Technology Creation, Diffusion, and Growth Cycles: John D. Stiver
Technology Creation, Diffusion, and Growth Cycles: John D. Stiver
Technology Creation, Diffusion, and Growth Cycles: John D. Stiver
John D. Stiver∗
Abstract
Standard macroeconomic models that assume an exogenous stochastic process for mul-
tifactor productivity offer the interpretation that recessions are the result of ”bad news”
(technological regress) and expansions are the result of ”good news” (technological advance-
ment). The view taken here is that both expansions and recessions are the result of ”good
news” in the sense that in both cases, aggregate production possibilities have increased.
Recessions can be thought of as the transition from one technological frontier to the next.
∗
Department of Economics, University of Connecticut, One University Place, Stamford, CT 06901. Tel:
(203)251-8433. FAx: (203)251-8592. Email: John.Stiver@uconn.edu
1
1 Introduction
process for multifactor productivity. The interpretation is that recessoins are the result of
a temporary decline in productivity while expansions are the result of a temporary increase
in productivity. In other words, downturns are the result of ’bad” news and expansions are
the result of ”good” news. The view taken here is that neither recessions nor expansions are
necessarily good or bad news, and that both are, in fact, associated with increasing production
possibilities. The driving force behind an economy’s development lies its ability to produce
newer, more productive capital goods. However, when a new, more productive capital good is
introduced into an economy, it takes time to learn how to use it appropriately and to improve
on its operation and efficiency. Therefore, there will be a natural slowdown as the economy
transitions to the new ”technological frontier”. Once the economy has sufficient knowledge of
the new product, it begins to improve on it - producing the next generation. However, as
each new generation is introduced, the marginal productivity gains become smaller and smaller.
Eventually, the marginal gains will become small enough that the costs outweugh the benefits of
improvement. At that point, when a capital good is ”played out”, a new, revolutionary product
For example, Gordon (2000) uses the example of word processing. The invention of the
typewriter surely represented a dramatic increase in productivity once individuals learned how to
type. The next generation memorey typewriter, which eliminated much repetitive retyping, also
(a DOS PC with Wordperfect 4.2, Wordperfect 6.0, Word for Windows, Word 95, Word 98, Word
2
2000), one can imagine the marginal productivity improvements rapidly approaching zero. From
my own experience, I can say that I am no more productive using windows 98 than I am using
windows 95. However, as we speak, Microsoft is working on perfecting word processing software
with voice recognition - possibly the next ”revolution” in word processing software. From a
more historical context, Gordon (2000) examines multifactor productivity frmo 1870 - 1999. He
finds that the show a growth pattern of ”slow - fast - slow- fast”.
Gordon attributes this pattern to patterns of innovation. The Late 1800’s produced many
revolutionary inventions. For example, the electric light (1879), the internal combustion engine
(1877),the telephone (1876). Gordon attributes the fast growth 1913 - 1972 to such inventions
as listed above. While it is difficult to distinctly classify inventions by generations, one might
suggest that the first generation electric light led to future generations such as the power station,
electric train, radios, and air conditioning. Similarly, the internal combustion engine led to future
Similarly, the rapid expansion of the late 90’s could be attributed to the invention of the
microprocessor (first marketed by INTEL in 1971). As a first generation invention, the microchip
has led to future generation products such as pentium processors, cellular telecommunications,
and the world wide web. The relative length of the ”slowdowns” compared the expansions
should depend on two factors: (1) The difficulty involved in perfecting and learning the new
3
technology and (2) the pace at which the new product diffuses through the economy. A new
product which is difficult to learn and costly to adopt will be associated with a large period of
low productivity and a corresponding long, slow recovery. On the other hand, a product that is
easy to learn and rather costlesss to adopt will be associated with a very short contraction and
a quick recovery.
Andolfatto and Macdonald use a model of technological adoption to examine the U.S. from
1940 to the present. They discover that the period is represented well by the production and
adoption of five new technologies. The first was developed in the late forties, was easy to learn,
diffused rapidly, and quickly developed into widespread usage (over 70%). In the mid fifties, a
new product came out that was also easy to use, but was a small improvement and, hence, while
it diffused rapidly, it never reached more that a 40% acceptance rate. More recently, another
innovation began in the early seventies (while the authors don’t identify these innovations as
particular products, it is reasonable to believe that this one is computer related). Unlike previous
technologies, this one was more difficult to learn and more difficult to adopt. However, eventually
(by the mid eighties), it reached a 60% adoption rate. Their model, however, took the size of
Authors such as Greenwood and Jovanovic (2000) and Boldrin and Levine(2001) offer further
evidence of this type of growth cycle by looking at the stock market. Boldrin and Levine note
that the stock market tends to rise slowly, but drop very rapidly with periodic crashes. While
many suggest that this market behavior is the result of bubbles, assymetric technology shocks,
etc., Boldrin/Levine argue that this market behavior is the natural result of innovation cycles.
The market rises during periods in which an existing technology is being improved on. Note
4
that this is a period of very little uncertainty. However, eventually, the market learns that
the existing technology is ”played out”. At that point, there is a great deal of uncertainty as
to how the new technology will evolve, how difficult the diffusion process will take, etc. - the
market responds with a sharp downturn until this uncertainty is resolved (ie, a slow recovery).
Greenwood and Jovanovic use this type of explanation to explain the behavior of the stock market
during the 1970’s. In 1970, the ratio of market capitalization to GDP was approximately 1.
In 1973, that ration dropped dramatically to approximately .4 and stayed at .4 until the late
eighties. The current ratio is currently around 2. Greenwood/Jovanivic attribute this to the
development of the microchip in 1971. The market recognized the complexity and difficulty
There is an important lesson to be learned from the above examples. Economic slowdowns
need not be caused by bad news. The introduction of the computer chip, while taking place
during a period of sluggish (even negative) economic growth, represented an increase, not a de-
crease in the productive cababilities of the U.S.. The measured drop in MFP is simply represents
the learning processas the economy transitions from old to new technology.
This paper formalizes the ideas discussed above by developing a general equilibrium model
of technology creation. The model is along the lines of Boldrin and Levine (2001). However, in
Boldrin and Levine, the decisions concerning the timing of new product develoment, upgrading
and reproducing existing capital are determined primarily by parameter values and technological
restrictions. Here, those decisions will be determined endogenously. A technology sector ex-
pends resources to produce new technologies. Periodically, the technology sector will develop a
”revolutionary product”, but most of the time, it simply improves on existing technologies. The
5
decision to ”revolutionize” will depend on the shape of the learning curve of the new technology.
Eventually, it will be the case that upgrading existing technologies will not be worth the effort
required. At that point, resourced will be moved into the development of new technologies.
When new technologies are developed, the manufacturing sector automatically (and costlessly)
adopts them.
2 The Model
The capital goods sector of the economy uses the existing stock of capital goods to produce
new capital goods to be used by the production sector. It also uses the knowledge embodied
in capital goods to improve on existing capital goods. Specifically, capital in the economy be
indexed by i and j where i represents the type of capital and j represents the generation of
capital good. Then, generation 1 might represent the telegraph, while generation 5 might be
the cellular telephone. Assume that the representative firm in the technology sector has 1 unit
1. Investment: Each unit of kij produces A Â 1 units of the same type and generation of
³ ´
Φ
2. Upgrading: Each unit of kij+1 produces 1+ωj
L units of the next generation capital type
i , generation j + 1
6
The capital goods sector will be restricted to only undertake one activity at a time. This
shouldn’t qualitatively change the results and will allow the analysis to go through without the
need for tracking the distribution of capital across sectors. Furter, diminishing returns to labor
are excluded to avoid the necessity of tracking the distrubution of labor across sectors.
The intuition here is straightforward. The reproducting of existing capital goods is a simple,
automated task. Note that it will be possible for the economy to maintain a constant long run
rate of growth through this process. If no new capital are created and no upgrading takes place,
the model is a simple AK economy. Upgrading is a more complicated task which requires the
addition of skilled labor as well as capital. Most importantly, ungrading exhibits diminishing
returns. The idea here is that each upgrade will produce small and smaller increases in produc-
tivity. The parameter ω is meant to capture the size of these diminishing returns. For example,
when Microsoft released its first word processing software program (think of this as the first
generation of a new capital goos), the improvement in productivity over, say, electric typwrit-
ers (the latest generation of the previous type of capital) was sizeable. However, as Microsoft
proceeded through Word, Word95, Word98, etc., the productivity gains from each new edition
become smaller and smaller. This is the key to the entire model. An economy cannot grow
indefinately from improving on existing capital. Eventually, it must either settle with simply
increasing the stock of capital or it must begin searcing for new, novel ideas. Sticking with the
microsoft example, as the improvment opportunities dimished with traditional word processing
software,Microsoft began shifting resources towards things like voice recognition software (think
7
2.2 The Research Sector
The research sector of the economy develops the blueprints for new capital goods and builds
the prototype. When new types of capital goods are produced, they are initially unproductive
relative to state of the art versions of earlier types. This can be thought of two ways. First,
early generations of capital are ”prototypes”, or ”betas”. They are not very productive due
to minor flaws or ”bugs” in the design. They must be tested and redesigned before they
will be used to produce consumption goods. Second, new capital have a ”learning by doing”
component. Initially, workers must learn how to use a new type of capital. As they redesign it,
they become more familiar and,hence,more productive. As with investment, R&D production is
linear. Further,it assumed that only labor is used in the research sector. This assumption is not
necessary, but allows for easier calculation. All that is necessary is for they process of upgrading
to be less labor intensive than R&D, but more labor intensive than Investment. First, a plan
for new capital must be developed. Each unit of labor applied to research can produce some
e
φ0 = φ + B L (1)
Note that it will require at least (1/B) periods to complete a new research plan (total labor
supply in the economy is set to 1). Once a plan is completed (φ = 1), any capital of type i,
8
2.3 The Production Sector
The Production sector of the economy converts type i , generation j capital into consumption
using the following technology. It should be noted here that consumption here is not measured in
physical units, but rather in quality units. That is, over time, we can produce more cunsumption
Note that there are three potential sources of growth in this economy. First is growth due to
an increase in the stock of physical capital. The second source is due the continual upgrading if
the existing capital stock and the periodic development of new, more productive capital goods.
However, upgrading capital will not represent a long run (sustainable) source of growth due to
2.4 Consumers
Consumers have preferences defined over streams of consumption represented by the expected
utility function. Again, for simplicity, labor will be supplied exogenously at 1 unit.
X
∞
β t W (ct ) (3)
t=0
9
1
W (c) = − c−θ
θ
3 Analysis
To begin, we need to place some initial restrictions on some of the parameters of the model to
avoid some uninteresting results. Suppose that there exists 1 unit of type zero, generation zero
capital. There are two options available to produce consumption to be available for the next
period. First, we could simply build more of the type zero, generation zero capital (we could
produce A units). This would provide us with A units of consumption (γ 0+0 A). The second
choice is to upgrade our capital to type zero, generation one. Using thuis method yields at most
Φ units of capital next period (assuming that all available labor is dedicated to upgrading rather
than innovating) which can be used to produce γΦ units of consumption next period. We want
to be sure that there is always some range for which upgrading is a preferable option to simply
reproducing existing capital. Otherwise the model collapses into a standard AK framework with
γΦ Â A (4)
Secondly, we know that labor will be atracted to the activity with the highest wage (i.e
10
the highest marginal product of labor). Once again, we have to be sure that there exists a
range of parameter values for which the marginal product of labor in the capital goods sector
(specifically, the marginal product of labor in upgrading) is greater than the marginal product
of labor in research. Again, assume that we are starting with 1 unit of type zero, generation
zero capital. One unit of labor used in upgradin will generate Φ units of type zero generation
one capital. On the other hand, each unit of labor dedicated to research produces B units of a
blueprint for type 1, generation zero capital. Note that the lifetime value of type one capital is
γ times that of type zero capital. Therefore, it must be the case that
Φ Â γB (5)
to be sure that there exists a labor allocation with a positive amount of labor engaged in
upgrading. Otherwise the model would once again reduce down to an AK model (with an
Given the above parameter restrictions, the model will revolve between three distinct regimes.
While the current type of capital is quite new, the costs of upgrading are small relative to the
benefits. Thertefore, early on, all the economy’s resources not devoted to consumption will be
used upgrading the economy’s capital stock. In this region, growth is a consequence of technology
accumulation as well as physical capital accumulation. Eventually, the current technology will
”play out”. That is, the costs of upgrading will drop below the benefits. This will result in the
labor force shifting from upgrading into research and the capital stock shifting out of upgrading
and into traditional investment. Growth in this region slows because technology accumulation
11
stops temporarily (actually, technology accumulation is still taking place but hasn’t manifested
in increased productive capability yet). To determine the upper bound for upgrading, set the
marginal product of capital in investment equal to the marginal product of capital in upgrading.
Note that the marginal product in upgrading must be scaled up by the factor γ because new
γΦ
A =
1 + ωj ∗
µ ¶µ ¶
1 γΦ
j∗ = −1 (6)
ω A
This solution makes sense. The ”technological frontier” in inversely related to ω. Recall
that this parameter governs the degree to which diminishing returns result with each upgrade.
γΦ
The term A
represents the baseline productivity in upgrading relative to investing. The above
The length of the second phase - one in which physical capital simply reproduces itself is
¡1¢
determined through the parameter value for B. A completeed plan takes B
periods. Once
the plan is completed, some of the economy’s capital will be converted into the new type of
capital. Note that new capital is initially quite unproductive relative to the existing capital
(existing capital is generation j ∗ while the new type will begin at generation 0). The new type,
however, has a very steep learning curve and can be upgraded so that eventually it will be more
productive than the existing stock. Suppose that type one capital has just been invented. You
have one unit of type zero, generation j ∗ capital at your disposal. You have two options for
producing consumption at some future time period M ∗ . First, you could simply reproduce your
12
existing capital for (M ∗ − 1) periods and then convert that capital into consumption. That
∗ −1
would provide AM units of consumption. The second option would be to convert your capital
into type one in the current period, upgrade that capital for M ∗ − 2 periods, and then convert
"M ∗ −2 µ ¶#
Y Φ
M ∗ −2
γ (7)
i=0
1 + ωi
units of capital in time M ∗ . Setteing the two equal will allow us to solve for M ∗ . Note
that M ∗ will dictate the point at the new type of capital becomes useful for producing current
consumption. Hence any of the old type of capital should be used up at M ∗ . At this point, the
The economy initially begins with an initial stock of capital. For simplicity, assume that the
initial stock is 1 unit of type 0, generation 0 capital (k00 ) . For periods 1 through j ∗ the capital
stock is upgraded to the next generation every period. Labor is entirely devoted to upgrading
the capital stock. The economy grows at the rate of capital accumulation plus technology growth.
The first order condition governing consumption give us optimal consumption growth.
µ ¶θ+1 µ ¶−1
ci γ iΦ
β =
ci+1 1 + ωi
µ ¶ 1+θ
1
ci+1 γ iΦ
= (8)
ci 1 + ωi
13
Note that during this phase, capital becomes more productive, but also becomes more ex-
pensive. Initially, the stock of physical capital grows, but eventually, begins to shrink. In fact,
at j ∗ we know the growth of potential output through invesment (gk = A) is equal to the growth
At j ∗ the rising cost of new capital finally outpaces productivity and the process of upgrading
stops. Labor is shifted into research and capital is shifted into investment. During this period,
the capital stock grows at the exogenous rate A. From the first order condition for consumption,
ct+1 1
= (Aβ) 1+θ (9)
ct
At time j ∗ + B the blueprint for a new type of capital becomes available. At this point, some
of the capital stock will be reproduced and used for current consumption while the remaining
capital stock is converted to the new type and then upgraded until it is useful for producing
14
kij = c + A−1 kij0 + ki+1,0 (10)
During the economy’s ”development” phase, the capital used for consumption grows at an
ct+1 1
= (Aβ) 1+θ (11)
ct
³ ´
γΦ
New capital in the economy grows at the rate 1+ωj
= gk .
Old capital can be used for either consumption or investment. Therefore, the period by period
Finally, note that any optimal plan will use up the old type capital once the new capital is
¡ ∗ ¢
ready for consumption purposes kijM = 0 .
To solve the model, first note that we have a starting capital stock (of type 0 generation 0)
15
µ ¶−1
Φ
k00 = 1 = c + k01
1 + ωi
At time j ∗ the process of investment begins. The period j ∗ budget constraint is equal to
Lastly, we have the ternminal condition that the old style capital is completely used up at
¡ M∗ ¢
the time that the new style capital is productive enough to produce consumption. kij ∗ = 0 .
Solving the budget constraints forward and inserting the starting and terminal condition results
in the lifetime budget constraint. Next, at time j ∗ +B (when the plans for the new type of capital
become available) resources allocated towards new capital creation must provide equal lifetime
utility at the margin as resources allocated towards consumption. Let V00 denote the lifetime
value of one unit of type 0 generation 0 capital. The value of kij unite of type i generation j capital
−θ
will produce (γ i+j kij ) V00 units of welfare. Therefore, the optimality condition governing new
16
" M µ
∗ ¶ #−θ
Y Φ
−(1+θ) M ∗ +1 M∗
β (c) =β γ k10 V00 (14)
i=1
1 + ωi
j ∗ +B+M ∗
" M µ
∗ ¶ #−θ
X Y Φ
j ∗ +B+M ∗ +1 M ∗ +1
V00 = β i U (ci ) + β γ k10 V00 (15)
i=1 i=1
1 + ωi
Equations (14), (15), and the lifetime budget constraint define a solution for k10 , c,and V00 .
B (Productivity in Research) .2
However, the economy actually averages 4% annual growth by moving back and forth between
the low growth state (research and development) and the high growth state (upgrading). Given
17
ci+1 1
= (γΦ) 1+θ = 1.19
ci
However, this growth rate continually declines. The first switching point j ∗ is equal to 12
(capital reaches twelve generations before upgrading becones to expensive. At j ∗ (and until
ct+1 1
= (Aβ) 1+θ = .98
ct
So consumption shrinks during the ”recession”. The length of this contraction is determined
by the exogenous parameter B. (In this case,the research phase takes 5 periods) and M ∗ (in this
case, M ∗ is determined to b 5). Therefore, the economy experiences alternating expansions (of
length equal to 12 periods) where consumption grows at an average rate of 8.5% and recessions
(of length equal to 10 periods) where consumption contracts at a rate of 2%. Figures (1) − (4)
plot the transitions for new capital, the aggregate capital stock, consumption, and productivity
4 Conclusions
Standard macroeconomic models stress the fact that expansions and contractions are the result of
random fluctuations to productivity. Expansions are the result of ”good” news while recessions
18
are the result of ”bad” news. The view taken here is that both recessions and expansions are
When new technologies are invented, they are initially very unproductive. However, over
time, they are modified and improved upon. Each successive generation becomes more produc-
tive at producing consumption goods, but becomes more costly to update. For example, the
telegraph was a new type of capital used in the production of communication services, then suc-
cessive generations would be the telephone, cordless phone, cellular phones, etc.. The constant
pattern of research, invention, development and replacement create a natural cycle of economic
activity.
• When a new type of capital is in its early stages, the cost up upgrading is low relative
to the productivity gains. Consumption grows at above trend rates as the capital stock
is constantly upgraded. However, as upgrades become more and more expensive, more
becomes ”played out” in the sense that it is no longer cost effective to continue updating.
Consumption growth falls and labor is reallocated to research activities (i.e., the invention
of new types of capital). Note that the length of this expansionary period depends on the
• Consumption growth remains low during the research period. Capital is simply reproduced
rather than upgraded. Labor is devoted to reserach activities. Eventually, a new type of
the new capiatl is still unproductive relative to the existing capital stock. A development
phase must take place before the new capital can be used for consumption purposes. Note
19
that while new capital is being improved, the old capital is in the process of being used
up in anticipation of the new capital coming online. Therefore, the aggregate capital
stock falls. This period looks very much like a recession - a declining capital stock and
low consumption growth - but actually, lifetime consumption possibilities have actually
increased. The length of the development also hinges crucially on the curvature of the
upgrading process (ω) and well as the baseline level of productivity (Φ) . Once the new
type of capital is productive enough to produce consumption goods, the cycle begins anew.
Obviously, there are some important drawbacks in the current framework. With only one
each in a different developmental stage. Further, the research stage should ideally be treated
as endogenous with a tradeoff between research time and certain features of the new capital
(i.e. initial productivity or developmental path). These are questions to be looked at in future
research.
5 References
Andolfatto, David and Glen MacDonald (1998), ”Technology Diffusion and Aggregtae Dynam-
Aghion, P. and P. Howitt (1996), ”On the Microeconomic Effects of Technological Change”,
20
Atkeson, Andrew and Parick Kehoe (1997), ”Industry Evolution and Transition: A Neoclas-
Boldrin, Michael and David Levine (2001), ”Growth Cycles and Market Crashes”, Journal of
Campbell, Jeffrey (1998), ”Entry, Exit, Embodied Technology and the Business Cycle”, Re-
J. Gali (1999), ”Technology, Employment, and The Business Cycle”, American Economic
Gordon, Robert (2000), ”Does the ’New Economy’ Measure Up to the Great Inventions of
Gort, Michael and S. Klepper (1982), ”Time Paths and the Diffusion of Product Innovations”,
Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz and Per Krusell (1997), ”Long Run Implications of In-
Greenwood, Jeremy and Boyan Jovanovic (1999), ”The IT Revolution and the Stock Market”,
Jones, Charles (1997), ”The Upcoming Slowdown in U.S. Economic Growth”, NBER Working
Paper #6284.
21
Jones, Charles (1995), ”R&D Based Models of Economic Growth”, Journal of Political Econ-
Jovanovic, Boyan and S. Lach (1997), ”Product Innovation and the Business Cycle”, Inter-
Jovanovic, Boyan and R. Rob (1990), ”Long Waves and Short Waves”, Econometrica, 58,
1391-1409.
Hornstein, A. and Per Krusell (1996), ”Can Technology Improvementc Cause Productivity
22
Figure 1:Capital Figure 2:Capital stock
1.4 1.15
1.2
1.1
1
0.8 1.05
0.6 1
0.4
0.95
0.2
0 0.9
0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20
0.018 1.12
1.1
0.016
1.08
0.014
1.06
0.012
1.04
0.01 1.02
0 5 10 15 20 0 5 10 15 20