Mohr Siebeck GMBH & Co. KG Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
Mohr Siebeck GMBH & Co. KG Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
Mohr Siebeck GMBH & Co. KG Zeitschrift Für Die Gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms
Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co. KG is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to Zeitschrift fr die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and
Theoretical Economics
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
Zeitschrift fr die gesamte Staatswissenschaft (ZgS) 140 (1984), 7-17
Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics
Since the cliometric revolution the building blocks used in the study of
nomic history have been those of neo-classical economics. That body of
was designed to explain and analyze the allocation of resources at a mom
of time under the severely restrictive test condition of zero transaction
In its pristine form, it assumed perfectly operating markets. While recent
sions have devoted attention to positive information costs, uncertainty
transaction costs, they are nowhere integrated into a general framewor
allows us to analyze the changing structure of economies over time,
i what economic history is all about. In this paper, I shall propos
a framework and suggest its implications for rethinking our views on eco
history1.
The bedrock of all economic theory is the gains from trade. From Adam
Smith on, economists have recognized that it is specialization and division
of labor that underlies the productivity of economies and permits and encour-
ages the growth of new technologies and more efficient forms of production.
But this theoretical foundation of economics is really half a theory. It ignores
the costs of trade - that is, the losses that arise because of specialization
and division of labor. Transaction costs are the costs of specifying and enforc-
ing the contracts that underlie exchange and therefore comprise all the costs
of political and economic organization that permit economies to capture the
gains from trade. How big a percentage of gross national product are these
costs? No one has yet measured them, but even a casual examination of
national income accounts suggests that today in advanced western countries
they may comprise as much as 50 percent of GNP. Moreover, they have
grown substantially in the last century. Since it is the combination of produc-
tion and transaction costs that have determined the output of political/eco-
nomic systems throughout history, a theory of transaction costs must be inte-
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
8 Douglass C. North ZgS
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
140/1 (1984) Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History 9
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
10 Douglass C. North ZgS
//
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
140/1 (1984) Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History 1 1
that is, the gains from trade arise because of specialization and division of
labor, but divergent ideologies, conflicting views about the justice and fairness
of the system, also emerge from these sources. They may emerge from geo-
graphic specialization in that geographically different groups evolve different
customs, traditions, languages as they confront different problems. Or they
may emerge from occupational specialization, which results in impersonal ex-
change and a loss of personalized relationship between employer and employee.
The implications of ideological consensus or ideological diversity for our
modeling of institutions should be clear. To the degree that the members
of a society have the same ideological framework, the formal rules of the
society that define the constraints making up institutions will not have to
be defined very clearly and enforcement mechanisms and procedures may
be minimal or even absent altogether. But to the degree that society has diverse
ideologies reflecting the growth of specialization and division of labor, more
resources will have to be devoted, first to defining the rules precisely, and
second to enforcing those rules. Such definition and enforcement is necessary
because, with conflicting ideologies, the individual participants will feel no
necessity to constrain individual maximization (cheating, shirking, etc.) at the
expense of the other party. Given the costliness of measuring performance,
ideological consensus or alienation is a fundamental influence upon the form
of institution.
We can summarize this very brief framework for theorizing about institu-
tions as follows: The gains from trade can only be realized by the establishment
of contracts between principals or principals and agents which form the institu-
tional framework of a political/economic system. Therefore, without some
form of political order, organized trade cannot develop. In effect, transaction
costs are so high that they preclude economic organization. With simple poli-
tical and economic organization, custom may be sufficient to specify the struc-
ture with a consensus ideology. As the gains from trade that arise from speciali-
zation and division of labor result in more and more complex forms of political
and economic organization, the resource costs of capturing those gains from
trade will increase. They will increase not only because the costs of measure-
ment and enforcement of an ever-lengthening chain that result from greater
and greater specialization will grow, but also because ideological alienation
will characterize the relations between participants in the exchange process
and will require greater and greater amounts of resources devoted to specifica-
tion and enforcement of contracts.
///
Let us now apply this analytical framework to the economic history of the
western world. That history has been shaped by two fundamental revolutions.
The first was the development of agriculture, which appears to have first
occurred in the Middle East about ten millenia ago and then developed inde-
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
12 Douglass C. North ZgS
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
140/1 (1984) Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History 13
interests. The state is an essential prerequisite for capturing the gains from
trade, but is also the source of exploitation. During the eight millenia from
the development of agriculture to the Roman Empire, there were periods
of sustained growth when the interests of the ruler coincided with productivity
increase: Athens in the fifth century, Rhodes in the fourth and third centuries,
and the Roman Empire in the first two centuries A.D.
But if the state is the necessary prerequisite for economic growth, it is
also the source of man-made economic decline. Ultimately, Athens fell to
Sparta; Rhodes was reduced by the competition and jealousy of Rome; and
the Roman Empire itself finally fell in the fifth century A.D. The inherent
instability of the state has been a basic characteristic of history, but at least
in the millenia to the end of the Roman Empire in the fifth century, A.D.,
it was the basic source of economic growth - at the price of increasing re-
sources going to political organizations, and persistent exploitation by those
in control of coercive power.
The second economic revolution, in contrast, was based on an elastic supply
curve of new knowledge which could be and was translated into the scientific
and technological advances of the modern world. It made the underlying as-
sumption of neoclassical economics realizable. That optimistic assumption
was that new knowledge could be produced at constant cost and that substitu-
tion at all margins made possible sustained growth even with the explosive
population increase that coincided. The price, however, has been an enormous
increase in the resources devoted to transacting and political and economic
institutions that are inherently even more unstable. Let us first look at the
economic consequences of this second economic revolution and then we shall
turn to some of the political consequences.
The technology of the second economic revolution was characterized by
significant indivisibilities in the production process with large fixed capital
investment. The realization of the potential scale economies required large
volume, continuous production and distribution. Alfred Chandler [1977],
has eloquently described the growing complex process of modern mass produc-
tion and distribution which occurred in the late nineteenth century. However,
this process required both occupational and territorial specialization and divi-
sion of labor on an unprecedented scale. The greater the specialization, the
greater the number of exchanges in the production process. Home production
is characterized by complete vertical integration. In this case, there are no
measurement costs, since each person tailors production to his or her own
needs, but the price is the productivity gains from specialization. The second
economic revolution produced just the reverse. It resulted in exponential mul-
tiplication of exchanges, with immense gains in productivity but at the price
of growing transactions costs arising from this exchange. Obviously, the pro-
ductivity gains from specialization have exceeded the increasing transactions
costs. Hence, the quantum leap in living standards that made possible the
modern western world.
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
14 Douglass C. North ZgS
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
140/1 (1984) Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History 15
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
16 Douglass C. North ZgS
IV
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
140/1 (1984) Transaction Costs, Institutions, and Economic History 17
References
North. D.C. f 198 11. Structure and Chanze in Economic Historv. New York.
Chandler, A. [1977], The Visible Hand, Cambridge.
This content downloaded from 196.43.135.150 on Tue, 29 Aug 2017 12:23:26 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms