0% found this document useful (0 votes)
88 views54 pages

Demand

The document discusses the properties of demand functions through comparative statics analysis. It examines how demand changes for a good as its own price changes, holding other prices and income constant. This generates the ordinary demand curve for the good. Examples are provided for Cobb-Douglas and perfect complements preferences, showing how their demand curves differ in shape. The analysis is also extended to examine how demand responds to changes in income, holding prices fixed.

Uploaded by

jamesyu
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
88 views54 pages

Demand

The document discusses the properties of demand functions through comparative statics analysis. It examines how demand changes for a good as its own price changes, holding other prices and income constant. This generates the ordinary demand curve for the good. Examples are provided for Cobb-Douglas and perfect complements preferences, showing how their demand curves differ in shape. The analysis is also extended to examine how demand responds to changes in income, holding prices fixed.

Uploaded by

jamesyu
Copyright
© Attribution Non-Commercial (BY-NC)
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PPT, PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 54

Demand

PROPORTIES OF DEMAND FUNCTIONS

◆ Comparative statics analysis of


ordinary demand functions: the
study of how ordinary demands
x1*(p1,p2,M) and x2*(p1,p2,M) change
as prices p1, p2 and income M
change.
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
◆ How does x1*(p1,p2,M) change as p1
changes, holding p2 and M constant?
◆ Suppose only p1 increases, from p1 =
1 to p1 = 2 and then to p1= 3.
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
x2 Fixed p2 and M
p1x1 + p2x2 = M
p1 = 1

x1
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1x1 + p2x2 = M
p1 = 1

p1= 2
x1
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1x1 + p2x2 = M
p1 = 1

p1= 3
p1= 2
x1
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1 = 1

P1= 1

x1*(p1=1) x1*

x1*(p1=1)
x1
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1 = 2

P1=1

x1*(p1=1) x1*

x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1 = 2
P1=2
P1=1

x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1*

x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2 P1=3
p1 = 3
P1=2
P1=1

x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1*

x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1


p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and M for product 1
x2 P1=3

P1=2

P1=1

x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1*

x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1


p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and M for product 1
x2 P1=3

P1=2
P1=1
P1 price
offer x1*
x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1)
curve

x1*(p1=3) x1*(p1=2) x1*(p1=1) x1


OWN-PRICE CHANGES
◆ The curve containing all the utility-
maximizing bundles traced out (in x1,
x2 space) as p1 changes, with p2 and
M constant, is the price offer curve.
◆ The plot of the x1co-ordinates of the
price offer curve against p1 is the
ordinary demand curve for product 1.
[Q = F(P) or X = F(P)]
Own-Price Changes
◆ Taking quantity demanded as given
and then asking what must be price
describes the inverse demand
function of a good. [P = F(Q) or P =
F(X)]
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
A Cobb-Douglas example:
* aM
x1 =
(a + b ) p1
is the ordinary demand function and
aM
p1 =
(a + b ) x1*
is the inverse demand function.
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
A perfect complements example:
M
x1* =
p1 + p2

is the ordinary demand function and


M
p1 = * − p2
x1
is the inverse demand function.
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
◆ What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for Cobb-Douglas preferences?
◆ Take
a b
U ( x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2

Then the ordinary demand functions


for goods 1 and 2 are
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
* aM
x1 ( p1 , p2 , M ) =
( a + b ) p1
and
* bM
x 2 ( p1 , p2 , M ) =
( a + b ) p2
Notice that x2* does not vary with p1 so the
price offer curve is flat and the ordinary
demand curve for product 1 is a
rectangular hyperbola.
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2

X2*=bM/
(a+b)p2

X1*=aM/ x1
(a+b)p1
p1
Own-Price Changes
Fixed p2 and M
x2

X2*=bM/
(a+b)p2 x1*

X1*=aM/ x1
(a+b)p1
p1
Ordinary
Own-Price Changes demand curve
Fixed p2 and M for product 1
x2 is
X1*=aM/(a+b)p1

X2*=bM/
(a+b)p2
x1*

X1*=aM/
x1
(a+b)p1
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS
◆ What does a p1 price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-complements utility
function?
U ( x1 , x 2 ) = min{ x1 , x 2 }
The ordinary demand functions
for products 1 and 2 are:
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS
M
x1* ( p1 , p2 , M ) = x2* ( p1 , p2 , M ) =
p1 + p2
With p2 and M fixed, higher p1 causes
smaller x1* and x2*.
M
As *
p1 →0, x1 *
= x2 →
p2

As * *
p1 → ∞ , x1 = x2 →0
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS
x2 Fixed p2 and M

x1
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
p1
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS
Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1 = p11
M/p2
p11
M
x2* =
p11 + p2 x1*
M
x1* = 1
p1 + p2

M x1
x1* =
p11 + p2
OWN-PRICE CHANGES p1
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS

Fixed p2 and M
x2
p1 = p12
M/p2 p12

p11

M
x2* = 2 x1*
p1 + p2 M
x1* = 2
p21 + p2

x1* = 2
M x1
p1 + p2
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
p1
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS
Fixed p2 and M. p13
x2
p1 = p13
M/p2 p12

p11

M x1*
x2* = 3 M
p1 + p2 x1* = 3
p1 + p2

x1* = 3
M x1
p1 + p2
p1
OWN-PRICE CHANGES Ordinary
PERFECT COMPLEMENTS demand curve
Fixed p2 and M p13 for product 1
x2 is
p12 * M
M/p2 x1 =
p1 + p2
p11
M
x2* =
p1 + p2
M x1*
p2

x1* =
M x1
p1 + p2
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT SUBSITUTES
◆ What does a price-offer curve look
like for a perfect-substitutes utility
function?
U ( x1 , x 2 ) = x1 + x 2
Then the ordinary demand functions
for products 1 and 2 are
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT SUBSTITUTES
 0, if p1 > p2
x ( p1 , p2 , M ) = 
*
1
 M / p1,if p1 < p2
and

0, if p1 < p2
x 2* ( p1 , p2 , M ) = 
M / p2 ,if p1 > p2
OWN-PRICE CHANGES
PERFECT SUBSTITUTES

Homework: Draw the diagrams.


INCOME CHANGES
◆ How does the value of x1*(p1,p2,M)
change as M changes, holding both
p1 and p2 constant?
INCOME CHANGES
◆ A plot of quantity demanded against
income is called an Engel curve.
INCOME CHANGES
Fixed p1 and p2

M1 < M2 < M3
Engel
Income curve;
offer curve M good 1
x 23 M3
x 22 M2
x 21 M1
x1 1
x1 3 x 11 x 13 x 1*
x 12 x 12
INCOME CHANGES M Engel
Fixed p1 and p2 curve;
M3 good 2
M2
M1 < M2 < M3
M1
Income
offer curve x 2
1 x 2
3
x 2*
x 22
x 23
x 22
x 21

x 11 x 13
x 12
INCOME CHANGES and
HOMOTHETIC PREFERENCES
◆ Demand for each good goes up by
the same proportion as income
◆ Income offer curve (also known as
the income expansion path) is a
straight line through the origin
◆ Engel curve is a straight line through
the origin
HOMOTHETICITY
◆ A consumer’s preferences are
homothetic if and only if
(x1, x2) > (y1, y2) ⇔ (tx1, tx2) > (ty1, ty2)
for all positive t.
HOMOTHETICITY
Linear expansion path through the
origin

X2

X1
Income Effects
◆ A product for which quantity
demanded rises with income is
called normal.
◆ Therefore a normal product’s Engel
curve is positively sloped.
Income Effects
◆ A product for which quantity
demanded falls as income increases
is called inferior.
◆ Therefore an inferior product’s Engel
curve is negatively sloped.
Income Changes: Products 1 & 2
M Engel
Normal curve;
M3 good 2
M2
M1
Income
offer curve M x 21 x 23 x 2*
x 22
x 23 M3
x 22 Engel
M2
x 21 curve;
M1
good 1
x 11 x 13 x 11 x 13 x 1*
x 12 x 12
As income
changes… Engel curves
M
x2 product 2

x 2*
M Inferior ∆x1/∆M<0
product 1
Normal ∆x1/∆M>0
x1 x 1*
Product 2 Is Normal, Product 1 Becomes Inferior
ORDINARY PRODUCTS
◆ A product is called ordinary if the
quantity demanded always increases
as its own price decreases.
ORDINARY PRODUCTS
Fixed p2 and M. Downward sloping
x2 p1 demand curve
p1 price


offer Product 1 is
curve ordinary

x1*

x1
GIFFEN PRODUCTS
◆ If, for some values of its own price,
the quantity demanded of a product
rises as its own price increases then
the product is called a Giffen
product.
GIFFEN PRODUCTS
Fixed p2 and M Demand curve has
x2 p1 a positively
p1 price offer sloped part
curve


Product 1 is
Giffen

x1*

x1
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS
◆ If an increase in p2
– increases demand for product 1 then
product 1 is a gross substitute for
product 2.
– reduces demand for product 1 then
product 1 is a gross complement for
product 2.
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS
A perfect complements example:
M
x1* =
p1 + p2
so
∂ x1* M
=− < 0.
∂ p2 ( p1 + p2 ) 2

Therefore product 2 is a gross


complement for product 1
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS
p1
Increase the price of
p13 product 2 from p21 to p22
and
p12

p11

x1*
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS
p1 Increase the price of
product 2 from p21 to p22
p13 and the demand curve
for product 1 shifts inwards
p12 -- product 2 is a
complement for product 1.
p11

x1*
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS

A Cobb- Douglas example:


* bM
x2 =
so ( a + b ) p2
CROSS PRICE EFFECTS
A Cobb- Douglas example:
bM
x 2* =
( a + b ) p2
so
∂ *
x2
=0
∂p1
Therefore product 1 is neither a gross
complement nor a gross substitute for
product 2.
SUMMARY I
Changes in income
*
Cobb Douglas * aM ∂ x a
x1 = ⇒ 1
= >0
p1 ∂ M p1

*
* M ∂ x11
Perfect Substitutes x1 = ⇒ = >0
p1 ∂ M p1

*
* M ∂ x 1
x1 = ⇒ 1
= >0
p1 + p2 ∂ M p1 + p2 Perfect Complements
SUMMARY II
Cross Price Changes
*
Cobb Douglas * aM ∂ x
x1 = ⇒ 1 =0
p1 ∂ p2

*
Perfect Substitutes * M ∂ x1
x1 = ⇒ =0
(Be Careful!) p1 ∂ p2
*
* M ∂ x −M
x1 = ⇒ 1
= <0
p1 + p2 ∂ p2 ( p1 + p2 ) 2
Perfect Complements

You might also like

pFad - Phonifier reborn

Pfad - The Proxy pFad of © 2024 Garber Painting. All rights reserved.

Note: This service is not intended for secure transactions such as banking, social media, email, or purchasing. Use at your own risk. We assume no liability whatsoever for broken pages.


Alternative Proxies:

Alternative Proxy

pFad Proxy

pFad v3 Proxy

pFad v4 Proxy