Lecture 2: Consumption: Tiago Cavalcanti

Download as pdf or txt
Download as pdf or txt
You are on page 1of 28

Lecture 2: Consumption

Tiago Cavalcanti1

1 University of Cambridge

E200: Macroeconomics
Cambridge
Michaelmas 2022
Main reading:

Romer, ch. 8

Lecture 1 Outline:
I Consumption Theory
I Permanent Income Hypothesis
I Consumption under uncertainty
I Empirical tests
I Borrowing constraints
Why Do We Study Consumption?

I Consumption is the largest component of GDP

I Consumption, savings, and ultimately investments are the main


drivers of the business cycle

I Consumption models constitute one of the main building blocks


of any macroeconomic model

I The effects of different reforms & policies depend on their


impact on consumption
I Social security reforms
I Tax reforms
I Cash transfers
Milton Friedman (1912-2006), Nobel Prize Winner, 1976
Historical Development

1. Keynesian consumption function:


I Essential component of IS (investment-saving) curve;
I Ct = α + βYt
I Yt is disposable income
I β is the marginal propensity to consume. Determines various
multipliers;
I ’Miopia’ property.

2. Friedman (1957) Permanent Income Hypothesis (PIH):


Ct = γt (Wt + Ht ), Wt is the market wealth; and Ht is the human
wealth;
I Consumption-saving decision is a forward looking and long
horizon planning problem
I Consumption should only adjust to changes of the permanent
component of income.
I Also see Modigliani and Brumberg (1954) life cycle theory.
Finite Horizon Case

I Time is discrete: t = 0, 1, ..., T;

I Utility function: U = u(c0 ) + βu(c1 ) + ... + β T u(cT );

I β ∈ [0, 1] : Time preference factor;

I u0 (·) > 0, u00 (·) < 0;

I Example:

c1−σ − 1
u(c) = , σ > 0. And lim u(c) = ln(c).
1−σ σ→1
Household’s Problem

The household’s problem is:


T
X
max β t u(ct ),
{ct ,at+1 }Tt=0
t=0

Subject to:

ct + at+1 = yt + (1 + r)at , ∀t = 0, 1, 2, ..., T.

a0 is given,

aT+1
≥ 0, (no-Ponzi games).
(1 + r)T+1
Notice that:
c0 + a1 = y0 + (1 + r)a0 ,
c1 − y1 a2
c1 + a2 = y1 + (1 + r)a1 ⇒ a1 = + . Then,
1+r 1+r
c1 a2 y1
c0 + + = (1 + r)a0 + y0 + ,
1+r 1+r 1+r
c2 − y2 a3
c2 + a3 = y2 + (1 + r)a2 ⇒ a2 = + , Then,
1+r 1+r
c1 c2 a3 y1 y2
c0 + + 2
+ 2
= (1+r)a0 +y0 + + .
1 + r (1 + r) (1 + r) 1 + r (1 + r)2
By repeated substitution, we have the present value budge constraint:
T T
X ct aT+1 X yt
t
+ T
= (1 + r)a 0 + .
(1 + r) (1 + r) (1 + r)t
t=0 t=0
Solution to Household’s Problem I
T
X T
X
t
L= β u(ct ) + λt [yt + (1 + r)at − ct − at+1 ],
t=0 t=0

First-order conditions:

∂L
= β t u0 (ct ) − λt = 0,
∂ct
∂L
= −λt + (1 + r)λt+1 = 0,
∂at+1
∂L
= −λT ≤ 0, aT+1 ≥ 0, λT aT+1 = 0
∂aT+1
Then:

u0 (ct )
= (1 + r) ∀ t = 0, 1, 2, ..., T. (Euler)
βu0 (ct+1 )
Solution to Household’s Problem II

Euler equation:
u0 (ct )
= (1 + r)
βu0 (ct+1 )
Complementary-slackness condition implies that:
aT+1
= 0, guarantees no-Ponzi games
(1 + r)T

Therefore, the present value budget constraint implies that:


T T
X ct X yt
t
= a0 (1 + r) + , a0 given.
(1 + r) (1 + r)t
t=0 t=0
Solution to Household’s Problem III
c1−θ
Let u(c) = 1−θ , then the Euler equation becomes:
1
ct+1 = (β(1 + r)) θ ct .

I Elasticity of substitution between consumption at two points in


time:
d(ct+1 /ct )/(ct+1 /ct ) d ln(ct+1 /ct ) 1
EIS = − d(1+r)
= = .
d ln(1 + r) θ
(1+r)

I When θ → 0, then any change in r generates large effects on


ct+1
ct . (“low preferences for consumption smoothing”).

I When θ → ∞, then any change in r generates small effects on


ct+1
ct . (“high preferences for consumption smoothing”).
Solution to Household’s Problem IV
Notice that:
1 1 t
c1 = (β(1 + r)) θ c0 , c2 = (β(1 + r)) θ c1 ⇒ ct = (β(1 + r)) θ c0 .

