Innovation, Competitiveness, and Growth: Korean Experiences
Innovation, Competitiveness, and Growth: Korean Experiences
Innovation, Competitiveness, and Growth: Korean Experiences
Sungchul Chung
Science and Technology Policy Institute (STEPI), Korea
Sungchul Chung
Research Fellow Emeritus
Science and Technology Policy Institute (STEPI)
Chungsc@stepi.re.kr
Korea has transformed itself from a stagnant agrarian society into one of the most dynamic
industrial economies of the world within four decades. In the early 1960s when Korea first
launched its industrialization efforts, it was a typical poor developing country with poor
resource and production base, small domestic market, and a large population. Korea’s GNP in
1961 was only $ 2.3 billion (in 1980 prices) or $87 per capita which came mainly from the
primary sectors. 2 The manufacturing sector’s share in GNP remained at a mere 15%.
International trade was also at a very infant stage: in 1961, Korea’s export volume was only $55
million and imports $390 million. But it is now 13th largest economy and one of the major
trading countries of the world. It has also established world prominence in such technology
areas as semi-conductors, LCD, telecommunication equipment, automobiles, shipbuilding, and
so on. Indeed, it has emerged from nowhere as one of the key international players in the global
economy.
Some say that in three decades, Korea has achieved what it took more than a century for the
Western industrial countries to accomplish. There exist rich literatures on Korean growth that
attribute the Korean success to an assortment of diverse factors. But many seem to agree that
Korean government’s “outward-looking development strategy,” well-educated and well-
1
A first draft. Only for discussion at the ABCDE Seoul.
2
Korea is a very small, resource-poor country: its land area is only 220 thousand square kilometers or 99
thousand square kilometers if we exclude the northern part, which is currently under a different political and
economic system. Korea’s land, of which 75% is non-arable mountains, produces not a single drop of oil and
contains virtually no valuable natural resources. Still it has to support a population of 70 million people.
1
disciplined work force, and technological innovation have been well combined to bring about
what they call “Korean Miracle.”
Of the three factors, this paper focuses on the role of technological innovation. If
technological innovation was the key factor, one may ask: What stimulated and facilitated
Korean industries to engage so actively in R&D and innovation; and to what extent
technological innovation has contributed to improving the competitiveness of Korean industries
and to the growth of the economy. This paper discusses these issues, with a view to drawing
some lessons from the Korean development experiences. Toward this end, this paper start with a
review of what Korea has done to learn and acquire technologies for industrialization, and how
Korea has been able to promote R&D and innovation and build up technological capability. And
then we analyze the contribution of R&D and innovation to industrial competitiveness and
economic growth in Korea. Finally, we draw some lessons for late-comers from the Korean
experiences.
3
The number here is an estimate based on the figure for 1969, which was 5,337 (MOST 1984)
2
education and scholarship. 4
Under such a setting, Korea launched the First Five-Year Economic Development Plan in
1962, which along with the subsequent plans generated huge demand for new technologies. As
Korea lacked in technological capability, it had to rely almost completely on foreign sources for
technologies. Korea’s policy strategy was geared to promoting the inward transfer of foreign
technologies, while, at the same time, developing domestic absorptive capacity to digest,
assimilate and improve upon the transferred technologies.
4
However, the Confucianism may have adverse effects on the development of science and technology in
Korea: it stresses patriotism and demands loyalty to the traditional values and, therefore, tends to devalue new,
unconventional ideas. The Korean society, like other Confucian societies, is less open to different ideas and
systems, which works as a barrier to innovation.
5
Foreign investors also did not view Korea as an attractive place for investment. Even though Korea took a very
open and liberal policy on direct foreign investment in the 1960s, few investments were made primarily because of
3
the 1960s, simply could not afford to buy technologies from foreign sources. It is quite
understandable that a country with a per capita GNP of $ 87 (1962) and annual export revenue
of only $ 55 million (1962) took such a restrictive policy on FL which very often entails long-
term financial commitment.
As an alternative, Korea opted for long-term foreign loans to finance industrial investments.
The Korean government brought in large-scale foreign loans and allocated them for investments
in selected industries, which led to massive importation of foreign capital goods and turn-key
plants. Industries later reverse-engineered imported capital goods for the purpose of acquiring
necessary technologies. This policy contributed to the formation of a unique business
conglomerate called “Chaebol.” The government selected not only the target industries for
investment but also the entrepreneurs who would actually implement the new investment
projects, and some of those selected entrepreneurs later became owners of the “Chaebols.” So,
we can say that the FDI policy has much to do with the evolution of the unique industrial
structure of Korea.
4
largely upon turn-key plant importation, which included technical training programs as part of
the packages. In the case of heavy machinery, FL was an important channel for technology
acquisition. (Chung and Branscomb 1996) To help industries adopt new technologies, the
government created GRIs in the fields of heavy machinery and chemicals, such as the Korea
Institute of Machinery and Metals (KIMM), the Electronics and Telecommunications Research
Institute (ETRI), the Korea Research Institute of Chemical Technology (KRICT), the Korea
Research Institute of Standards and Science (KRISS), the Korea Institute for Energy Research
(KIER), the Korea Ocean R&D Institute (KORDI), etc. These institutes worked with private
industries in building technological foundation for industrial development.
As a result, FDI had minimal impact on the Korean economy. For example, FDI accounted
for only 3.9% of the cumulative total of long-term foreign capital in Korea over the period of
1962-1982 ($ 9 billion). According to a United Nations report, FDI in all developing countries
in the early and mid-1970s accounted for 10-20% of their total foreign capital inflow. Over the
period of 1962-1972, FDI inflow in Korea remained at $ 223 million, while capital goods import
reached $ 2,857 million. (Ahn 1991)
In short, Korean industries depended more on informal channels for technology acquisition
than formal channels. As informal channels involve less market mediation and more active roles
of technology recipients, they are less costly but require higher capability of technology
recipients in not just identifying and selecting technologies but also absorbing, assimilating and
improving upon the transferred technologies. 6 This means that Korea has been able to succeed
in acquiring technologies for industrialization largely owing to the rich pool of well-educated
people who are determined to work for the betterment of their lives.
6
For more discussions on the roles of technology suppliers and recipients in different modes of technology transfer,
see Kim (1997) pp. 100-103.
5
Technology Promotion Act and the Science Education Act were enacted in 1967 as a legal base
for government’s policies for S&T development. In the same year, the government established
the Korea Institute of Science and Technology (KIST), and in the following year, the Ministry
of Science and Technology (MOST) was created as the central government agency responsible
for S&T policy. In 1970, the government enacted the Korea Advanced Institute of Sciences Act,
on the basis of which the Korea Advanced Institute of Sciences (KAIS; currently KAIST) was
founded. KIST was the first organization in Korea for R&D in a strict sense, while KAIS first
brought US graduate education system into Korea. It was also in the 1970s that various GRIs
were established to assist industries in absorbing and assimilating technologies. In the early
stage of the development, these institutions did two important contributions: first, as mentioned
earlier, they helped industries acquire new technologies, and second, they contributed to the
building up of indigenous R&D capability by bringing back many established scientists and
engineers from abroad.
6
operation. 7 The most important lesson here is that had it not been for the well-educated work
force, it would not have been possible for Korea to succeed in acquiring and utilizing
technologies through informal modes of technology transfer.
7
Another negative effect is that large-scale loans that had been brought in instead of FDI might have contributed to
the financial crisis of 1997 (Chung and Suh 2005)
7
massive way. As a result, the relationship between technology imports and R&D changed. The
ratio of technology imports to business R&D declined sharply from about 90% in 1975 to 30%
in the mid-1980s. 8 This implies that by that time Korean industries turned to indigenous R&D
for technology acquisition. R&D investment has since undergone a quantum jump. Korea’s
R&D investment, which stood at only 368.8 billion Won ($526 million, 0.81 % GDP) in 1981,
rose to 10,878 billion Won ($13.5 billion, 2.8% of GNP) in 1996, to 13,848 billion Won ($12.2
billion, 2.7% of GDP) in 2000, and to 31,301.4 billion Won ($33.7 billion, 3.47% of GDP) in
2007. Over a period of twenty-five years, investment in R&D increased over sixty times.
Korea invests in R&D a lot more of its income than others with the same or higher income.
Korea now is the 6th largest spender in R&D among OECD countries.
35000 4
30000 3.5
3
25000
2.5
Billion Won
20000
R&D Investment
2
GDP Ratio
15000
1.5
10000
1
5000 0.5
0 0
63 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 02 04 06 07
Year
8
OECD (1996) pp. 91-92; Ratio of technology imports to business R&D was 15% in 2007. (KOITA 2008)
8
90
80
70
60
Gov
50
Pri
%
40
30
20
10
0
1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2007
9
R&D in a few industries.
The average R&D intensity of Korean industries was 2.43% in 2007, and that of
manufacturing industries was 2.97%. The industries that invested largest shares of their sales
in R&D include medical and precision equipment (7.5%), communication equipment (6.71%),
and electronic components (6.33%). In contrast, constructions, pulp and paper industries, food
and beverages, textile industries invested less than 1% of their sales in R&D. (Table 2)
Quite naturally, industrial research is very much focused on development (72%) and applied
research (12.6%) with the remaining 12.6% devoted to basic research. Of the total industrial
R&D, 80% were for new product development, while only 20% were for the improvement or
development of processes.
Industrial R&D activities in Korea are highly concentrated in large enterprises. Twenty
largest companies account for 55.73% of the total manufacturing R&D, top ten companies
50.2%, and top five companies 44.3%. In the case of electronic components, top 20 companies’
share is 91.4%. (Table 3) The extremely high concentration of industrial R&D is a direct
reflection of the large-firm oriented industrial structure of Korea. Top five companies in R&D
investments are Samsung Electronics, LG Electronics, Hyundai Motors, Hynix, and GM
Daewoo Auto and Technology, all of which are Chaebol companies.
Another unique feature is that the participation of foreign funds and institutions in R&D and
innovation in Korea is very limited. Probably due to the once restrictive FDI policy, foreign
funds seldom flow into Korea for industrial R&D. The proportion of foreign funds in Korea’s
industrial R&D expenditures remains at 0.3%, while in many of the OECD countries, foreign
funds accounts for more than 10% of the domestic industrial R&D outlays. (OECD MSTI,
OECD STI Scoreboard) Considering the fact that Korea is one of the major trading countries
in the world, it is rather against expectation that Korea’s international interaction in research and
technology remains at such a level.
10
Table 2 Manufacturing R&D, 2007
1997 to 797.2 billion Won in 1998 and R&D personnel by 15% from 102 thousand in 1997 to
87 thousand in the next year. This was a serious blow to the Korean innovation system. If
the crisis had continued several more years, the Korean innovation system would have collapsed.
Fortunately, however, Korea recovered from the crisis in a relatively short period of time: it
took only two years for the industrial R&D to recover and rise over the level prior to the
11
financial crisis. There are two factors behind this development: one is the government’s efforts
to make up for the decrease in industrial R&D expenditures by increasing government R&D
expenditures. The share of government in the gross R&D expenditures increased from less
than 20% before the crisis to 27% after the crisis. Government R&D funds flew into private
industrial sectors, in particular, small technology-based firms and helped them maintain and
expand innovation activities. The other is the promotion of IT and IT-related ventures that led
to an IT boom in the early 2000s. The government’s commitment to IT development is well
reflected in the fact that the share of IT in government R&D expenditures rose to 33.5% in 2002
from 13% in 1997. Such a pro-IT policy fuelled innovation in IT sector, which then affected
innovation activities in other sectors. This policy not just helped the Korean innovation system
recover vitality but also resulted in promoting Korea’s transition toward an information society.
What Are the Factors behind the Rapid Growth of R&D and Innovation?
There are many factors that have contributed to the rapid increases in private sector R&D
investments. But the rapid growth in R&D expenditures can be explained by two sets of factors
– demand factors and supply factors. On the demand side, market competition placed
tremendous pressure on Korean industries for technological competitiveness. Such pressure
generated continuous demand for R&D and innovation. On the supply side, Korean industries
have been able to meet the increasing demand for R&D and innovation because they have been
financially able to do so and also because their investments have been backed up by well-trained
human resources. The government contributed to such a development in several indirect ways.
12
it invests in R&D and innovation. A recent study at the Science and Technology Policy Institute
(STEPI) has confirmed the relationship using the Korean Innovation Survey (KIS) data. 9 The
empirical study shows that companies with higher export intensity (export volume/total sales)
tend to invest more in R&D and innovation. (Shin and others 2006) The study also found that
there exists a negative relationship between innovation activities and market concentration. In
other words, the study confirmed that companies operating in a more competitive market invest
more in R&D and innovation. This study seems to say that international competition motivates
companies to invest in innovation. But a reverse relationship may hold, too, as more
innovative companies are more likely to win international competition and sell more in the
international markets. In that sense, we can say that the two are mutually reinforcing and so the
effects of one on the other are determined simultaneously.
9
The survey (KIS 2005) covers 2,737 companies of 23 industries for the period from 2002 to 2004. The survey
follow the OECD Manual and has been authorized as a national statistics by the National Statistics Administration
of Korea.
13
therefore, they can be quicker in responding to emerging opportunities.
There have been many attempts to verify the arguments, but there are only a few studies that
directly investigate the differences in innovation behavior between companies belonging to
Chaebols and independent companies. Recently, a group of researchers at STEPI conducted a
research on this issue using the data-base of the Korea Information Service Inc covering 51,270
observations for the period of 1987-2003. (Shin and others 2006) Of the total observations,
2,064 are for Chaebol companies. The study divided the period into two – one before the
financial crisis (1987-1997) and the other after the crisis (2000-2003), because the government
changed the regulation governing the Chaebol system during the period of the economic crisis.
The new regulation bans cross- financing and cross-investment between and among Chaebol
companies, and, therefore, pooling financial resources and sharing financial risks between and
among Chaebol companies have become impossible. In other words, the Chaebol in the original
sense disappeared around the end of the 1990s.
The statistical analysis for the pre-crisis period shows that Chaebol companies are more able
and more likely to invest in R&D than independent companies. But the analysis for the post-
crisis period could not find any statistically significant differences in innovation behavior
between Chaebol companies and independent companies. This supports the argument perception
that Chaebol companies which are usually big international operators, have deeper pockets and
are able to engage in risky and expensive R&D projects that are even unthinkable for small- and
medium-sized firms.
14
human resource development. 10
Government support programs
No less important is the policy supports of the government for industrial R&D and
innovation. In order to promote private innovation, the Korean government, like many others,
offers various forms of incentives for industrial R&D and innovation. 11 Overall, Korea employs
grants and tax credits as the major instruments to promote industrial R&D which are
complemented by such support programs as procurement, technical consultancy, information,
technology transfer and so on. According to a recent survey, there are currently more than 250
small and large programs to support private R&D and innovation. (Shin and others 2006)
How effective those programs have been in promoting industrial R&D is an issue of great
concern. There have been a few attempts to evaluate the effectiveness of the policy programs. 12
In order to evaluate the policy programs, quantitative assessments on each of the programs is
most desired. But full-scale quantitative analysis is not practically possible due to the lack of
data. In 2006, STEPI undertook a survey of private industries to assess the effectiveness of the
government incentive programs. Using the results of the survey and the Korean Innovation
Survey (KIS 2005) data, they conducted econometric and statistical analyses. Interestingly, the
survey results and the econometric analysis using the KIS data showed a very similar result that
all categories of support programs have been effective in promoting private R&D and
innovation except for the procurement program. The econometric analysis further found the tax
incentive most effective, followed by loan program, human resource program, and technical
consultancy and so on. This is also consistent with the OECD evaluation that “Tax incentives
for R&D in Korea are generous and cover every stage: facility investment, R&D outlays,
10
There are cases where R&D investments are constrained by the shortage of suitable manpower. OECD (2003)
emphasizes the importance of the supply of skilled scientists and engineers as one of the framework conditions for
achieving R&D spending target.
11
The major legal bases for the incentives are the Technology Development Promotion Law (1967) and the
Industrial Development Promotion Law.
12
For example, Lee and Jang (1998), Song(2007), and Shin(2006)
15
technology transfer…” (Bae and Jones 2005) 13
made simpler and easier to13 Despite the overall effectiveness of the programs, the STEPI study assesses
that the numerous and diverse programs are so well understood by the potential users and need to be access.(STEPI
2006)
14
Albert (1998)
16
publications by Koreans reported by the Science Citation Index (SCI) increased from a mere
171 in 1980, 5,390 in 1995, 23,099 in 2005, and 25,494 in 2007. Korea now is the 12th largest
producer of SCI publications, which should be considered a phenomenal growth. (See Table 6)
R&D efforts have also contributed to the development of high-tech industries in Korea.
Korea’s technological competitiveness in semi-conductors, displays, cellular phones, computers,
telecommunication equipments and so on are partly the results of the government-industry
collaborative R&D. Considering the contribution of these technologies to the Korean exports
and economic growth, we can get a rough idea on the relationship between R&D and innovation
and the socio-economic changes in Korea.
Even though Korea acquired technological competitiveness in many of high-tech products,
its reliance on foreign core technology has not been reduced in s substantial way. For example,
Korea succeeded in commercializing the CDMA technology, but the Korean cellular phone
manufacturers have had to pay a cumulative royalty of over 5 trillion Won to Qualcomm over
the period from 1995 to 2008. (NSTC and KISTEP) So, Korea’s overseas royalty payments are
concentrated in the areas where Korea is known to have international competitiveness. It is
simply because Korea’s industrial R&D and innovation have been focused too much on
commercializing foreign technologies rather than on developing new original technologies, such
as new materials, components, devices or designs.
17
Rank in the world - 9 - - 7 4
Source: USPTO
15
We follow here the OECD categorization of high-tech, high-medium-tech, medium-low-tech, and low-tech.
18
Individual industry’s contribution to exports has also changed drastically during the period
from 1990 to 2007. In the case of the primary and light industries, their shares in the total
exports have declined in a massive way. The primary industry’s share has gone down from 4.9%
to 1.5%, and textiles’ share from 26.7% down to 3.7%. On the other hand, the shares of high-
tech products have risen significantly during the period. In particular, precision machineries,
telecommunication equipments, displays and automobiles account for almost 40% of the total
exports of Korea. The highly concentrated export structure of Korea is a kind of reflection of the
highly concentrated distribution of Korea’s R&D expenditures and highly concentrated patents.
Of the Korean patents registered in 2006 (KOITA 2008), electronics and communications took
up 54.2% and machineries 15.0%, which is consistent with the data on Korean industrial R&D
expenditures which are concentrated in a few industries such as telecommunications,
transportation and so on. What is evident is that R&D-intensive industries have gained in their
market shares, while low-R&D industries have lost their pace in the international markets. This
is also confirmed by WTO data which show that Korea’s world market share has been increased
remarkably in technology-intensive products, such as office machineries, telecommunication
equipments, automotive parts and chemicals. (WTO ) Interestingly, in those areas, R&D
investments have also increased significantly in Korea. 16
16
In the case of office machinery, the ratio of R&D expenditures to sales has increased from 4.74% to 6.05% in
Korea during 1990-2007, contributing to the increase in its share in world trade from 2% in 1980 to 6.1% in 2007.
More contrasting is the case of telecommunication equipments, where R&D intensity has also increased from
3.05% to 6.52% over the same period and this contributed to the change in its share in world trade from 0 in 1980
to 7.2% in 2007.
19
4 Synthetic fiber Ships Cell phones Ships
5 Audio Video Synthetic fiber Petroleum prod
6 Tire Iron and steel Auto parts Displays
7 Wooden prod Synthetic fiber Display Auto parts
8 Misc goods Computers Telecom equip Computer
9 Semi-conductors Audio Computer Visual inst
10 Video Automobiles Color TV Electro parts
Source: Korea International Trade Association
20
How Much R&D and Innovation Have Contributed to Economic Growth?
It is hard to estimate how much investments in R&D and innovation have contributed
to economic growth, because it involves many complex data and methodological issues.
One widely used method of measuring this was first suggested by Grilliches (1984) who
calculated the growth rate of total factor productivity (TFP) and related this to the changes
in R&D stock to measure the R&D elasticity of TFP. His estimates of R&D elasticity of
TFP ranged between 0.17 and 0.34. Coe and Helpman (1995) conducted the same
experiments using 22 OECD country data for the period of 1971-1990. They found that
the elasticity for G-7 countries was 0.234, but the estimated elasticity for OECD countries
was only 0.07, which suggests that R&D investments of G-7 countries were a lot more
efficient than those of OECD countries.
Similar attempts have been made to measure the R&D elasticity of TFP in Korea.
Kim (2004) estimated R&D elasticity of TFP in Korea for the period of 1970-2002 to be
0.13, while an earlier study by Shin (1996) came up with a higher number, 0.166. More
recently, Shin and others (2007) estimated R&D elasticities of individual OCED countries
and found that Japan is the most efficient (elasticity: 0.278-0.292) in terms of economic
contribution of R&D, followed by the US (elasticity: 0.167-0.263), and Korea (elasticity:
0.133-0.199). The elasticity for Korea turned out to be almost the same as the average
elasticity for all OECD countries (0.188). This suggests that R&D in Korea has performed
relatively well in enhancing the productivity of the economy.
There is a very interesting study in Korea (Lee and others 2007) that estimated the
R&D elasticity separately for high-tech, high-medium-tech, medium-low-tech, and low-
tech industry. They found that R&D elasticity of TFP for high-tech industry was 0.32 and
that for high-medium tech industry 0.10. But they found, interestingly, in medium-low-
tech, and low-tech industries, TFP does not respond to changes in R&D stocks, that is,
R&D does not affect the productivities in those industries.
Many economists use aggregate production function to estimate the contribution of
R&D stock to economic growth. The results of estimations vary depending on the periods
covered, data, and methods. A recent study (Lee 2008) in Korea estimates that R&D stock
accounts for 22.7% of the economic growth during the period of 1971-1990. According
21
to the study, R&D stock’s contribution to economic growth has been increasing along
with economic development. The share of R&D stock in the economic growth during the
period 1991-2006 was estimated to be 29.9%. But sometimes, study results vary too
widely to reconcile. For example, according to Hah (2004), R&D stock explains 48% of
the growth of TFP, while Bae and others (2006) came up with a result that the contribution
of R&D stock to TFP growth amounts to 82% which is much higher than that suggested
by Hah.
22
government to “technology-based national development” and private industries’ efforts for
competitiveness. Despite the short history of R&D, Korea has already harvested rich crops from
the endeavor in the forms of patents, scientific papers, and exports of technology-intensive
products, such as semiconductors, cellular phones, LCD, automobiles, and others. These
achievements have been the sources of growth in the past and will function as a base for further
growth in the future.
23
Fourth, the Korean innovation system needs to be made more open to the outer world.
Korea accounts for about 3% of the world R&D activities, which means that 97% of the world’s
R&D activities are taking place outside Korea. In order to access to the new knowledge, ideas
and technology generated and produced outside the country, Korea need to open the system
more and promote interactions with foreign scientists and institutions. The current level of
international interaction of Korea, which is the lowest among OECD countries, if not checked,
will work as a barrier to further growth of Korea into the future.
Fifth, the extremely high concentration of R&D activities poses a serious problem. High
concentration means that only a few large firms are actively involved in R&D, while others are
not. If this persists for long, this will dichotomize Korean industries into technologically
advanced and retarded firms and sectors. This will result in reducing inter-firm and inter-
industry interactions that are the key elements of innovation. This is important because even
Chaebol companies would not be able to sustain competitiveness without technologically strong
domestic SMEs.
24
investment in education, further promoting demand for education.
Korea’s industrialization evolved from imitation to innovation. In the initial stage, Korean
industries attained technological capability through informal channels for technology transfer,
such as OEM production arrangements, reverse engineering of imported machines, technical
training as part of turn-key plant importation, and so on. Contrary to the experiences of other
developing countries, FDI played a modest role in technological learning in the course of
development in Korea. To lay the initial technological foundation, many Korean industries
resorted to non-market processes, relying on the technological absorptive capacity of their
workers for technology acquisition. This approach enabled them to acquire technology at
lower cost and maintain independence in business operation. But Korea had to pay a great cost
for this – it had to abandon many of the technological opportunities that foreign direct investors
might have offered.
By adopting an outward-looking development strategy, the government drove Korean
industries out into competitive international market, putting them under great pressure for
technological learning and/or development. Korean industries responded to such pressures by
investing heavily in technology development. By developing technological competence, they
have been able to survive international competition, and establish world prominence in such
high-technology areas as telecommunications, semi-conductor memory chips, LCD,
automobiles, shipbuilding, and so on. Protectionist policy may be effective in creating initial
market opportunities for domestic industries, but if such a policy is prolonged, industries will
develop immunity against market pressure for innovation. It may be for this reason that
export-oriented firms achieved technological learning more rapidly than import-substituting
firms
Since the early 1960s, the government has played a key role in Korea’s development. The
government first initiated science and technology development as part of the national economic
development plan, and has led the development, not just as a rule-setter but also as a target-
setter as well as a financier. But as industrial development proceeds, it has become increasingly
difficult for the government to intervene in economic as well as R&D activities because of the
increased scale and complexity of industrial activities. Therefore, the pattern of government
intervention in science and technology had to change from direct involvement as a target-setter
25
and commander-in-chief type leader to indirect involvement as a facilitator and promoter
In sum, Korea owes very much to its human resource and the outward-looking
development strategy for the technological development and industrialization. Two major
lessons form the Korean experiences are: First, human resource is the key to science and
technology development and thus to economic growth, and second, nothing can better motivate
private businesses to invest in technology development than market competition. But for
Korea to sustain the past development into the future, it has to further strengthen basic scientific
research capability and improve framework conditions for innovation, the core of which is
competitive market.
References
Albert, M.B. 1998, The New Innovators: Global Patenting Trends in Five Sectors,
US Department of Commerce, Washington DC
Amsden, A. 1989, Asia’s Next Giant, South Korea and Late Industrialization, Oxford:
University Press
Ahn, Choong-Yong. 1991, “Technology Transfer and Economic Development: the Case
of Korea,” in Minden, K. (Ed), Pacific Cooperation in Science and
Technology, Honolulu: East West Center,
Bae, Y. and Jones, R.S. 2005. “Sustaining High Growth through Innovation, Reforming
the R&D and Education System in Korea,” OECD Economics Department
Working Paper No 470, OECD, Paris
Bae, Y. and others. 2006. Innovation Strategy for Growth and Job Creation, STEPI Policy
Report 06-05, STEPI, Seoul (Koran)
Cantwell, J. 2003. “Innovation, Competitiveness and Growth,” Chapter 21 in Fargerberg,
J., D. C. Mowery, R. R. Nelson (Eds), Handbook of Innovation, Oxford:
Oxford University Press
Chung SC and L.M. Branscomb. 1996, “Technology Transfer and International
26
Cooperation,” in Branscomb and Choi (Ed), Korea at the Turning Point,
Westport: Praeger
Chung SC and J. Jang. 1993, Gisul Gaebal Tujaeu Kyungjejok Hyogwa Bunsuk (The
Economic Effects of R&D), Policy research 93-04, STEPI, Seoul (Korean)
Cohen, D. and M. Soto. 2001, “Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results,”
Technical Paper No. 179, OECD Development Center, Paris
Grilliches, Zvi., and F. Lichtenberg. 1984. “R&D and Productivity Growth at the Industry
LevelL Is there still a relationship?,” Zvi Grilliches (Ed) R&D, Patents, and
Productivity, Chicago: Chicago University Press
Hah, J. 2004. “Analysis of the Economic Effects of R&D,” Kyung-je Bun-suk, Kora
Financial Institute, Seoul (Korean)
Hobday, M. 1995, Innovation in East Asia: The Challenge to Japan, Aldershot: Edward
Elgar,
KEDI(various years), Educational Statistical Yearbook, KEDI, Seoul
Kim, Linsu. 1997, Imitation to Innovation, The Dynamics of Korea’s Technological
Learning, Cambbridge: Harvard Business School Press
Kim, L. and C. Dahlman. 1992, “Technology Policy for Industrialization: An Integrative
Framework and Korea’s Experience,” Research Policy (21), 437-452
Kim,W. 2004. Possibility of Productivity Loss Due to Ageing Population and Policy
Implications,” San-up-Kyung-je-Wol-bo No 329 (Korean)
Kim, Young-Gul (1996), “Innovation and the Role of Korea’s Universities,” in
Branscomb, L. and Y. Choi (Ed), Korea at the Turning Point, West Port:
Praeger,
KOITA (various years), Major Indicators of Industrial Technology, Seoul
Koo, Bohn-Young (1986), “Role of Government in Korea’s Industrial Development,” in
Lee, K. (Ed), Industrial Development Policies and Issues, KDI, Seoul
Lee, W-Y and J. Jang (1998), Sanup Gisul Gaebal Jiwon Jedoeu Jonghap Pyonggawa
Gaesun Bangan (Evaluation of the Government Supports for Industrial
Innovation and Policy Implication), Policy research 98-10, STEPI,
Seoul (Korean)
27
Lee, W. and others 2007. Technological Innovation Strategy and Policy Agenda to
Strengthen Economic Growth Potential, STEPI Policy Report 07-12, STEPI,
Seoul (Korean)
Leipziger, D.M. and V. Thomas. 1993, The Lessons of East Asia, An Overview of
Country Experiences, World Bank, Washington, DC
MOST (various years), Report on the Survey of R&D in Science and Technology,
Seoul
_____ 1997, Tukjung Yongu Gaebal Saub Shihaeng 15 Nyun (Fifteen Years of the
National R&D Program), Seoul (Korean)
______2004, 2004 Gisul Hyuksin Jiwon Jedo (Support programs to promote innovation)
, MOST, Seoul (Korean)
NSTC. 2004, “2005Nyundo Gukka Yungu Gaebal Tuja Usun Sunwi Suljung Yungu”
(National R&D Priority Setting for the Year 2005) (Korean), NSTC, Seoul
Nadiri, I.M. 1993, “Output and Labor Productivity, R&D Expenditure and Catch-up
Scenarios: A Comparison of the US, Japanese, and Korean Manufacturing
Sectors,” Mimeo, Department of Economics, New York University
OECD .1996, Review of National Science and Technology Policy, Republic of Korea,
OECD, Paris
_____ 2003, “Meeting R&D Funding Targets: Policy Implications,” DSTI/STP (2003)2,
OECD, Paris
Shin, T. and others. 2006. The Determinants of Technological Innovation in
Manufacturing Industries and Policy Implications, Policy Report 2006-02,
STEPT, Seoul (Korean)
Shin, T. and others. 20-6. A Comprehensive Appraisal of Policy Support Programs for
Technological Innovation, STEPI Policy Report 2006-04. STEPI, Seoul
Shin, T. 1996. Economic Impacts of R&D Budgets, STEPI policy paper 96-07, STEPI,
Seoul (Korean)
Song, Byung-Nak .1990, The Rise of Korean Economy, Hong Kong: Oxford University
Press
Stewart, F. 1978, Technology and Underdevelopment, London: Macmillan
28
Vernon, R. 1977, Storm over Multinationals, Cambridge: Harvard University Press
Websites: USPTO, WTO, KIPO, KOITA, KITA
29