MIll and Wage Fund
MIll and Wage Fund
MIll and Wage Fund
The actual grounds Thornton gives for rejecting ‘supply and demand’ need to be
considered with care. Most of the literature claims that Thornton’s arguments
are so logically weak that Mill could not possibly have accepted them, and this
leads to the suspicion that Mill rejected the doctrine on other grounds.
“The demand for those who live by wages, it is evident, cannot increase
but in proportion to the increase of the funds which are destined for the
payment of wages.” Smith chapter 8 p 117
“Universally, then, we may affirm, other things remaining the same, that
if the ratio which capital and population bear to one another remains the
same, wages will remain the same; if the ratio which capital bears to
population increases, wages will rise; if the ratio which population bears
This is clearly very loose terminology: if by the ratio of capital to labour Mill
means the whole of the national capital stock, then obviously, as
industrialisation occurs, this ratio is likely to rise permanently.
M’Culloch
“No other fund [than capital] is in existence from which the labourers, as such,
can draw a single shilling.” Wealth of Nations, M’Culloch’s edition p 470 as
quoted by Taussig (1896),Wages and capital: an examination of the wage fund
doctrine, Appleton, p 192
“the rate of wages in all countries and at all periods depends on the ratio
between the portion of their capital allotted to paying wages, and the number of
their labourers.” Taussig p 192
Fawcett
Fawcett claims that it is not the case that wages are controlled soley by
employers “………… wages are regulated by fixed and well-ascertained
laws, and that these laws are as certain in their operations as those which
control physical nature...” Fawcett “Economic position of the British
labourer, p 119-121 as quoted by Longe, F.D., (1886) p 13-14
W = F/L
So we can say,
L = F/W
dL w
dw L
with L = F/W ,
dL F
=− 2
dw w
dL w F w F
then =− 2 = = −1
dw L w L LW
This is unit elastic, and thus changes in the wage rate will not affect the total
wage bill.
“Wages, then, depend upon the demand and supply of labour; or, as it is often
expressed, on the proportion between population and capital. By population is
here meant the number only of the labouring class, or rather of those who work
In other words, wages are determined by the amount of capital and the level of
the working population, and nothing else.
The result of the ‘law’, claims Mill, is that it is impossible for labourers to
combine in a trade union and successfully increase wages.
Apparently, prior to the Thornton critique the wage fund theorem was thought
to be an irresistible law.
“It is laid down that wages, by an irresistible law, depend on the demand
and supply of labour, and can in no circumstances be either more or less
than what will distribute the existing wages-fund among the existing
competitors for employment.” John Stuart Mill, The Collected Works of
John Stuart Mill, Volume V - Essays on Economics and Society Part II
(Chapters of Socialism) “ Thornton On Labour And Its Claims” 1869, pp
634
Thornton.
We come now to the actual review by Mill of Thornton’s book On Labour.
Though there are s different interpretations of this work, the essence would
appear to be an attack on ‘Supply and Demand’.
Mill’s response seems unclear. At times he seems to defend the ‘law’ of supply
and demand. At times he seems to accept that Thornton has a point. He also
seems to take the position that the ‘general’ law of supply and demand cannot
be subverted, but that it might be inadequate in individual cases.
Thornton’s Approach.
Putting the second method - the ‘examples’- aside for the moment, just what is
Thornton’s generalised rejection of supply and demand?
“For those who do not choose to be confined within this millhorse circle
there is no alternative but to cut the supply and demand theory adrift.”
1870 2nd ed, P44
“the theory [of supply and demand] is not simply imperfect, but radically and
intrinsically unsound. I assert positively that the price, whether of labour or of
anything else, in no case whatsoever depends on the proportion between supply
and demand…” 1870 2nd ed, P44
It must be admitted that the argument is not entirely clear, but Thornton seems
to be interested in just how prices, if they are not equilibrium prices, get
adjusted to equilibrium, that is, the process of price adjustment.
If they did, this would remove a certain quantity of the good from supply (and a
quantity of buyers from demand) and hence change the character of any new
‘equilibrium’ price. (This can be referred to as ‘transactions at non-equilibrium
prices’.)
