ECO2003P - Production
ECO2003P - Production
Microeconomics
Geraint.vanderrede@uct.ac.za
1
An Introduction to Production
We generally think about production as “raw materials
being turned into final goods”
3
The Production Function
Think of this like a recipe … but instead of eggs and flour and butter, we use capital
and labour
Obviously, capital and labour by themselves are not enough to make output – you
need raw materials as well.
You can’t just make bread out of bakers and ovens – you need flour, yeast, salt, etc.
But for simplicity of analysis, we will not model raw materials into our analysis
separately, but there is no reason why you can’t include these intermediate
products in the model.
4
The Production Function
2(2)(2)=8 2(3)(3)=18
1 2 3 4
3 6 12 18 24
How many machine-hours would you
need to create 60 units of output with 6
person-hours? 4 8 16 24 32
5
Fixed and Variable Inputs
Different factors take different lengths of time to change.
For example, does it take the same amount of time to buy and
set up a new factory as it does to hire a new worker?
This introduces the idea of the short run and the long run
VS
6
Fixed and Variable Inputs
Short run: The longest period of time during which at least one of the inputs cannot be varied
Long run: The shortest period of time required to alter the amounts of all inputs in the process
If the input can be changed in the short run, then it is a variable input.
If the input cannot be changed in the short run (or if it can, it costs an enormous amount of
money), then it is considered a fixed input.
In the production of good grades for this course, what would the inputs be? Menti.com -
530646
7
Production in the Short Run
In the short run we assume that capital is a fixed input.
8
Production in the Short Run
Let’s do an example:
Draw the short run production function that corresponds to where capital is fixed at K 0 = 4.
𝐹 ( 4 , 𝐿 )= √ 4 𝐿=2 √ 𝐿
Output
Labour
9
Production in the Short Run
As you saw in the example, we aren’t limited to straight line production functions – in fact, one of
the most common production function shapes is non-linear.
10
Production in the Short Run
11
Production in the Short Run
Some things to think about:
Why might you start off by seeing increasing levels of the variable input increasing output at an
increasing rate?
Maybe there is something to do with benefits from division of tasks – when you’re making
sandwiches, maybe having two people instead of one person means you get specialisation.
Does the concept of diminishing marginal returns make sense in reality? Do we see it in practice?
It does seem to make sense. Think about our group of sandwich makers. Does adding a third person
really make such a difference to our total production? What about a fourth person?
At what point do we see everyone getting distracted and sitting around drinking tea? 12
Technology in the Production
Function
In 1798, Thomas Malthus said that the law of diminishing marginal returns basically meant that because land is
fixed, having more farmworkers would ultimately add less and less to food production and we would all starve to
death. He predicted that average food consumption per capita would be driven down to starvation level.
But he didn’t account for technological advances, which might not spell doom and gloom for the human race.
BUT we still saw diminishing returns – it’s just that the growth in technology outstripped the effect of diminishing
returns.
Unfortunately, the logic of Malthus’ prediction still holds: if the population continues to grow, the limits on the
amount of land we have will spell food shortages.
Why?
14
Total, Marginal and Average
Products
We are now moving on to define some important concepts in the theory of production:
Total product curve: A curve showing the total amount of output as a function of the amount
of variable input (think about this as the graph of the production function)
Average product: Total product divided by the number of units of the variable input used in the
production process.
Marginal product: Change in total product due to a one-unit change in the variable input.
15
Marginal Product
Geometrically, marginal product is the slope of the
total product curve.
Discrete MP:
Continuous MP:
16
Marginal Product
L
17
Average Product
Algebraically:
L
18
Average Product and Marginal Product
Suppose you have a fleet of fishing boats and you have 2 boats on each end of a lake. You get
100kg of fish from each boat sent to the East end of the lake, and 120kg of fish from each boat
sent to the West side of the lake.
Should you change your allocation of boats?
Not necessarily – it depends on what gains you get from sending the third boat to the West
side.
The question hinges on marginal product, but most people seem to answer this question by
thinking about average product.
21
Practical Considerations of MP
and AP
Number of East End West End
Boats
TP AP MP TP AP MP
0 0 0 0 0
Here, it makes no sense to send the third boat to the West End as the marginal gain from doing so is not
worth it. 22
Practical Considerations of MP
and AP
Number of East End West End
Boats
TP AP MP TP AP MP
0 0 0 0 0
Here, it does make sense to send the third (and fourth) boat to the West End as the marginal gain from
doing so outstrips what they could earn you in the East End
23
Practical Considerations of MP
and AP
Basically, you have to consider how to best allocate your resources – how
do you do it?
If you have perfectly divisible inputs, and for processes where the MP of
one isn’t always higher than the MP of the other, you should allocate this
input between production processes until the marginal product is equal
across both processes.
24
Example
Given the following function for baking loaves of
bread To maximise output, we need to hire 7 labourers
2. 215
Where L= hours spent baking loaves The maximum output produced when the firm hires 7
labourers
1. Where is Q maximised? 3.
This can be used to find the marginal product of each
2. What is this maximum value of Q? respective worker. To find the
marginal product of the 5 worker,
th
simply substitute 5 in for L.
3. Write an expression for MPL.
4.
4. Write an expression for APL.
We could use this function to find the average product of
5. What is the MPL and APL when L=2? labour for any number of workers
5.
25
ECO2003 – Intermediate
Microeconomics
Geraint.vanderrede@uct.ac.za
26
Production in the Long Run
Recall: the long run is the shortest period of time it takes for all
inputs to become variable.
27
Production in the Long Run
How do we graph production in the long run?
So, we choose a value for Q, say Q0, and plot our graph in L-K space.
Does this remind you of something? Maybe how we represent 3D utility functions with
indifference curves.
28
Production in the Long Run
So, for Q = 2KL:
Assume Q=Q0=16
Assume Q=Q1=32
Assume Q=2C (Arbitrary constant)
This is a rectangular hyperbola defined for
positive K, L and C.
Rearranging, we get:
32
Thus, we can write
Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution
33
Returns to Scale
It is very important to remember the distinction between diminishing returns and decreasing
returns:
Diminishing marginal returns: a short run concept which talks about how output changes due
to an increase in a specific factor.
Decreasing returns to scale: a long run concept which talks about how an increase in every
factor affects total production.
Firms with increasing, decreasing or constant returns to scale will probably still exhibit
diminishing returns.
36
Returns to Scale vs. Diminishing
Returns
Your returns to scale depend crucially on the
production function you are dealing with.
There are 3 basic types of production functions you will come across:
1. Cobb-Douglas function (this is the most commonly used function)
This is the function used when the inputs are perfect complements
3. Straight line production function
This is the function used when the inputs are perfect substitutes 38
The Leontief (Fixed Proportions) Production Function
Example:
MRTS does not exist
Assume K=1 and L=1.
MRTS=/undefined
Thus, Q = min{2(1), 3(1)} = min{2, 3} = 2
Does it help us at all if K increases and L doesn’t?