Using the present value budget constraint, we have that:


T 1
!t T
X [β(1 + r)] θ X yt
c0 = a0 (1 + r) + ,
(1 + r) (1 + r)t
t=0 t=0

1
[β(1+r)] θ
If b = (1+r) < 1 ⇔ β < (1 + r)θ−1 , then:
1
1 − [β(1+r)]
θ " T
#
(1+r)
X yt
c0 = T+1 (1 + r)a0 + .
(1 + r)t
 1
[β(1+r)] θ t=0
1− (1+r)
Solution to Household’s Problem V
I As T → ∞, then:
 
1
! Financial wealth ∞ 
[β(1 + r)] θ  z }| { X yt 
c0 = 1 −  a0 (1 + r) + t
.
(1 + r)  (1 + r) 
 t=0 
| {z } | {z }
Eat a fraction of life-time income
I Recall that, ln(1 − b) ≈ −b for b < 1. If β = 1
1+ρ , then in logs:
1
[β(1+r)] θ
(1+r) ≈ θ1 (r − ρ) − r, and −b = r − θ1 (r − ρ).
" ∞
 #
1 X yt
c0 = r − (r − ρ) a0 (1 + r) + .
θ (1 + r)t
t=0

If θ → 0 and r > ρ postpone consumption;


If θ → ∞, then consume r of total wealth;
Savings Under Uncertainty I

X∞
max Et { β j u(ct+j )}, subject to
at+j+1 ,ct+j
j=0
at+j+1 + ct+j = (1 + r)at+j + yt+j ∀ j,
at+1+J
lim Et ≥ 0.
J→∞ (1 + r)J
Assume: yt+j is a random variable. At t the agent know yt .


X ∞
X
j
L = Et { β u(ct+j ) + λt+j [(1 + r)at+j + yt+j − ct+j − at+j+1 ]},
j=0 j=0

∂L ∂L
= u0 (ct ) − λt = 0, = βEt [u0 (ct+1 )] − Et [λt+1 ] = 0,
∂ct ∂ct+1
∂L
= −λt + (1 + r)Et [λt+1 ] = 0,
∂at+1
Savings Under Uncertainty II

I Euler equation:

u0 (ct ) = β(1 + r)Et [u0 (ct+1 )].

I If β(1 + r) = 1 ⇒ u0 (ct ) = Et [u0 (ct+1 )]

I Suppose that variance of future consumption rise, then if u0 (c) is


strictly convex, then Et [u0 (ct+1 )] rises.

I By the Euler equation u0 (c) has to rise and ct falls (precautionary


savings).
Savings Under Uncertainty III

I Example: Quadratic utility function.


α2 2 α1
u(c) = α1 c − c , ⇒ u0 (c) = α1 − α2 c, c < .
2 α2
α1 − α2 ct = Et [α1 − α2 ct+1 ] ⇒ ct = Et [ct+1 ].
I Consumption follows a martingale and changes of consumption
can’t be predicted:

ct+1 = ct + µt+1 , Et [µt+1 ] = 0,

⇒ Et [∆ct+1 ] = 0.
Savings Under Uncertainty IV
Present value budget constraint:
   
∞ ∞
X 1 X 1
Et  ct+j  = at (1 + r) + Et  yt+j  .
(1 + r)j (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0

ct = Et [ct+1 ] and ct+1 = Et+1 [ct+2 ]


By the law of iterated expectations: Et [Et+1 (·)] = Et [·], then:

ct = Et [ct+1 ] ⇒ ct = Et [Et+1 (ct+2 )] = Et [ct+2 ] ... ct = Et [ct+2 ],


 
  ∞
1 1 X 1
ct 1 + + + ... = at (1+r)+Et  yt+j  .
(1 + r) (1 + r)2 (1 + r)j
j=0
  

r X 1
ct = at (1 + r) + Et  yt+j  ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0
Savings under uncertainty IV
At any period t:
  

r X 1
ct = at (1 + r) + Et  yt+j  ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0
  

r X 1
ct = rat + Et  yt+j  = r(at + Ht ) = yPt ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0

at : Financial wealth; and Ht : Human wealth. Consumption in t is then


the annuity value of total wealth.

If σy increases but does not change the expected value, then ct


remains the same (Certainty Equivalence Principle). It holds for a
quadratic utility function, but it is not a general result.
Savings under uncertainty V
  

r X 1
ct = at (1 + r) + Et  yt+j  ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0

and ct + at+1 = (1 + r)at + yt or (1 + r)at = ct + at+1 − yt


 

r X 1
ct = rat+1 + Et  yt+1+j  . Since
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0

  

r X 1
ct+1 = at+1 (1 + r) + Et+1  yt+j+1  ,
1+r (1 + r)j
j=0

∞ ∞
r X 1 X 1
ct+1 −ct = {Et+1 [ j
yt+1+j ]−Et [ yt+j+1 ]}.
1+r (1 + r) (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0
∞ ∞
r X 1 X 1
ct+1 −ct = {Et+1 [ yt+1+j ]−Et [ yt+j+1 ]}.
1+r (1 + r)j (1 + r)j
j=0 j=0

Interpretation:
I Consumption changes because new information arrives at date
t + 1;
I The new information arrives between t and t + 1 is yt+1 ;
I yt+1 can be decomposed into two parts:

yt+1 =Et [yt+1 ] + yt+1 − Et [yt+1 ] .


| {z } | {z }
Forecast at t Shock: new information
I Consumption should only react towards the new information
Robert Hall’s (1978) random walk test
I Basis of the test: Et (ct+1 ) = ct .

I Conditioned on present consumption, no other variable should


help to predict future consumption.
I Empirical Strategy: Run regression,
ct = γ0 + γ1 ct−1 + γ2 zt−1 + ηt , where zt−1 could be any lagged
variables.
I Data: Aggregate consumption, GDP and others.

I H0 : γ1 = 1 and γ2 = 0.

I Results: Null hypothesis is rejected


I consumption lagged more than one period and lagged income
have coefficients close to zero,
I but lagged return on stocks has prediction power on current
consumption.
Flavin’s (1981) excess sensitivity test I
I Assume that income process is a AR(q) process;
I yt+1 = α1 yt + α2 yt−1 + ... + αq yt+1−q + υt+1 .
I υt+1 is the new information at time t + 1.
I Under PIH, ct+1 − ct = ∆ct+1 = θυt+1 and ∆ct+1 should not
react towards Et [yt+1 ]
I Data: aggregate consumption and GDP

I Empirical Strategy:
I First run the income regression and get:

υt+1 = yt+1 − (α1 yt + α2 yt−1 + ... + αq yt+1−q )

I Run the consumption regression:

∆ct+1 = β0 + β1 ∆yt+1 + β2 ∆yt + θυt+1 + ηt

I β1 and β2 excess sensitivity parameters.


Flavin’s (1981) excess sensitivity test II

I ∆ct+1 = β0 + β1 ∆yt+1 + β2 ∆yt + θυt+1 + ηt

I PIH ⇒ H0 : β1 = 0 and β2 = 0;
I Consumption should react only to unexpected change in income
θ 6= 0.

I Results: βi 6= 0 and β1 = 0.355. Consumption reacts strongly


towards predicted income changes.

I Campbell and Mankiw (1989) found that excess sensitivity exists


for many countries other than US.

I What is wrong with this theory of consumption?


Saving is a buffer to income variations
I Frequent and short term income variations.
I due to job loss, illness, or other unforeseen events;
I Households usually build buffer stock in the form of saving
account in banks (more liquid) to prevent a dramatic fall in their
consumption when such an unfortunate event does occur. This is
precautionary motive of saving.

I Earning variations during life-cycle; age-earning profile is


hump-shaped;
I Over the life-cycle, consumption tracks income; excess
sensitivity;
I With perfect credit market, i.e., without borrowing limit,
household consumption should be more less constant. We should
observe young households borrow.
I That is not what we observe in the data. This suggests existence
of borrowing limits
Life-time consumpt. and income (Carroll, 1997, QJE)
Borrowing constraint

P∞ t u(c
I maxat+1 ,ct E0 { t=0 β t )}, subject to

at+1 + ct = (1 + r)at + yt ∀ t, at+1 ≥ −φ, φ[0, ∞).


I Euler eq. when at+1 > −φ: u0 (ct ) = β(1 + r)Et [u0 (ct+1 )].

I Euler eq. when at+1 = −φ: u0 (ct ) ≥ β(1 + r)Et [u0 (ct+1 )].
I Constrained household has lower consumption today and would
like to reduce future consumption to increase today’s
consumption but can’t.

I Point: The consumption growth rate of constrained households is


on average higher than that of unconstrained households.
Zeldes’ (1989) test of existence of liquidity constraint
I Data: PSID (Panel Study of Income Dynamics). Split the sample
into three groups:
I Constrained group has low wealth-to-income ratio;
I Unconstrained group has high wealth-to-income ratio;
I Omit the middle group.

I Maintained hypothesis: the two groups are identical in every


other aspect other than one group is temporary short on cash.
I Empirical Strategy:
I estimate preference parameter β and θ using data of
unconstrained group;
I Use the estimates and data of constrained group to compute the
following:
λt = β(1 + rt )Et [c−θ −θ
t+1 ] − ct .
I Test: H0 : λt = 0.
I Result: λt > 0. Liquidity constraint exists.
Next time:

Real Business Cycles

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy