08 Chapter 3
08 Chapter 3
08 Chapter 3
CHAPTER - 3
POWER AND AUTHORITY IN THE COUNTRYSIDE
This chapter focuses on the evolution of the doras in the diwani or khalsa
(directly government ruled) areas. Theirs is a history of the evolution of new cultural
and political domination in Telangana, against which, the Telangana struggle was
fought. The village landlords belonging to a upper caste are called doras even today
in the Telangana villages. Mostly, the former deshmukhs or watandars (hereditary
local chiefs recognized / appointed by the rulers) were called the doras. In course of
time all upper caste landlords or their relatives were also called doras. Therefore, all
doras need not be former deshmukhs. Thought the peoples struggle in Telangana
was carried out against the jagirdars and the doras, the former without strong local
roots either surrendered or ran away. But the doras put up a strong fight against the
people. The structure of their domination and power was based on the enforcement of
physical coercion and obstruction of free market in land and labour. Therefore, they
became the prime target of the people.
93
The doras in Telangana present a unique case in the survival of the landlords
having their roots for over 300 hundred years in the pre-independence period,
undergoing transformation, and adapting to the changing circumstances and needs.
Even in the face of opposition from the people at the beginning of the twentieth
century, the doras attempted to consolidate their domination at social and cultural
levels, citing reasons like their upper caste position and domination in the past.
In Telangana, a part of the Deccan region, the office of deshmukh came into
existence during the medieval period, and survived for a long period as local chiefs
whose sphere of power often spread to a pargana. A pargana usually consisted of
twenty to sixty villages. The deshmukhs presided over the meetings of the chiefs in
the pargana known as gotsabha (regional council of local chiefs), which decided and
confirmed claims over inheritance, purchase and transfer of watans. Being locally
powerful, they were absorbed into the regional political and administrative structure
by the Qutb Shah kings as revenue collectors. This office got deeply entrenched into
94
the region with local support and structured in organized community life by the end
of the seventeenth century.
pargana and deep local roots could not easily be displaced by the ruler. The first ruler
of Asafjah dynasty, Nizam-ul-Mulk realized this fact and depended upon them to
carry on the administration.
(magisterial and judicial) and became the chiefs of the parganas. Gradually, the
office of the deshmukh tended to become a watan, i.e, hereditary lease. Despite
changes in the political authority at the top, the office of the deshmukh survived since
no ruler wished to risk disturbing the local administration.
95
abandoned the role they formerly played in the local communities. They were only
contractors or managers for the time being but not proprietors. However, some of
them did not agree to the new arrangement and the British had to fight in many places
to bring some of the locally powerful rebel deshmukhs under their control. Most of
them were respectable in their respective areas and had established themselves as
powerful chiefs. The Aswaraopet deshmukh, for example, occupied the ghurry
[gadi] a neat and strong stone structure of1000 yards and maintain [ed] at his own
expense a retinue of 100 sebundee peons besides a few horses. But by and large
they had been brought under the new regime either through battles or threats and were
co-opted as revenue collectors for the new regime. But the difficulty of introducing
the new system was chiefly experienced in Telangana where the payment in kind has
always been prevalent which helped them play the role of merchants by taking
revenue in kind and paying cash to the state; this role widened their activity and
enlarged their power. Thus they played the additional role of merchants and usurers
under colonial rule restricting the local bania, komati to shop-keeping.
96
replacing the British stooge Raja Chandulal in 1853. The main task of Salarjung I
was to bring such deserted lands under cultivation apart from introducing other
policies to promote agrarian production and trade.
As part of the reforms, the patta (ownership) right over land was introduced
after introduction of zillabandi (yearly district-wise confirmation of land ownership
rights) in 1865.
Though the loss of watans deprived them of their title of deshmukh and power
over paraganas, yet under the new reforms, they were converted into big landlords
with judicial and legal guarantee to their proprietary rights. These reforms helped
97
them to stabilize their position as permanent landlords unlike the earlier uncertain and
speculative sarbasta or tahud. They were also able to lease in government lands under
various tenures like makta (panmakta and bilmakta), ijara and banjara to bring not
only deserted lands but also forests under cultivation to increase agrarian production.
Thus locally powerful landlord families acquired new titles such as maktadars,
ijaradars and banjaradars, though all of them were not necessarily from the former
deshmukh families. These tenure-holders had to bring new land under cultivation and
guarantee the cultivation. For this purpose, again they got some more land on patta
right.
The pattern of land settlement during the 1880s was in favour of large
holdings, which naturally helped the emergence of big landholders.
It was not
unusual for influential village bosses to make their way into the survey records as
pattadars by bribing survey officials. Even the official survey favoured them because,
while surveying the land, all surrounding waste/uncultivated barren lands in between
the ridges with thorny shrubs and bushes were attached to the actually cultivated
terraced fields. Hence, even today, large holdings of about twenty to hundred acres
may be observed under a single survey number. Under such a survey, the cultivator
had to pay land revenue for the surrounding uncultivated land full of thorny shrubs
and granite rooks which required intensive human labour for clearing.
Small
cultivators who could not bring such barren lands under cultivation often surrendered
even cultivating lands to the government. The states concern was to maximize
revenue by forcing cultivators to expand the arable land, which ultimately favoured
98
the emergence of big landlords. Those cultivators, who were confident of carrying on
large-scale cultivation by clearing shrubs and constructing water tanks for irrigation
purposes supported by capital and the capacity to employ adequate labourers, took
overland under patta right. It was not possible for small peasants who, mainly relying
on family labour to bring such lands under cultivation. The settlement officials did
not take this fact into account; instead they preferred to promote the landlord
agriculture, in the state.
revenue, poor quality of soil and peasants dependence on market for money, peasant
agriculture became unviable. On the other hand, the landlord got the land directly
cultivated by vetti therefore large-scale share-cropping or tenancy cultivation did not
exist in Telangana. Thus historical and ecological reasons did not favour the growth
of small peasant holdings in Telangana.
