Lecture 3
Lecture 3
Lecture 3
x1
2
Slopes of Indifference Curves
The slope of an indifference curve (at
a given point) is its marginal rate-of-
substitution (MRS).
3
Economic Rationality
A decision maker chooses its most
preferred alternative from those
available to it.
5
Rational Constrained Choice
x2
More preferred
bundles
Affordable
bundles
x1
Rational Constrained Choice
x2
x2*
x1* x1
Rational Constrained Choice
x2 (x1*,x2*) is the most
preferred affordable
bundle.
How do we
mathematically
x2* solve for this
point?
x1* x1
Rational Constrained Choice
The most preferred affordable bundle
is the consumer’s ORDINARY
DEMAND at the given prices and
budget.
If
buying (x1*,x2*) costs $m then the
budget is exhausted since
p1x1* + p2x2* = m.
Rational Constrained Choice
x2 (x1*,x2*) is interior.
x1* x1
Rational Constrained Choice
x2 The slope of the indiff.
curve at (x1*,x2*) equals
the slope of the budget
constraint.
x2*
x1* x1
Rational Constrained Choice
(x1*,x2*) satisfies two conditions:
U (x 1,x 2 ) x x
a
1
b
2
Computing Ordinary Demands -
a Cobb-Douglas Example.
U (x 1,x 2 ) x xa
1
b
2
Then
U
MU1 ax 1a 1x b2
x1
U
MU 2 bx 1a x b2 1
x2
Computing Ordinary Demands -
a Cobb-Douglas Example.
So the MRS is
a 1 b
U / x 1 ax x ax 2
MRS - 1
2
U / x 2 bx x
a b 1
1 2
bx 1
ax 2 p1 bp 1 *
- x
*
x1 (A)
bx 1 p2 2
ap 2
Computing Ordinary Demands -
a Cobb-Douglas Example.
(x1*,x2*) also exhausts the budget so
px px m
1 1
* *
2 2
(B)
Computing Ordinary Demands -
a Cobb-Douglas Example.
So now we know that
bp 1 *
x *
2 x1 (A)
ap 2
px px m
1 1
* *
2 2
(B)
am
x
*
1
(a b )p 1
Computing Ordinary Demands
We find that the most preferred
affordable bundle for a consumer with
Cobb-Douglas preferences:
U (x 1,x 2 ) x x a
1
b
2
is am bm
(x , x ) (
* *
, ).
( a b ) p1 ( a b ) p 2
1 2
Computing Ordinary Demands -
a Cobb-Douglas Example.
x2
bm
x2*
( a b ) p2
am
x1*
( a b ) p1
x1
Rational Constrained Choice
When x1* > 0 and x2* > 0
and (x1*,x2*) exhausts the budget,
and indifference curves have no ‘kinks’
the ordinary demands are obtained by
solving:
(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = y
(b) the slopes of the budget constraint, -
p1/p2, and of the indifference curve
containing (x1*,x2*) are equal at (x1*,x2*).
Rational Constrained Choice
But what if x1* = 0?
Or if x2* = 0?
25
Examples of Corner Solutions --
Perfect Substitutes
x2
MRS = -1
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
the Perfect Substitutes Case
x2
MRS = -1 Which is the
optimal bundle?
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
the Perfect Substitutes Case
x2
MRS = -1
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
the Perfect Substitutes Case
x2
y MRS = -1
x 2*
p2
x 1* 0 x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
the Perfect Substitutes Case
x2
MRS = -1
x 2* 0 y
x 1* x1
p1
Perfect Substitutes Case
So when U(x1,x2) = x1 + x2, the most
preferred affordable bundle is (x1*,x2*)
where
y
( x , x ) ,0
*
1
*
2 if p1 < p2
p1
and
y
( x , x ) 0,
*
1
*
2
if p1 > p2.
p2
Basically, you only buy the good that is cheaper
since they are perfectly substitutable. (What if p1
= p2 ?)
Perfect Substitutes Case
x2
MRS = -1
y
p2 Slope = -p1/p2 with p1 = p2.
y
p1 x1
Perfect Substitutes
x2 All the bundles in the
constraint are equally the
y
p2 most preferred affordable
when p1 = p2.
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
Non-Convex Preferences
x2
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
Non-Convex Preferences
x2
Which is the most preferred
affordable bundle?
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
Non-Convex Preferences
x2
The most preferred
affordable bundle (on
the highest indiff.
curve)
x1
Examples of Corner Solutions --
Non-Convex Preferences
x2 Notice that the “tangency solution”
is not the most preferred affordable
bundle.
The most preferred
affordable bundle
x1
Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions --
the Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
x2 = ax1
x1
Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions --
the Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
x2 = ax1
x1
Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
x2 = ax1
x1
Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
The most preferred
affordable bundle (on
the highest indiff. curve)
x2 = ax1
x1
Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
x2 = ax1
x2*
x1* x1
Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m
x2 = ax1
x2*
x1* x1
Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m
(b) x2* = ax1*
x2 = ax1
x2*
x1* x1
Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions --
the Perfect Complements Case
(a) p1x1* + p2x2* = m; (b) x2* = ax1*.
Substitution from (b) for x2* in (a) gives
p1x1* + p2ax1* = m
which gives
m am
x
*
; x2
*
.
p1 ap 2 p1 ap 2
1
Examples of ‘Kinky’ Solutions --
the Perfect Complements Case
x2 U(x1,x2) = min{ax1,x2}
x2 = ax1
am
x
*
p1 ap 2
2
x1*
m x1
p1 ap 2
With the analytical tools, what
kind of research questions can we
ask?
48
Properties of Demand Functions
Comparativestatics analysis of
ordinary demand functions:
Why do we care?
49
Own-Price Changes
How does x1*(p1,p2,y) change as p1
changes, holding p2 and y constant?
Suppose only p1 increases, from p1’ to
p1’’ and then to p1’’’.
50
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’
What happens if
p1 increases?
x1
51
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’
X1 becomes
more
p1= p1’’ expensive
x1
52
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1x1 + p2x2 = y
p1 = p1’
p1=
p1’’’ p1= p1’’
x1
53
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’
x1*(p1’)
54
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’)
55
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’)
56
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
57
p1 Demand
Own-Price Changes for x1
Fixed p2 and y. decreases
as p1
increases.
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
58
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
59
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
p1 = p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
60
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y. p1’’’
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
61
p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and y. p1’’’ for commodity 1
p1’’
p1’
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
62
p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and y. p1’’’ for commodity 1
p1’’
p1 price
offer p1’
curve
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’) x 1*
x1*(p1’’)
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
x1*(p1’’)
63
Own-Price Changes
Thecurve containing all the utility-
maximizing bundles traced out as p1
changes, with p2 and y constant, is
the p1- price offer curve.
65
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
Take
a b
U( x 1 , x 2 ) x 1 x 2 .
Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
66
Own-Price Changes
a y
x*1 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
a b p1
and
b y
x*2 ( p1 , p 2 , y ) .
a b p2
Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
p1 price offer curve is flat
67
p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and y. for commodity 1
is
* ay
x1
( a b )p1
by
x
*
2
(a b )p 2 x 1*
x1*(p1’’’) x1*(p1’)
ay
x1*(p1’’) x 1*
(a b )p 1
68
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
69
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
U ( x 1 , x 2 ) m in x 1 , x 2 .
Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
70
Own-Price Changes
y
x*1 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) x*2 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) .
p1 p 2
71
Own-Price Changes
y
x*1 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) x*2 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) .
p1 p 2
* * y
As p1 0 , x1 x 2 .
p2
72
Own-Price Changes
y
x*1 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) x*2 ( p 1 , p 2 , y ) .
p1 p 2
* *
As p 1 , x1 x 2 0.
73
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
x1
74
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 = p1’
y/p2
x*2 p1’
y
p1’ p2 y x 1*
x*1
p1 ’ p 2
y
x*1 x1
p1’ p 2
75
p1
Own-Price Changes
p1’ increases to p1’’
x2
p1 = p1’’
y/p2 p1’’
p1’
x*2
y y x 1*
p1’’ p2 x*1
p1’’ p 2
y
x*1 x1
p1’’ p 2
76
Own-Price Changes p1
p1’’increases to p1’’’
p1’’’
x2
p1 = p1’’’
y/p2 p1’’
p1’
x*2 y x 1*
y x*1
p1’’’ p 2
p1’’’ p2
y
x*1 x1
p1’’’ p 2
77
p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and y. p1’’’ for commodity 1
x2 is
* y
p1’’ x1 .
y/p2 p1 p 2
x*2 p1’
y
p1 p2 y x 1*
p2
y
x*1 x1
p1 p 2
78
Own-Price Changes
What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-substitutes utility
function?
U(x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2 .
Then the ordinary demand functions
for commodities 1 and 2 are
79
Own-Price Changes
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 1 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 1 , if p 1 p 2
and
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 2 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 2 , if p 1 p 2 .
80
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 = p1’ < p2
Consume
only x1
x *2 0
* y
x1 x1
p1’
81
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 = p1’ < p2
p1’
* y x*
x1 1
p1’
x *2 0
* y
x1 x1
p1’
82
p1
Own-Price Changes
Increase p1 to p1’’
x2
p1 = p1’’ = p2
p1’
x 1*
x1
83
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 = p1’’ = p2
p1’
x 1*
x1
84
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 = p1’’ = p2
* y p1’
x2
p2
x 1*
All the bundles on the
constraint.
x 2 0
*
* y x
*
x1 0 x1 1
p1’’
85
p1
Own-Price Changes
p1 = p1’’ = p2
x2
p2 = p1’’
* y p1’
x2
p2
x 1*
0 x*1
y
p2
x 2 0
*
* y x1
*
x1 0 x1
p2
86
p1
Own-Price Changes
p1 continues to increase to p1’’’ p1’’’
x2
p2 = p1’’
* y p1’
x2
p2
x *1 0 x 1*
Only consume
X2 since X2 is
x *1 0 x1 cheaper.
87
p1 Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and y. p1’’’ for commodity 1
x2 * y
x1
p1
p2 = p1’’
p1 price
y p1’
offer
p2
curve x 1*
y
0 x*1
p2
x1
88
Inverse Demand
Usually
we ask “Given the price for
commodity 1 what is the quantity
demanded of commodity 1?”
89
Inverse Demand
p1
Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
p1’
x1*
90
Inverse Demand
p1
Given p1’, what quantity is
demanded of commodity 1?
Answer: x1’ units.
p1’
x1’ x1*
91
Inverse Demand
p1
The inverse question is:
Given x1’ units are demanded,
what is the price of commodity 1?
x1’ x1*
92
Inverse Demand
p1 The inverse question is:
Given x1’ units are demanded,
what is the price of commodity 1?
Answer: p1’
p1’
x1’ x1*
93
Inverse Demand
Takingquantity demanded as given
and then asking what must be price
describes the inverse demand
function of a commodity.
94
Inverse Demand
A Cobb-Douglas example:
ay
x*1
( a b )p1
ay
p1
( a b ) x*1
is the inverse demand function.
95
Inverse Demand
A perfect-complements example:
* y
x1
p1 p 2
y
p1 p2
x*1
97
Income Changes
How does the value of x1*(p1,p2,y)
change as y changes, holding both
p1 and p2 constant?
98
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
99
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2’’’
x2’’
x2’
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’
100
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x1’ x1’’’
x1’’
101
Income Changes
A plot of quantity demanded against
income is called an Engel curve.
102
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
105
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
An example of computing the
equations of Engel curves; the Cobb-
Douglas case.
a b
U( x 1 , x 2 ) x 1 x 2 .
The ordinary demand equations are
* ay * by
x1 ; x2 .
( a b )p1 ( a b )p 2
106
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
* ay * by
x1 ; x2 .
( a b )p1 ( a b )p 2
Rearranged to isolate y, these are:
( a b )p1 *
y x1 Engel curve for good 1
a
( a b )p 2 *
y x 2 Engel curve for good 2
b
107
Income Changes and Cobb-
Douglas Preferences
y ( a b )p1 *
y x1
a Engel curve
for good 1
x1*
y
( a b )p 2 *
y x2
b
Engel curve
for good 2
x2*
108
Discussion
The Covid outbreak resulted in significant
decline in household spending.
110
Discussion: Stimulating Tools
Vouchers: XX yuan to spend on retail or
service outlets
Shopping Coupons: x-yuan off if purchasing
y-yuan or more.
112
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Complementary Preferences
The perfectly-complementary case.
U ( x 1 , x 2 ) m in x 1 , x 2 .
113
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Complementary Preferences
* * y
x1 x 2 .
p1 p 2
Rearranged to isolate y, these are:
*
y ( p1 p 2 ) x 1 Engel curve for good 1
*
y ( p1 p 2 ) x 2 Engel curve for good 2
114
Income Changes
Fixed p1 and p2.
x2
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
x2’’’
x2’’
x2’
x1’ x1’’’ x1
x1’’
115
Income Changes y Engel
Fixed p1 and p2.
curve;
y’’’ good 2
x2 y’’
y’ < y’’ < y’’’
y’
118
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
* 0 , if p1 p 2
x 1 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 1 , if p1 p 2
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 2 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 2 , if p 1 p 2 .
119
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 1 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 1 , if p 1 p 2
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 2 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 2 , if p 1 p 2 .
y *
and x 2 0
*
Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1
p1
120
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 1 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 1 , if p 1 p 2
* 0 , if p 1 p 2
x 2 ( p1 , p 2 , y )
y / p 2 , if p 1 p 2 .
y *
and x 2 0
*
Suppose p1 < p2. Then x1
p1
*
y p 1x 1 and x 2 0 .
*
121
Income Changes and Perfectly-
Substitutable Preferences
y y
*
* x 2 0.
y p 1x 1
x1* 0 x2*
Engel curve Engel curve
for good 1 for good 2
122
Income Changes
In
every example so far the Engel
curves have all been straight lines.
123
Income Changes
124
Homotheticity
A consumer’s preferences are
homothetic if and only if
(x1,x2) p (y1,y2) (kx1,kx2) p (ky1,ky2)
for every k > 0.
Consumer’s preferences only depend
on the ratio of good 1 to good 2.
That is, the consumer’s MRS is the
same anywhere on a straight line
drawn from the origin.
125
A Nonhomothetic Example
Quasilinear preferences are not
homothetic.
U(x1 , x 2 ) f(x1 ) x 2 .
For example,
U(x1 , x 2 ) x1 x 2 .
126
Quasi-linear Indifference Curves
x2 Each curve is a vertically shifted
copy of the others.
x1
127
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility X1 increases
x2 first and then
stops
increasing.
y Engel
curve
for
good 1
x1 ~
x1 x1*
~
x1
128
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
Increasing the income doesn’t
change the demand for good 1 at all,
and all the extra income goes to the
consumption of good 2.
129
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
Suppose good 1 is rice and good 2
represents all other goods.
130
Income Changes; Quasilinear
Utility
Thisassumption may be plausible when
we examine a choice between all other
goods and some single good that isn’t a
large part of the budget.
131
Does the demand for a good always
increase as the income increases?
132
Normal and Inferior
Normal good: the demand for a normal
good would increase when income
increases.
133
Does the demand for a good always
increase as its own price reduces?
134
Ordinary Goods
A good is called ordinary if the
quantity demanded of it always
increases as its own price decreases.
135
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2 p1 decreases, the
budget line
becomes flatter
and the quantity
demanded of
good 1 increases.
x1
136
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
p1 price
offer
curve
x1
137
Ordinary Goods
Fixed p2 and y. Downward-sloping
x2 p1 demand curve
p1 price
offer Good 1 is
curve ordinary
x 1*
Quantity demanded
increases as price
x1 decreases.
138
Giffen Goods
If,for some values of its own price,
the quantity demanded of a good
rises as its own-price increases then
the good is called Giffen.
Do you have any examples?
139
Giffen Goods
Fixed p2 and y.
x2
A decrease in p1
reduces the
consumption of x1.
x1
140
Giffen Goods
Withthe extra money you have saved
because of the lower price of the
good, you decide to consume even
more better-quality stuff and reduce
your consumption of the Giffen good.
141
Giffen Goods
A Giffen good is a low-income, non-
luxury good for which demand
increases as the price increases.
142
Does the demand of a good
increase/decrease as the price of the
other good goes up?
143
Cross-Price Effects
Ifan increase in p2
– increases demand for commodity 1
then commodity 1 is a substitute for
commodity 2.
144
Cross-Price Effects
Perfect-complements example:
y
x*1
p1 p 2
so
x*1 y
0.
p2 p1 p 2 2
Therefore commodity 2 is a
complement for commodity 1.
145
Cross-Price Effects
A Cobb- Douglas example:
by
x*2
( a b )p 2
so
x*2
0.
p1
Therefore commodity 1 is neither a
complement nor a substitute for
commodity 2.
146
Exercise
Linda’s preferences over magazines (M)
and books (B) are given by:
147
Exercise
Linda’s preferences over magazines (M)
and books (B) are given by:
148
Effects of a Price Change
What happens when a commodity’s
price decreases?
149
Effects of a Price Change
2. Income effect: the consumer’s
budget of $y can purchase more
than before, as if the consumer’s
income rose, with consequent
income effects on quantities
demanded.
150
Effects of a Price Change
Consumer’s budget is $y.
x2
y Original choice
p2
x1
151
Effects of a Price Change
Consumer’s budget is $y.
x2
Lower price for commodity 1
y pivots the constraint outwards.
p2
x1
152
Effects of a Price Change
x2
Now only $y’ are needed to buy the
y original bundle at the new prices,
p2 as if the consumer’s income has
increased by $y - $y’.
y'
p2
x1
153
Effects of a Price Change
Changes to quantities demanded due
to this ‘extra’ income are the income
effect of the price change.
154
Effects of a Price Change
Slutskydiscovered that changes to
demand from a price change are
always the sum of a pure
substitution effect and an income
effect.
155
Real Income Changes
Slutsky asserted that if, at the new
prices,
– less income is needed to buy the
original bundle, “real income” is
increased
– more income is needed to buy the
original bundle, “real income” is
decreased
156
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
157
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
158
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
159
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
160
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
161
Real Income Changes
x2
x1
162
Pure Substitution Effect
Toisolate the change in demand due
only to the change in relative prices:
163
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
164
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
165
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
166
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
167
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
168
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
169
Pure Substitution Effect Only
x2 Lower p1 makes good 1 relatively
cheaper and causes a substitution
from good 2 to good 1.
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’,x2’’) is the
x 2’
pure substitution effect.
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
170
And Now The Income Effect
x2
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
171
And Now The Income Effect
x2 The income effect is
(x1’’,x2’’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
172
The Overall Change in Demand
x2 The change to demand due to
lower p1 is the sum of the
income and substitution effects,
(x1’,x2’) (x1’’’,x2’’’).
x 2’
(x1’’’,x2’’’)
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
173
Substitution and Income Effects
• The pivot gives the substitution effect,
and the shift gives the income effect.
174
Substitution and Income Effects
• Step 2: (shift) a movement where the
slope stays constant, and the purchasing
power changes.
175
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
Do these two effects work in the
same direction?
176
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
Most goods are normal (i.e. demand
increases with income).
The substitution and income effects
reinforce each other when a normal
good’s own price changes.
The two effects work in the same
direction.
177
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
x2 Good 1 is normal because
higher income increases
demand, so the income
and substitution
x 2’ (x1’’’,x2’’’) effects reinforce
each other.
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
178
Slutsky’s Effects for Normal Goods
Since both the substitution and income
effects increase demand when own-
price falls, a normal good’s ordinary
demand curve slopes down.
179
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
Some goods are income-inferior (i.e.
demand is reduced by higher
income).
180
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
181
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
182
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
x 2’
x 1’ x1
183
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
184
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
The pure substitution effect is as for
a normal good. But, ….
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
185
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2 The pure substitution effect is as for a
normal good. But, the income effect is
in the opposite direction.
(x1’’’,x2’’’)
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
186
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-Inferior
Goods
x2
The overall changes to demand are
the sums of the substitution and
(x ’’’,x ’’’) income effects.
1 2
x 2’
x2’’
x 1’ x1’’ x1
187
Slutsky’s Effects for Income-
Inferior Goods
A Giffen good is an inferior good and
the contrary income effect more than
offsets the substitution effect, and the
net effect of its price increase is to
increase demand for it.
188