Hall 1967
Hall 1967
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp
.
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.
The MIT Press is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The Review of
Economics and Statistics.
http://www.jstor.org
cases, no index of concentration, was available firms among the top 400 which were excluded appears in
an appendix available on request from Leonard W. Weiss,
for the industry to which they were assigned. Economics Department, University of Wisconsin, Madison,
A few of these were heavily committed to dis- Wisconsin, 53706.
that we have understated, if anything, the rayon [2, p. 170]. His capital requirement
relationship between size and profits. barrier reached its maximum in industries such
We can make some judgment about the as steel where minimum efficient scale may re-
height of the "capital requirements"barrier to quire 500 million dollars. Using this range
entry from the slopes of the curves in figure 3. only, equations (2) and (5) suggest that firms
Several of the industries in which Bain found in industries with such high entry fees could
only "moderate" barriers are typified by elevate HI1/Ei,from 8.8 to 10.4 or by about 18
"small"firms in the $50,000,000 neighborhood. per cent and could elevate IIit/Ait from 5.7 to
This is true of tires, metal containers, and 6.8 or by about 19 per cent without attracting
Rate of
Return
14
'3 -0(
2 ?
11
I0
@~~~~~~ it
O IlJI II * I I 1I I .1
20 Mn. 5OMn. IOOMn. 200Mn. 500 Mn. I Bn. 2Bn. 5Bn. IOBn.
entry from those capable of breaking into in- from firm size as a determinantof profits. This
dustries with moderate barriers. While these is an important conclusion because concentra-
figures are based on a slightly dubious regres- tion and size are correlated,5and without hold-
sion, any possible upward bias in them is ing concentration constant it would be impos-
probably offset by the very probable under- sible to distinguish the effects of size. As we
reporting of high profits. have measured it in table 1, the effect of con-
The expected tendency for the size-profit centration is significant but small. A 40-point
curve to flatten out proved very weak. This increase in Cj (from 30 to 70 which includes 77
suggests that capital is rationed approximately per cent of our observations) would increase
in proportion to assets over the whole range of Hj,1Ej,by only 0.7 to 1.1 points and would in-
large-scale firms observed and that the capital crease II1/Aj, by only 0.3 to 0.6 points. At the
cost barrier to entry is approximately propor- 5 The simple (unweighted) correlation coefficient relat-
tional to the log of assets. ing Cj to Att is .1569 and that relating C; to 1/log Ait is
Market concentrationturns out to be distinct -.2906.
a Percentages computed by (Vsk bk)/[ (Vk be) where Vk iS Qjt-k+l / Qj e- and be is the correspondingcoefficient from table 1.
6 Since the largest firm was also one of the most profit-
rates using the regression coefficients from
able firms (General Motors) we further tested our hypoth- table 1 and the mean values shown in the first
esis by running the same regressions with that firm ex-
cluded from the sample. The coefficients for 1/log Att were two columns of table 2.
reduced but were still significant. In equations correspond- The rapid drop in past influences sup-
ing to (1), (2), (4), and (5) but with concentration dum-
mies instead of the continuous concentration variable, the
ports Stigler's contension that market
coefficients for 1/log Att were: -123.7, -18.02, changes are rapidly translated into investment
(23.86) (7.079) changes and have only mild and temporary
-143.2, and -23.29, respectively. We would argue,
(16.27) (4.328)
effects on profitability [22, pp. 4-6, 18-19, 37,
however, that General Motors is perhaps the prime example and 69-70]. In his study the average correla-
of the Baumol hypothesis in the American economy today tion coefficient relating profit rates in year t
and that there is no good economic reason for excluding it
from the sample. We predict high profit rates in large firms
and in year (t + n) fell to nonsignificance by
and should not be surprised, therefore, when the largest the time n reached three years for the 1937-
firm yields one of the highest rates of return. Moreover, 1947 period and seven years for the 1947-
the rates of returns of the remaining large firms seem par-
ticularly likely to be understated because oil producers play
1957 period [22, pp. 70-71]. Our finding that
such a large role among them. changes in output five years back account for
-
10 8-I
III
To summarize,our main conclusions are that
size does tend to result in high profit rates as
Baumol proposed, that there is a significant
2 / though probably not enormous capital require-
ments barrier as a result, and that this barrier
/1 / very likely has a greater effect on profit rates
O 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 than concentration, the traditional index of
E/A market power. As by-product results of our
study we found support for Stigler's conten-
equity capital.9 The three sets of relationships tion that profits are almost completely equal-
are similar over the range of observations ized in about half a decade for firms of given
(.23 < Eit/Ait < .92) in both charts. The re- size and concentration,we detected a persistent
sulting values of (llt + r)/Ait still seem to be tendency toward lower profit rates as the 1956-
much more affected by the amount of leverage 1962 period progressed, and we found support
than is litl/Eit. Using equation (1) from table for the use of the ratio of profits to equity over
1 (i.e., figure 4), at the mean value of Eit/Ait, the ratio of profits plus interest to total assets
the elasticity of nitlEit with respect to Eit/Ait in inter-industry studies. These results have a
is .19, that of litl/Ait with respect to Eit/Ait is number of interesting implications.
1.19, and that of (iIlt + r)/Ait with respect to In Baumol, the size-profits hypothesis was
Eit/Ait is .72. It would take an interest rate of one of the bases for his contention that en-
10.5 per cent to make this elasticity as low as trepreneurs forego current profits to maximize
.19. Alternatively, it could equal .19 with a growth [5, p. 33]. He introduced various
mean interest rate of four per cent if the elas- other considerations in support of his sales
ticity of the interest rate with respect to Eit/Ait maximization hypothesis which we have not
were as great as -3.2. Since such high interest examined, but to the extent that his argument
rates and such high sensitivity of interest rates can be based on the size-profit relationship
to leverage seem quite unrealistic for firms of alone, we feel that we have given it some
the size discussed here, we conclude that the support.
rate of return on assets is, in fact, more sensi- The capital requirements barrier to entry,
tive to Eit/Ait than the rate of return on equity. about which Bain expressed uncertainty [2, p.
It follows that the latter-is, indeed, more nearly 156] and Stigler expressed skepticism [23, p.
equalized among industries and is therefore 27] would appear to be "substantial" though
the appropriateprofit measure to use for inter- probably not "high" unless accounting profits
industry comparisons. understate high profit rates by perhaps a half
The less reliable results shown in figure 5 or more. To go by Bain's final assignments of
largely confirm those of figure 4, though the overall barriers, this is apparently the evalua-
relationship derived from the lItl/Eit equation tion he gave to the barrier, also.
The classic criticism of "monopoly profits"
9 (Iltt+r)/Ait =Ilit/Att+.04 (1-Eut/Aut). The fig- has been that they imply product prices in ex-
ure four per cent is slightly lower than the Aaa bond rate for
1956-1962 (4.07) and the average short-term rates for loans cess of opportunity costs of factors employed
of more than $200,000 (4.59). Both figures were derived and therefore result in the misallocation of re-
from [8, pp. 199-200 and earlier issues]. Perhaps a differ- sources. To the extent that these profits are
ent interest rate could be justified since a substantial part
of (At - Eit) is accounts payable, reserve accounts, and
due to the capital requirements barrier rather
the like. than to concentration or other elements of