Moreover, how many buyers and sellers are there? Just how does one
‘aggregate’ to get the ‘market’ demand function or the ‘market’ supply
function? Moreover, does the ‘supply function’ mean that sellers are willing to
accept any price to get rid of their wares? (To leap ahead, exactly this problem
will recur in the study of Leon Walras, who introduced the concept of
‘Tattonement’ in order to deal with the process of getting from non-equilibrium
to market-clearing or equilibrium prices.)
Thornton is arguing that the assumptions necessary for price to adjust to equate
supply and demand at an ‘equilibrium’ price are simply unrealistic – no
transactions at non-equilibrium prices, instantaneous quantity adjustments.
He points out that the assumptions necessary are that there needs to be a
perfectly free and open market, with competing dealers and customers, and that
the goods supplied or offered for sale are offered unreservedly, Book II ch 1 p
51
1
Without which there would be nothing.
In Thornton’s own words, he gets rid of the problem of the ‘supply curve’
implying instantaneous quantity adjustment simply by assuming that supply is a
fixed quantity.
Not only that, but Thornton claims that sellers will not offer for sale below a
given or reserved price. This is crucial to Thornton’s analysis since he claims
that the unrealistic, assumed ‘condition’ of supply and demand theory is that
sellers offer their whole quantity for sale unreservedly, that is, for any price it
will bring. There is thus a seller-determined minimum price: but sellers would
be willing to sell for a higher price, determined by the most ardent buyers.
Various quantities of the goods will therefore be sold at any price between the
buyer determined maximum and the seller determined minimum i.e., at
‘intermediate’ prices.
Thorntons Examples.
(i) Dutch2 and English Auctions (Multiple ‘equilibrium’ prices can arise)
(iv) ‘Discriminatory’ Sales: (Non-equilibrium trading) and (v) the use of ‘time’
to increase prices. See book II ch 1
We should say at the outset that these examples have been defined as ‘absurd’,
‘bizarre’, ‘confusing and weak’, ‘fatuous’, ‘flimsy’, ‘blatant naivety’,
‘unsophisticated’.
They did give his opponents some apparently easy grounds for rejection. Any
defence of Thornton seems to rest on the claim that his major argument rests on
the ‘general’ critique of supply and demand requiring unrealistic assumptions:
the examples are weak, and can be rejected on the grounds that they all rely
upon supply and demand ‘functions’ that are reduced to mere dots or points, or
functions that are either vertical, horizontal, or contain jump discontinuities.
That is, they can be rejected on the grounds that they are all ‘anomalous cases’.
The details of these ‘cases’ can be found either in Thornton’s chapter on Supply
& Demand, or in Mill’s review.
2
In Dutch auctions prices start high and then are moved down until someone is prepared to buy.
In the next two cases Thornton simply assumes there are sellers with a fixed
quantity to sell at a given price. In each market there are more people willing to
buy at the fixed price, but not at a penny more, than the number for sale; excess
demand does not change price.
The last two cases again express Thornton’s general worry about the price-
adjustment process, and behaviour at ‘non-equilibrium’ prices. He takes a case
where ‘ultimately’ the whole of the available supply will be sold, so in that
sense ‘supply equals demand’, but since some buyers are willing to pay higher
prices than others, they will be charged a higher price, the price being only
reduced later “to get rid of the remainder”. (Just which price is ‘equilibrium’ if
different prices are charged?)
He then gives the example of “a corn dealer who in the course of a season sells
thousands of quarters of wheat at fifty shillings per quarter.” Such a dealer,
claims Thornton, “would not get twenty shillings a quarter if, as soon as his
corn ships arrived, he was obliged to turn the cargoes into money.” p 53. How
does he get the higher price asks Thornton? Thornton argues this is by not
selling unreservedly: “simply by declining the price which would have resulted
“the theory [of supply and demand] is not simply imperfect, but radically and
intrinsically unsound. I assert positively that the price, whether of labour or of
anything else, in no case whatsoever depends on the proportion between supply
and demand…” 1870 2nd ed p44
Mill seems to confirm this, but with ‘modifications’, arguing that no economist
would consider supply and demand to be the “ultimate regulator of value”, but
that the cost of production is (exempting the possibility of a monopoly).
“The law, therefore, of values, as affected by demand and supply, is that they
adjust themselves so as always to bring about an equation between demand and
supply, by the increase of the one or the diminution of the other; the movement
of price being only arrested when the quantity asked for at the current price, and
the quantity offered at the current price, are equal. This point of exact
equilibrium may be as momentary, but it is nevertheless as real, as the level of
the sea.” Thornton on labour and its claims, 1869.
“It is, therefore, strictly correct to say, that the value of things which can be
increased in quantity at pleasure, does not depend (except accidentally, and
during the time necessary for production to adjust itself) upon demand and
supply; on the contrary, demand and supply depend upon it……Demand and
supply govern the value of all things which cannot be indefinitely increased
except that, even for them, when produced by industry, there is a minimum
value determined by the cost of production. But in all things which admit of
indefinite multiplication, demand and supply only determine the perturbations
of value, during a period which cannot exceed the length of time necessary for
altering the supply. While thus ruling the oscillations of value, they themselves
obey a superior force, which makes value gravitate towards cost of production,
and which would settle it and keep it there, if fresh disturbing influences were
not continually arising to make it again deviate.” Mill 1869 Book III ch3p 635
“He has proved that the law of the equalisation of supply and demand is
not the whole theory of the particular case…..The demand and supply are
equal at twenty shillings, and equal also at eighteen shillings. The
conclusion ought to be, not that the law is false, for Mr. Thornton does
not deny that in the case in question it is fulfilled; but only, that it is not
the entire law of the phenomenon.…nor has he now, shown it to be in the
smallest degree incorrect.” Mill 1869 Vol V ,“Thornton on labour and its
Claims”
Mill’s conclusion is clear: Thornton’s strictures on ‘supply & demand’ are not,
in general valid. Mill calls them ‘minute’ and ‘unimportant’. Moreover:
“I confess I cannot perceive that these considerations are subversive of the law
of supply and demand.” Volume V 1869 ,“Thornton on labour and its Claims”
Given these statements, what comes next, therefore, has caused much debate.
Mill would appear to accept that ‘the labour market’ is an exceptional case.
Mill’s Recantation.
Whilst he describes Thornton’s improvement of the theory of price as
“minute” and “unimportant” he acknowledges them as of great practical
importance in the case of labour.
“… there is this difference between the labour market and the market for
tangible commodities, that in commodities it is the seller, but in labour it
is the buyer, who has the initiative in fixing he price. It is the employer,
the purchaser of labour, who makes the offer of wages; the dealer, who is
in this case the labourer, accepts or refuses. Whatever advantage can be
derived from the initiative is, therefore, on the side of the employer.”
Volume V 1869 ,“Thornton on labour and its Claims” P 643
“The demand for labour consists of the whole circulating capital of the
country, including what is paid in wages for unproductive labour. The
supply is the whole labouring population…. If the supply is in excess of
what the capital can at present employ, wages must fall…. The only way
the power of the employers can be overcome is by a “close combination”
of labour.” Volume V 1869 ,“Thornton on labour and its Claims” P 643
Mill points out that, between the highest wages possible and the lowest
ones there is an intermediate region “ within which wages will range
higher or lower according to what Adam Smith calls "the higgling of the
market."
Long, FD 1886
Long describes Mill’s law of wages as “so certain is the natural law by which
wages are controlled, that employers cannot be held responsible for the amount
of wages they pay” p 14
He points out that whether the wage fund would be able to pay more and keep
the same number of employees is a matter of fact, p21, but clarifies that Mill
does not mean “existing capital” of a given set of employers or a given number
of employees but those of the whole nation. P 22
Long later argues that the “law” is merely application of demand and supply –
demand the capital, supply the population. P26, and that the demand and supply
of labour is “directly the reverse” of that of normal goods, p. 38 A supplier of
“ The true theory of the production of wealth is embodied in these words: both
capital and labour are the servants of the consumer” Longe (1886) p43-44
He also points out, again, that the amount of capital available may not be fixed,
we may use some of our wealth for other things – consumption, saving, etc.
Good 3 is 'circulating capital', that is, it is the 'wage good' of the economy
(food). Using arbitrary numbers:
Good 3 60 15 120 42
Note: only 42 units of food are produced, despite 420 units of labour being
used. Though the remainder of the analysis can be completed using only this
example in 'physical' units, it is also possible to solve for classical 'values', and
conduct the analysis in labour time. Both will be done here:
v1 = 1,v2 = 2,v3 = 5
to make
output
/depreciation
From now on, physical units will be used in the top table, labour units in the
bottom.
Let us now assume that the whole of the output of the 'circulating capital' good
(good 3) is distributed to workers as wages.
Good 3 60 15 12 42 0
(depreciation)
On the top, the output of good 1 is 360, depreciation 240, so surplus 120; of
good 2, output is 135, depreciation 90, surplus 45. There is no excess output of
good 3
In table 3, it is clear that the whole of the 'wage fund' is distributed as wages.
That is the 42 units of food (good 3) are paid out as wages. Therefore, as the
total labour force is 420,
Output 42 1
w= = . In units So labour is given 1 unit of food per each
total labour hours 420 10
unit of labour.
In table 3, the output of good 1 is 120 units (360, depreciation 240) ; net output
of good 2 is 45 (output is 135, depreciation 90). There is no excess ( or net)
output of good 3 ( the food).
(=360*1)
years(=135*2)
(=42*5)
In table 4, total labour input has been divided into Marx's variable capital and
surplus labour: 210 labour years worth of output are distributed to 420
210 1
labourers, therefore w = = . In labour years.
420 2
F
These are equivalent to w = , where the 'Fund' is the total output of
L
circulating capital. It is also clear that it is impossible to pay workers any more,
for wages to be higher, since there are no more wage goods to distribute.
Identifying the net national product, however, helps to interpret what is going
on.
In both cases, the net national product consists entirely of 'fixed capital' goods,
120 units of good 1 (120 labour years) and 45 units of good 2 (90 labour years).
As fixed capital goods can only be accumulated (added to the capital stock), this
economy can grow.
Suppose it grows by 50% in the next period, we can examine the effects by
scaling up the previous period’s output.
If the two above systems are scaled up by the factor 50%, one gets next period’s
output:
Good 3 90 22.5 18 63
depreciation
3(labour) labour”
(45*2)
L1 270
L2 180
L3 180
Total 630
It should be clear here that the deprecation of fixed capital goods in this 'period'
is exactly the quantity of gross output of these goods from the previous 'period',
360 good 1 (360 labour years) and 135 good 2 (270 labour years).
Once again, in the new circumstance, total circulating capital goes as wages,
and it is impossible to pay workers any more. That is, as before:
63 1 315 1
w= = units or w = = hours
630 10 630 2
All one needs to do is rearrange the relative sizes of the three sectors of the
economy so that the whole of the net national product is in fact composed of the
circulating capital good. In other words we now have an economy that no
longer accumulates capital.
Return to the original economy but suppose the data had been as below.
Good 2 60 45 12 135
labour” output
Good 2 60 90 60 60 270
L1 210
L2 120
L3 440
Total 770
It is clear here that the output of fixed capital goods exactly equals the
depreciation (420-420) + (270-270), which means that the national product is
154 units of circulating capital (which takes 770 labour years to produce).
1 1
In this case, the old wage rate of w = (w = in labour time)
10 2
need not now apply, for if the whole of the circulating capital is now paid as
wages,
770
or, in labour time. w = =1
770
This would appear to suggest that the 'Fund' for the payment of wages can be
anything from some minimum, to the whole of the net national product.
There would appear to be no truth in Fawcett's claim that "wages are regulated
by fixed and well-ascertained laws, and that these laws are as certain in their
operation as those which control physical nature." Fawcett Economic Position
of the British Labourer, pp. 119-121. As quoted by Longe, F.D., p 14
Mill's final position appears to be that the total wage bill, and therefore the
average wage, can be "between two limits…the highest wages consistent with
keeping up the capital of the country…and the lowest that will enable labourers
to keep up their numbers".