99
The British colonial influence was another important exogenous factor that
contributed to the growth of the landlord economy in Telangana. The fixing of the
responsibility of regular payment of land revenue on the landholder (during the
Salarjung reforms) was conditioned by the demands of the British colonial
domination. The basic thrust of the Salarjung policy was to increase the volume of
Hyderabads external trade to expand the state revenues. The British administrators,
led by Director General of Revenue, A.J. Dunlop, in the 1890s planned to promote
commodity production within the state.
castor seed [were] originally exempted from [excise] duty in pursuance of the
colonial interest to promote its production in the state. The autonomy given to
Salarjung I by the Resident in introducing the reforms was obviously motivated by
colonial interests to develop agrarian production in the late nineteenth century.
The two conditions outlined above the pattern of land settlement and the
state-induced production for the external market were important factors, which
guided the pattern of production in the state. The landlord economy which emerged
out of Salarjungs reforms, worked most suitably and efficiently using vast lands and
cheap labour, responding positively to the changing needs and circumstances. It was
during the heyday of the landlord dominated economy that Hyderabads agrarian
produce castor seed, sesame, cotton, tobacco, rice, wheat, jowar, bajra and pulses
entered the external market. Due to this change the states revenue on account of
external trade increased by about forty per cent between 1875-76 and 1889-90.
100
The landlords had the advantages of possessing enough liquid capital to meet
the farm requirements. The state granted them a regular annual rusum (remuneration
or a sort of pension) after abolition of revenue farming. Later by taking up excise
contacts and money-lending they acquired additional capital. This proved to be very
lucrative in a situation of hard currency scarcity in the villages after the state made
revenue payment in cash compulsory.
available in Telangana. The landlords forcibly transformed the large mass of rural
poor into servile labour, thus ensuring regular and constant supply of labourers. The
service castes of the village, holding inam had were forced to work free on landlords
land; though the inam grants were made to facilitate professional services like
shaving, making pots in villages rather than work for the landlords. Landlords thus
by attaching labourers to their domestic and agricultural work, converted them into
vetti (forced) labour. They also converted the untouchable and low-caste traditional
musicians, bards and genealogists into bhagelas (servile labourers attached to dora
family), when more labour was required to intensify agricultural production. In the
process, the growth of a free labour market was restricted. Seizing the economic
opportunities that colonialism threw up during (Salarjung-I reforms) the late 19th
century, the landlords with the help of servile labour, diverted their vast lands to the
101
cultivation of commercial crops like castor and groundnuts. However, it was also
easy to cultivate castor and groundnuts, as they do not require constant attention.
102
The landlords subdued the people with their authority whereas the patwaris
exercised control over them through various kinds of machinations. The landlords
and the village officers sometimes vied with each other to prove their superiority. But
despite these hiccups they often coalesced into one to prolong the system of
oppression and exploitation. They shared a conviction that the emerging awareness
of people would spell their doom and the unity of both the doras and village officials
was recognized by both as a way of retaining their strengths.
The third group in the hierarchy was the village landholders with considerable
size of patta land. They emerged as a distinct social group from amongst the kapus
who distanced themselves from the lower-caste sudras. However, they were different
from the landlords, these landholders lived mostly in bhavanti (a bungalow of rich in
villages) type pucca houses and had enough cattle, land and stocks of grain and
agricultural implements. In appearance and dress they looked like peasants, but they
lived with izzat (dignity) enjoying the status of asamis, pedda kapus, pedda rytus or
motubari rytus. Though they could read and write they were considered uneducated
in the sense that they were not aware of the intricacies of the government rules. They
were not conversant with Urdu and were unable to meet officers and get their work
done. Their sons and in some cases even their daughters were provided modern
education.
103
In other words, these dominant landholding motubaries obliged and endorsed the
doras effort in enforcing caste-based labour exploitation.
104
the peasant paid his rent or revenue he could not be evicted by anybody. Cultivation
of land was considered a socially vital function. There was zamindari oppression of
the peasantry but since the rights of the landed aristocracy were not absolute, it was
limited to extortion of revenue. Whenever signs of decay of the imperial power
became visible, ambitious zamindars and local chieftains rebelled against the emperor
and asserted their own political independence. 3
Initially all agrarian classes were distressed by the governments high revenue
demands. Although the economic burden was greater for the lower strata of peasantry,
the peasants revolted against their oppressors the landlords under whom they held
land.4 The body of the royal army was the cultivating peasant who resisted the
zamindars, money lenders. Between 1840 and 1857, the transfer of land from
cultivators to non-cultivating classes of money-lenders, urban traders and so on had
increased considerably. Evictions, imposition of levies and illegal taxes by corrupt
revenue officials had steadily built up tension.
Another important factor that contributed to the growth of the alliance between
the landlords, money- lenders and the British was the revenue demands which were
steadily going up throughout the latter half of the nineteenth century. Cash was
needed to meet the demands. At times the market price of agricultural produce would
fall and further pressurize peasants into borrowing. Similarly, the wages of
105
agricultural labourers who constituted the lowest stratum did not rise proportionately
with the cost of living. This too contributed to growing indebtedness and strengthened
the position of the money-lenders and landlords in rural India.
There was a growing population of the cultivating classes in the latter half of
the nineteenth century. The zamindars had powers to create fresh tenures and this
sub-infeudation had multiplied a number of intermediary proprietors between the state
and the actual cultivator. The demand for cultivatable land increased. This naturally
benefitted landlords, land speculators and money-lenders. Rents increased arbitrarily
by landlords because no tenant could afford to give up land, and similarly, moneylenders could tighten their grip on the credit seeking peasantry.
In the Jagirdari areas, rising land values enabled the landed classes to resort to
somewhat different form of oppression. Most of them also supplied credit to their
tenantry; rent enhancement and rack- renting were of course more profitable devices
to exploit the needy peasant. In the decades following the 1857 mutiny, then the
landowning and money lending classes gradually rose to power in the rural area. It
had immediate and direct social consequences of the petty revenue officials, police
now safeguarded the interests of the usurers the money lending and rich landowning
classes. The new alliance also worked against the interests of small land owners, and
share croppers who constituted the poor peasants.
106
The money lenders tyranny prevailed throughout the latter half of nineteenth
century and its immediate victims were the small landholders, tenants and under
tenants, and share croppers, whose lands were passing to the money lenders and rich
land owners. The economic lot of the landless agricultural labourer was still worse on
account of poor wages and high cost of living. The disturbances, known as Deccan
riots of 1875, occurred in western Maharashtra, After the British introduced the
ryotwari system of land tenure, the old institution of caste and the village
communities had little role to play as landlords they
individually responsible to the state for payment of revenue. The vanis, a caste of
merchants and money-lenders, supplied credit in the Deccan villages. At the village
level the vanis, being the only source of credit gained considerable economic power.
As land value went up, the vanis intensified the usurpation of peasants lands through
civil suits. The vanis took no interest in actual cultivation owing to their social
values. The newly acquired lands were cultivated by the former proprietors, who now
worked as sub-tenants and the vanis left them only a bare subsistence.5
107
debt relief is organized. Small and fragmented holdings had their definite impact on
agricultural production and also the condition of their cultivating owners. The
holdings being uneconomical restricted the scope and capacity of the cultivator to
invest profitably on well construction. This compelled many such farmers owning
insufficient holdings to leave their fields. During the off -season and serve themselves
as agricultural labourers.7 In the fragmented plots much cultivable land was wasted
on hedges and paths. The worst of all the effects of these unprofitable holdings was
that they formed one of the basic causes of debt.
Though Taccavi was advanced for well sinking, only those ryots who
promised to grow food crops for first five years could get the benefits. After wells,
108
kuntas and tanks formed the largest source of irrigation. Though they were 50%
higher in number than larger tanks, get, due to vagaries of the monsoon, water
sufficient for wet cultivation could be collected only once in four or five years. But
the cultivations were charged wet rate even during the lean period, they were made to
go round patwaris and Girdavars for recommending talaf-mal on account of crop
failure.9 Intending and affording pattedars were allowed to construct tanks and they
were also held responsible for their repair and upkeep. Netris or neerudus were
appointed to look after the release of water to the fields pertaining to Government
tanks for which purpose they granted. Inam land also tax remission amounting to
Rs.36/- per year.10 A tank in Jafargadh, a Sarf-e-Khas village in Warangal district
that got breached in 1901 was not repaired even upto 1933.11
The taluqs of
109
Sl.
Taluq
No
Total
By
area
By
Tanks
Wells
Canals Canals
shown
Govt.
Private
Other
Total
sources
(acres)
1
Warangal
333192
4019
955
12330
4581
155
16961
Khammam
313005
3910
349
29812
3243
1905
33957
Mahboobabad
343052
2617
601
32353
42359
Madhira
194427
1249
107
16337
16407
Pakhal
67362
950
500
27646
1438
38084
Palaoncha
127460
1071
300
2618
7618
Mulugu
91825
549
169
1564
564
Yellandu
86620
744
201
16514
16514
Paloncha(s)
989
2575
2575
10
Kanath
19841
239
709
731
966
97
109
1576784
16337
3946
140916
11792
2157
175148
Total
Dist.
Warangal
110
Sl.
Taluq
No.
Total
area
shown
By
By
Tanks
Wells
Canals Canals
Govt.
Other
Total
sources
Private
(acres)
1
Jagityal
266521
4426
20215
4635
1321
42987
Sultanabad
199909
1500
201398
1806
4369
17619
Karimnagar
331942
2044
1511
28550
4200
529
47723
Sircilla
217606
2355
550
25150
5120
910
47199
Huzurabad
178884
1500
16714
7277
1454
19891
Parkal
173173
18596
2117
1886
14599
Mahadeopur
138841
170
20664
325
11159
Metpalli(J)
40299
5894
900
432
5235
Peddapalli (J)
94403
350
2936
1576
4662
10
Vemulawada(J)
1862
811
15
126
11
Kamanpur
13812
1443
1493
Total
Karimnagar
1657452
11995
47
10901 214693
Dist.
(J) = Jagir
Source: Hyderabad District Gazetteer Tables Volumes 1931 & 1936, Warangal,
pp.300-1; Karimnagar, p.380.
111
Ryots applied for Taccavi loans only when they were in extreme need and
failed to get credit through other sources for it involved lot of delay, effort and
expense to get through.12 Another significant point that emerged in this connection
was that the lists of loan distribution showed that real, needy and poor ryots were not
benefitted out of this, but instead, influential big landlords, patels, patwaris and
Deshmukhs received their gains that resulted.13 Very often, the latter even misused
them in the sense that taccavi wheat and paddy taken for the purpose of sowing were
used instead, for domestic purposes.14
112
only for by this, they not only received the usual rate of interest but also had the
added advantage of receiving the grain at the rate of Rs.5/- per khandy.16
The jagirdars were so powerful that they could grab the land by framed, which
reduced the actual cultivator to the status of a tenant at will or landless labour.
Moreover, the Jagirdars, Zamindars, Deshmukhs and Deshpandes exploited their
tenants and labourers through such pernicious practices as vetti or forced labour. It
has been generally suggested that feudal domination in Telangana was prominently
expressed by force (physical) and coercion.
The Doras were able to resort to various methods of surplus extraction and
extended their control over the countryside. The nature of Telangana feudalism and
feudal domination is merely listing of certain Jagirdars and Deshmukhs who held big
estates. Caste must be seen as a material reality and a solid foundation of socioeconomic production, for in Telangana, it shaped the evolution of agrarian relation
and perpetuated feudal landlord power and authority caste in rural Telangana not only
113
Most important among the serfi rights was that of working on a particular
piece of land. If he was born into a family owned by a particular landholder, the
114
landholder had the obligation to employ him on the land and pay him the customary
wages. But two points are very relevant here: First , Although the serf may have had
some right to share in the produce of his land he had far fewer economic rights than
the Jagirdar or tenant, his share of the produce was very much smaller, and he had
moreover no right to sell the land. Secondly, the right to work on a particular plot of
land was not always granted. In certain parts of India the agricultural labours was in
some respects treated like a commodity of production. In early nineteenth century
there was a great variety of institutional forms, ranging from slavery to completely
free hired labour and these covered not only agricultural labourers but also domestic
servants and even artisans.19
The Baghela system, the balutha, the begar (involuntary labour), the vetti, the
slave labour and the bonded labour are different forms of serfdom the characteristic of
feudal society where the zamindars and jagirdars claimed a number of petty
perquisites from the peasantry and other depressed castes of the society. The
landlords assumed entitlement to exhort labour services from begar, vetti and other
forms of labour without any remuneration paid or treated it as a compulsory free
labour from certain depressed and landless castes of the society. Taking the perpetual
poverty as the advantage, the depressed castes and landless castes and communities
were advanced with petty amounts on usurious loans, they either became slave labour
or worked as a Baghela or Balutha or bonded labour. The problem of bonded labour
has become a serious issue in the Agrarian relation of Indian society and particularly
115
in the Hyderabad State. The landlords exploited the people of all classes and castes
under these systems.
In the process of social evolution the tradition paved a way for the pervasive
and cruel practices resulting in the dominance of some castes over the others. The
Reddy, the karnam and the Komati acquired dominance over the other castes
becoming three leeches of the village, viz., the deshmukh, the patwari and the money
lender.
The zamindari and jagirdari feudal estates the feudal system adopted
pervasive, vulgar, cruel, oppressive methods to exploit and dominate over the people,
particularly the low castes.
Caste system played a crucial role in India in its inexorable way to create a
fixed labour reserve force for agricultural production. Members of the low caste
families were assigned most menial and contemptible occupations, who could never
aspire to the status of peasants and landless labourer indicates certain degree of class
differentiation in the rural areas.20
Infact the status of many of them semi servile, involving a kind of bondage to
high caste peasants and landlords. Almost every craft, carpentry, pottery, smiths etc,
was the business of separate castes. It was observed, that even if the separation of
trades was originally spontaneously developed it was crystallized and finally made
permanent by law. The caste system played the same role In Hyderabad state also.
The field labour was recruited from almost all the communities except the Brahmins,
116
Komatis, Kshatriyas and Sutars. Domestic servants drew mainly from Bedars,
Hajjams, Lingayats, Telagas, Sunars, etc.21
Vetti in Telangana:
117
to do vetti. Their job was to work in the house of the Deshmukh, Patwari and Patel
mali-patel to carry reports to the police station, Tahasil office, watching the village
chavidi. They also work for the officers who visited the villages. They collected wood
from the forests for fuel and carried post and supplies. They were supposed to be paid
one anna for carrying post from 2 miles distance, which was not honoured in
practice.22
The vetti system was not restricted to the untouchables alone, other people like
Boyalu (Hunters), Bestalu (fisher men ) and chakali (washer men ) were forced to
carry on their shoulders men and women of the land lord families in pallakis or
Minas, specially made carriers over long distance from one village to another. The
servants were made to run fast before and behind the fast driven bullock carts
whenever the members of the landlord families travelled as path cleaners and escort. 23
It could be observed that the Agrarian structure in Hyderabad state was like a page
from medieval feudal history.24 Although the general pattern of land tenure in the
state was Ryotwari, the number of big landlords owning large area of lands was
tremendous.25
Mahboobnagar and Warangal, the number of pattadars owning more than 500 acres
was about 550, owning 60 to 70% of the total cultivable land.26
118
The Deshmukhs and Deshpandes were traditional tax collectors for the Government.
When the Government introduced direct collection by itself, the Deshmukhs and
Deshpandes were granted watan or mash based on the percentage of the past
collection. The Deshmukhs and Deshpandes due to their access to land records
fraudulently grabbed thousands of acres of fertile cultivated lands and made it their
own property. The peasants cultivating those lands were unaware of this grab, and
were thus reduced in such process to the position of tenants at-will or become landless
labourers. It was felt that the landlords started their grab or forcible occupation of the
peasants lands during the first survey settlement in 1870.
Subsequently during the survey settlements they got the lands registered in
their names without the knowledge of the peasants who came to know about the loss
of their lands they could do nothing except to surrender themselves. The landlords
further occupied the lands during the years of economic hardships in 1920-22 and
1930-33 when the peasants were unable to pay the taxes either due to failure of crops
or unfair prices for their crops. The rich peasant, the sahukars used to lend agricultural
products like grain, seeds, chillies etc., to the needy peasant at usurious rates of
interest and failure to repay the loans resulted in confiscation of their lands. The
peasants could not to anything as the Deshmukhs were not only rich landlords, Doras,
but were either village officers like the patwaris, patels and mali-patel, particularly
under the control of the Dora. Each Dora used to get five to ten villages under him as
watan.
119
It was not only the social, economic political, cultural and all pervasive
exploitation of the landlords and village officers with the collaboration of the
Government officers, but it was the land tenure system that developed and enforced
made the lives of the peasants miserable and ultimately forcing the small and the
middle peasants to give up cultivation and become either rent receivers or agricultural
labourers. Consequent to receiving of frequent complaints from the ryots of forcible
eviction of agricultural tenants, rack renting and unauthorized occupation of lands, the
Government appointed a committee in June, 1949, under the chairmanship of N.
Madhava Rao to investigate in to the problems of peasantry.27
State economy was predominantly rural (82%) and agrarian (60%) Agriculture
was the main-stay, but government did not bestow adequate attention for its
development. Increasing poverty and debt of peasant, land alienation due to distress
and fall in prices of agricultural products owing to world economic depression,
dominance of Jagirdari system and the existence of Begari and Baghela and tenancy
problems all show the deterioration of the agrarian conditions in the state.
The land tenures (60% Diwani 30% Jagirdari and 10% Sarf-e-Khas) in the
state show feudal predominance and exploitative treatment. The survey and
settlement varying from 25% to 50% of the produce was fixed with the Pattadars,
Pot-pattadars, Shikmidars and Asmi-shikmidars, the existing of tenancy cultivating
tenants-at-will etc., caused many problems to the ryots. The foregoing show that the
problems of the cultivators and their debt trap was increasing. The government was
120
not in a position to help the peasant from the worsening condition, therefore the
problems of ryots have been highlighted by organizations like Andhra Maha Sabha,
Andhra Jana Sangham etc. they tried to alleviate the position of the peasant from the
misery.
Under the caption Awakening among Ryots and the necessity of Ryots
Association, the Golkonda Patrika wrote about the plight of the ryots and their timid
nature, exploitation of Patels, Patwaris, Deshmukhs, Giradwars28 and appealed for
the establishment of ryots association. Consequently in 1929 a Ryots association was
established in Nalgonda and it suggested that a conference of the association was
essential to save the ryots from exploitation.29 These associations created command
among ryots at Sultanabad, Karimnagar, Jagityal in Karimnagar district in 1929. In
Bhongir taluq, 200 villagers of Tummalagudem, Nagaram, Valigonda represented to
Tusker, Secretary, land revenue department against the increase in land revenue
assessment when the village was transfered from jagir to khalsa.30
121
the position of farmers increasingly miserable in 1930s for agrarian purpose, the state
was divided into Diwani (Khalsa), Sarf-e-khas, Paigah and Jagir areas.
The last three were generally known as Jagirdari areas. In the diwani and jagir
areas of the state about 85% of the population lived on agriculture. Jagirs including
the sarf-e-khas comprised approximately 40% of the total area of the state and the rest
was Diwani area. Ryotwari system was prevalent in the Diwani area whereas
feudalism had taken roots in the Jagirdari areas. 5,29,26,720 acres of land under
cultivation 333,82,938 acres were under Diwani area and the remaining area was
shared between sarf-e-khas, paigahs, samsthanams, jagirs etc.31
Depression had seriously affected the market oriented rich peasant economy,
Salar Jung-I carried out survey and settlement operation in the 1870 in Diwani areas
and introduced ryotwari system of collecting 50% of the produce by abolishing
revenue farming. The cultivators called shikmidars were given pattas, who were free
to sub-lease the lands to the tenants-at-will called asami-shikmidars. This subinfeudation of lands coupled with heavy revenue demand had negative consequences
on the rural agrarian society. As for the Jagirdari system, it was oppressive and much
hated by the people. Under the Jagirs, concentration of the land varied: from 1.5 lac
acres under one jagirdar to thousands of acres divided among the 1167 jagirdars in
1922. The number of smaller jagirdars increased in the subsequent period. The
jagirdars controlled around 6500 villages and have become notorious in illegal
exactions from the peasantry. 82 varieties of such exactions were recorded. The
122
magnitude of the burden of illegal exactions could be judged from the fact that 110
jagirdars were collecting regularly about Rs. 10 Crore through various taxes from the
peasantry of which Rs. 5.5 Crore were appropriated only by about 19 Jagirdars, in
addition to the various taxes, baghela and begari.32
The Deshmukhs wielded lot of political and economic power being rent
collectors and owners of vast lands. The patels and patwaris supported the
Deshmukhs. A Deshmukh was called Dora, and being all powerful he extracted vetti
from all sections of the people under his control. Initially brahmins were owners of
substantial land but later on Reddy, kamma, velama peasant proprietors, rose to
prominance reducing the influence of Brahmins, vaisyas and shahukars (marwaris) as
traders and money lenders gradually penetrated into the rural society. 33
123
grinded turmeric garlic and pound chillies. The potters were to provide the needed
pots to the landlords and villages officers and cooked food for the officers who visited
the villages besides providing them the pots face of cost. The barbers had to do daily
service in the house of landlord and in the morning and night massage the body and
press the feet. The shepherds had to give their goats and sheep one each from their
herds on every auspicious occasion in the landlords house or on all village festival
days. The merchants on the demand of the police patel had to supply by turn, all the
commodities whenever the Government officers visited the village. They were subject
to torture and to various indignities if they failed to meet the demand.
The peasants were forced to give their carts, even in the odd times when they
have to travel their destination. They had to till the lands of the village officials and
landlords before they could take up their own fields and they would not get water to
their fields till the landlords fields watered. Agricultural labourers worked in their
fields without any compensation and only then they were permitted to work on wages
in other fields.35 The poor people who cannot provide anything specific were forced
to supply bowls and eggs to the landlords and village officials on tour. Under this
vetti System, as stated earlier, people of all castes irrespective of their social and
economic backgrounds were exploited in various degrees. The Brahmins had to
supply leaf plates to the landlords. 36
The worst barbarous of these feudal exactions and practices were that the
landlords kept girls of different communities as slaves and used them as concubines.
124
They were presented and forced to accompany the married daughters of the landlord
when they were going to establish their new homes and serve them. The landlords
along with the other village officials forced the young women folk of the village for
illegal relations and those refused were ill-treated whenever opportunity occurred.
The people of Telangana villages with this vetti system lived a life of utter
degradation and abject poverty and serfdom. 37 The system had its deep roots to crush
the human dignity by brute force and ruin the self-respect completely. Its sanction lied
in social custom and brute force.38 It is well beyond the bonded labour or debtbondage. All the castes particularly the agricultural labourers and artisans were forced
to supply free of charge or on some nominal payment whatever the products or
services they produced. Besides these, the landlord along with the village officials
acted as jury in all the village disputes and collected fine from the offenders.
The landlords also demand gifts from the villagers on all special occasions like
festivals, marriages etc, and contributions in cash or kind to the cost of ceremonial
functions in his family or village. Anything attractive and beautiful on demand should
be handover to the landlord. For his pleasure, they did not allow anybody to possess
good things like a pair of bullocks, a good house, a lush crop. It is almost looting and
plunders the watchward of the feudals in Telangana. The feudal exactions, the vetti
system and the feudal tenurial relations constituted the twin oppressions that crushed
the people of Telangana for more than seven to eight decades.
125
Sarojini Regani observes that in the Telangana villages serfdom and semislavery known as baghela, or vetti (Begara) were the common features during 1930s.
The agricultural labourers were unable to pay the petty loans advanced by the
landlords became their serfs. The baghelas were maintained not only by every big
land holder in big number but also by the middle peasants who cultivated with one or
two Baghelas. Baghelas were mostly drawn from aboriginal tribes. It was observed
that the vetti and Beghela systems were perversion of the traditional Hindu Jajmani
system which was based on the principle of reciprocal exchange.
The origin of a Baghela was a landless labourer of the lower caste, often from
the untouchable caste, who was obliged to offer the labour as security for debts and
works till the debt was cleared. It was often reported that when a man married,
involving a considerable expense he became a Baghela. A part of the wages for his
work was deducted to repay the loan. But as the wages were so low and with a high
rate of interest (not less than 25%) the debt remained unpaid forever. When the
126
Baghela died the debt was inherited by his heir and the system continued for
generations of agricultural labourers rendering totally unpaid labour to landlords,
cultivating their large holdings for the most minimal amount in wages.
1.
2.
3.
4.
5.
6.
Remuneration was less than the bear physical needs of low class labour
Bonus of two months remuneration Tobacco were given free.
7.
The master was looked upon as having the right to punish, starves or
confine the Baghela for any offence of omission or commission.
8.
No written agreement
9.
10.
If the Baghela dies, the debt due from him was wiped off. 40
S.M. Barucha reported that some of the Baghelas were hereditary servants and
the cultivator used to feed and clothe them and took service in lieu of interest on the
advances (Rs. 100-300) for their marriages. They were living in chronic penury and
indebtedness.
127
driven into debts by their poverty and agreed to serve the man from whom he has
borrowed. The money is not repaid, nor is not intended to be repaid, but the borrower
remains a life-long slave of his creditors. Thus, the consequences of the Vetti, the
begar, the Baghela are the compulsion of stress to mortgage ones personal liberty. 41
This practice was in vogue in all parts for a long time, but its intensity was felt
more in the feudal Hyderabad state. The root cause of this unsocial practice was the
poverty of the parents who cloud not provides anything to them. Therefore, they were
forced to sell their children boys and girls at a very young age. This situation
perpetuated the existence and continuance of slave labour in the state. 42
128
Parwada System:
The extreme poverty on one side and wealth on the other encouraged this
system. Most of the jagirdars and money gentry who had homes in their jagirs
collected, small children from poor families who could not maintain them. These
children when grown up were used as domestic servants. The parents also completely
detached themselves from the children after they were handed over. In rare cases, the
parents kept contact with their children and visited them at intervals and the master
sometimes gave them some rewards and sends them away. The ultimate object of the
master was to utilize the children as domestic servants. In the city of Hyderabad, very
often cruelties as putting chilly powder in the eyes, torturing them with or without
instruments, beating harshly and depriving food for hours together and other types of
ill-treatment came to the notice of the Government. As most of the Jagirdars and
proprieted people lived in the city, they brought parwardas into the city. 43
The feudalism had taken a special shape which may be summed up in the
phrase the Jagirdari system. The Jagir was a free grant of one or more villages from
the rulers of the state to the grantee as a reward for some conspicuous service, either
military or otherwise. The grantee, called the jagirdar, had the right to collect land
revenue and generally retained the whole of it without passing it on to the state. But
the jagirdar was not the owner of the land. Like the state in non-jagir (Diwani) areas,
the jagirdar had the power to create ownership rights in his teats by conferring lands
129
on others. The owners either cultivated the land themselves or leased it out to tenants
for a rent. The jagirs, thus, were states within a state. 44
It may be observed that the history of the state since the establishment of Asaf
Jahi dynasty had been one of constant warfare. In the absence of the settled
government, confusion and chaos reigned everywhere. Frequent revolts by petty rajas
and zamindars, which were always turbulent in the payment of Peshkush, were
common. Some nobles, on the other hand, enjoyed their estates with almost supreme
power. They had the power of life and death, exercising a kind of imperium in
imperio.46 The assessment and collection of revenue was entrusted to contractors
and lease-holders. People were harassed and high handedness of the Taluqdars were
routing. Before the collection of the goods and the harvest of the crops, the authorities
demanded revenue, and thus put the cultivators in the clutches of money -lenders
130
which involved them in paying compound interest. Thus they collected revenue by
unlawful means which worsened the condition of the people. The zamindars /
jagirdars were arrogant and the people were gradually ruined. Agriculture was in the
state of decline. Government servants were incharge of taluqs. The deshmukhs the
deshpandes were mainly interested in collecting money. They were busy making their
fortunes, indifferent to the welfare of the villages. As a result of such disorders and
lawlessness, there was a decrease in the collection of diwani revenue with adverse
effects upon the economic life of the people. 47
131
Nizam. Mansab rank alone was not a sufficient definition of noble status, since
hereditary possession of Jagirs became a major factor in defining noble status. 50
The most prominent Muslim noble family of paigah in Hyderabad state. They
ranked next to the Nizam and his family. Muslim nobles held Jagirs or estates on
military tenures.51 The means of production have been concentrated in the hands of
the Jagirdars who exploited and appropriated the surplus in the state. Some of the
prominent issues which figured between 1926-48 were.
1.
2.
3.
Vetti (bonded labour) and the exploitation of the patels, and patwaris;
4.
5.
6.
Baghelas etc.
They were so severe that the condition of the ryots could be seen. We will
discuss all the above points in the coming chapter. Such was the oppression of the
Jagirdars and money-lenders who squeezed out the money like leech to the blood. The
ryots lived in utter penury. They brought amounts from the money- lender for large
rates of interest which they could not repay and ultimately the land was handed over
by the zamindar.
132
133
village offices (patel, mansab) etc., and command respect and authority. Below the
landlords was found a large peasant community comprising owner-cultivators,
occupancy tenants and various types of under-tenants.
The artisan castes like Sali, Goundla, Mangala, Chakali, etc., did own some
land but it was too meagre to depend upon for livelihood. Since many of these castes
witnessed the destruction of their traditional occupations (de-industrialisation), they
swelled the ranks of the rural poor. Consequently, they constituted a large part of
agricultural labour, next only to untouchables. Many micro studies reveal that the
artisan castes gradually lost their landed Property in favour of other dominant castes
and thus became landless.52
134
occupation of relinquished and evicted lands bought from the ryots. It has also been
stated that the private lands were enlarged by illegal occupations and encroachment of
communal lands.53 The jagirdars employed farm servants and wage labourers to
cultivate their personal lands. But in most of the estates, private lands were leased out
to middlemen and under tenants / tenants- at-will. The possession of the vast estates
and private lands helped the landlords exercise control over the tenants. Control over
land and acquisition of wealth and affluence helped the landlords to exercise power
and authority. The jagirdars and landlords exercised both economic and political
domination over the peasants.54 If we look into the classification of jagirs and their
nature:
1)
i)
ii)
iii)
Vicar-ul-Umra Paigah.
The term paigah is of Persian origin and means foot or space or stable.
135
2)
The next kind of Jagirs comes, the Ilaqas or estates of the premier
nobles (Umra-e-Ozam) of the state. There are four such estates:
i)
ii)
iii)
iv)
The nobles, who held these jagirs, were very powerful nobles of high rank.
3)
The next category of the jagirs is the Samsthanams. All of them pay a
tribute called peshkash to the Ruler. According to the Daftar Diwanio-Mal which has the custody of all sanads and parwanas relating to the
crown grants the word peshkash means Nazar or present.
Under Gasti No.2 of 1312, Samsthan shall mean a group of Villages, granted
by the Government to Jagirdars and Samsthandars on payment of Peshkash. There
are 14 Samsthanams paying Peshkash.
(3)Jatprole (4) Amara Chinta (5) Palavancha (6) Domakonda (7) Gopalpet
(8)Anegondi (9) Rajapet (10) Dubbaka (11) Narayanpur (12) Papannapet
(13)Gurgunta and (14) Sirnapalli.
136
Jagir
No. of Villages
1,634
401
2,89,920
1,555
396
3,15,024
Vicar-ul-Umra Paigah
1,163
397
2,50,664
Total - (A)
4,352
1,194
8,55,608
Estate of Salarjung
1126
359
2,21,382
Kishe
362
208
1,11,759
197
89
63,459
234
113
94,464
211
75
41,862
817
122
1,29,618
Estate of Wanaparti
605
150
1,00,356
Estate of Jatprole
357
86
59,968
162
186
82,428
Raj
272
119
39,372
Samsthan
161
69
55,856
272
60
47,798
3090
70
66,032
34
29,327
Estate
of
Sir
Population
Pershad
Khanan
Estate of Nawab Fakhar
ul Mulk
Estate of Nawab Mehdi
Jung Bahadur
Estate
of
Samsthan
Gadwal
Karan
Estate
of
Sham
Bahadur
Estate
of
Amarachinta
Estate of Jagir Kalyani
Estate
of
Samsthan
Palvancha
Estate of Surya Jung
Bahadur
Total - (B)
7,866
1,740
11,43,681
12,218
2,934
19,99,28955
137
Aurangabad Suba
254
Medak Suba
244
Warangal Suba
124
Gulbarga Suba
218
84056
TOTAL
138
names had the right over the land. But the whole peasant community did not know
that the land which they cultivated should be on their name, and the tax was to be paid
on their names. At this juncture taking advantage of above revenue Policy the
Deshmukhs & Deshpandes and their henchmen who collected the land revenue prior
to 1866 A. D. Created number of false evidences of land revenue receipts on their
names and in collusion with the government officers exploited the illiterate people
and grabbed thousands of acres of lands of people of the Telangana. The feudal
system is strikingly apparent in the rural areas of the Telangana. This reveals that the
government or its machinery did not care to enlighten the peasants on the laws
governing the land and the land taxes. The government had no benevolent intention of
the welfare of the peasantry and even the title face saving relief measures undertaken
did not help. So ultimately the illiterate and ignorant peasantry was made landless.
During drought or Famines and economic depression peasantry was not in a position
to pay land revenue. In light of above, the government issued firman, stating that
farmers were exempted from paying taxes in drought or famine conditions. But such
subsidies given by the government did not reach them.
requested the village landlords to retain the lands on their name and pay the land
revenue to the government. In this case once again the feudal institution or machinery
including its henchmen, who in collusion with the government officers exploited the
situation of people and grabbed thousands of acres of land of people
in rural
Telangana.57 The above feudal forces who had come to know the value of bourgeois
rights over property still continued their hold on the land. They used their status and
139
influence in the government to grab thousands of acres and the produce of which they
enjoyed denying the ploughing right of peasantry and their due.
Under such a system peasants had to pay half to 2/3rd of their produce as land
revenue.58 Merchant capital operated by the indigenous and other money-lenders is
not regarded as public capital. This is purely private capital where the rate of interest
depends on the party who takes the loan. The private bankers were very popular
among the people, especially the poor folk. Even if they charged higher rate of
interest or discount, people were still attracted to them for the practices of these
bankers are nearer to the habits of the people in general, unlike those of the joint stock
banks.
The problem of credit became acute for all categories of peasants. The
merchants and landlords cum money lenders played an important role in agrarian
economy. Money lending as a business, has always existed in Hyderabad state.
Ancestral debt and constantly recurring small items of debt for food and other
necessities, social, religious, ceremonies, Seeds, bullocks and land revenue are the
principle causes of enhancing rural indebtedness. The need of agriculturist for loans is
therefore, imperative, and the money lender is the only person to satisfy it. In the rural
parts money lending and grain dealing are inseparably combined in one person.59
140
division. Taking three types of villages in each taluq of total Telangana region, which
reveals that, there were 328 agricultural money lenders and 363 non-agricultural
money lenders in Medak division. Whereas in Warangal revenue division there were
982 total agricultural and non-agricultural money lenders were 2397 in 147 selected
villages i.e., 4.40%.60
Villages
57
328
363
Villages
90
982
724
According to the 1931 census reports, the total money lenders in Telangana
were 6401. It is significant to note that the concentration of money lenders in
Telangana increased in 1941.61
Some of the practices which the private money lenders had been following
were very popular in Telangana which were as follows:
141
1.
1.
2.
3.
2.
Between the sowing and reaping of a crop, the ryot borrow money from the
sahukars for expenses of weeding and other agricultural operation. Repayment at
harvest is compulsory; otherwise compound interest is levied.64
3.
In most of the cases the cultivator was never in the position to repay the loan
fully. In the cases where the land was good for cultivation and the ryot tries to repay
the loan after borrowing from another sahukar. He generally finds that he does not
142
give back the land, and the ryots were helpless in the civil court in the face of the
registered sale deed.65
No. of Banks
Functioning
1.
Hyderabad
Dominion Jagirdar
Capital
(Rs.)
20,99,978
-
Brahmakatyan
2.
Atraf-i-Balda
3.
Nizamabad
Nizamabad, Banswada
1,27,807
4.
Medak
Medak, Sangareddy,
4,66,474
Vikarabad
5.
Baghat
6.
Mahbubnagar
Mahbubnagar,
1,51,621
Nagarkurnool,
Wanaparthy
7.
Nalgonda
Bhongir, Suryapet
4,65,080
8.
Warangal
Warangal, Mahbubabad,
3,56,211
1,3 8,009
96,416
22
39,01,596
Khammam
9.
Karimnagar
Karimnagar, Jagityal,
Manthani
10.
Adilabad
Adilabad, Nirmal,
Chennur
TOTAL
143
It was observed that 113 debts were based on crop security out of
242 resident families in Mahboobnagar district i.e.,
47%
77%
17%
The Non-Land mortgage debts that were borrowed in the districts were
as follows:
Mahboobnagar district 242 resident families borrowed Rs. 19,340/Nizamabad district 148 resident families borrowed
Rs.
14,460/-
Rs. 2,14,660/-
This shows that the right of patta on land had in fact led the peasant into debt
which in turn led him to lose his land. Thus indebtedness had been increasing since
1920 onwards. The increase was to such an extent that the difference in debt between
1920 and 1929 was nearly 720%.66 Non-productive debts were more than productive
debts.
Warangal
Rs. 2,14,660/-
Mahaboobnagar
Rs.
19,340/-
Nizamabad
Rs.
14,460/-
144
Warangal
1,176
Mahaboobnagar
113
Nizamabad
Warangal
5% to 50%
Mahboobnagar
13.5% to 33%
Nizamabad
12.5% to 65%
Warangal
Rs. 181.23
Mahboobnagar
Rs. 171.50
Nizamabad
Rs. 127.9667
Causes of Indebtedness:
1.
Small Holdings
2.
145
3.
Insecurity of crop
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
Now we pass on to the next chapter which deals with resistance to Dominance
where the dominated class had been resisted by oppressors.
146
REFERENCES
1
Sarkar, J., History of Aurangzeb, The Closing Years, London, 1924, pp.1-19.
Ibid., pp.170-4.
10
D.G.R. (T) File No.4 of 1337F (1928) & R.No. 3795 of 1338F (1929).
11
W.S. File No.4 of 1342F (1933) & R.No. 454 of 1343F (1934).
12
13
14
15
16
17
Satyanarayana, A., Society, Economy and Polity in Modern Andhra, Kanishka, New
Delhi, 2007, pp.9-11.
18
Kumar Dharma, Land and Caste in South India, Manohar, New Delhi, 1992, p.34.
19
147
20
Irfan Habib, The Agrarian System of Mughal India, (1556-1707), Asia, London,
1963, p.122.
21
22
Sundarayya, P., Telangana Peoples Struggles and Its Lessons, CPI(M), Calcutta,
1972, pp.12-3.
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
148
36
37
38
Balagopal, K., Economic and Political Weekly, April 30, 1983, p.712.
39
40
41
Ibid., pp.95-6.
42
Ibid., pp.98-100.
43
Ibid., pp.102-3.
44
45
Alim Moulvi, Chirag, Hyderabad under Sir Salar Jung, Education Society Press,
Bombay, 1886, p.13.
46
47
48
49
50
Leonard Karen, The Hyderabad Political System and Its Participants, Journal of
Asian Studies, Vol. XXX, May, 1971, pp.569-600.
51
Ghulam Samdani Khan Gauhar, Tazuk-e-Mahboobia, Vol. II, Fakhr Nizamia Press,
Hyderabad, 1901, pp.1-6.
149
52
53
Baker, C.J., The Politics of South India, 1920-37, Delhi, 1976, p.113.
54
55
Report of the Royal Commission on Jagir Administration and Reforms, H.E.H., The
Nizams Government 1356 F - 1947, pp.28-32.
56
Ibid., p.36.
57
58
Census Reports of India, 1941, Vol. XXI, H.E.H., The Nizams Dominions,
Hyderabad-Dn, Part-I, Government Central Press, 1945, p.158.
60
61
62
63
Ibid., p.88.
64
Ibid., p.28.
65
Ibid., p. 29.
66
67
68