ahead, N.Y. TIMES, Jan. 8, 2010, at B1, B4, (quoting
James S. Chanos's view that China's real estate sector looks like "Dubai times
1,000or worse.").
10. Compare Bloomberg News, China's Foreign-Exchange Reserves Surge,
Exceeding $2 Trillion, BLOOMBERG.COM, July 15, 2009,
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&sid=alZgI4B1lt3s, with
Sara Haimowitz, China's Record Reserves, TRADEREFORM.ORG, Jan. 27, 2010,
http://www.tradereform.org/content/view/2319/52.
11. World Bank, Key Development Data & Statistics,
http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/DATASTATISTICS/0,,content
MDK:20535285~menuPK:1192694~pagePK:64133150~piPK:64133175~theSiteP
K:239419,00.html (reporting global GDP at $60,587 billion in current US dollars).
12. See Eswar Prasad & Isaac Sorkin, Brookings Inst., Sky's the Limit?:
National and Global Implications of China's Reserve Accumulation, BROOKINGS,
July 29, 2009,
http://www.brookings.edu/articles/2009/0721_chinas_reserve_prasad.aspx#table1.
- 10 -
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
reduce their exports and trade surpluses and force their industry to
focus on higher value added production, a transition that Japan and
South Korea successfully underwent in the past.
A recent
econometric analysis suggests that an across-the-board currency
appreciation in China and East Asia would reduce processed exports
by ten percent, which would "switch [global] expenditures towards
US and European goods," and thus rebalance world trade. 14 To
offset falling foreign demand, these countries would have to
rebalance their growth strategies towards more reliance on domestic
demand, which would obviously come at the cost of a reduction in
their current accounts.
A similar refocusing on domestic consumption must occur in
Germany and other European surplus nations. Because currency
appreciation cannot be prescribed to these countries, only an
expansionary fiscal policy would contribute to regional and global
rebalancing by stimulating domestic employment and consumption.
At the regional level, any European Union-wide effort to cure its
deficit countries' economic slump through trade surpluses would be
viewed as a "beggar-thy-neighbor" policy, leading to trade friction
with its global partners and threatening global macroeconomic
coordination at a critical time. Therefore, policies that stimulate
eurozone surplus countries' domestic demand must be coupled with a
region-wide expansionary monetary policy so that a resurgence in
debt-financed growth reduces eurozone deficit countries' large
external and fiscal deficits. Absent such coordinated response,
demand weakness will persist, the slump in the entire eurozone will
be long-lasting and political crises will likely occur. 15
From the United States' perspective, the rebalancing of the
dollar vis--vis other world currencies would increase its saving-toGDP. ratio, make its exports more competitive and reduce its trade
deficit. While this would be welcome news for U.S. competitiveness
and employment, such change would not come without a cost. The
decline of the dollar in world trade and finance would not only be a
14. Willem Thorbecke & Gordon Smith, How Would an Appreciation of the
Renminbi and Other East Asian Currencies Affect China's Exports?, 18 REV. INT'L
ECON. 95, 106 (2010).
15. See Matthew Saltmarsh, Europe's Recovery Comes to Near Halt, N.Y.
TIMES, Feb. 13, 2010, at B7 ("The Federal Statistics Agency in Germany said that
the 'only positive contribution [in the fourth quarter of 2009] was made by foreign
trade,'" while stating that German GDP was flat in the fourth quarter of 2009, with
domestic consumption and investment declining.).
- 12 -
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
6/15/2010 9:47:09 PM
created, the fact remains that global rebalancing can only come as a
result of multilateral cooperation; short-term nationally or even
regionally-focused fixes are too limited in scope and can be quite
divisive.
CONCLUSION
If an international monetary system awash with liquidity has
been a major conduit to bubbles, crashes and bailouts, the transition
to a new, more stable system, would require major changes to the
status quo and thus constitutes a daunting challenge. Certainly,
global macroeconomic coordination will not be easy whichever form
it takes. However, such transition is absolutely inevitable in an
increasingly interdependent international system plagued by major
imbalances that call for greater macroeconomic coordination and
flexibility. Failure on the part of policymakers to grasp the scope
and transnational causes of the financial crisis and the Great
Recession of 2008-2009 would not bode well for the future of the
global economic system. The stakes could not be higher as failure to
restore the world to a sounder, more balanced footing could produce
major disruptions and a resurgence of protectionism.
- 16 -