Lecture 2: Consumption: Tiago Cavalcanti
Lecture 2: Consumption: Tiago Cavalcanti
Lecture 2: Consumption: Tiago Cavalcanti
Tiago Cavalcanti1
1 University of Cambridge
E200: Macroeconomics
Cambridge
Michaelmas 2022
Main reading:
Romer, ch. 8
Lecture 1 Outline:
I Consumption Theory
I Permanent Income Hypothesis
I Consumption under uncertainty
I Empirical tests
I Borrowing constraints
Why Do We Study Consumption?
I Example:
c1−σ − 1
u(c) = , σ > 0. And lim u(c) = ln(c).
1−σ σ→1
Household’s Problem
Subject to:
a0 is given,
aT+1
≥ 0, (no-Ponzi games).
(1 + r)T+1
Notice that:
c0 + a1 = y0 + (1 + r)a0 ,
c1 − y1 a2
c1 + a2 = y1 + (1 + r)a1 ⇒ a1 = + . Then,
1+r 1+r
c1 a2 y1
c0 + + = (1 + r)a0 + y0 + ,
1+r 1+r 1+r
c2 − y2 a3
c2 + a3 = y2 + (1 + r)a2 ⇒ a2 = + , Then,
1+r 1+r
c1 c2 a3 y1 y2
c0 + + 2
+ 2
= (1+r)a0 +y0 + + .
1 + r (1 + r) (1 + r) 1 + r (1 + r)2
By repeated substitution, we have the present value budge constraint:
T T
X ct aT+1 X yt
t
+ T
= (1 + r)a 0 + .
(1 + r) (1 + r) (1 + r)t
t=0 t=0
Solution to Household’s Problem I
T
X T
X
t
L= β u(ct ) + λt [yt + (1 + r)at − ct − at+1 ],
t=0 t=0
First-order conditions:
∂L
= β t u0 (ct ) − λt = 0,
∂ct
∂L
= −λt + (1 + r)λt+1 = 0,
∂at+1
∂L
= −λT ≤ 0, aT+1 ≥ 0, λT aT+1 = 0
∂aT+1
Then:
u0 (ct )
= (1 + r) ∀ t = 0, 1, 2, ..., T. (Euler)
βu0 (ct+1 )
Solution to Household’s Problem II
Euler equation:
u0 (ct )
= (1 + r)
βu0 (ct+1 )
Complementary-slackness condition implies that:
aT+1
= 0, guarantees no-Ponzi games
(1 + r)T
1
[β(1+r)] θ
If b = (1+r) < 1 ⇔ β < (1 + r)θ−1 , then:
1
1 − [β(1+r)]
θ " T
#
(1+r)
X yt
c0 = T+1 (1 + r)a0 + .
(1 + r)t
1
[β(1+r)] θ t=0
1− (1+r)
Solution to Household’s Problem V
I As T → ∞, then:
1
! Financial wealth ∞
[β(1 + r)] θ z }| { X yt
c0 = 1 − a0 (1 + r) + t
.
(1 + r) (1 + r)
t=0
| {z } | {z }
Eat a fraction of life-time income
I Recall that, ln(1 − b) ≈ −b for b < 1. If β = 1
1+ρ , then in logs:
1
[β(1+r)] θ
(1+r) ≈ θ1 (r − ρ) − r, and −b = r − θ1 (r − ρ).
" ∞
#
1 X yt
c0 = r − (r − ρ) a0 (1 + r) + .
θ (1 + r)t
t=0
X∞
max Et { β j u(ct+j )}, subject to
at+j+1 ,ct+j
j=0
at+j+1 + ct+j = (1 + r)at+j + yt+j ∀ j,
at+1+J
lim Et ≥ 0.
J→∞ (1 + r)J
Assume: yt+j is a random variable. At t the agent know yt .
∞
X ∞
X
j
L = Et { β u(ct+j ) + λt+j [(1 + r)at+j + yt+j − ct+j − at+j+1 ]},
j=0 j=0
∂L ∂L
= u0 (ct ) − λt = 0, = βEt [u0 (ct+1 )] − Et [λt+1 ] = 0,
∂ct ∂ct+1
∂L
= −λt + (1 + r)Et [λt+1 ] = 0,
∂at+1
Savings Under Uncertainty II
I Euler equation:
⇒ Et [∆ct+1 ] = 0.
Savings Under Uncertainty IV
Present value budget constraint:
∞ ∞
X 1 X 1
Et ct+j = at (1 + r) + Et yt+j .
(1 + r)j (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0
∞
r X 1
ct+1 = at+1 (1 + r) + Et+1 yt+j+1 ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0
∞ ∞
r X 1 X 1
ct+1 −ct = {Et+1 [ j
yt+1+j ]−Et [ yt+j+1 ]}.
1+r (1 + r) (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0
∞ ∞
r X 1 X 1
ct+1 −ct = {Et+1 [ yt+1+j ]−Et [ yt+j+1 ]}.
1+r (1 + r)j (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0
Interpretation:
I Consumption changes because new information arrives at date
t + 1;
I The new information arrives between t and t + 1 is yt+1 ;
I yt+1 can be decomposed into two parts:
I H0 : γ1 = 1 and γ2 = 0.
I Empirical Strategy:
I First run the income regression and get:
I PIH ⇒ H0 : β1 = 0 and β2 = 0;
I Consumption should react only to unexpected change in income
θ 6= 0.
P∞ t u(c
I maxat+1 ,ct E0 { t=0 β t )}, subject to
I Euler eq. when at+1 = −φ: u0 (ct ) ≥ β(1 + r)Et [u0 (ct+1 )].
I Constrained household has lower consumption today and would
like to reduce future consumption to increase today’s
consumption but can’t.