Intenational Trade
Intenational Trade
Without international trade, few nations could maintain an adequate standard of living,
particularly those of smaller size. With only domestic resources being available, each
country could only produce a limited number of products, and scarcity would be
prevalent. Global trade allows for an enormous variety of resources – from Persian Gulf
oil, Brazilian coffee to Chinese labor – to be made more widely accessible. Each item
being traded is subject to an internationally recognized classification (called Standard
International Trade Classification; SITC), allowing nations to clearly identify the goods
and the extent they are subject to tariffs and duties. Clear categorization also facilitates
the distribution of a wide range of manufactured goods that are produced in different
parts of the world to global markets. Wealth becomes increasingly derived through the
regional specialization of economic activities. This way, production costs are lowered,
productivity rises, and surpluses are generated, which can be transferred or traded for
commodities that would be too expensive to produce domestically (convenience) or
would simply not be available (necessity). As a result, international trade decreases the
overall costs of production. Consumers can buy more goods from the wages they earn,
and standards of living should, in theory, increase.
Separation factors. These are usually exogenous factors separating two trade
partners, such as distance, transportation costs, travel time, as well as common
attributes shared by trade partners. These usually involve being part of an
economic agreement (e.g. a free trade zone), which is facilitated when partners
have a common boundary.
Country-specific factors. Relates endogenous to factors that are either related to
the origin or the destination of trade. This usually involves customs procedures
(tariff and non-tariff factors), the overall performance of the national transport and
logistics sector, and how well an economy is connected to the international
transport system through its gateways (mostly ports and airports).
United Nations estimates have underlined that for developing countries, a 10% reduction
in transportation costs could be accompanied by a growth of about 20% in international
and domestic trade. Thus, the ability to compete in a global economy is dependent on the
transport system as well as a trade facilitation framework that includes measures related
to economic integration, the capabilities of international transportation systems, and the
ease of negotiating and settling transactions.
The quality, cost, and efficiency of trade services influence the trading environment as
well as the overall costs linked with the international trade of goods. Many factors have
been conducive to trade facilitation in recent decades:
All these measures are expected to promote the level of economic and social
development of the concerned nations since trade facilitation relies on the expansion of
human, infrastructure, and institutional capabilities.
Regionalization has been one of the dominant features of global trade as the bulk of
trade has a regional connotation, promoted by proximity and the setting of economic
blocs such as NAFTA and the European Union. The closer economic entities are, the
more likely they are to trade due to lower transport costs, fewer potential delays in
shipments, common customs procedures, and linguistic and cultural affinities. The most
intense trade relations are within Western Europe and North America, with a more recent
trend involving trade within Asia, particularly between Japan, China, Korea, and Taiwan,
as these economies are getting more integrated.
Still, many challenges are impacting future developments in international trade and
transportation, mostly in terms of demographics, politics, supply chain, energy, and
environmental issues. While the global population and its derived demand will continue
to grow and reach around 9 billion by 2050, demographic changes such as the aging of
the population, particularly in developed economies, will transform consumption patterns
as a growing share of the population shifts from wealth-producing (working and saving)
to wealth consuming (selling saved assets). Demographic trends in North America,
Europe, and East Asia (e.g. Japan, South Korea, Taiwan) may not place them as drivers
of global trade, a function they have assumed in recent decades. The demographic
dividend in terms of peak share of the working-age population that many countries
benefited from, particularly China, will recede. This has ramifications on both the
demand side (consumption structure) and the production side (workforce).
As both maritime and air freight transportation depend on petroleum, international trade
remains influenced by fluctuations in energy prices. The paradox has become that periods
of high energy prices usually impose a rationalization of international trade and its
underlying supply chains. However, periods of low or sharply declining energy prices,
which should benefit international transportation, are linked with economic recessions.
Environmental issues have also become more salient with the growing tendency of the
public sector to regulate components of international transportation that are judged to
have negative externalities. International trade enables several countries to mask their
energy consumption and pollutant emissions by importing goods that are produced
elsewhere and where environmental externalities are generated. Thus, international trade
has permitted a shift in the international division of production, but also a division
between the generation of environmental externalities and the consumption of the goods
related to these externalities.